CS计算机代考程序代写 1

1
Continued Overleaf

1.You are about to sit an online assessment

You have a 24-hour period in which to complete this exam. This 24-hour period is the time
during which you can arrange to take the exam. It is NOT the length of the exam.

2.Advice on the contents of the exam and technical support

In case you should have questions about the contents of this paper, or you require technical
assistance, please contact our virtual invigilation team at the UofG Helpdesk.

Questions relating to the contents of the paper should be raised within the first 3 hours of the
assessment period, when an academic member of staff will be available to answer these.
Technical support will be available 24 hours per day. To ensure timely responses and that all
students receive the same information, you should not contact academic staff directly but
instead use the Helpdesk.

3.Completing the exam paper

It should take you no longer than 2 hours to complete this exam and you should pay specific
attention to guidance provided on the exam paper regarding the total word count.

You should be able to complete the exam in the time indicated and are unlikely to derive major
benefits from taking longer. Note that spending longer often leads to muddled answers which do
not receive high grades. It is better to answer in a clear and concise fashion within the time limit
given.

4.Time adjustments for students with disabilities

If you are normally granted adjustments to your exam time through the University’s Disability
Service, allowance is made for these since you have a 24-hour period in which to complete this
exam.

5.Enlarging the text

In case you should need to enlarge the text of a PDF document:

Open Adobe Acrobat; click on the VIEW tab; click on ZOOM and then ZOOM TO; select the
desired magnification level.

6.Planning your time

When planning your time, you should allocate 30 minutes to download the exam paper and a
further 30 minutes to upload your answers to Moodle at the end of the exam. This is important
as these times give you the ability to report any problems within the 24-hour exam availability
period.

7.Submitting your answers

Acceptable file types for submitting typed documents are: DOC/DOCX; RTF; PDF; XLS/XLSX

2
Continued Overleaf

Acceptable file types for submitting high resolution images are: JPG; PNG; TIF; PDF In case
you are unable to upload your answers to Moodle you may email them to: business-school-
.uk.

• Only one file should be submitted per question.

• Ensure you save your document using your student ID, course code and question
number, e.g 7299019_MGT5317_1.

8.Declaration of Academic Integrity

Your answers must entirely be your own work. During the 24-hour period that this exam is
active, you must not for any reason communicate or collude with other students taking this

exam. Note that your exam papers may be processed through Turnitin for plagiarism checking.

We may also conduct a further oral examination to check your knowledge and establish that the

exam answers are your own.

This declaration incorporates the University’s Declaration of Originality which applies to all
academic work (see below).

9.Declaring that the work is your own

By selecting the check box to open the exam paper, you have agreed to both this declaration
and the University’s Declaration of Originality.

3
Continued Overleaf

Students must answer any TWO questions. The word limit per question is 1500 words

maximum. Anything you write once you have reached the word limit will not be marked.

Question 1

Let two dimensions of choice be apples and money, with apples being dimension 1 and money being

dimension 2. Denote outcomes in apples and money by 𝑐1 and 𝑐2, respectively, and reference points in

the two dimensions by 𝑟1 and 𝑟2, respectively. The person’s utility is given by:

4𝑐1 + 𝑐2 + 4𝑣(𝑐1 − 𝑟1) + 𝑣(𝑐2 − 𝑟2)

where 𝑣(𝑥) = 𝑥, 𝑥 ≥ 0 and 𝑣(𝑥) = 𝛼𝑥, 𝑥 < 0. a. For which values of α, does this formulation capture loss aversion? How would you change the specification of the value function to capture diminishing sensitivity? [10%] b. Suppose than an individual owns one apple and has no money. What is her reference point? Given this reference point, solve for the "selling price", i.e. the minimum price at which the individual is willing to sell the apple. [10%] c. Suppose than an individual has a one pound coin but no apples. What is her reference point? Solve for the "buying price", i.e. the maximum price at which the individual is willing to buy an apple. [10%] d. Suppose than an individual has no money or apples. What is her reference point? This individual is told she can have either one apple or money. Solve for the "choosing price", i.e. the minimum amount of money which she would be willing to accept instead of one apple. [10%] e. In an actual experiment, buying and choosing prices were found to be close to each other (although the choosing price was slightly higher) while selling prices were found to be two and half times the buying price. How well does the above model explain these findings? To the extent that it cannot explain the findings, what do you think goes wrong? [10%] [Total 50%] 4 Continued Overleaf Question 2 Assume that an individual is a hyperbolic discounter with 0 < 𝛽 < 1, 𝛿 = 1 where 𝛽 denotes the quasi- hyperbolic discount factor (present bias) and 𝛿 denotes the exponential discount factor. She cannot commit her future behaviour. The individual has to undertake a costly action in one of the time periods 𝑡 = 0,1,2,3,4,5. The utility cost of the action in period 𝑡 is 𝑐𝑡. a. For which values of 𝛽, 𝑐 will a naive individual undertake the action at 𝑡 = 5? Explain the intuition behind this result. [20%] b. For which values of 𝛽, 𝑐 will a sophisticated individual undertake the action at 𝑡 = 1? [20%] c. Based on your answers, comment on the suggestion that the naive and sophisticated models of behaviour with hyperbolic discounting are "too extreme" with the sophisticated one being too rational, and the naive one being too irrational. [10%] [Total 50%] Question 3 Consider the ultimatum bargaining game (with available bargaining surplus normalised to one) where the proposer (player 1) offers a share 𝑠 ∈ [0,1] to the responder (player 2). Let the preferences of the two players be characterized by inequality aversion (as stated in Fehr and Schmidt (1999) and referred to in the lecture notes) with parameters 0 < 𝛽1 = 1 3 < 𝛼1 and 0 < 𝛽2 < 𝛼2 ≤ 1 2 . Assume that player 2 (responder) knows the correct value of 𝛼2 but player 1 (proposer) only knows the probability distribution over 𝛼2 so that 𝛼2 = 1 2 with probability (1/2) and 𝛼2 = 1 4 with probability (1/2). Compute the sub game perfect equilibrium of this bargaining game. Explain, intuitively, the answer you obtain. [50%] 5 End of Paper Question 4 Consider the following simultaneous move game with material payoffs as shown below: C D C 3X, 3X 0,4X D 4X,0 X, X (i) Show that (D,D) is a fairness equilibrium. [10%] (ii) Under what conditions on X is (C,C) also a fairness equilibrium? Explain, intuitively, your answer. [25%] (iii) Suppose the game is altered so that the row player is forced to cooperate (i.e. the action “D” is no longer available to the row player). Compute the unique fairness equilibrium in this case and intuitively explain your answer. [15%] [Total 50%]