CS计算机代考程序代写 LECTURE 5:

LECTURE 5:
EXPECTATIONS, UNCERTAINTY, AND ASSET HOLDINGS
Reading:
• William A. Lord (2002), Household Dynamics: Economic Growth and Policy, Chapters 2 (Section 2.2)
1

1. INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND

INTRODUCTION AND BACKGROUND
In this lecture we will:
• Introduce economic uncertainty
• Study household consumption and savings decisions under uncertainty • Understand the precautionary savings motive
• Study the relationship between asset prices and risk
2

BACKGROUND ON ECONOMIC RISK
• A major feature of economic life is the presence of uncertainty and risk • We all face many different risks to our economic outcomes:
• Unemployment, income, unexpected expenses, health, death, etc
• Households must make consumption and savings decisions taking these risks into account • As we will see, these risks affect both asset holdings and asset prices
3

ECONOMIC RISKS: DEATH RISK BY AGE
4

ECONOMIC RISKS: UNEMPLOYMENT RISK BY AGE
Source: US Bureau of Labor Statistics, https://www.bls.gov/web/empsit/cpseea10.htm 5

ECONOMIC RISKS: EARNINGS RISK BY INCOME RANK
Source: Guvenen, Schulhoffer-Wohl, Song, and Yogo (2017), Worker Betas: Five Facts About Systematic Earnings Risk
6

2. RISK AVERSION AND THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE

CONCEPTS: RISK AVERSION AND PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS
• Risk aversion: a tendency to prefer economic outcomes with low uncertainty to those with more uncertainty
• Precautionary Savings: an increase in income uncertainty that leaves expected income unchanged reduces current consumption. But savings increase as a form of self insurance against low income states of the world.
• Expected income = probability-weighted average of possible incomes • E.g. E(y) = αy1 +(1−α)y2
7

CONCEPTS: RISK AVERSION AND PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS
• Risk aversion is a consequence of diminishing marginal utility • For utility function u(·), then u′ > 0 and u′′ < 0 • Implies a loss of $x matters more than a gain of $x • A risk averse agent would turn down a fair bet with even odds of an increase of x or a decrease in x • But risk aversion does not tell us how an agent responds to uncertainty or risk 8 CONCEPTS: RISK AVERSION AND PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS • Precautionary Savings is a result of marginal utility declining at a decreasing rate: • For utility function u(·), then u′′′ > 0
• This feature of utility functions/preferences is sometimes called prudence
• In this case, an increase in income uncertainty (holding expected income constant) raises expected marginal utility
• This means that the value of additional consumption is higher, which means that households save more in order to consume more in the periods of heightened uncertainty
• These additional savings in the face of greater uncertainty are called precautionary savings
9

3. THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE:
AN ILLUSTRATIVE MODEL

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• Let’s begin with the standard model from earlier lectures
• A household makes consumption and savings decisions, subject to known and constant
incomes
• Assume β = 1, return on savings is zero (r = 0), income in each period is Y ̄, utility function
u′ >0,u′′ <0,u′′′ >0
max u(C1) + u(C2) C1 ,C2
s.t. C1+C2=Y ̄+Y ̄
• The first order condition yields the optimality condition (Euler Equation):
u′(C1) = u′(C2) ⇒ C 1 = C 2 = Y ̄
• Label these consumption choices Cc1 and Cc2 for the choices under certainty
10

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• Now suppose there are different states of the world
• These states affect income in period 2, with a chance of a good outcome and a chance of a
bad outcome
Y2 =
􏰤
Y ̄ + x with probability 0.5 Y ̄ − x with probability 0.5
(Good Outcome) (Bad Outcome)
• The expected value of period 2 income is:
E ( Y 2 ) = 0 . 5 ( Y ̄ + x ) + 0 . 5 ( Y ̄ − x ) = Y ̄
• Which is the same as period 2 income under the model with certainty
11

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• So the household now chooses consumption and savings to maximize expected utility: max u(C1) + E(u(C2))
C1 ,C2 ,S
s.t. C1+S=Y ̄
C2 = Y2 + S
• where consumption in period 2 is uncertain because it depends on the realization of income in period 2:
􏰤
C2 =
Y ̄ + x + S Y ̄ − x + S
with probability 0.5 with probability 0.5
(Good Outcome) (Bad Outcome)
12

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• The first order condition in this case yields the Expected Euler Equation: u′(C1) = E(u′(C2))
• Where E(u′(C2)) is the expectation over marginal utility of consumption in period 2 • Note that we can compute this as:
E(u′(C2)) = 0.5 × u′(C2(good)) + 0.5 × u′(C2(bad)) = 0 . 5 × u ′ ( Y ̄ + x + S ) + 0 . 5 × u ′ ( Y ̄ − x + S )
13

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• Suppose the household were to choose period 1 consumption the same as under the certainty case: C1 = Cc1 = Y ̄
• Then from the period 1 budget constraint, savings are: S = Y ̄ − Cc1
• And we can write consumption in period two as:
C2 = Y2 + S
= Y 2 + Y ̄ − C c1
􏰤Y ̄ + x + Y ̄ − Cc1 with probability 0.5 = Y ̄ − x + Y ̄ − Cc1 with probability 0.5
􏰤Cc2 + x with probability 0.5 = Cc2 − x with probability 0.5
• If choosing the certainty consumption in period 1, period 2 consumption is equal to the certainty consumption (Cc2) plus or minus the uncertain component of income x
14

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• Now, write the expected marginal utility of consumption in period 2 as: E(u′(C2)) = 0.5 × u′(Cc2 + x) + 0.5 × u′(Cc2 − x)
≥ u′(Cc2)
• Because u′′′ > 0, the expected marginal utility of consumption in the uncertain case is greater than marginal utility in the certain case
• This means that the value of the certain consumption choice is greater than the value of the uncertain consumption outcomes
• Another way: households prefer certainty to uncertainty, even when the expected value of outcomes is the same in both cases
Technical Note: We can prove this inequality using the properties of convex functions and Jensen’s inequality. This is not required knowledge for this class.
15

GRAPHICAL ILLUSTRATION OF THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
u′, E(u′)
u′(Cc1) = u′(Cc2) (A) 􏰄 􏰃􏰂 􏰅
Euler Equation
u′(C2) Cc2 C2
16

GRAPHICAL ILLUSTRATION OF THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
u′, E(u′)
u ′ ( C c2 − x ) u′(Cc) = u′(Cc)
(1)
(A)
12 (2)
u ′ ( C c2 + x )
C c2 − x C c2 = E ( C 2 ) C c2 + x
u ′ ( C 2 )
C 2
17

GRAPHICAL ILLUSTRATION OF THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
u′, E(u′)
u ′ ( C c2 − x ) E(u′ (C2 ))
(1)
(B)
(A)
12 (2)
u′(Cc) = u′(Cc) u ′ ( C c2 + x )
C c2 − x C c2 = E ( C 2 ) C c2 + x • Notice that: E(u′(C2)) > u′(Cc2) = u′(Cc1)
Euler Equation
• Therefore: increase C2, decrease C1, higher (precautionary) savings S
u ′ ( C 2 )
C 2
􏰄 􏰃􏰂 􏰅
18

A MODEL WITH THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE
• Point (A) corresponds to marginal utility of the certain consumption Cc2
• Recall that this is the optimal consumption choice for the certainty case: u′(Cc1) = u′(Cc2)
• Point (B) is the expected marginal utility over consumption in the uncertain case: E(u′(C2)) • Note that E(u′(C2)) > u′(Cc2) = u′(Cc1)
• This means that consumption is too low in period 2 (i.e. marginal utility is too high)
• Therefore, the household should consume less in period 1: Cu1 < Cc1 • This allows household to save more and so consume more in period 2: Cu2 (s) > Cc2 (s)
19

PRECAUTIONARY SAVING IN THE MACROECONOMY: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
• Does greater uncertainty really lead to more savings?
20

PRECAUTIONARY SAVING IN THE MACROECONOMY: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Equity Market
Volatility Tracker
(Bloom et al., 2019; scaled)
Real Consumption Growth
Equity Market
Volatility Tracker
(Bloom et al., 2019; scaled)
Real Savings Growth
15 10 5 0 −5 −10 −15
150
100
50
0
−50
1992 1996 2000 2004
2008 2012
2016 2020
1992 1996 2000
2004 2008 2012 2016
2020 21

4. PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES

PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
• The main lesson from the precautionary savings model:
• An increase in uncertainty increases demand for savings/assets
• But if asset demand increases, what happens to asset prices?
22

A MODEL OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
• Consider our two-period model:
• Where a one period bond B can be purchased at price Pb
• And again:
Y2 =
􏰤
Y ̄ + x Y ̄ − x
with probability 0.5 with probability 0.5
Pbu′(C1) = βE(u′(C2)) ⇒ Pb = β E(u′(C2))
(Good Outcome) (Bad Outcome)
• The first order condition yields:
max u(C1) + βE(u(C2)) C1 ,C2 ,B
s.t. C1+PbB=Y ̄ C2 = Y2 + B
u′(C1) • This is referred to as an asset pricing equation
23
• Asset prices given by the marginal rate of substitution between consumption across periods

A MODEL OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
• The first order condition yields the Expected Euler Equation: Pbu′(C1) = βE(u′(C2))
• And rearranging we have:
Pb = β E(u′(C2)) u′(C1)
• This is referred to as an Asset Pricing Equation
• Asset prices determined by the ratio of marginal utilities of consumption in each period
• Or, another way: asset prices are given by the marginal rate of substitution between consumption across periods
24

A MODEL OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
How does uncertainty affect asset prices?
• Consider an increase from x to x∗:
• Now Y2 = Y ̄ + x∗ with probability 0.5, and Y2 = Y ̄ − x∗ with probability 0.5
• Still the case that E(Y2) = Y ̄
• This is called a mean-preserving spread in Y2
• Uncertainty only affects period 2, so the effect on asset prices comes through E(u′(C2))
25

GRAPHICAL ILLUSTRATION: INCREASE IN UNCERTAINTY x → x∗
u′, E(u′)
E(u′(C∗2 )) E(u′ (C2 ))
Cc2 −x∗
Cc2 −x∗
E(C2) Cc2 −x∗
u′(C2) Cc2 +x∗ C2
26

A MODEL OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
• Since E(u′(C2)) increases, Pb increases also:
↑Pb = β E(u′(C2))↑
u′(C1)
• But C1 also decreases in response to greater uncertainty, which increases u′(C1)
• So what is the overall effect?
• Substitute in the budget constraints:
Pb =βE(u′(Y2 +B)) u′(Y ̄ − PbB)
• Illustrate optimal choices graphically by plotting the left-hand-side and right-hand-side of the asset pricing equation
27

GRAPHICAL ILLUSTRATION: INCREASE IN UNCERTAINTY x → x∗
LHS, RHS
Pb
βE(u′(Y∗2 +B)) u′ ( ̄Y−Pb B)
β E(u′ (Y2 +B)) u′ ( ̄Y−Pb B)
Pb P∗b
Pb 28

A MODEL OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
• An increase in uncertainty increases the price of assets • This is intuitive:
• Greater uncertainty induces precautionary savings which increases demand for assets • Higher asset demand is associated with higher asset prices
• Recall that the asset return: R = 1 Pb
• So higher asset prices are associated with lower asset returns • Do we observe this empirically?
29

UNCERTAINTY AND ASSET PRICES/RETURNS: EMPIRICAL EVIDENCE
Equity Market
Volatility Tracker
(Bloom et al., 2019; scaled)
3 Month Treasury Bond Return
10
8
6
4
2
0
1992 1996 2000 2004
2008 2012 2016 2020
30

A MODEL OF PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS AND ASSET PRICES
• Note, we need to compare risk-free bonds
• For risky assets, demand and prices may increase or decrease depending on the nature of
the asset risk (see next lecture!)
Equity Market
Volatility Tracker
(Bloom et al., 2019; scaled)
Aaa Corporate Bond Spread Over 10-Year Treasury
Baa Corporate Bond Spread Over 10-Year Treasury
10
8
6
4
2
0
1992 1996
2000 2004
2008 2012 2016
2020 31

5. HOW MUCH DOES THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE MATTER?

HOW MUCH DOES THE PRECAUTIONARY SAVINGS MOTIVE MATTER?
• The two motives for asset holding that we have studied so far:
• Life-cycle motive: consumption smoothing across time
• Precautionary savings motive: consumption smoothing across outcomes/states of the world
• Consumption over the Life Cycle (Gourinchas and Parker; 2002) uses a model to distinguish between the two motives
• Finds that precautionary savings matter much more for young households’ asset decisions
• Finds that life-cycle motives matter much more for older households’ asset decisions
• Young households start out with low wealth, need to save to build a precautionary savings buffer
32

EMPIRICAL APPLICATION: PRECAUTIONARY VS. LIFE-CYCLE SAVINGS
Source: Gourinchas and Parker (2002) 33