程序代写代做代考 chain algorithm finance database data structure game graph go AI flex Hive ant C Excel data mining Introductory

Introductory
Econometrics
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Introductory
Econometrics
A MODERN APPROACH
FIFTH EDITION
Jeffrey M. Wooldridge
Michigan State University
􏰧􏰨􏰩􏰪􏰫􏰬􏰭􏰮􏰬 􏰰 􏰱􏰫􏰬􏰲􏰮􏰭 􏰰 􏰳􏰬􏰴􏰬􏰵 􏰰 􏰶􏰷􏰫􏰸􏰬 􏰰 􏰹􏰸􏰺􏰮􏰻􏰷 􏰰 􏰼􏰮􏰵􏰽􏰬􏰴􏰷􏰫􏰸 􏰰 􏰼􏰴􏰬􏰮􏰵 􏰰 􏰾􏰵􏰮􏰪􏰸􏰿 􏰶􏰮􏰵􏰽􏰿􏰷􏱀 􏰰 􏰾􏰵􏰮􏰪􏰸􏰿 􏰼􏰪􏰬􏰪􏰸􏰩
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

This is an electronic version of the print textbook. Due to electronic rights restrictions, some third party content may be suppressed. Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. The publisher reserves the right to remove content from this title at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. For valuable information on pricing, previous editions, changes to current editions, and alternate formats, please visit www.cengage.com/highered to search by
ISBN#, author, title, or keyword for materials in your areas of interest.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach, Fifth Edition
Jeffrey M. Wooldridge
􏰼􏰸􏰵􏰮􏰷􏰫 􏱓􏰮􏰻􏰸 􏱥􏰫􏰸􏰩􏰮􏰿􏰸􏰵􏰪􏱆 􏱌􏱍􏰼􏱦􏰧􏰻􏱧􏰨􏰮􏰩􏰮􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏰩 􏱨 􏰼􏰷􏰭􏰨􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏰩 􏱥􏰭􏰬􏰵􏰵􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱠 􏰳􏰬􏰻􏱙 􏱊􏱕 􏱋􏰬􏰭􏱈􏰷􏰨􏰵
􏱒􏰿􏰮􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰮􏰬􏰭 􏱔􏰮􏰫􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱆 􏰱􏰨􏰩􏰮􏰵􏰸􏰩􏰩 􏱨 􏱒􏰻􏰷􏰵􏰷􏱀􏰮􏰻􏰩􏱠 􏱒􏰫􏰮􏰵 􏰳􏰷􏱜􏰵􏰸􏰫
􏱒􏰿􏰮􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱉􏰮􏰵􏱉􏱋􏱈􏰮􏰸􏱗􏱠 􏰳􏰷􏰸 􏰼􏰬􏱛􏰬􏰪􏰮􏰵􏰷 􏱒􏰺􏰸􏰻􏰨􏰪􏰮􏱚􏰸 􏱒􏰿􏰮􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏰹􏰮􏰻􏱈􏰬􏰸􏰭 􏱊􏰷􏰫􏰭􏰩
􏰧􏰩􏰩􏰷􏰻􏰮􏰬􏰪􏰸 􏱔􏰸􏱚􏰸􏰭􏰷􏰴􏱀􏰸􏰵􏰪􏰬􏰭 􏱒􏰿􏰮􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏰳􏰨􏰭􏰮􏰸 􏱊􏰬􏰫􏱘􏰮􏰻􏱙
􏱒􏰿􏰮􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰮􏰬􏰭 􏰧􏰩􏰩􏰮􏰩􏰪􏰬􏰵􏰪􏱠 􏱌􏰮􏱛􏱛􏱜 􏰱􏰸􏰮􏰪􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱉􏱌􏰮􏰴􏰴􏰩
􏰱􏰫􏰬􏰵􏰿 􏰹􏰬􏰵􏰬􏰽􏰸􏱀􏰸􏰵􏰪 􏱔􏰮􏰫􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏰳􏰬􏰩􏰷􏰵 􏰼􏰬􏱙􏰷􏰩
􏰹􏰬􏰫􏱙􏰸􏰪 􏱔􏰸􏱚􏰸􏰭􏰷􏰴􏱀􏰸􏰵􏰪 􏱔􏰮􏰫􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏱌􏰮􏰩􏰬 􏱌􏱜􏰩􏰵􏰸
􏰼􏰸􏰵􏰮􏰷􏰫 􏰱􏰫􏰬􏰵􏰿 􏰹􏰬􏰵􏰬􏰽􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏱍􏰷􏱛􏰮􏰵 􏱌􏰸􏱤􏰸􏱚􏰫􏰸
􏰼􏰸􏰵􏰮􏰷􏰫 􏰹􏰬􏰫􏱙􏰸􏰪 􏱔􏰸􏱚􏰸􏰭􏰷􏰴􏱀􏰸􏰵􏰪 􏰹􏰬􏰵􏰬􏰽􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏰳􏰷􏱈􏰵 􏱋􏰬􏰫􏰸􏱜
􏱋􏰷􏰵􏰪􏰸􏰵􏰪 􏱥􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰹􏰬􏰵􏰬􏰽􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏰳􏰸􏰬􏰵 􏰱􏰨􏰪􏰪􏰫􏰷􏱀
􏱍􏰮􏰽􏱈􏰪􏰩 􏰧􏰻􏱧􏰨􏰮􏰩􏰮􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏱔􏰮􏰫􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏰧􏰨􏰿􏰫􏰸􏱜 􏱥􏰸􏰪􏰪􏰸􏰵􏰽􏰮􏰭􏰭
􏱍􏰮􏰽􏱈􏰪􏰩 􏰧􏰻􏱧􏰨􏰮􏰩􏰮􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰼􏰴􏰸􏰻􏰮􏰬􏰭􏰮􏰩􏰪􏱆 􏱑􏰸􏰺􏰪􏱦􏱎􏱀􏰬􏰽􏰸􏱠 􏰳􏰷􏱈􏰵 􏱐􏰮􏰭􏰭
􏰹􏰸􏰿􏰮􏰬 􏱒􏰿􏰮􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏰧􏰵􏰮􏰪􏰬 􏱓􏰸􏰫􏱀􏰬
􏰼􏰸􏰵􏰮􏰷􏰫 􏰹􏰬􏰵􏰨􏱗􏰬􏰻􏰪􏰨􏰫􏰮􏰵􏰽 􏱥􏰭􏰬􏰵􏰵􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏰶􏰸􏱚􏰮􏰵 􏰶􏰭􏰨􏰻􏱙
􏰼􏰸􏰵􏰮􏰷􏰫 􏰧􏰫􏰪 􏱔􏰮􏰫􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰷􏰫􏱠 􏰹􏰮􏰻􏱈􏰸􏰭􏰭􏰸 􏰶􏰨􏰵􏱙􏰭􏰸􏰫
􏱥􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰹􏰬􏰵􏰬􏰽􏰸􏱀􏰸􏰵􏰪 􏰬􏰵􏰿 􏱋􏰷􏱀􏰴􏰷􏰩􏰮􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏱠 􏱥􏰫􏰸􏰹􏰸􏰿􏰮􏰬􏱏􏰭􏰷􏱛􏰬􏰭
􏱎􏰵􏰪􏰸􏰫􏰵􏰬􏰭 􏱔􏰸􏰩􏰮􏰽􏰵􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏱥􏰫􏰸􏰹􏰸􏰿􏰮􏰬􏱏􏰭􏰷􏱛􏰬􏰭 􏱋􏰷􏱚􏰸􏰫 􏱔􏰸􏰩􏰮􏰽􏰵􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏱍􏰷􏱙􏰨􏰩􏰸􏱙 􏱔􏰸􏰩􏰮􏰽􏰵
􏱋􏰷􏱚􏰸􏰫 􏱎􏱀􏰬􏰽􏰸􏱠 􏱁 􏱒􏰭􏰸􏰵􏰬 􏱍􏱦􏰼􏱈􏰨􏰪􏰪􏰸􏰫􏰩􏰪􏰷􏰻􏱙􏱕􏰻􏰷􏱀􏱩 􏰹􏰮􏰭􏰷􏰩􏰲 􏰧􏰵􏰮􏰷􏰭􏱦􏰼􏱈􏰨􏰪􏰪􏰸􏰫􏰩􏰪􏰷􏰻􏱙􏱕􏰻􏰷􏱀
􏱁 􏱂􏱃􏱄􏱅􏱆 􏱂􏱃􏱃􏱇 􏰼􏰷􏰨􏰪􏱈􏱉􏱊􏰸􏰩􏰪􏰸􏰫􏰵􏱆 􏱋􏰸􏰵􏰽􏰬􏰽􏰸 􏱌􏰸􏰬􏰫􏰵􏰮􏰵􏰽
􏰧􏱌􏱌 􏱍􏱎􏱏􏱐􏱑􏰼 􏱍􏱒􏰼􏱒􏱍􏱓􏱒􏱔􏱕 􏱖􏰷 􏰴􏰬􏰫􏰪 􏰷􏱗 􏰪􏱈􏰮􏰩 􏱘􏰷􏰫􏱙 􏰻􏰷􏱚􏰸􏰫􏰸􏰿 􏱛􏱜 􏰪􏱈􏰸 􏰻􏰷􏰴􏱜􏰫􏰮􏰽􏱈􏰪 􏱈􏰸􏰫􏰸􏰮􏰵 􏱀􏰬􏱜 􏱛􏰸 􏰫􏰸􏰴􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰸􏰿􏱆 􏰪􏰫􏰬􏰵􏰩􏱀􏰮􏰪􏰪􏰸􏰿􏱆 􏰩􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰸􏰿􏱆 􏰷􏰫 􏰨􏰩􏰸􏰿 􏰮􏰵 􏰬􏰵􏱜 􏱗􏰷􏰫􏱀 􏰷􏰫 􏱛􏱜 􏰬􏰵􏱜 􏱀􏰸􏰬􏰵􏰩 􏰽􏰫􏰬􏰴􏱈􏰮􏰻􏱆 􏰸􏰭􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰫􏰷􏰵􏰮􏰻􏱆 􏰷􏰫 􏱀􏰸􏰻􏱈􏰬􏰵􏰮􏰻􏰬􏰭􏱆 􏰮􏰵􏰻􏰭􏰨􏰿􏰮􏰵􏰽 􏱛􏰨􏰪 􏰵􏰷􏰪 􏰭􏰮􏱀􏰮􏰪􏰸􏰿
􏰪􏰷 􏰴􏱈􏰷􏰪􏰷􏰻􏰷􏰴􏱜􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱆 􏰫􏰸􏰻􏰷􏰫􏰿􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱆 􏰩􏰻􏰬􏰵􏰵􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱆 􏰿􏰮􏰽􏰮􏰪􏰮􏰲􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱆 􏰪􏰬􏰴􏰮􏰵􏰽􏱆 􏱘􏰸􏱛 􏰿􏰮􏰩􏰪􏰫􏰮􏱛􏰨􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏱆 􏰮􏰵􏱗􏰷􏰫􏱀􏰬􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰵􏰸􏰪􏱘􏰷􏰫􏱙􏰩􏱆 􏰷􏰫 􏰮􏰵􏱗􏰷􏰫􏱀􏰬􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰩􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰬􏰽􏰸 􏰬􏰵􏰿 􏰫􏰸􏰪􏰫􏰮􏰸􏱚􏰬􏰭 􏰩􏱜􏰩􏰪􏰸􏱀􏰩􏱆 􏰸􏰺􏰻􏰸􏰴􏰪 􏰬􏰩 􏰴􏰸􏰫􏱀􏰮􏰪􏰪􏰸􏰿 􏰨􏰵􏰿􏰸􏰫 􏰼􏰸􏰻􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏱄􏱃􏱝 􏰷􏰫 􏱄􏱃􏱞 􏰷􏱗 􏰪􏱈􏰸 􏱄􏱇􏱝􏱟 􏰾􏰵􏰮􏰪􏰸􏰿 􏰼􏰪􏰬􏰪􏰸􏰩 􏱋􏰷􏰴􏱜􏰫􏰮􏰽􏱈􏰪 􏰧􏰻􏰪􏱆 􏱘􏰮􏰪􏱈􏰷􏰨􏰪 􏰪􏱈􏰸 􏰴􏰫􏰮􏰷􏰫 􏱘􏰫􏰮􏰪􏰪􏰸􏰵 􏰴􏰸􏰫􏱀􏰮􏰩􏰩􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰷􏱗 􏰪􏱈􏰸 􏰴􏰨􏱛􏰭􏰮􏰩􏱈􏰸􏰫􏱕
􏱌􏰮􏱛􏰫􏰬􏰫􏱜 􏰷􏱗 􏱋􏰷􏰵􏰽􏰫􏰸􏰩􏰩 􏱋􏰷􏰵􏰪􏰫􏰷􏰭 􏱖􏰨􏱀􏱛􏰸􏰫􏱠 􏱂􏱃􏱄􏱂􏱇􏱡􏱢􏱄􏱂􏱃 􏱎􏰼􏰱􏱖􏱉􏱄􏱅􏱠 􏱇􏱝􏱞􏱉􏱄􏱉􏱄􏱄􏱄􏱉􏱢􏱅􏱄􏱃􏱡􏱉􏱄
􏱎􏰼􏰱􏱖􏱉􏱄􏱃􏱠 􏱄􏱉􏱄􏱄􏱄􏱉􏱢􏱅􏱄􏱃􏱡􏱉􏱞
South-Western
􏱢􏱄􏱇􏱄 􏱖􏰬􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰴 􏰱􏰷􏰨􏰭􏰸􏱚􏰬􏰫􏰿 􏰹􏰬􏰩􏰷􏰵􏱆 􏱣􏱐 􏱡􏱢􏱃􏱡􏱃 􏰾􏰼􏰧
􏱋􏰸􏰵􏰽􏰬􏰽􏰸 􏱌􏰸􏰬􏰫􏰵􏰮􏰵􏰽 􏰴􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰪􏰩 􏰬􏰫􏰸 􏰫􏰸􏰴􏰫􏰸􏰩􏰸􏰵􏰪􏰸􏰿 􏰮􏰵 􏱋􏰬􏰵􏰬􏰿􏰬 􏱛􏱜 􏱖􏰸􏰭􏰩􏰷􏰵 􏱒􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰬􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏱆 􏱌􏰪􏰿􏱕
􏱤􏰷􏰫 􏱜􏰷􏰨􏰫 􏰻􏰷􏰨􏰫􏰩􏰸 􏰬􏰵􏰿 􏰭􏰸􏰬􏰫􏰵􏰮􏰵􏰽 􏰩􏰷􏰭􏰨􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏰩􏱆 􏱚􏰮􏰩􏰮􏰪 www.cengage.com
􏱥􏰨􏰫􏰻􏱈􏰬􏰩􏰸 􏰬􏰵􏱜 􏰷􏱗 􏰷􏰨􏰫 􏰴􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰪􏰩 􏰬􏰪 􏱜􏰷􏰨􏰫 􏰭􏰷􏰻􏰬􏰭 􏰻􏰷􏰭􏰭􏰸􏰽􏰸 􏰩􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰸 􏰷􏰫 􏰬􏰪 􏰷􏰨􏰫 􏰴􏰫􏰸􏱗􏰸􏰫􏰫􏰸􏰿
􏰷􏰵􏰭􏰮􏰵􏰸 􏰩􏰪􏰷􏰫􏰸 www.cengagebrain.com
Printed in the United States of America 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 16 15 14 13 12
􏱤􏰷􏰫 􏰴􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰪 􏰮􏰵􏱗􏰷􏰫􏱀􏰬􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰬􏰵􏰿 􏰪􏰸􏰻􏱈􏰵􏰷􏰭􏰷􏰽􏱜 􏰬􏰩􏰩􏰮􏰩􏰪􏰬􏰵􏰻􏰸􏱆 􏰻􏰷􏰵􏰪􏰬􏰻􏰪 􏰨􏰩 􏰬􏰪
Cengage Learning Customer & Sales Support, -“àà-$%&-‘àà)
􏱤􏰷􏰫 􏰴􏰸􏰫􏱀􏰮􏰩􏰩􏰮􏰷􏰵 􏰪􏰷 􏰨􏰩􏰸 􏱀􏰬􏰪􏰸􏰫􏰮􏰬􏰭 􏱗􏰫􏰷􏱀 􏰪􏱈􏰮􏰩 􏰪􏰸􏰺􏰪 􏰷􏰫 􏰴􏰫􏰷􏰿􏰨􏰻􏰪􏱆 􏰩􏰨􏱛􏱀􏰮􏰪 􏰬􏰭􏰭 􏰫􏰸􏱧􏰨􏰸􏰩􏰪􏰩 􏰷􏰵􏰭􏰮􏰵􏰸 􏰬􏰪 www.cengage.com/permissions 􏱤􏰨􏰫􏰪􏱈􏰸􏰫 􏰴􏰸􏰫􏱀􏰮􏰩􏰩􏰮􏰷􏰵􏰩 􏱧􏰨􏰸􏰩􏰪􏰮􏰷􏰵􏰩 􏰻􏰬􏰵 􏱛􏰸 􏰸􏱀􏰬􏰮􏰭􏰸􏰿 􏰪􏰷 permissionrequest@cengage.com
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

BRIEF CONTENTS
o Chapter 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 1 PART 1: Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 21
Chapter 2 Chapter 3 Chapter 4 Chapter 5 Chapter 6 Chapter 7
Chapter 8 Chapter 9
The Simple Regression Model 22 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 68 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 118 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 168 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 186 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative
Information: Binary (or Dummy) Variables 227 Heteroskedasticity 268 More on Specification and Data Issues 303
PART 2: Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 343
Chapter 10 Chapter 11 Chapter 12
Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 344 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 380 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 412
PART 3: Advanced Topics 447
Chapter 13 Chapter 14 Chapter 15
O Chapter 16 Chapter 17 Chapter 18 Chapter 19
Pooling Cross Sections Across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 448 Advanced Panel Data Methods 484 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 512 Simultaneous Equations Models 554 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 583 Advanced Time Series Topics 632 Carrying Out an Empirical Project 676
APPENDICES
Appendix A Appendix B Appendix C Appendix D Appendix E Appendix F Appendix G
References Glossary Index
Basic Mathematical Tools 703 Fundamentals of Probability 722 Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 755 Summary of Matrix Algebra 796 The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 807 Answers to Chapter Questions 821 Statistical Tables 831
838 844 862
v
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CONTENTS
Preface xv
About the Author xxv
CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 1
1.1 What Is Econometrics? 1
1.2 Steps in Empirical Economic Analysis 2
1.3 The Structure of Economic Data 5
Cross-Sectional Data 5
Time Series Data 8
Pooled Cross Sections 9
Panel or Longitudinal Data 10
A Comment on Data Structures 11
1.4 Causality and the Notion of Ceteris Paribus in Econometric Analysis 12
Summary 16
Key Terms 17 Problems 17 Computer Exercises 17
PART 1
Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 21
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 22
2.1 Definition of the Simple Regression Model 22
2.2 Deriving the Ordinary Least Squares Estimates 27
A Note on Terminology 34
2.3 Properties of OLS on Any Sample of Data 35 Fitted Values and Residuals 35
Algebraic Properties of OLS Statistics 36 Goodness-of-Fit 38
2.4 Units of Measurement and Functional Form 39 The Effects of Changing Units of Measurement on OLS Statistics 40
Incorporating Nonlinearities in Simple Regression 41 The Meaning of “Linear” Regression 44
2.5 Expected Values and Variances of the OLS Estimators 45
Unbiasedness of OLS 45
Variances of the OLS Estimators 50 Estimating the Error Variance 54
2.6 Regression through the Origin and Regression on a Constant 57
Summary 58
Key Terms 59 Problems 60 Computer Exercises 63 Appendix 2A 66
CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 68
3.1 3.2
Motivation for Multiple Regression 69
The Model with Two Independent Variables 69
The Model with k Independent Variables 71
Mechanics and Interpretation of Ordinary Least Squares 72
Obtaining the OLS Estimates 72
Interpreting the OLS Regression Equation 74 On the Meaning of “Holding Other Factors Fixed” in Multiple Regression 76
Changing More Than One Independent Variable Simultaneously 77
vi
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

OLS Fitted Values and Residuals 77
A “Partialling Out” Interpretation of Multiple Regression 78
Comparison of Simple and Multiple Regression Estimates 78
Goodness-of-Fit 80
Regression through the Origin 81
3.3 The Expected Value of the OLS Estimators Including Irrelevant Variables in a Regression Model 88
Omitted Variable Bias: The Simple Case 88 Omitted Variable Bias: More General Cases 91
3.4 The Variance of the OLS Estimators 93 The Components of the OLS Variances: Multicollinearity 94
Variances in Misspecified Models 98 Estimating s2: Standard Errors of the OLS Estimators 99
3.5 Efficiency of OLS: The Gauss-Markov Theorem 101
3.6 Some Comments on the Language of Multiple Regression Analysis 103
Summary 104
Key Terms 105 Problems 106 Computer Exercises 110 Appendix 3A 113
CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 118
4.1 Sampling Distributions of the OLS Estimators 118
4.2 Testing Hypotheses about a Single Population Parameter: The t Test 121
4.5 Testing Multiple Linear Restrictions: The F Test 143
Testing Exclusion Restrictions 143 Relationship between F and t Statistics
The R-Squared Form of the F Statistic Computing p-Values for F Tests 151
The F Statistic for Overall Significance of a Regression 152
Testing General Linear Restrictions 153
4.6 Reporting Regression Results 154 Summary 157
Key Terms 159
Problems 159
Computer Exercises 164
CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 168
5.1 Consistency 169
Deriving the Inconsistency in OLS 172
5.2 Asymptotic Normality and Large Sample Inference 173
Other Large Sample Tests: The Lagrange Multiplier Statistic 178
5.3 Asymptotic Efficiency of OLS 181
Summary 182 Key Terms 183 Problems 183
Computer Exercises 183 Appendix 5A 185
CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 186
83
Contents
vii
149 150
Testing against One-Sided Alternatives Two-Sided Alternatives 128
Testing Other Hypotheses about bj 130 Computing p-Values for t Tests 133
123
6.1 6.2
6.3
Effects of Data Scaling on OLS Statistics 186
Beta Coefficients 189
More on Functional Form 191
More on Using Logarithmic Functional Forms 191
Models with Quadratics 194
Models with Interaction Terms 198 More on Goodness-of-Fit and Selection of Regressors 200
Adjusted R-Squared 202
Using Adjusted R-Squared to Choose between Nonnested Models 203
A Reminder on the Language of Classical Hypothesis Testing 135
Economic, or Practical, versus Statistical Significance 135
4.3 Confidence Intervals 138
4.4 Testing Hypotheses about a Single Linear
Combination of the Parameters 140
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

viii
Contents
6.4
Controlling for Too Many Factors in Regression Analysis 205
Adding Regressors to Reduce the Error Variance 206
Prediction and Residual Analysis 207
CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 268
8.1 Consequences of Heteroskedasticity for
OLS 268
8.2 Heteroskedasticity-Robust Inference after OLS Estimation 269
Computing Heteroskedasticity-Robust LM Tests 274
8.3 Testing for Heteroskedasticity 275
The White Test for Heteroskedasticity 279
8.4 Weighted Least Squares Estimation 280
The Heteroskedasticity Is Known up to a Multiplicative Constant 281
The Heteroskedasticity Function Must Be Estimated: Feasible GLS 286
What If the Assumed Heteroskedasticity Function Is Wrong? 290
Prediction and Prediction Intervals with Heteroskedasticity 292
8.5 The Linear Probability Model Revisited 294
Summary 296 Key Terms 297 Problems 297
Computer Exercises 299
CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 303
Confidence Intervals for Predictions Residual Analysis 211
207
Predicting y When log(y) Is the Dependent Variable 212
Summary 216
Key Terms 217 Problems 218 Computer Exercises 220 Appendix 6A 225
CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information: Binary (or Dummy) Variables 227
7.1 Describing Qualitative Information 227
7.2 A Single Dummy Independent Variable 228
Interpreting Coefficients on Dummy Explanatory Variables When the Dependent Variable Is log(y) 233
7.3 Using Dummy Variables for Multiple Categories 235
Incorporating Ordinal Information by Using Dummy Variables 237
7.4 Interactions Involving Dummy Variables 240 Interactions among Dummy Variables 240 Allowing for Different Slopes 241
Testing for Differences in Regression Functions across Groups 245
7.5 A Binary Dependent Variable: The Linear Probability Model 248
7.6 More on Policy Analysis and Program Evaluation 253
7.7 Interpreting Regression Results with Discrete Dependent Variables 256
9.1
9.2
9.3 9.4
9.5
Functional Form Misspecification 304
RESET as a General Test for Functional Form Misspecification 306
Tests against Nonnested Alternatives 307 Using Proxy Variables for Unobserved Explanatory Variables 308
Using Lagged Dependent Variables as Proxy Variables 313
A Different Slant on Multiple Regression 314 Models with Random Slopes 315 Properties of OLS under Measurement
Error 317
Measurement Error in the Dependent Variable 318
Measurement Error in an Explanatory Variable 320
Missing Data, Nonrandom Samples, and Outlying Observations 324
Summary 257
Key Terms 258 Problems 258 Computer Exercises
262
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Missing Data 324
Nonrandom Samples 324
Outliers and Influential Observations 326
Contents ix CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using
OLS with Time Series Data 380
11.1 Stationary and Weakly Dependent Time Series 381
Stationary and Nonstationary Time Series 381
Weakly Dependent Time Series 382
11.2 Asymptotic Properties of OLS 384
11.3 Using Highly Persistent Time Series in Regression Analysis 391
Highly Persistent Time Series 391 Transformations on Highly Persistent Time Series 395
Deciding Whether a Time Series Is I(1) 396
11.4 Dynamically Complete Models and the Absence of Serial Correlation 399
11.5 The Homoskedasticity Assumption for Time Series Models 402
Summary 402
Key Terms 404 Problems 404 Computer Exercises 407
CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 412
12.1 Properties of OLS with Serially Correlated Errors 412
Unbiasedness and Consistency 412 Efficiency and Inference 413 Goodness-of-Fit 414
Serial Correlation in the Presence of Lagged Dependent Variables 415
12.2 Testing for Serial Correlation 416
A t Test for AR(1) Serial Correlation with Strictly Exogenous Regressors 416
The Durbin-Watson Test under Classical Assumptions 418
Testing for AR(1) Serial Correlation without Strictly Exogenous Regressors 420
Testing for Higher Order Serial Correlation 421
12.3 Correcting for Serial Correlation with Strictly Exogenous Regressors 423
Obtaining the Best Linear Unbiased Estimator in the AR(1) Model 423
9.6 Least Absolute Deviations Estimation Summary 334
Key Terms 335
Problems 335
Computer Exercises 338
PART 2
331
Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 343
CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 344
10.1 The Nature of Time Series Data 344
10.2 Examples of Time Series Regression Models 345
Static Models 346
Finite Distributed Lag Models 346
A Convention about the Time Index 349
10.3 Finite Sample Properties of OLS under Classical Assumptions 349
Unbiasedness of OLS 349
The Variances of the OLS Estimators and the Gauss-Markov Theorem 352
Inference under the Classical Linear Model Assumptions 355
10.4 Functional Form, Dummy Variables, and Index Numbers 356
10.5 Trends and Seasonality 363 Characterizing Trending Time Series 363
Using Trending Variables in Regression Analysis 366
A Detrending Interpretation of Regressions with a Time Trend 368
Computing R-Squared when the Dependent Variable Is Trending 370
Seasonality 371
Summary 373
Key Terms 374 Problems 375 Computer Exercises
377
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

x Contents
Feasible GLS Estimation with AR(1) Errors
Comparing OLS and FGLS 427 Correcting for Higher Order Serial Correlation 428
12.4 Differencing and Serial Correlation 429
12.5 Serial Correlation-Robust Inference after
OLS 431
12.6 Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 434
Heteroskedasticity-Robust Statistics 435 Testing for Heteroskedasticity 435
Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity 436
Heteroskedasticity and Serial Correlation in Regression Models 438
Summary 439
Key Terms 440 Problems 440 Computer Exercises 441
PART 3
Advanced Topics 447
CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 448
13.1 Pooling Independent Cross Sections across Time 449
The Chow Test for Structural Change across Time 453
13.2 Policy Analysis with Pooled Cross Sections
13.3 Two-Period Panel Data Analysis 459
Organizing Panel Data 465
13.4 Policy Analysis with Two-Period Panel Data
13.5 Differencing with More Than Two Time Periods 468
Potential Pitfalls in First Differencing Panel Data 473
425
CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 484
14.1 Fixed Effects Estimation 484
The Dummy Variable Regression 488 Fixed Effects or First Differencing? 489
Fixed Effects with Unbalanced Panels
14.2 Random Effects Models 492 Random Effects or Fixed Effects? 495
14.3 The Correlated Random Effects Approach 497
491
14.4 Applying Panel Data Methods to Other Data Structures 499
Summary 501
Key Terms 502 Problems 502 Computer Exercises 503 Appendix 14A 509
CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 512
15.1 Motivation: Omitted Variables in a Simple Regression Model 513
Statistical Inference with the IV Estimator 517 Properties of IV with a Poor Instrumental Variable 521
Computing R-Squared after IV Estimation 523
15.2 IV Estimation of the Multiple Regression
Summary 474
Key Terms 474 Problems 474 Computer Exercises Appendix 13A 481
476
454 465
Model 524
15.3 Two Stage Least Squares 528
A Single Endogenous Explanatory Variable Multicollinearity and 2SLS 530
Multiple Endogenous Explanatory Variables 531
Testing Multiple Hypotheses after 2SLS Estimation 532
15.4 IV Solutions to Errors-in-Variables Problems 532
15.5 Testing for Endogeneity and Testing Overidentifying Restrictions 534
Testing for Endogeneity 534
Testing Overidentification Restrictions 535
15.6 2SLS with Heteroskedasticity 538
528
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

15.7 Applying 2SLS to Time Series Equations 538
15.8 Applying 2SLS to Pooled Cross Sections and
Panel Data 540
Summary 542
Key Terms 543 Problems 543 Computer Exercises 546 Appendix 15A 551
CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 554
16.1 The Nature of Simultaneous Equations Models 555
16.2 Simultaneity Bias in OLS 558
16.3 Identifying and Estimating a Structural Equation 560
Identification in a Two-Equation System 560
Estimation by 2SLS 565
16.4 Systems with More Than Two Equations 567
Identification in Systems with Three or More Equations 567
Estimation 568
16.5 Simultaneous Equations Models with Time Series 568
16.6 Simultaneous Equations Models with Panel Data 572
17.2 The Tobit Model for Corner Solution Responses 596
Interpreting the Tobit Estimates 598
Specification Issues in Tobit Models 603
17.3 The Poisson Regression Model 604
17.4 Censored and Truncated Regression Models 609
Censored Regression Models 609
Truncated Regression Models 613
17.5 Sample Selection Corrections 615 When Is OLS on the Selected Sample Consistent? 615
Incidental Truncation 617
Summary 621
Key Terms 622 Problems 622 Computer Exercises 624 Appendix 17A 630 Appendix 17B 630
CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 632
18.1 Infinite Distributed Lag Models 633
The Geometric (or Koyck) Distributed Lag 635 Rational Distributed Lag Models 637
18.2 Testing for Unit Roots 639
18.3 Spurious Regression 644
18.4 Cointegration and Error Correction Models 646
Cointegration 646
Error Correction Models 651
18.5 Forecasting 652
Types of Regression Models Used for Forecasting 654
One-Step-Ahead Forecasting 655
Comparing One-Step-Ahead Forecasts 658 Multiple-Step-Ahead Forecasts 660 Forecasting Trending, Seasonal, and Integrated Processes 662
Summary 667
Key Terms 669 Problems 669 Computer Exercises 671
Contents xi
Summary 574
Key Terms 575 Problems 575 Computer Exercises
578
CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 583
17.1 Logit and Probit Models for Binary Response 584
Specifying Logit and Probit Models 584 Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Logit and Probit Models 587
Testing Multiple Hypotheses 588 Interpreting the Logit and Probit
Estimates 589
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

xii Contents
CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an
Empirical Project 676
19.1 Posing a Question 676
A.5 Differential Calculus 717 Summary 719
Key Terms 719
Problems 719
APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 722
19.2 Literature Review
19.3 Data Collection 679
Deciding on the Appropriate Data Set 679
Entering and Storing Your
Data 680
Inspecting, Cleaning, and Summarizing Your Data 682
19.4 Econometric Analysis 683
19.5 Writing an Empirical Paper 686
Introduction 686
Conceptual (or Theoretical) Framework 687
Econometric Models and Estimation Methods 687
The Data 690
Results 690
Conclusions 691
Style Hints 692
Summary 694
Key Terms 694
Sample Empirical Projects 694 List of Journals 700
Data Sources 701
APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 703
A.1 The Summation Operator and Descriptive Statistics 703
A.2 Properties of Linear Functions 705
A.3 Proportions and Percentages 707
A.4 Some Special Functions and Their Properties 710 Quadratic Functions 710
The Natural Logarithm 712 The Exponential Function 716
678
B.1
B.2
B.3
Random Variables and Their Probability Distributions 722
Discrete Random Variables 723 Continuous Random Variables 725
Joint Distributions, Conditional Distributions, and Independence 727
Joint Distributions and
Independence 727
Conditional Distributions 729
Features of Probability Distributions 730
A Measure of Central Tendency: The Expected Value 730
Properties of Expected Values 731
Another Measure of Central Tendency: The Median 733
Measures of Variability: Variance and Standard Deviation 734
Variance 734
Standard Deviation 736
Standardizing a Random Variable 736
Skewness and Kurtosis 737
Features of Joint and Conditional Distributions 737
Measures of Association: Covariance and Correlation 737
Covariance 737 Correlation Coefficient 739
Variance of Sums of Random
Variables 740
Conditional Expectation 741
Properties of Conditional Expectation 742 Conditional Variance 744
The Normal and Related
Distributions 745
The Normal Distribution 745
The Standard Normal Distribution 746
B.4
B.5
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Additional Properties of the Normal Distribution 748
Asymptotic Tests for Nonnormal Populations 783
Computing and Using p-Values 784 The Relationship between Confidence Intervals and Hypothesis
Testing 787
Practical versus Statistical Significance 788
Remarks on Notation 789
The Chi-Square Distribution The t Distribution 749
The F Distribution 750
Summary 752 Key Terms 752 Problems 752
749
APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 755
C.1 Populations, Parameters, and Random Sampling 755
Sampling 756
C.2 Finite Sample Properties of Estimators 756
Estimators and Estimates 757 Unbiasedness 758
The Sampling Variance of Estimators Efficiency 762
760
Summary 790 Key Terms 790 Problems 791
APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra 796
D.1 Basic Definitions 796 D.2 Matrix Operations 797
Matrix Addition 797
Scalar Multiplication 798
Matrix Multiplication 798
Transpose 799
Partitioned Matrix Multiplication 800 Trace 800
Inverse 801
D.3 Linear Independence and Rank of a Matrix 801
D.4 Quadratic Forms and Positive Definite Matrices 802
D.5 Idempotent Matrices 802
D.6 Differentiation of Linear and Quadratic
Forms 803
D.7 Moments and Distributions of Random Vectors 803
Expected Value 803 Variance-Covariance Matrix 803 Multivariate Normal Distribution 804 Chi-Square Distribution 804
t Distribution 805
F Distribution 805
Summary 805 Key Terms 805 Problems 806
C.7
Contents xiii
C.3 Asymptotic or Large Sample Properties of Estimators 763
Consistency 763
Asymptotic Normality
766
C.4 General Approaches to Parameter Estimation 768
Method of Moments 768
Maximum Likelihood
Least Squares 770
769
C.5 IntervalEstimationandConfidence Intervals 770
The Nature of Interval Estimation 770 Confidence Intervals for the Mean from a Normally Distributed Population 772
A Simple Rule of Thumb for a 95% Confidence Interval 775
Asymptotic Confidence Intervals for Nonnormal Populations 776
C.6 Hypothesis Testing 777
Fundamentals of Hypothesis
Testing 778
Testing Hypotheses about the Mean in a Normal Population 780
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

xiv Contents
APPENDIX E The Linear Regression
Model in Matrix Form 807
E.1 The Model and Ordinary Least Squares Estimation 807
E.2 Finite Sample Properties of OLS 809
E.3 Statistical Inference 813
E.4 Some Asymptotic Analysis 815
Wald Statistics for Testing Multiple Hypotheses 818
Summary 819 Key Terms 819 Problems 819
APPENDIX F Answers to Chapter Questions 821
APPENDIX G Statistical Tables 831
References 838 Glossary 844 Index 862
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

PREFACE
My motivation for writing the first edition of Introductory Econometrics: A Modern Approach was that I saw a fairly wide gap between how econometrics is taught to undergraduates and how empirical researchers think about and apply econometric methods. I became convinced that teaching introductory econometrics from the perspective of professional users of econometrics would actually simplify the presentation, in addition to making the subject much more interesting.
Based on the positive reactions to earlier editions, it appears that my hunch was correct. Many instructors, having a variety of backgrounds and interests and teaching students with different levels of preparation, have embraced the modern approach to econometrics espoused in this text. The emphasis in this edition is still on applying econo- metrics to real-world problems. Each econometric method is motivated by a particular issue facing researchers analyzing nonexperimental data. The focus in the main text is on understanding and interpreting the assumptions in light of actual empirical applica- tions: the mathematics required is no more than college algebra and basic probability and statistics.
Organized for Today’s Econometrics Instructor
The fifth edition preserves the overall organization of the fourth. The most noticeable feature that distinguishes this text from most others is the separation of topics by the kind of data being analyzed. This is a clear departure from the traditional approach, which presents a linear model, lists all assumptions that may be needed at some future point in the analysis, and then proves or asserts results without clearly connecting them to the assumptions. My approach is first to treat, in Part 1, multiple regression analysis with cross-sectional data, under the assumption of random sampling. This setting is natural to students because they are familiar with random sampling from a population in their intro- ductory statistics courses. Importantly, it allows us to distinguish assumptions made about the underlying population regression model—assumptions that can be given economic or behavioral content—from assumptions about how the data were sampled. Discussions about the consequences of nonrandom sampling can be treated in an intuitive fashion after the students have a good grasp of the multiple regression model estimated using random samples.
An important feature of a modern approach is that the explanatory variables—along with the dependent variable—are treated as outcomes of random variables. For the social sciences, allowing random explanatory variables is much more realistic than the traditional assumption of nonrandom explanatory variables. As a nontrivial benefit, the population model/random sampling approach reduces the number of assumptions that students must
xv
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

xvi Preface
absorb and understand. Ironically, the classical approach to regression analysis, which treats the explanatory variables as fixed in repeated samples and is still pervasive in intro- ductory texts, literally applies to data collected in an experimental setting. In addition, the contortions required to state and explain assumptions can be confusing to students.
My focus on the population model emphasizes that the fundamental assumptions underlying regression analysis, such as the zero mean assumption on the unobservable error term, are properly stated conditional on the explanatory variables. This leads to a clear understanding of the kinds of problems, such as heteroskedasticity (nonconstant variance), that can invalidate standard inference procedures. By focusing on the popula- tion I am also able to dispel several misconceptions that arise in econometrics texts at all levels. For example, I explain why the usual R-squared is still valid as a goodness-of- fit measure in the presence of heteroskedasticity (Chapter 8) or serially correlated errors (Chapter 12); I provide a simple demonstration that tests for functional form should not be viewed as general tests of omitted variables (Chapter 9); and I explain why one should always include in a regression model extra control variables that are uncorrelated with the explanatory variable of interest, which is often a key policy variable (Chapter 6).
Because the assumptions for cross-sectional analysis are relatively straightforward yet realistic, students can get involved early with serious cross-sectional applications with- out having to worry about the thorny issues of trends, seasonality, serial correlation, high persistence, and spurious regression that are ubiquitous in time series regression models. Initially, I figured that my treatment of regression with cross-sectional data followed by regression with time series data would find favor with instructors whose own research in- terests are in applied microeconomics, and that appears to be the case. It has been gratify- ing that adopters of the text with an applied time series bent have been equally enthusiastic about the structure of the text. By postponing the econometric analysis of time series data, I am able to put proper focus on the potential pitfalls in analyzing time series data that do not arise with cross-sectional data. In effect, time series econometrics finally gets the serious treatment it deserves in an introductory text.
As in the earlier editions, I have consciously chosen topics that are important for reading journal articles and for conducting basic empirical research. Within each topic, I have deliberately omitted many tests and estimation procedures that, while traditionally included in textbooks, have not withstood the empirical test of time. Likewise, I have emphasized more recent topics that have clearly demonstrated their usefulness, such as obtaining test statistics that are robust to heteroskedasticity (or serial correlation) of unknown form, using multiple years of data for policy analysis, or solving the omitted variable problem by instrumental variables methods. I appear to have made fairly good choices, as I have received only a handful of suggestions for adding or deleting material.
I take a systematic approach throughout the text, by which I mean that each topic is presented by building on the previous material in a logical fashion, and assumptions are introduced only as they are needed to obtain a conclusion. For example, empirical researchers who use econometrics in their research understand that not all of the Gauss-Markov assumptions are needed to show that the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimators are unbiased. Yet the vast majority of econometrics texts introduce a complete set of assumptions (many of which are redundant or in some cases even logically con- flicting) before proving the unbiasedness of OLS. Similarly, the normality assumption is often included among the assumptions that are needed for the Gauss-Markov Theorem, even though it is fairly well known that normality plays no role in showing that the OLS estimators are the best linear unbiased estimators.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

My systematic approach is illustrated by the order of assumptions that I use for multiple regression in Part 1. This structure results in a natural progression for briefly summarizing the role of each assumption:
MLR.1: Introduce the population model and interpret the population parameters (which we hope to estimate).
MLR.2: Introduce random sampling from the population and describe the data that we use to estimate the population parameters.
MLR.3: Add the assumption on the explanatory variables that allows us to compute the estimates from our sample; this is the so-called no perfect collinearity assumption.
MLR.4: Assume that, in the population, the mean of the unobservable error does not depend on the values of the explanatory variables; this is the “mean independence” assumption combined with a zero population mean for the error, and it is the key assumption that delivers unbiasedness of OLS.
After introducing Assumptions MLR.1 to MLR.3, one can discuss the algebraic properties of ordinary least squares—that is, the properties of OLS for a particular set of data. By adding Assumption MLR.4, we can show that OLS is unbiased (and consistent). Assumption MLR.5 (homoskedasticity) is added for the Gauss-Markov Theorem and for the usual OLS variance formulas to be valid. Assumption MLR.6 (normality), which is not introduced until Chapter 4, is added to round out the classical linear model assumptions. The six assumptions are used to obtain exact statistical inference and to conclude that the OLS estimators have the smallest variances among all unbiased estimators.
I use parallel approaches when I turn to the study of large-sample properties and when I treat regression for time series data in Part 2. The careful presentation and discussion of assumptions makes it relatively easy to transition to Part 3, which covers advanced top- ics that include using pooled cross-sectional data, exploiting panel data structures, and applying instrumental variables methods. Generally, I have strived to provide a unified view of econometrics, where all estimators and test statistics are obtained using just a few intuitively reasonable principles of estimation and testing (which, of course, also have rig- orous justification). For example, regression-based tests for heteroskedasticity and serial correlation are easy for students to grasp because they already have a solid understanding of regression. This is in contrast to treatments that give a set of disjointed recipes for out- dated econometric testing procedures.
Throughout the text, I emphasize ceteris paribus relationships, which is why, after one chapter on the simple regression model, I move to multiple regression analysis. The multiple regression setting motivates students to think about serious applications early. I also give prominence to policy analysis with all kinds of data structures. Practical top- ics, such as using proxy variables to obtain ceteris paribus effects and interpreting partial effects in models with interaction terms, are covered in a simple fashion.
New to This Edition
I have added new exercises to nearly every chapter. Some are computer exercises using existing data sets, some use new data sets, and others involve using computer simulations to study the properties of the OLS estimator. I have also added more challenging problems that require derivations.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Preface xvii

xviii
Preface
Some of the changes to the text are worth highlighting. In Chapter 3 I have further expanded the discussion of multicollinearity and variance inflation factors, which I first introduced in the fourth edition. Also in Chapter 3 is a new section on the language that researchers should use when discussing equations estimated by ordinary least squares. It is important for beginners to understand the difference between a model and an estimation method and to remember this distinction as they learn about more sophisticated procedures and mature into empirical researchers.
Chapter 5 now includes a more intuitive discussion about how one should think about large-sample analysis, and emphasizes that it is the distribution of sample averages that changes with the sample size; population distributions, by definition, are unchanging. Chapter 6, in addition to providing more discussion of the logarithmic transformation as applied to proportions, now includes a comprehensive list of considerations when using the most common functional forms: logarithms, quadratics, and interaction terms.
Two important additions occur in Chapter 7. First, I clarify how one uses the sum of squared residual F test to obtain the Chow test when the null hypothesis allows an intercept differ- ence across the groups. Second, I have added Section 7.7, which provides a simple yet general discussion of how to interpret linear models when the dependent variable is a discrete response.
Chapter 9 includes more discussion of using proxy variables to account for omitted, confounding factors in multiple regression analysis. My hope is that it dispels some mis- understandings about the purpose of adding proxy variables and the nature of the result- ing multicollinearity. In this chapter I have also expanded the discussion of least absolute deviations estimation (LAD). New problems—one about detecting omitted variables bias and one about heteroskedasticity and LAD estimation—have been added to Chapter 9; these should be a good challenge for well-prepared students.
The appendix to Chapter 13 now includes a discussion of standard errors that are robust to both serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in the context of first-differencing estimation with panel data. Such standard errors are computed routinely now in applied microeconomic studies employing panel data methods. A discussion of the theory is beyond the scope of this text but the basic idea is easy to describe. The appendix in Chapter 14 contains a similar discussion for random effects and fixed effects estimation. Chapter 14 also contains a new Section 14.3, which introduces the reader to the “correlated random effects” approach to panel data models with unobserved heterogeneity. While this topic is more advanced, it provides a synthesis of random and fixed effects methods, and leads to important specification tests that are often reported in empirical research.
Chapter 15, on instrumental variables estimation, has been expanded in several ways. The new material includes a warning about checking the signs of coefficients on instru- mental variables in reduced form equations, a discussion of how to interpret the reduced form for the dependent variable, and—as with the case of OLS in Chapter 3—emphasizes that instrumental variables is an estimation method, not a “model.”
Targeted at Undergraduates, Adaptable for Master’s Students
The text is designed for undergraduate economics majors who have taken college algebra and one semester of introductory probability and statistics. (Appendices A, B, and C contain the req- uisite background material.) A one-semester or one-quarter econometrics course would not be expected to cover all, or even any, of the more advanced material in Part 3. A typical introductory
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

course includes Chapters 1 through 8, which cover the basics of simple and multiple regression for cross-sectional data. Provided the emphasis is on intuition and interpreting the empirical ex- amples, the material from the first eight chapters should be accessible to undergraduates in most economics departments. Most instructors will also want to cover at least parts of the chapters on regression analysis with time series data, Chapters 10, 11, and 12, in varying degrees of depth. In the one-semester course that I teach at Michigan State, I cover Chapter 10 fairly carefully, give an overview of the material in Chapter 11, and cover the material on serial correlation in Chapter 12. I find that this basic one-semester course puts students on a solid footing to write em- pirical papers, such as a term paper, a senior seminar paper, or a senior thesis. Chapter 9 contains more specialized topics that arise in analyzing cross-sectional data, including data problems such as outliers and nonrandom sampling; for a one-semester course, it can be skipped without loss of continuity.
The structure of the text makes it ideal for a course with a cross-sectional or pol- icy analysis focus: the time series chapters can be skipped in lieu of topics from Chapters 9, 13, 14, or 15. Chapter 13 is advanced only in the sense that it treats two new data structures: independently pooled cross sections and two-period panel data analysis. Such data structures are especially useful for policy analysis, and the chapter provides several examples. Students with a good grasp of Chapters 1 through 8 will have little dif- ficulty with Chapter 13. Chapter 14 covers more advanced panel data methods and would probably be covered only in a second course. A good way to end a course on cross-sectional methods is to cover the rudiments of instrumental variables estimation in Chapter 15.
I have used selected material in Part 3, including Chapters 13, 14, 15, and 17, in a senior seminar geared to producing a serious research paper. Along with the basic one- semester course, students who have been exposed to basic panel data analysis, instrumen- tal variables estimation, and limited dependent variable models are in a position to read large segments of the applied social sciences literature. Chapter 17 provides an introduc- tion to the most common limited dependent variable models.
The text is also well suited for an introductory master’s level course, where the empha- sis is on applications rather than on derivations using matrix algebra. Several instructors have used the text to teach policy analysis at the master’s level. For instructors wanting to present the material in matrix form, Appendices D and E are self-contained treatments of the matrix algebra and the multiple regression model in matrix form.
At Michigan State, PhD students in many fields that require data analysis—including accounting, agricultural economics, development economics, economics of education, finance, international economics, labor economics, macroeconomics, political science, and public finance—have found the text to be a useful bridge between the empirical work that they read and the more theoretical econometrics they learn at the PhD level.
Design Features
Numerous in-text questions are scattered throughout, with answers supplied in Appendix F. These questions are intended to provide students with immediate feedback. Each chapter contains many numbered examples. Several of these are case studies drawn from recently published papers, but where I have used my judgment to simplify the analysis, hopefully without sacrificing the main point.
The end-of-chapter problems and computer exercises are heavily oriented toward empirical work, rather than complicated derivations. The students are asked to reason
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Preface xix

xx Preface
carefully based on what they have learned. The computer exercises often expand on the in-text examples. Several exercises use data sets from published works or similar data sets that are motivated by published research in economics and other fields.
A pioneering feature of this introductory econometrics text is the extensive glossary. The short definitions and descriptions are a helpful refresher for students studying for exams or reading empirical research that uses econometric methods. I have added and updated several entries for the fifth edition.
Data Sets—Available in Six Formats
This edition adds R data set as an additional format for viewing and analyzing data. In response to popular demand, this edition also provides the Minitab® format. With more than 100 data sets in six different formats, including Stata®, EViews®, Minitab®, Microsoft® Excel, R, and TeX, the instructor has many options for problem sets, examples, and term projects. Because most of the data sets come from actual research, some are very large. Except for partial lists of data sets to illustrate the various data structures, the data sets are not reported in the text. This book is geared to a course where computer work plays an integral role.
Updated Data Sets Handbook
An extensive data description manual is also available online. This manual contains a list of data sources along with suggestions for ways to use the data sets that are not described in the text. This unique handbook, created by author Jeffrey M. Wooldridge, lists the source of all data sets for quick reference and how each might be used. Because the data book contains page numbers, it is easy to see how the author used the data in the text. Students may want to view the descriptions of each data set and it can help guide instructors in generating new homework exercises, exam problems or term projects. The author also provides suggestions on improv- ing the data sets in this detailed resource that is available on the book’s companion website at http://login.cengage.com and students can access it free at www.cengagebrain.com.
Instructor Supplements
Instructor’s Manual with Solutions
The Instructor’s Manual with Solutions (978-1-111-57757-5) contains answers to all problems and exercises, as well as teaching tips on how to present the material in each chapter. The instructor’s manual also contains sources for each of the data files, with many suggestions for how to use them on problem sets, exams, and term papers. This supple- ment is available online only to instructors at http://login.cengage.com.
PowerPoint slides
Exceptional new PowerPoint® presentation slides, created specifically for this edition, help you create engaging, memorable lectures. You’ll find teaching slides for each chapter in this edition, including the advanced chapters in Part 3. You can modify or customize the slides for your spe- cific course. PowerPoint® slides are available for convenient download on the instructor-only, password-protected portion of the book’s companion website at http://login.cengage.com.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Scientific Word Slides
Developed by the author, new Scientific Word® slides offer an alternative format for instructors who prefer the Scientific Word® platform, the word processor cre- ated by MacKichan Software, Inc. for composing mathematical and technical docu- ments using LaTeX typesetting. These slides are based on the author’s actual lectures and are available in PDF and TeX formats for convenient download on the instructor- only, password-protected section of the book’s companion website at http://login. cengage.com.
Test Bank
In response to user requests, this edition offers a brand new Test Bank written by the author to ensure the highest quality and correspondence with the text. The author has cre- ated Test Bank questions from actual tests developed for his own courses. You will find a wealth and variety of problems, ranging from multiple-choice, to questions that require simple statistical derivations to questions that require interpreting computer output. The Test Bank is available for convenient download on the instructor-only, password-protected portion of the companion website at http://login.cengage.com.
Student Supplements
The Student Solutions Manual contains suggestions on how to read each chapter as well as answers to selected problems and computer exercises. The Student Solutions Manual can be purchased as a Printed Access Code (978-1-111-57694-3) or as an Instant Access Code (978-1-111-57693-6) and accessed online at www.cengagebrain.com.
Suggestions for Designing Your Course
I have already commented on the contents of most of the chapters as well as possible outlines for courses. Here I provide more specific comments about material in chapters that might be covered or skipped:
Chapter 9 has some interesting examples (such as a wage regression that includes IQ score as an explanatory variable). The rubric of proxy variables does not have to be for- mally introduced to present these kinds of examples, and I typically do so when finishing up cross-sectional analysis. In Chapter 12, for a one-semester course, I skip the material on serial correlation robust inference for ordinary least squares as well as dynamic models of heteroskedasticity.
Even in a second course I tend to spend only a little time on Chapter 16, which cov- ers simultaneous equations analysis. I have found that instructors differ widely in their opinions on the importance of teaching simultaneous equations models to undergraduates. Some think this material is fundamental; others think it is rarely applicable. My own view is that simultaneous equations models are overused (see Chapter 16 for a discussion). If one reads applications carefully, omitted variables and measurement error are much more likely to be the reason one adopts instrumental variables estimation, and this is why I use omitted variables to motivate instrumental variables estimation in Chapter 15.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Preface xxi

xxii Preface
Still, simultaneous equations models are indispensable for estimating demand and supply functions, and they apply in some other important cases as well.
Chapter 17 is the only chapter that considers models inherently nonlinear in their parameters, and this puts an extra burden on the student. The first material one should cover in this chapter is on probit and logit models for binary response. My presentation of Tobit models and censored regression still appears to be novel in introductory texts. I explicitly recognize that the Tobit model is applied to corner solution outcomes on random samples, while censored regression is applied when the data collection process censors the dependent variable at essentially arbitrary thresholds.
Chapter 18 covers some recent important topics from time series econometrics, including testing for unit roots and cointegration. I cover this material only in a second- semester course at either the undergraduate or master’s level. A fairly detailed introduction to forecasting is also included in Chapter 18.
Chapter 19, which would be added to the syllabus for a course that requires a term paper, is much more extensive than similar chapters in other texts. It summarizes some of the methods appropriate for various kinds of problems and data structures, points out potential pitfalls, explains in some detail how to write a term paper in empirical economics, and includes suggestions for possible projects.
Acknowledgments
I would like to thank those who reviewed the proposal for the fifth edition or provided helpful comments on the fourth edition:
Erica Johnson,
Gonzaga University
Mary Ellen Benedict,
Bowling Green State University
Yan Li,
Temple University
Melissa Tartari,
Yale University
Michael Allgrunn,
University of South Dakota
Gregory Colman,
Pace University
Yoo-Mi Chin,
Missouri University of Science and Technology
Arsen Melkumian,
Western Illinois University
Kevin J. Murphy,
Oakland University
Kristine Grimsrud,
University of New Mexico
Will Melick,
Kenyon College
Philip H. Brown,
Colby College
Argun Saatcioglu,
University of Kansas
Ken Brown,
University of Northern Iowa
Michael R. Jonas,
University of San Francisco
Melissa Yeoh,
Berry College
Nikolaos Papanikolaou,
SUNY at New Paltz
Konstantin Golyaev,
University of Minnesota
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Soren Hauge,
Ripon College
Kevin Williams,
University of Minnesota
Hailong Qian,
Saint Louis University
Rod Hissong,
University of Texas at Arlington
Steven Cuellar,
Sonoma State University
Yanan Di,
Wagner College
John Fitzgerald,
Bowdoin College
Philip N. Jefferson,
Swarthmore College
Yongsheng Wang,
Washington and Jefferson College
Sheng-Kai Chang,
National Taiwan University
Damayanti Ghosh,
Binghamton University
Susan Averett,
Lafayette College
Kevin J. Mumford,
Purdue University
Nicolai V. Kuminoff,
Arizona State University
Subarna K. Samanta,
The College of New Jersey
Jing Li,
South Dakota State University
Gary Wagner,
University of Arkansas–Little Rock
Kelly Cobourn,
Boise State University
Timothy Dittmer,
Central Washington University
Daniel Fischmar,
Westminster College
Subha Mani,
Fordham University
John Maluccio,
Middlebury College
James Warner,
College of Wooster
Christopher Magee,
Bucknell University
Andrew Ewing,
Eckerd College
Debra Israel,
Indiana State University
Jay Goodliffe,
Brigham Young University
Stanley R. Thompson,
The Ohio State University
Michael Robinson,
Mount Holyoke College
Ivan Jeliazkov,
University of California, Irvine
Heather O’Neill,
Ursinus College
Leslie Papke,
Michigan State University
Timothy Vogelsang,
Michigan State University
Stephen Woodbury,
Michigan State University
Some of the changes I discussed earlier were driven by comments I received from people on this list, and I continue to mull over other specific suggestions made by one or more reviewers.
Many students and teaching assistants, too numerous to list, have caught mistakes in earlier editions or have suggested rewording some paragraphs. I am grateful to them.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Preface
xxiii

xxiv Preface
As always, it was a pleasure working with the team at South-Western/Cengage Learning. Mike Worls, my longtime acquisitions editor, has learned very well how to guide me with a firm yet gentle hand. Julie Warwick has quickly mastered the difficult challenges of being the developmental editor of a dense, technical textbook. Julie’s careful reading of the manuscript and fine eye for detail have improved this fifth edition considerably.
Jean Buttrom did a terrific job as production manager and Karunakaran Gunasekaran at PreMediaGlobal professionally and efficiently oversaw the project management and typesetting of the manuscript.
Special thanks to Martin Biewen at the University of Tübingen for creating the origi- nal Powerpoint slides for the text. Thanks also to Francis Smart for assisting with the creation of the R data sets.
This book is dedicated to my wife, Leslie Papke, who contributed materially to this edition by writing the initial versions of the Scientific Word slides for the chapters in Part 3; she then used the slides in her public policy course. Our children have contrib- uted, too: Edmund has helped me keep the data handbook current, and Gwenyth keeps us entertained with her artistic talents.
Jeffrey M. Wooldridge
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

ABOUT THE AUTHOR
Jeffrey M. Wooldridge is University Distinguished Professor of Economics at Michigan State University, where he has taught since 1991. From 1986 to 1991, Dr. Wooldridge was an assistant professor of economics at the Massachusetts Institute of Technology. He received his bachelor of arts, with majors in computer science and economics, from the University of California, Berkeley, in 1982 and received his doctorate in economics in 1986 from the University of California, San Diego. Dr. Wooldridge has published more than three dozen articles in internationally recognized journals, as well as several book chapters. He is also the author of Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data, second edition. His awards include an Alfred P. Sloan Research Fellowship, the Plura Scripsit award from Econometric Theory, the Sir Richard Stone prize from the Journal of Applied Econometrics, and three graduate teacher-of-the-year awards from MIT. He is a fellow of the Econometric Society and of the Journal of Econometrics. Dr. Wooldridge is currently coeditor of the Journal of Econometric Methods, is past editor of the Journal of Business and Economic Statistics, and past econometrics coeditor of Economics Letters. He has served on the editorial boards of Econometric Theory, the Journal of Economic Literature, the Journal of Econometrics, the Review of Economics and Statistics, and the Stata Journal. He has also acted as an occasional econometrics consultant for Arthur Andersen, Charles River Associates, the Washington State Institute for Public Policy, and Stratus Consulting.
xxv
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER
1
The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
Chapter 1 discusses the scope of econometrics and raises general issues that arise in the application of econometric methods. Section 1.1 provides a brief discussion about the purpose and scope of econometrics, and how it fits into economics analysis. Section 1.2 provides examples of how one can start with an economic theory and build a model that can be estimated using data. Section 1.3 examines the kinds of data sets that are used in business, economics, and other social sciences. Section 1.4 provides an intui- tive discussion of the difficulties associated with the inference of causality in the social sciences.
1.1 What Is Econometrics?
Imagine that you are hired by your state government to evaluate the effectiveness of a publicly funded job training program. Suppose this program teaches workers various ways to use computers in the manufacturing process. The twenty-week program offers courses during nonworking hours. Any hourly manufacturing worker may participate, and enroll- ment in all or part of the program is voluntary. You are to determine what, if any, effect the training program has on each worker’s subsequent hourly wage.
Now, suppose you work for an investment bank. You are to study the returns on dif- ferent investment strategies involving short-term U.S. treasury bills to decide whether they comply with implied economic theories.
The task of answering such questions may seem daunting at first. At this point, you may only have a vague idea of the kind of data you would need to collect. By the end of this introductory econometrics course, you should know how to use econometric methods to formally evaluate a job training program or to test a simple economic theory.
Econometrics is based upon the development of statistical methods for estimating economic relationships, testing economic theories, and evaluating and implementing gov- ernment and business policy. The most common application of econometrics is the fore- casting of such important macroeconomic variables as interest rates, inflation rates, and gross domestic product. Whereas forecasts of economic indicators are highly visible and often widely published, econometric methods can be used in economic areas that have nothing to do with macroeconomic forecasting. For example, we will study the effects of
1
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

2 CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
political campaign expenditures on voting outcomes. We will consider the effect of school spending on student performance in the field of education. In addition, we will learn how to use econometric methods for forecasting economic time series.
Econometrics has evolved as a separate discipline from mathematical statis- tics because the former focuses on the problems inherent in collecting and analyzing nonexperimental economic data. Nonexperimental data are not accumulated through controlled experiments on individuals, firms, or segments of the economy. (Nonexperi- mental data are sometimes called observational data, or retrospective data, to empha- size the fact that the researcher is a passive collector of the data.) Experimental data are often collected in laboratory environments in the natural sciences, but they are much more difficult to obtain in the social sciences. Although some social experiments can be devised, it is often impossible, prohibitively expensive, or morally repugnant to conduct the kinds of controlled experiments that would be needed to address economic issues. We give some specific examples of the differences between experimental and nonexperimen- tal data in Section 1.4.
Naturally, econometricians have borrowed from mathematical statisticians whenever possible. The method of multiple regression analysis is the mainstay in both fields, but its focus and interpretation can differ markedly. In addition, economists have devised new techniques to deal with the complexities of economic data and to test the predictions of economic theories.
1.2 Steps in Empirical Economic Analysis
Econometric methods are relevant in virtually every branch of applied economics. They come into play either when we have an economic theory to test or when we have a rela- tionship in mind that has some importance for business decisions or policy analysis. An empirical analysis uses data to test a theory or to estimate a relationship.
How does one go about structuring an empirical economic analysis? It may seem obvious, but it is worth emphasizing that the first step in any empirical analysis is the careful formulation of the question of interest. The question might deal with testing a certain aspect of an economic theory, or it might pertain to testing the effects of a govern- ment policy. In principle, econometric methods can be used to answer a wide range of questions.
In some cases, especially those that involve the testing of economic theories, a for- mal economic model is constructed. An economic model consists of mathematical equa- tions that describe various relationships. Economists are well known for their building of models to describe a vast array of behaviors. For example, in intermediate microeconom- ics, individual consumption decisions, subject to a budget constraint, are described by mathematical models. The basic premise underlying these models is utility maximization. The assumption that individuals make choices to maximize their well-being, subject to resource constraints, gives us a very powerful framework for creating tractable economic models and making clear predictions. In the context of consumption decisions, utility maximization leads to a set of demand equations. In a demand equation, the quantity demanded of each commodity depends on the price of the goods, the price of substi- tute and complementary goods, the consumer’s income, and the individual’s character- istics that affect taste. These equations can form the basis of an econometric analysis of consumer demand.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 3
Economists have used basic economic tools, such as the utility maximization framework, to explain behaviors that at first glance may appear to be noneconomic in nature. A classic example is Becker’s (1968) economic model of criminal behavior.
EXAMPLE 1.1 ECONOMIC MODEL OF CRIME
In a seminal article, Nobel Prize winner Gary Becker postulated a utility maximization framework to describe an individual’s participation in crime. Certain crimes have clear economic rewards, but most criminal behaviors have costs. The opportunity costs of crime prevent the criminal from participating in other activities such as legal employment. In addition, there are costs associated with the possibility of being caught and then, if con- victed, the costs associated with incarceration. From Becker’s perspective, the decision to undertake illegal activity is one of resource allocation, with the benefits and costs of competing activities taken into account.
Under general assumptions, we can derive an equation describing the amount of time spent in criminal activity as a function of various factors. We might represent such a func- tion as
where
y 􏱪 hours spent in criminal activities,
x1 􏱪 “wage” for an hour spent in criminal activity, x2 􏱪 hourly wage in legal employment,
x3 􏱪 income other than from crime or employment, x4 􏱪 probability of getting caught,
x5 􏱪 probability of being convicted if caught,
x6 􏱪 expected sentence if convicted, and
x7 􏱪 age.
y 􏱪 f(x1, x2, x3, x4, x5, x6, x7),
[1.1]
Other factors generally affect a person’s decision to participate in crime, but the list above is representative of what might result from a formal economic analysis. As is common in economic theory, we have not been specific about the function f(􏱫) in (1.1). This function depends on an underlying utility function, which is rarely known. Nevertheless, we can use economic theory—or introspection—to predict the effect that each variable would have on criminal activity. This is the basis for an econometric analysis of individual criminal activity.
Formal economic modeling is sometimes the starting point for empirical analysis, but it is more common to use economic theory less formally, or even to rely entirely on intuition. You may agree that the determinants of criminal behavior appearing in equation (1.1) are reasonable based on common sense; we might arrive at such an equa- tion directly, without starting from utility maximization. This view has some merit, although there are cases in which formal derivations provide insights that intuition can overlook.
Next is an example of an equation that we can derive through somewhat informal reasoning.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

4
CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data EXAMPLE 1.2 JOB TRAINING AND WORKER PRODUCTIVITY
Consider the problem posed at the beginning of Section 1.1. A labor economist would like to examine the effects of job training on worker productivity. In this case, there is little need for formal economic theory. Basic economic understanding is sufficient for realizing that factors such as education, experience, and training affect worker produc- tivity. Also, economists are well aware that workers are paid commensurate with their productivity. This simple reasoning leads to a model such as
where
wage 􏱪 hourly wage,
educ 􏱪 years of formal education,
exper 􏱪 years of workforce experience, and training 􏱪 weeks spent in job training.
wage 􏱪 f (educ, exper, training),
[1.2]
Again, other factors generally affect the wage rate, but equation (1.2) captures the essence of the problem.
After we specify an economic model, we need to turn it into what we call an econometric model. Because we will deal with econometric models throughout this text, it is important to know how an econometric model relates to an economic model. Take equation (1.1) as an example. The form of the function f (􏱫) must be specified before we can undertake an econometric analysis. A second issue concerning (1.1) is how to deal with variables that cannot reasonably be observed. For example, consider the wage that a person can earn in criminal activity. In principle, such a quantity is well defined, but it would be difficult if not impossible to observe this wage for a given individual. Even vari- ables such as the probability of being arrested cannot realistically be obtained for a given individual, but at least we can observe relevant arrest statistics and derive a variable that approximates the probability of arrest. Many other factors affect criminal behavior that we cannot even list, let alone observe, but we must somehow account for them.
The ambiguities inherent in the economic model of crime are resolved by specifying a particular econometric model:
crime􏱪􏱬0􏱕􏱬1wagem􏱕􏱬2othinc􏱕􏱬3 freqarr􏱕􏱬4 freqconv 􏱕􏱬5avgsen􏱕􏱬6age􏱕u,
􏱪 some measure of the frequency of criminal activity,
􏱪 the wage that can be earned in legal employment,
􏱪 the income from other sources (assets, inheritance, and so on), 􏱪 the frequency of arrests for prior infractions (to approximate
the probability of arrest),
􏱪 the frequency of conviction, and
􏱪 the average sentence length after conviction.
The choice
considerations. The term u contains unobserved factors, such as the wage for criminal activity, moral character, family background, and errors in measuring things like criminal
where
crime wagem othinc freqarr
freqconv avgsen
of these variables is determined by the economic theory as well as data
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
[1.3]

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 5
activity and the probability of arrest. We could add family background variables to the model, such as number of siblings, parents’ education, and so on, but we can never elimi- nate u entirely. In fact, dealing with this error term or disturbance term is perhaps the most important component of any econometric analysis.
The constants 􏱬0, 􏱬1, …, 􏱬6 are the parameters of the econometric model, and they describe the directions and strengths of the relationship between crime and the factors used to determine crime in the model.
A complete econometric model for Example 1.2 might be
wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3training 􏱕 u, [1.4]
where the term u contains factors such as “innate ability,” quality of education, family background, and the myriad other factors that can influence a person’s wage. If we are specifically concerned about the effects of job training, then 􏱬3 is the parameter of interest.
For the most part, econometric analysis begins by specifying an econometric model, without consideration of the details of the model’s creation. We generally follow this approach, largely because careful derivation of something like the economic model of crime is time-consuming and can take us into some specialized and often difficult areas of economic theory. Economic reasoning will play a role in our examples, and we will merge any underlying economic theory into the econometric model specification. In the economic model of crime example, we would start with an econometric model such as (1.3) and use economic reasoning and common sense as guides for choosing the variables. Although this approach loses some of the richness of economic analysis, it is commonly and effectively applied by careful researchers.
Once an econometric model such as (1.3) or (1.4) has been specified, various hypotheses of interest can be stated in terms of the unknown parameters. For example, in equation (1.3), we might hypothesize that wagem, the wage that can be earned in legal em- ployment, has no effect on criminal behavior. In the context of this particular econometric model, the hypothesis is equivalent to 􏱬1 􏱪 0.
An empirical analysis, by definition, requires data. After data on the relevant vari- ables have been collected, econometric methods are used to estimate the parameters in the econometric model and to formally test hypotheses of interest. In some cases, the econo- metric model is used to make predictions in either the testing of a theory or the study of a policy’s impact.
Because data collection is so important in empirical work, Section 1.3 will describe the kinds of data that we are likely to encounter.
1.3 The Structure of Economic Data
Economic data sets come in a variety of types. Whereas some econometric methods can be applied with little or no modification to many different kinds of data sets, the special features of some data sets must be accounted for or should be exploited. We next describe the most important data structures encountered in applied work.
Cross-Sectional Data
A cross-sectional data set consists of a sample of individuals, households, firms, cities,
states, countries, or a variety of other units, taken at a given point in time. Sometimes, the
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

6 CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
data on all units do not correspond to precisely the same time period. For example, several families may be surveyed during different weeks within a year. In a pure cross-sectional analysis, we would ignore any minor timing differences in collecting the data. If a set of families was surveyed during different weeks of the same year, we would still view this as a cross-sectional data set.
An important feature of cross-sectional data is that we can often assume that they have been obtained by random sampling from the underlying population. For example, if we obtain information on wages, education, experience, and other characteristics by ran- domly drawing 500 people from the working population, then we have a random sample from the population of all working people. Random sampling is the sampling scheme cov- ered in introductory statistics courses, and it simplifies the analysis of cross-sectional data. A review of random sampling is contained in Appendix C.
Sometimes, random sampling is not appropriate as an assumption for analyzing cross- sectional data. For example, suppose we are interested in studying factors that influence the accumulation of family wealth. We could survey a random sample of families, but some families might refuse to report their wealth. If, for example, wealthier families are less likely to disclose their wealth, then the resulting sample on wealth is not a random sample from the population of all families. This is an illustration of a sample selection problem, an advanced topic that we will discuss in Chapter 17.
Another violation of random sampling occurs when we sample from units that are large relative to the population, particularly geographical units. The potential problem in such cases is that the population is not large enough to reasonably assume the observa- tions are independent draws. For example, if we want to explain new business activity across states as a function of wage rates, energy prices, corporate and property tax rates, services provided, quality of the workforce, and other state characteristics, it is unlikely that business activities in states near one another are independent. It turns out that the econometric methods that we discuss do work in such situations, but they sometimes need to be refined. For the most part, we will ignore the intricacies that arise in analyzing such situations and treat these problems in a random sampling framework, even when it is not technically correct to do so.
Cross-sectional data are widely used in economics and other social sciences. In economics, the analysis of cross-sectional data is closely aligned with the ap- plied microeconomics fields, such as labor economics, state and local public finance, industrial organization, urban economics, demography, and health economics. Data on individuals, households, firms, and cities at a given point in time are important for testing microeconomic hypotheses and evaluating economic policies.
The cross-sectional data used for econometric analysis can be represented and stored in computers. Table 1.1 contains, in abbreviated form, a cross-sectional data set on 526 working individuals for the year 1976. (This is a subset of the data in the file WAGE1.RAW.) The variables include wage (in dollars per hour), educ (years of educa- tion), exper (years of potential labor force experience), female (an indicator for gender), and married (marital status). These last two variables are binary (zero-one) in nature and serve to indicate qualitative features of the individual (the person is female or not; the person is married or not). We will have much to say about binary variables in Chapter 7 and beyond.
The variable obsno in Table 1.1 is the observation number assigned to each person in the sample. Unlike the other variables, it is not a characteristic of the individual. All econometrics and statistics software packages assign an observation number to each data
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 7
TABLE 1.1 ACross-SectionalDataSetonWagesandOtherIndividualCharacteristics
obsno wage educ exper female married
1
3.10
11
2
1
0
2
3.24
12
22
1
1
3
3.00
11
2
0
0
4
6.00
8
44
0
1
5
5.30
12
7
0
1
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
525
11.56
16
5
0
1
526
3.50
14
5
1
0
unit. Intuition should tell you that, for data such as that in Table 1.1, it does not matter which person is labeled as observation 1, which person is called observation 2, and so on. The fact that the ordering of the data does not matter for econometric analysis is a key feature of cross-sectional data sets obtained from random sampling.
Different variables sometimes correspond to different time periods in cross-sectional data sets. For example, to determine the effects of government policies on long-term eco- nomic growth, economists have studied the relationship between growth in real per capita gross domestic product (GDP) over a certain period (say, 1960 to 1985) and variables de- termined in part by government policy in 1960 (government consumption as a percentage of GDP and adult secondary education rates). Such a data set might be represented as in Table 1.2, which constitutes part of the data set used in the study of cross-country growth rates by De Long and Summers (1991).
The variable gpcrgdp represents average growth in real per capita GDP over the pe- riod 1960 to 1985. The fact that govcons60 (government consumption as a percentage of GDP) and second60 (percentage of adult population with a secondary education) cor- respond to the year 1960, while gpcrgdp is the average growth over the period from 1960 to 1985, does not lead to any special problems in treating this information as a cross- sectional data set. The observations are listed alphabetically by country, but nothing about this ordering affects any subsequent analysis.
T A B L E 1 . 2 A Data Set on Economic Growth Rates and Country Characteristics
obsno country gpcrgdp govcons60 second60
1
Argentina
0.89
9
32
2
Austria
3.32
16
50
3
Belgium
2.56
13
69
4
Bolivia
1.24
18
12
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
61
Zimbabwe
2.30
17
6
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013 © Cengage Learning, 2013

8 CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data Time Series Data
A time series data set consists of observations on a variable or several variables over time. Examples of time series data include stock prices, money supply, consumer price in- dex, gross domestic product, annual homicide rates, and automobile sales figures. Because past events can influence future events and lags in behavior are prevalent in the social sci- ences, time is an important dimension in a time series data set. Unlike the arrangement of cross-sectional data, the chronological ordering of observations in a time series conveys potentially important information.
A key feature of time series data that makes them more difficult to analyze than cross-sectional data is that economic observations can rarely, if ever, be assumed to be independent across time. Most economic and other time series are related, often strongly related, to their recent histories. For example, knowing something about the gross domes- tic product from last quarter tells us quite a bit about the likely range of the GDP during this quarter, because GDP tends to remain fairly stable from one quarter to the next. Al- though most econometric procedures can be used with both cross-sectional and time series data, more needs to be done in specifying econometric models for time series data before standard econometric methods can be justified. In addition, modifications and embellish- ments to standard econometric techniques have been developed to account for and exploit the dependent nature of economic time series and to address other issues, such as the fact that some economic variables tend to display clear trends over time.
Another feature of time series data that can require special attention is the data frequency at which the data are collected. In economics, the most common frequencies are daily, weekly, monthly, quarterly, and annually. Stock prices are recorded at daily intervals (exclud- ing Saturday and Sunday). The money supply in the U.S. economy is reported weekly. Many macroeconomic series are tabulated monthly, including inflation and unemployment rates. Other macro series are recorded less frequently, such as every three months (every quarter). Gross domestic product is an important example of a quarterly series. Other time series, such as infant mortality rates for states in the United States, are available only on an annual basis.
Many weekly, monthly, and quarterly economic time series display a strong seasonal pattern, which can be an important factor in a time series analysis. For example, monthly data on housing starts differ across the months simply due to changing weather conditions. We will learn how to deal with seasonal time series in Chapter 10.
Table 1.3 contains a time series data set obtained from an article by Castillo-Freeman and Freeman (1992) on minimum wage effects in Puerto Rico. The earliest year in the
T A B L E 1 . 3 Minimum Wage, Unemployment, and Related Data for Puerto Rico
obsno year avgmin avgcov prunemp prgnp
1
1950
0.20
20.1
15.4
878.7
2
1951
0.21
20.7
16.0
925.0
3
1952
0.23
22.6
14.8
1015.9
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
37
1986
3.35
58.1
18.9
4281.6
38
1987
3.35
58.2
16.8
4496.7
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 9
data set is the first observation, and the most recent year available is the last observation. When econometric methods are used to analyze time series data, the data should be stored in chronological order.
The variable avgmin refers to the average minimum wage for the year, avgcov is the average coverage rate (the percentage of workers covered by the minimum wage law), prunemp is the unemployment rate, and prgnp is the gross national product, in millions of 1954 dollars. We will use these data later in a time series analysis of the effect of the minimum wage on employment.
Pooled Cross Sections
Some data sets have both cross-sectional and time series features. For example, suppose that two cross-sectional household surveys are taken in the United States, one in 1985 and one in 1990. In 1985, a random sample of households is surveyed for variables such as income, savings, family size, and so on. In 1990, a new random sample of households is taken using the same survey questions. To increase our sample size, we can form a pooled cross section by combining the two years.
Pooling cross sections from different years is often an effective way of analyzing the effects of a new government policy. The idea is to collect data from the years before and after a key policy change. As an example, consider the following data set on housing prices taken in 1993 and 1995, before and after a reduction in property taxes in 1994. Sup- pose we have data on 250 houses for 1993 and on 270 houses for 1995. One way to store such a data set is given in Table 1.4.
Observations 1 through 250 correspond to the houses sold in 1993, and observations 251 through 520 correspond to the 270 houses sold in 1995. Although the order in which
T A B L E 1 . 4 Pooled Cross Sections: Two Years of Housing Prices
obsno year hprice proptax sqrft bdrms bthrms
1
1993
85500
42
1600
3
2.0
2
1993
67300
36
1440
3
2.5
3
1993
134000
38
2000
4
2.5
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
250
1993
243600
41
2600
4
3.0
251
1995
65000
16
1250
2
1.0
252
1995
182400
20
2200
4
2.0
253
1995
97500
15
1540
3
2.0
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
520
1995
57200
16
1100
2
1.5
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

10 CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
we store the data turns out not to be crucial, keeping track of the year for each observation is usually very important. This is why we enter year as a separate variable.
A pooled cross section is analyzed much like a standard cross section, except that we often need to account for secular differences in the variables across the time. In fact, in addition to increasing the sample size, the point of a pooled cross-sectional analysis is often to see how a key relationship has changed over time.
Panel or Longitudinal Data
A panel data (or longitudinal data) set consists of a time series for each cross-sectional member in the data set. As an example, suppose we have wage, education, and employ- ment history for a set of individuals followed over a ten-year period. Or we might collect information, such as investment and financial data, about the same set of firms over a five-year time period. Panel data can also be collected on geographical units. For example, we can collect data for the same set of counties in the United States on immigration flows, tax rates, wage rates, government expenditures, and so on, for the years 1980, 1985, and 1990.
The key feature of panel data that distinguishes them from a pooled cross section is that the same cross-sectional units (individuals, firms, or counties in the preceding ex- amples) are followed over a given time period. The data in Table 1.4 are not considered a panel data set because the houses sold are likely to be different in 1993 and 1995; if there are any duplicates, the number is likely to be so small as to be unimportant. In contrast, Table 1.5 contains a two-year panel data set on crime and related statistics for 150 cities in the United States.
There are several interesting features in Table 1.5. First, each city has been given a number from 1 through 150. Which city we decide to call city 1, city 2, and so on is ir- relevant. As with a pure cross section, the ordering in the cross section of a panel data set does not matter. We could use the city name in place of a number, but it is often useful to have both.
T A B L E 1 . 5 A Two-Year Panel Data Set on City Crime Statistics
obsno
city
year
murders
population
unem
police
1
1
1986
5
350000
8.7
440
2
1
1990
8
359200
7.2
471
3
2
1986
2
64300
5.4
75
4
2
1990
1
65100
5.5
75
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
.
297
149
1986
10
260700
9.6
286
298
149
1990
6
245000
9.8
334
299
150
1986
25
543000
4.3
520
300
150
1990
32
546200
5.2
493
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 11
A second point is that the two years of data for city 1 fill the first two rows or observations. Observations 3 and 4 correspond to city 2, and so on. Because each of the 150 cities has two rows of data, any econometrics package will view this as 300 observa- tions. This data set can be treated as a pooled cross section, where the same cities happen to show up in each year. But, as we will see in Chapters 13 and 14, we can also use the panel structure to analyze questions that cannot be answered by simply viewing this as a pooled cross section.
In organizing the observations in Table 1.5, we place the two years of data for each city adjacent to one another, with the first year coming before the second in all cases. For just about every practical purpose, this is the preferred way for ordering panel data sets. Contrast this organization with the way the pooled cross sections are stored in Table 1.4. In short, the reason for ordering panel data as in Table 1.5 is that we will need to perform data transformations for each city across the two years.
Because panel data require replication of the same units over time, panel data sets, especially those on individuals, households, and firms, are more difficult to obtain than pooled cross sections. Not surprisingly, observing the same units over time leads to sev- eral advantages over cross-sectional data or even pooled cross-sectional data. The benefit that we will focus on in this text is that having multiple observations on the same units allows us to control for certain unobserved characteristics of individuals, firms, and so on. As we will see, the use of more than one observation can facilitate causal inference in situations where inferring causality would be very difficult if only a single cross section were available. A second advantage of panel data is that they often allow us to study the importance of lags in behavior or the result of decision making. This information can be significant because many economic policies can be expected to have an impact only after some time has passed.
Most books at the undergraduate level do not contain a discussion of econometric methods for panel data. However, economists now recognize that some questions are dif- ficult, if not impossible, to answer satisfactorily without panel data. As you will see, we can make considerable progress with simple panel data analysis, a method that is not much more difficult than dealing with a standard cross-sectional data set.
A Comment on Data Structures
Part 1 of this text is concerned with the analysis of cross-sectional data, because this poses the fewest conceptual and technical difficulties. At the same time, it illustrates most of the key themes of econometric analysis. We will use the methods and insights from cross- sectional analysis in the remainder of the text.
Although the econometric analysis of time series uses many of the same tools as cross-sectional analysis, it is more complicated because of the trending, highly persistent nature of many economic time series. Examples that have been traditionally used to illus- trate the manner in which econometric methods can be applied to time series data are now widely believed to be flawed. It makes little sense to use such examples initially, since this practice will only reinforce poor econometric practice. Therefore, we will postpone the treatment of time series econometrics until Part 2, when the important issues concerning trends, persistence, dynamics, and seasonality will be introduced.
In Part 3, we will treat pooled cross sections and panel data explicitly. The analy- sis of independently pooled cross sections and simple panel data analysis are fairly
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

12 CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
straightforward extensions of pure cross-sectional analysis. Nevertheless, we will wait
until Chapter 13 to deal with these topics.
1.4 Causality and the Notion of Ceteris Paribus in Econometric Analysis
In most tests of economic theory, and certainly for evaluating public policy, the economist’s goal is to infer that one variable (such as education) has a causal effect on another variable (such as worker productivity). Simply finding an association between two or more variables might be suggestive, but unless causality can be established, it is rarely compelling.
The notion of ceteris paribus—which means “other (relevant) factors being equal”— plays an important role in causal analysis. This idea has been implicit in some of our earlier discussion, particularly Examples 1.1 and 1.2, but thus far we have not explicitly mentioned it.
You probably remember from introductory economics that most economic questions are ceteris paribus by nature. For example, in analyzing consumer demand, we are in- terested in knowing the effect of changing the price of a good on its quantity demanded, while holding all other factors—such as income, prices of other goods, and individual tastes—fixed. If other factors are not held fixed, then we cannot know the causal effect of a price change on quantity demanded.
Holding other factors fixed is critical for policy analysis as well. In the job train- ing example (Example 1.2), we might be interested in the effect of another week of job training on wages, with all other components being equal (in particular, education and experience). If we succeed in holding all other relevant factors fixed and then find a link between job training and wages, we can conclude that job training has a causal effect on worker productivity. Although this may seem pretty simple, even at this early stage it should be clear that, except in very special cases, it will not be possible to literally hold all else equal. The key question in most empirical studies is: Have enough other factors been held fixed to make a case for causality? Rarely is an econometric study evaluated without raising this issue.
In most serious applications, the number of factors that can affect the variable of interest—such as criminal activity or wages—is immense, and the isolation of any partic- ular variable may seem like a hopeless effort. However, we will eventually see that, when carefully applied, econometric methods can simulate a ceteris paribus experiment.
At this point, we cannot yet explain how econometric methods can be used to esti- mate ceteris paribus effects, so we will consider some problems that can arise in trying to infer causality in economics. We do not use any equations in this discussion. For each example, the problem of inferring causality disappears if an appropriate experiment can be carried out. Thus, it is useful to describe how such an experiment might be structured, and to observe that, in most cases, obtaining experimental data is impractical. It is also helpful to think about why the available data fail to have the important features of an experimental data set.
We rely for now on your intuitive understanding of such terms as random, indepen- dence, and correlation, all of which should be familiar from an introductory probability and statistics course. (These concepts are reviewed in Appendix B.) We begin with an example that illustrates some of these important issues.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 13 EXAMPLE 1.3 EFFECTS OF FERTILIZER ON CROP YIELD
Some early econometric studies [for example, Griliches (1957)] considered the effects of new fertilizers on crop yields. Suppose the crop under consideration is soybeans. Since fertilizer amount is only one factor affecting yields—some others include rainfall, quality of land, and presence of parasites—this issue must be posed as a ceteris paribus question. One way to determine the causal effect of fertilizer amount on soybean yield is to conduct an experiment, which might include the following steps. Choose several one-acre plots of land. Apply different amounts of fertilizer to each plot and subse- quently measure the yields; this gives us a cross-sectional data set. Then, use statistical methods (to be introduced in Chapter 2) to measure the association between yields and fertilizer amounts.
As described earlier, this may not seem like a very good experiment because we have said nothing about choosing plots of land that are identical in all respects except for the amount of fertilizer. In fact, choosing plots of land with this feature is not feasible: some of the factors, such as land quality, cannot even be fully observed. How do we know the results of this experiment can be used to measure the ceteris paribus effect of fertilizer? The answer depends on the specifics of how fertilizer amounts are chosen. If the levels of fertilizer are assigned to plots independently of other plot features that affect yield—that is, other charac- teristics of plots are completely ignored when deciding on fertilizer amounts—then we are in business. We will justify this statement in Chapter 2.
The next example is more representative of the difficulties that arise when inferring causality in applied economics.
EXAMPLE 1.4 MEASURING THE RETURN TO EDUCATION
Labor economists and policy makers have long been interested in the “return to educa- tion.” Somewhat informally, the question is posed as follows: If a person is chosen from the population and given another year of education, by how much will his or her wage increase? As with the previous examples, this is a ceteris paribus question, which implies that all other factors are held fixed while another year of education is given to the person.
We can imagine a social planner designing an experiment to get at this issue, much as the agricultural researcher can design an experiment to estimate fertilizer effects. Assume, for the moment, that the social planner has the ability to assign any level of education to any person. How would this planner emulate the fertilizer experiment in Example 1.3? The planner would choose a group of people and randomly assign each person an amount of education; some people are given an eighth-grade education, some are given a high school education, some are given two years of college, and so on. Subsequently, the planner mea- sures wages for this group of people (where we assume that each person then works in a job). The people here are like the plots in the fertilizer example, where education plays the role of fertilizer and wage rate plays the role of soybean yield. As with Example 1.3, if levels of education are assigned independently of other characteristics that affect pro- ductivity (such as experience and innate ability), then an analysis that ignores these other factors will yield useful results. Again, it will take some effort in Chapter 2 to justify this claim; for now, we state it without support.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

14 CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
Unlike the fertilizer-yield example, the experiment described in Example 1.4 is unfeasible. The ethical issues, not to mention the economic costs, associated with randomly determin- ing education levels for a group of individuals are obvious. As a logistical matter, we could not give someone only an eighth-grade education if he or she already has a college degree.
Even though experimental data cannot be obtained for measuring the return to educa- tion, we can certainly collect nonexperimental data on education levels and wages for a large group by sampling randomly from the population of working people. Such data are available from a variety of surveys used in labor economics, but these data sets have a feature that makes it difficult to estimate the ceteris paribus return to education. People choose their own levels of education; therefore, education levels are probably not deter- mined independently of all other factors affecting wage. This problem is a feature shared by most nonexperimental data sets.
One factor that affects wage is experience in the workforce. Since pursuing more edu- cation generally requires postponing entering the workforce, those with more education usually have less experience. Thus, in a nonexperimental data set on wages and education, education is likely to be negatively associated with a key variable that also affects wage. It is also believed that people with more innate ability often choose higher levels of edu- cation. Since higher ability leads to higher wages, we again have a correlation between education and a critical factor that affects wage.
The omitted factors of experience and ability in the wage example have analogs in the fertilizer example. Experience is generally easy to measure and therefore is similar to a variable such as rainfall. Ability, on the other hand, is nebulous and difficult to quantify; it is similar to land quality in the fertilizer example. As we will see throughout this text, accounting for other observed factors, such as experience, when estimating the ceteris paribus effect of another variable, such as education, is relatively straightforward. We will also find that accounting for inherently unobservable factors, such as ability, is much more problematic. It is fair to say that many of the advances in econometric methods have tried to deal with unobserved factors in econometric models.
One final parallel can be drawn between Examples 1.3 and 1.4. Suppose that in the fertilizer example, the fertilizer amounts were not entirely determined at random. Instead, the assistant who chose the fertilizer levels thought it would be better to put more fertilizer on the higher- quality plots of land. (Agricultural researchers should have a rough idea about which plots of land are of better quality, even though they may not be able to fully quantify the differences.) This situation is completely analogous to the level of schooling being related to unobserved abil- ity in Example 1.4. Because better land leads to higher yields, and more fertilizer was used on the better plots, any observed relationship between yield and fertilizer might be spurious.
Difficulty in inferring causality can also arise when studying data at fairly high levels of aggregation, as the next example on city crime rates shows.
EXAMPLE 1.5 THE EFFECT OF LAW ENFORCEMENT ON CITY CRIME LEVELS
The issue of how best to prevent crime has been, and will probably continue to be, with us for some time. One especially important question in this regard is: Does the presence of more police officers on the street deter crime?
The ceteris paribus question is easy to state: If a city is randomly chosen and given, say, ten additional police officers, by how much would its crime rates fall? Another way
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data 15
to state the question is: If two cities are the same in all respects, except that city A has ten more police officers than city B, by how much would the two cities’ crime rates differ?
It would be virtually impossible to find pairs of communities identical in all respects except for the size of their police force. Fortunately, econometric analysis does not require this. What we do need to know is whether the data we can collect on community crime levels and the size of the police force can be viewed as experimental. We can certainly imagine a true experiment involving a large collection of cities where we dictate how many police officers each city will use for the upcoming year.
Although policies can be used to affect the size of police forces, we clearly cannot tell each city how many police officers it can hire. If, as is likely, a city’s decision on how many police officers to hire is correlated with other city factors that affect crime, then the data must be viewed as nonexperimental. In fact, one way to view this problem is to see that a city’s choice of police force size and the amount of crime are simultaneously deter- mined. We will explicitly address such problems in Chapter 16.
The first three examples we have discussed have dealt with cross-sectional data at various levels of aggregation (for example, at the individual or city levels). The same hurdles arise when inferring causality in time series problems.
EXAMPLE 1.6 THE EFFECT OF THE MINIMUM WAGE ON UNEMPLOYMENT
An important, and perhaps contentious, policy issue concerns the effect of the minimum wage on unemployment rates for various groups of workers. Although this problem can be studied in a variety of data settings (cross-sectional, time series, or panel data), time series data are often used to look at aggregate effects. An example of a time series data set on unemployment rates and minimum wages was given in Table 1.3.
Standard supply and demand analysis implies that, as the minimum wage is increased above the market clearing wage, we slide up the demand curve for labor and total employ- ment decreases. (Labor supply exceeds labor demand.) To quantify this effect, we can study the relationship between employment and the minimum wage over time. In addition to some special difficulties that can arise in dealing with time series data, there are pos- sible problems with inferring causality. The minimum wage in the United States is not determined in a vacuum. Various economic and political forces impinge on the final mini- mum wage for any given year. (The minimum wage, once determined, is usually in place for several years, unless it is indexed for inflation.) Thus, it is probable that the amount of the minimum wage is related to other factors that have an effect on employment levels.
We can imagine the U.S. government conducting an experiment to determine the em- ployment effects of the minimum wage (as opposed to worrying about the welfare of low- wage workers). The minimum wage could be randomly set by the government each year, and then the employment outcomes could be tabulated. The resulting experimental time series data could then be analyzed using fairly simple econometric methods. But this sce- nario hardly describes how minimum wages are set.
If we can control enough other factors relating to employment, then we can still hope to estimate the ceteris paribus effect of the minimum wage on employment. In this sense, the problem is very similar to the previous cross-sectional examples.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

16
CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
Even when economic theories are not most naturally described in terms of causality, they often have predictions that can be tested using econometric methods. The following example demonstrates this approach.
EXAMPLE 1.7 THE EXPECTATIONS HYPOTHESIS
The expectations hypothesis from financial economics states that, given all information available to investors at the time of investing, the expected return on any two invest- ments is the same. For example, consider two possible investments with a three-month investment horizon, purchased at the same time: (1) Buy a three-month T-bill with a face value of $10,000, for a price below $10,000; in three months, you receive $10,000. (2) Buy a six-month T-bill (at a price below $10,000) and, in three months, sell it as a three-month T-bill. Each investment requires roughly the same amount of initial capital, but there is an important difference. For the first investment, you know exactly what the return is at the time of purchase because you know the initial price of the three-month T-bill, along with its face value. This is not true for the second investment: although you know the price of a six-month T-bill when you purchase it, you do not know the price you can sell it for in three months. Therefore, there is uncertainty in this investment for some- one who has a three-month investment horizon.
The actual returns on these two investments will usually be different. According to the expectations hypothesis, the expected return from the second investment, given all information at the time of investment, should equal the return from purchasing a three- month T-bill. This theory turns out to be fairly easy to test, as we will see in Chapter 11.
Summary
In this introductory chapter, we have discussed the purpose and scope of econometric analysis. Econometrics is used in all applied economics fields to test economic theories, to inform gov- ernment and private policy makers, and to predict economic time series. Sometimes, an econo- metric model is derived from a formal economic model, but in other cases, econometric models are based on informal economic reasoning and intuition. The goals of any econometric analysis are to estimate the parameters in the model and to test hypotheses about these parameters; the values and signs of the parameters determine the validity of an economic theory and the effects of certain policies.
Cross-sectional, time series, pooled cross-sectional, and panel data are the most com- mon types of data structures that are used in applied econometrics. Data sets involving a time dimension, such as time series and panel data, require special treatment because of the correla- tion across time of most economic time series. Other issues, such as trends and seasonality, arise in the analysis of time series data but not cross-sectional data.
In Section 1.4, we discussed the notions of ceteris paribus and causal inference. In most cases, hypotheses in the social sciences are ceteris paribus in nature: all other relevant factors must be fixed when studying the relationship between two variables. Because of the nonexperi- mental nature of most data collected in the social sciences, uncovering causal relationships is very challenging.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

Key Terms
Causal Effect
Ceteris Paribus Cross-Sectional Data Set Data Frequency Econometric Model
Problems
Economic Model Empirical Analysis Experimental Data Nonexperimental Data Observational Data
Panel Data
Pooled Cross Section Random Sampling Retrospective Data Time Series Data
CHAPTER 1
The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
17
1 Suppose that you are asked to conduct a study to determine whether smaller class sizes lead to improved student performance of fourth graders.
(i) If you could conduct any experiment you want, what would you do? Be specific.
(ii) More realistically, suppose you can collect observational data on several thousand
fourth graders in a given state. You can obtain the size of their fourth-grade class and a standardized test score taken at the end of fourth grade. Why might you expect a negative correlation between class size and test score?
(iii) Would a negative correlation necessarily show that smaller class sizes cause better performance? Explain.
2 Ajustificationforjobtrainingprogramsisthattheyimproveworkerproductivity.Suppose that you are asked to evaluate whethe r more job training makes workers more productive. However, rather than having data on individual workers, you have access to data on manu- facturing firms in Ohio. In particular, for each firm, you have information on hours of job training per worker (training) and number of nondefective items produced per worker hour (output).
(i) Carefully state the ceteris paribus thought experiment underlying this policy question.
(ii) Does it seem likely that a firm’s decision to train its workers will be independent of
worker characteristics? What are some of those measurable and unmeasurable worker
characteristics?
(iii) Name a factor other than worker characteristics that can affect worker productivity.
(iv) If you find a positive correlation between output and training, would you have con-
vincingly established that job training makes workers more productive? Explain.
3 Suppose at your university you are asked to find the relationship between weekly hours spent studying (study) and weekly hours spent working (work). Does it make sense to char- acterize the problem as inferring whether study “causes” work or work “causes” study? Explain.
Computer Exercises
C1 Use the data in WAGE1.RAW for this exercise.
(i) Find the average education level in the sample. What are the lowest and highest
years of education?
(ii) Find the average hourly wage in the sample. Does it seem high or low?
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

18
CHAPTER 1
The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
(iii)
(iv) (v)
The wage data are reported in 1976 dollars. Using the Economic Report of the President (2011 or later), obtain and report the Consumer Price Index (CPI) for the years 1976 and 2010.
Use the CPI values from part (iii) to find the average hourly wage in 2010 dollars. Now does the average hourly wage seem reasonable?
How many women are in the sample? How many men?
C2 Use
(i) How many women are in the sample, and how many report smoking during
pregnancy?
(ii) What is the average number of cigarettes smoked per day? Is the average a good
measure of the “typical” woman in this case? Explain.
(iii) Among women who smoked during pregnancy, what is the average number
of cigarettes smoked per day? How does this compare with your answer from
part (ii), and why?
(iv) Find the average of fatheduc in the sample. Why are only 1,192 observations used
to compute this average?
(v) Report the average family income and its standard deviation in dollars.
the data in BWGHT.RAW to answer this question.
C3 The
data to answer the following questions.
(i) Find the largest and smallest values of math4. Does the range make sense?
data in MEAP01.RAW are for the state of Michigan in the year 2001. Use these
Explain.
(ii) How many schools have a perfect pass rate on the math test? What percentage is
this of the total sample?
(iii) How many schools have math pass rates of exactly 50%?
(iv) Compare the average pass rates for the math and reading scores. Which test is
harder to pass?
(v) Find the correlation between math4 and read4. What do you conclude?
(vi) The variable exppp is expenditure per pupil. Find the average of exppp along
with its standard deviation. Would you say there is wide variation in per pupil
spending?
(vii) Suppose School A spends $6,000 per student and School B spends $5,500 per
student. By what percentage does School A’s spending exceed School B’s? Com- pare this to 100 · [log(6,000) – log(5,500)], which is the approximation percent- age difference based on the difference in the natural logs. (See Section A.4 in Appendix A.)
C4 The data in JTRAIN2.RAW come from a job training experiment conducted for low- income men during 1976–1977; see Lalonde (1986).
(i) Use the indicator variable train to determine the fraction of men receiving job
training.
(ii) The variable re78 is earnings from 1978, measured in thousands of 1982 dollars.
Find the averages of re78 for the sample of men receiving job training and the
sample not receiving job training. Is the difference economically large?
(iii) The variable unem78 is an indicator of whether a man is unemployed or not in
1978. What fraction of the men who received job training are unemployed? What
about for men who did not receive job training? Comment on the difference.
(iv) From parts (ii) and (iii), does it appear that the job training program was effective?
What would make our conclusions more convincing?
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 1 The Nature of Econometrics and Economic Data
C5 The data in FERTIL2.DTA were collected on women living in the Republic of Botswana in 1988. The variable children refers to the number of living children. The variable electric is a binary indicator equal to one if the woman’s home has electricity, and zero if not.
(i) Find the smallest and largest values of children in the sample. What is the average of children?
(ii) What percentage of women have electricity in the home?
(iii) Compute the average of children for those without electricity and do the same for
those with electricity. Comment on what you find.
(iv) From part (iii), can you infer that having electricity “causes” women to have fewer
children? Explain.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
19

Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

PART
1
Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
21
21
Part 1 of the text covers regression analysis with cross-sectional data. It builds upon a solid base of college algebra and basic concepts in probability and statistics. Appendices A, B, and C contain complete reviews of these topics.
Chapter 2 begins with the simple linear regression model, where we explain one variable in terms of another variable. Although simple regression is not widely used in applied econometrics, it is used occasionally and serves as a natural starting point because the algebra and interpretations are relatively straightforward.
Chapters 3 and 4 cover the fundamentals of multiple regression analysis, where we allow more than one variable to affect the variable we are trying to explain. Multiple regression is still the most commonly used method in empirical research, and so these chapters deserve careful attention. Chapter 3 focuses on the algebra of the method of ordinary least squares (OLS), while also establishing conditions under which the OLS estimator is unbiased and best linear unbiased. Chapter 4 covers the important topic of statistical inference.
Chapter 5 discusses the large sample, or asymptotic, properties of the OLS estimators. This provides justification of the inference procedures in Chapter 4 when the errors in a regression model are not normally distributed. Chapter 6 covers some additional topics in regression analysis, including advanced functional form issues, data scaling, prediction, and goodness-of-fit. Chapter 7 explains how qualitative information can be incorporated into multiple regression models.
Chapter 8 illustrates how to test for and correct the problem of heteroskedasticity, or nonconstant variance, in the error terms. We show how the usual OLS statistics can be adjusted, and we also present an extension of OLS, known as weighted least squares, that explicitly accounts for different variances in the errors. Chapter 9 delves further into the very important problem of correlation between the error term and one or more of the explanatory variables. We demonstrate how the availability of a proxy variable can solve the omitted variables problem. In addition, we establish the bias and inconsis- tency in the OLS estimators in the presence of certain kinds of measurement errors in the variables. Various data problems are also discussed, including the problem of outliers.

CHAPTER
2
The Simple Regression Model
The simple regression model can be used to study the relationship between two vari- ables. For reasons we will see, the simple regression model has limitations as a general tool for empirical analysis. Nevertheless, it is sometimes appropriate as an empirical tool. Learning how to interpret the simple regression model is good practice for studying multiple regression, which we will do in subsequent chapters.
2.1 Definition of the Simple Regression Model
Much of applied econometric analysis begins with the following premise: y and x are two variables, representing some population, and we are interested in “explaining y in terms of x,” or in “studying how y varies with changes in x.” We discussed some examples in Chapter 1, including: y is soybean crop yield and x is amount of fertilizer; y is hourly wage and x is years of education; and y is a community crime rate and x is number of police officers.
In writing down a model that will “explain y in terms of x,” we must confront three issues. First, since there is never an exact relationship between two variables, how do we allow for other factors to affect y? Second, what is the functional relationship between y and x? And third, how can we be sure we are capturing a ceteris paribus relationship between y and x (if that is a desired goal)?
We can resolve these ambiguities by writing down an equation relating y to x. A simple equation is
y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 u. [2.1]
Equation (2.1), which is assumed to hold in the population of interest, defines the simple linear regression model. It is also called the two-variable linear regression model or bivariate linear regression model because it relates the two variables x and y. We now dis- cuss the meaning of each of the quantities in (2.1). [Incidentally, the term “regression” has origins that are not especially important for most modern econometric applications, so we will not explain it here. See Stigler (1986) for an engaging history of regression analysis.]
When related by (2.1), the variables y and x have several different names used inter- changeably, as follows: y is called the dependent variable, the explained variable, the
22
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 23
T A B L E 2 . 1 Terminology for Simple Regression
yx
Dependent variable
Independent variable
Explained variable Explanatory variable
Response variable
Control variable
Predicted variable Predictor variable
Regressand
Regressor
response variable, the predicted variable, or the regressand; x is called the indepen- dent variable, the explanatory variable, the control variable, the predictor variable, or the regressor. (The term covariate is also used for x.) The terms “dependent variable” and “independent variable” are frequently used in econometrics. But be aware that the label “independent” here does not refer to the statistical notion of independence between random variables (see Appendix B).
The terms “explained” and “explanatory” variables are probably the most descrip- tive. “Response” and “control” are used mostly in the experimental sciences, where the variable x is under the experimenter’s control. We will not use the terms “predicted vari- able” and “predictor,” although you sometimes see these in applications that are purely about prediction and not causality. Our terminology for simple regression is summa- rized in Table 2.1.
The variable u, called the error term or disturbance in the relationship, represents factors other than x that affect y. A simple regression analysis effectively treats all factors affecting y other than x as being unobserved. You can usefully think of u as standing for “unobserved.”
Equation (2.1) also addresses the issue of the functional relationship between y and x. If the other factors in u are held fixed, so that the change in u is zero, 􏰧u 􏱪 0, then x has a linear effect on y:
􏰧y􏱪􏱬1􏰧x if 􏰧u􏱪0. [2.2]
Thus, the change in y is simply 􏱬1 multiplied by the change in x. This means that 􏱬1 is the slope parameter in the relationship between y and x, holding the other factors in u fixed; it is of primary interest in applied economics. The intercept parameter 􏱬0, sometimes called the constant term, also has its uses, although it is rarely central to an analysis.
EXAMPLE 2.1 SOYBEAN YIELD AND FERTILIZER Suppose that soybean yield is determined by the model
yield 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 fertilizer 􏱕 u, [2.3]
so that y 􏱪 yield and x 􏱪 fertilizer. The agricultural researcher is interested in the effect of fertilizer on yield, holding other factors fixed. This effect is given by 􏱬1. The error term u contains factors such as land quality, rainfall, and so on. The coefficient 􏱬1 measures the effect of fertilizer on yield, holding other factors fixed: 􏰧yield 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧 fertilizer.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

24
PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
EXAMPLE 2.2 A SIMPLE WAGE EQUATION
A model relating a person’s wage to observed education and other unobserved factors is
wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u. [2.4]
If wage is measured in dollars per hour and educ is years of education, then 􏱬1 measures the change in hourly wage given another year of education, holding all other factors fixed. Some of those factors include labor force experience, innate ability, tenure with current employer, work ethic, and numerous other things.
The linearity of (2.1) implies that a one-unit change in x has the same effect on y, regardless of the initial value of x. This is unrealistic for many economic applications. For example, in the wage-education example, we might want to allow for increasing returns: the next year of education has a larger effect on wages than did the previous year. We will see how to allow for such possibilities in Section 2.4.
The most difficult issue to address is whether model (2.1) really allows us to draw ceteris paribus conclusions about how x affects y. We just saw in equation (2.2) that 􏱬1 does mea- sure the effect of x on y, holding all other factors (in u) fixed. Is this the end of the causality issue? Unfortunately, no. How can we hope to learn in general about the ceteris paribus effect of x on y, holding other factors fixed, when we are ignoring all those other factors?
Section 2.5 will show that we are only able to get reliable estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 from a random sample of data when we make an assumption restricting how the unobservable u is related to the explanatory variable x. Without such a restriction, we will not be able to estimate the ceteris paribus effect, 􏱬1. Because u and x are random variables, we need a concept grounded in probability.
Before we state the key assumption about how x and u are related, we can always make one assumption about u. As long as the intercept 􏱬0 is included in the equation, nothing is lost by assuming that the average value of u in the population is zero. Mathematically,
E(u) 􏱪 0. [2.5]
Assumption (2.5) says nothing about the relationship between u and x, but simply makes a statement about the distribution of the unobserved factors in the population. Using the previous examples for illustration, we can see that assumption (2.5) is not very restrictive. In Example 2.1, we lose nothing by normalizing the unobserved factors affecting soybean yield, such as land quality, to have an average of zero in the population of all cultivated plots. The same is true of the unobserved factors in Example 2.2. Without loss of gener- ality, we can assume that things such as average ability are zero in the population of all working people. If you are not convinced, you should work through Problem 2 to see that we can always redefine the intercept in equation (2.1) to make (2.5) true.
We now turn to the crucial assumption regarding how u and x are related. A natural measure of the association between two random variables is the correlation coefficient. (See Appendix B for definition and properties.) If u and x are uncorrelated, then, as ran- dom variables, they are not linearly related. Assuming that u and x are uncorrelated goes a long way toward defining the sense in which u and x should be unrelated in equation (2.1). But it does not go far enough, because correlation measures only linear dependence between u and x. Correlation has a somewhat counterintuitive feature: it is possible for u to be uncor- related with x while being correlated with functions of x, such as x2. (See Section B.4 for further discussion.) This possibility is not acceptable for most regression purposes, as it
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

causes problems for interpreting the model and for deriving statistical properties. A better assumption involves the expected value of u given x.
Because u and x are random variables, we can define the conditional distribution of u given any value of x. In particular, for any x, we can obtain the expected (or average) value of u for that slice of the population described by the value of x. The crucial assumption is that the average value of u does not depend on the value of x. We can write this assumption as
E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 E(u). [2.6]
Equation (2.6) says that the average value of the unobservables is the same across all slices of the population determined by the value of x and that the common average is necessarily equal to the average of u over the entire population. When assumption (2.6) holds, we say that u is mean independent of x. (Of course, mean independence is implied by full inde- pendence between u and x, an assumption often used in basic probability and statistics.) When we combine mean independence with assumption (2.5), we obtain the zero condi- tional mean assumption, E(u􏱊x) 􏱪 0. It is critical to remember that equation (2.6) is the assumption with impact; assumption (2.5) essentially defines the intercept, 􏱬0.
Let us see what (2.6) entails in the wage example. To simplify the discussion, assume that u is the same as innate ability. Then (2.6) requires that the average level of ability is the same regardless of years of education. For example, if E(abil􏰫8) denotes the average ability for the group of all people with eight years of education, and E(abil􏰫16) denotes the average ability among people in the population with sixteen years of education, then (2.6) implies that these must be the same. In fact, the average ability level must be the same for all education levels. If, for example, we think that average ability increases with years of education, then (2.6) is false. (This would happen if, on average, people with more ability choose to become more educated.) As we cannot observe innate ability, we have no way of knowing whether or not average ability is the same for all education levels. But this is an issue that we must address before relying on simple regression analysis.
In the fertilizer example, if fertil- izer amounts are chosen independently of other features of the plots, then (2.6) will hold: the average land quality will not depend on the amount of fertilizer. However, if more fertilizer is put on the higher-quality plots of land, then the ex- pected value of u changes with the level of fertilizer, and (2.6) fails.
The zero conditional mean as- sumption gives 􏱬1 another interpretation that is often useful. Taking the expected value of (2.1) conditional on x and using
E(u􏱊x) 􏱪 0 gives
E(y􏱊x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x. [2.8]
Equation (2.8) shows that the population regression function (PRF), E(y􏰫x), is a linear function of x. The linearity means that a one-unit increase in x changes the expected value of y by the amount 􏱬1. For any given value of x, the distribution of y is centered about E(y􏰫x), as illustrated in Figure 2.1.
It is important to understand that equation (2.8) tells us how the average value of y changes with x; it does not say that y equals 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x for all units in the population.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 25
EXPLORING FURTHER 2.1
Suppose that a score on a final exam, score, depends on classes attended (attend) and unobserved factors that affect exam perfor- mance (such as student ability). Then
score 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1attend 􏱕 u. [2.7]
When would you expect this model to satisfy (2.6)?

26 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
FIGURE 2.1 E(y􏱘x) as a linear function of x.
y
E(y|x) 5 0 1 1x
x1 x2 x3
For example, suppose that x is the high school grade point average and y is the college GPA, and we happen to know that E(colGPA􏰫hsGPA) 􏱪 1.5 􏱕 0.5 hsGPA. [Of course, in practice, we never know the population intercept and slope, but it is useful to pretend momentarily that we do to understand the nature of equation (2.8).] This GPA equation tells us the average college GPA among all students who have a given high school GPA. So suppose that hsGPA 􏱪 3.6. Then the average colGPA for all high school graduates who attend college with hsGPA 􏱪 3.6 is 1.5 􏱕 0.5(3.6) 􏱪 3.3. We are certainly not saying that every student with hsGPA 􏱪 3.6 will have a 3.3 college GPA; this is clearly false. The PRF gives us a relationship between the average level of y at different levels of x. Some students with hsGPA 􏱪 3.6 will have a college GPA higher than 3.3, and some will have a lower college GPA. Whether the actual colGPA is above or below 3.3 depends on the unobserved factors in u, and those differ among students even within the slice of the population with hsGPA 􏱪 3.6.
Given the zero conditional mean assumption E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0, it is useful to view equation (2.1) as breaking y into two components. The piece 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x, which represents E(y􏰫x), is called the systematic part of y—that is, the part of y explained by x—and u is called the unsystematic part, or the part of y not explained by x. In Chapter 3, when we introduce more than one explanatory variable, we will discuss how to determine how large the systematic part is relative to the unsystematic part.
In the next section, we will use assumptions (2.5) and (2.6) to motivate estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 given a random sample of data. The zero conditional mean assumption also plays a crucial role in the statistical analysis in Section 2.6.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 27 2.2 Deriving the Ordinary Least Squares Estimates
Now that we have discussed the basic ingredients of the simple regression model, we will address the important issue of how to estimate the parameters 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 in equa- tion (2.1). To do this, we need a sample from the population. Let {(xi,yi): i 􏱪 1, …, n} denote a random sample of size n from the population. Because these data come from (2.1), we can write
yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui [2.9]
for each i. Here, ui is the error term for observation i because it contains all factors affect- ing yi other than xi.
As an example, xi might be the annual income and yi the annual savings for family i during a particular year. If we have collected data on fifteen families, then n 􏱪 15. A scatterplot of such a data set is given in Figure 2.2, along with the (necessarily fictitious) population regression function.
We must decide how to use these data to obtain estimates of the intercept and slope in the population regression of savings on income.
There are several ways to motivate the following estimation procedure. We will use (2.5) and an important implication of assumption (2.6): in the population, u is uncorrelated with x. Therefore, we see that u has zero expected value and that the covariance between x and u is zero:
E(u) 􏱪 0 [2.10]
F I G U R E 2 . 2 Scatterplot of savings and income for 15 families, and the population regression E(savings􏱘income) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1 income.
savings
0
0
E(savings|income) 5 0 1 1income income
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

28 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data and
Cov(x,u) 􏱪 E(xu) 􏱪 0, [2.11]
where the first equality in (2.11) follows from (2.10). (See Section B.4 for the definition and properties of covariance.) In terms of the observable variables x and y and the un- known parameters 􏱬0 and 􏱬1, equations (2.10) and (2.11) can be written as
and
E(y 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1x) 􏱪 0 [2.12] E[x(y 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1x)] 􏱪 0, [2.13]
respectively. Equations (2.12) and (2.13) imply two restrictions on the joint probability distribution of (x,y) in the population. Since there are two unknown parameters to esti- mate, we might hope that equations (2.12) and (2.13) can be used to obtain good estima- tors of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. In fact, they can be. Given a sample of data, we choose estimates 􏱬ˆ 0 and 􏱬ˆ1 to solve the sample counterparts of (2.12) and (2.13):
and
􏱦1∑n ˆˆ
n (yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi) 􏱪 0
i􏱪1
􏱦1∑n ˆˆ
n xi(yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi) 􏱪 0.
[2.14] [2.15]
i􏱪1
This is an example of the method of moments approach to estimation. (See Section C.4
for a discussion of different estimation approaches.) These equations can be solved for
􏱬ˆ and 􏱬ˆ . 01
Using the basic properties of the summation operator from Appendix A, equation (2.14) can be rewritten as
y ̄ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x ̄, [2.16]
􏱬ˆ0 􏱪 y ̄ 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1x ̄. [2.17]
Therefore, once we have the slope estimate 􏱬ˆ1, it is straightforward to obtain the intercept estimate 􏱬ˆ0, given y ̄ and x ̄.
Dropping the n􏱦1 in (2.15) (since it does not affect the solution) and plugging (2.17) into (2.15) yields
∑n ˆˆ
x i [ y i 􏱦 ( y ̄ 􏱦 􏱬 1 x ̄ ) 􏱦 􏱬 1 x i ] 􏱪 0 ,
i􏱪1 which, upon rearrangement, gives
∑n ˆ ∑n
xi(yi 􏱦 y ̄) 􏱪 􏱬1 xi(xi 􏱦 x ̄).
i􏱪1 i􏱪1
From basic properties of the summation operator [see (A.7) and (A.8)],
(x 􏱦x ̄)(y 􏱦y ̄). ii
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
where y ̄ 􏱪 n􏱦1∑ n y is the sample average of the y and likewise for x ̄. This equation allows ii
ˆ i􏱪1 ˆ
us to write 􏱬0 in terms of 􏱬1, y ̄, and x ̄:
∑n ∑n ∑n ∑n
x(x 􏱦x ̄)􏱪 (x 􏱦x ̄)2 and x(y 􏱦y ̄)􏱪
i
ii
i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1
ii

Therefore, provided that
∑n
(x 􏱦 x ̄)2 􏱰 0, i
[2.18]
[2.19]
the estimated slope is
i􏱪1 ∑n
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model
29
(x 􏱦x ̄)(y 􏱦y ̄) ii
􏱬ˆ 􏱪 i􏱪1 ∑ 1n
( x 􏱦 x ̄ ) 2 i
.
i􏱪1
Equation (2.19) is simply the sample covariance between x and y divided by the sample
variance of x. (See Appendix C. Dividing both the numerator and the denominator by n 􏱦 1 changes nothing.) This makes sense because 􏱬1 equals the population covariance divided by the variance of x when E(u) 􏱪 0 and Cov(x,u) 􏱪 0. An immediate implication is that if x and y are positively correlated in the sample, then 􏱬ˆ1 is positive; if x and y are negatively correlated, then 􏱬ˆ1 is negative.
Although the method for obtaining (2.17) and (2.19) is motivated by (2.6), the only assumption needed to compute the estimates for a particular sample is (2.18). This is hardly an assumption at all: (2.18) is true provided the xi in the sample are not all equal to the same value. If (2.18) fails, then we have either been unlucky in obtaining our sample from the population or we have not specified an interesting problem (x does not vary in the population). For example, if y 􏱪 wage and x 􏱪 educ, then (2.18) fails only if everyone in the sample has the same amount of education (for example, if everyone is a high school graduate; see Figure 2.3). If just one person has a different amount of education, then (2.18) holds, and the estimates can be computed.
FIGURE 2.3 A scatterplot of wage against education when educi 􏱪 12 for all i.
wage
0 12 educ
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

30 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
The estimates given in (2.17) and (2.19) are called the ordinary least squares (OLS) estimates of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. To justify this name, for any 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 define a fitted value for y whenx􏱪xi as
yˆi 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi. [2.20]
This is the value we predict for y when x 􏱪 xi for the given intercept and slope. There is a fitted value for each observation in the sample. The residual for observation i is the differ- ence between the actual yi and its fitted value:
uˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 yˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1xi. [2.21]
Again, there are n such residuals. [These are not the same as the errors in (2.9), a point we return to in Section 2.5.] The fitted values and residuals are indicated in Figure 2.4.
Now, suppose we choose 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 to make the sum of squared residuals, ∑n ∑n ˆˆ
uˆi2 􏱪 (yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi)2, [2.22] i􏱪1 i􏱪1
as small as possible. The appendix to this chapter shows that the conditions necessary for (􏱬ˆ0,􏱬ˆ1) to minimize (2.22) are given exactly by equations (2.14) and (2.15), without n􏱦1. Equations (2.14) and (2.15) are often called the first order conditions for the OLS esti- mates, a term that comes from optimization using calculus (see Appendix A). From our previous calculations, we know that the solutions to the OLS first order conditions are given by (2.17) and (2.19). The name “ordinary least squares” comes from the fact that these estimates minimize the sum of squared residuals.
FIGURE 2.4 Fitted values and residuals.
y
yi
ûi 5 residual
yˆi 5 fitted value
yˆ 5 ˆ 0 1 ˆ 1 x
yˆ 1 y1
x1xi x
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

When we view ordinary least squares as minimizing the sum of squared residuals, it is natural to ask: Why not minimize some other function of the residuals, such as the abso- lute values of the residuals? In fact, as we will discuss in the more advanced Section 9.4, minimizing the sum of the absolute values of the residuals is sometimes very useful. But it does have some drawbacks. First, we cannot obtain formulas for the resulting estimators; given a data set, the estimates must be obtained by numerical optimization routines. As a consequence, the statistical theory for estimators that minimize the sum of the absolute residuals is very complicated. Minimizing other functions of the residuals, say, the sum of the residuals each raised to the fourth power, has similar drawbacks. (We would never choose our estimates to minimize, say, the sum of the residuals themselves, as residu- als large in magnitude but with opposite signs would tend to cancel out.) With OLS, we will be able to derive unbiasedness, consistency, and other important statistical properties relatively easily. Plus, as the motivation in equations (2.13) and (2.14) suggests, and as we will see in Section 2.5, OLS is suited for estimating the parameters appearing in the conditional mean function (2.8).
Once we have determined the OLS intercept and slope estimates, we form the OLS regression line:
yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x, [2.23]
where it is understood that 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 have been obtained using equations (2.17) and (2.19). The notation ˆy, read as “y hat,” emphasizes that the predicted values from equation (2.23) are estimates. The intercept, 􏱬ˆ0, is the predicted value of y when x 􏱪 0, although in some cases it will not make sense to set x 􏱪 0. In those situations, 􏱬ˆ0 is not, in itself, very interesting. When using (2.23) to compute predicted values of y for various values of x, we must account for the intercept in the calculations. Equation (2.23) is also called the sample regression function (SRF) because it is the estimated version of the population regression function E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x. It is important to re- member that the PRF is something fixed, but unknown, in the population. Because the SRF is obtained for a given sample of data, a new sample will generate a different slope and intercept in equation (2.23).
In most cases, the slope estimate, which we can write as
􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏰧yˆ􏰩􏰧x, [2.24]
is of primary interest. It tells us the amount by which yˆ changes when x increases by one unit. Equivalently,
􏰧yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1􏰧x, [2.25]
so that given any change in x (whether positive or negative), we can compute the predicted change in y.
We now present several examples of simple regression obtained by using real data. In other words, we find the intercept and slope estimates with equations (2.17) and (2.19). Since these examples involve many observations, the calculations were done using an econometrics software package. At this point, you should be careful not to read too much into these regressions; they are not necessarily uncovering a causal relationship. We have said nothing so far about the statistical properties of OLS. In Section 2.5, we consider
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 31

32
PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
statistical properties after we explicitly impose assumptions on the population model
equation (2.1).
EXAMPLE 2.3 CEO SALARY AND RETURN ON EQUITY
For the population of chief executive officers, let y be annual salary (salary) in thou- sands of dollars. Thus, y 􏱪 856.3 indicates an annual salary of $856,300, and y 􏱪 1,452.6 indicates a salary of $1,452,600. Let x be the average return on equity (roe) for the CEO’s firm for the previous three years. (Return on equity is defined in terms of net income as a percentage of common equity.) For example, if roe 􏱪 10, then average return on equity is 10%.
To study the relationship between this measure of firm performance and CEO com- pensation, we postulate the simple model
salary 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1roe 􏱕 u.
The slope parameter 􏱬1 measures the change in annual salary, in thousands of dollars, when return on equity increases by one percentage point. Because a higher roe is good for the company, we think 􏱬1 􏱰 0.
The data set CEOSAL1.RAW contains information on 209 CEOs for the year 1990; these data were obtained from Business Week (5/6/91). In this sample, the average an- nual salary is $1,281,120, with the smallest and largest being $223,000 and $14,822,000, respectively. The average return on equity for the years 1988, 1989, and 1990 is 17.18%, with the smallest and largest values being 0.5 and 56.3%, respectively.
Using the data in CEOSAL1.RAW, the OLS regression line relating salary to roe is
􏱱salary 􏱪 963.191 􏱕 18.501 roe [2.26] n 􏱪 209,
where the intercept and slope estimates have been rounded to three decimal places; we use “salary hat” to indicate that this is an estimated equation. How do we interpret the equation? First, if the return on equity is zero, roe 􏱪 0, then the predicted salary is the intercept, 963.191, which equals $963,191 since salary is measured in thousands. Next, we can write the predicted change in salary as a function of the change in roe: 􏰧􏱱salary 􏱪 18.501 (􏰧roe). This means that if the return on equity increases by one percentage point, 􏰧roe 􏱪 1, then salary is predicted to change by about 18.5, or $18,500. Because (2.26) is a linear equation, this is the estimated change regardless of the initial salary.
We can easily use (2.26) to compare predicted salaries at different values of roe. Suppose roe 􏱪 30. Then s􏱱alary 􏱪 963.191 􏱕 18.501(30) 􏱪 1,518,221, which is just over $1.5 million. However, this does not mean that a particular CEO whose firm had a roe 􏱪 30 earns $1,518,221. Many other factors affect salary. This is just our prediction from the OLS regression line (2.26). The estimated line is graphed in Figure 2.5, along with the popu- lation regression function E(salary􏰫roe). We will never know the PRF, so we cannot tell how close the SRF is to the PRF. Another sample of data will give a different regression line, which may or may not be closer to the population regression line.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 33
FIGURE 2.5 The OLS regression line 􏱱salary 􏱪 963.191 􏱕 18.501 roe and the (unknown) population regression function.
salary
963.191
salary 5 963.191 1 18.501 roe
E(salary|roe) 5 0 1 1roe
roe
EXAMPLE 2.4 WAGE AND EDUCATION
For the population of people in the workforce in 1976, let y 􏱪 wage, where wage is measured in dollars per hour. Thus, for a particular person, if wage 􏱪 6.75, the hourly wage is $6.75. Let x 􏱪 educ denote years of schooling; for example, educ 􏱪 12 cor- responds to a complete high school education. Since the average wage in the sample is $5.90, the Consumer Price Index indicates that this amount is equivalent to $19.06 in 2003 dollars.
Using the data in WAGE1.RAW where n 􏱪 526 individuals, we obtain the following OLS regression line (or sample regression function):
wage􏱪􏱦0.90 􏱕 0.54 educ [2.27] 􏱱
n 􏱪 526.
We must interpret this equation with caution. The intercept of 􏱦0.90 liter- ally means that a person with no edu- cation has a predicted hourly wage of 􏱦90¢ an hour. This, of course, is silly. It turns out that only 18 people in the sam- ple of 526 have less than eight years of
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
EXPLORING FURTHER 2.2
The estimated wage from (2.27), when educ 􏱪 8, is $3.42 in 1976 dollars. What is this value in 2003 dollars? (Hint: You have enough information in Example 2.4 to an- swer this question.)
© Cengage Learning, 2013

34 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
education. Consequently, it is not surprising that the regression line does poorly at very low levels of education. For a person with eight years of education, the predicted wage is
The slope estimate in (2.27) implies that one more year of education increases hourly wage by 54¢ an hour. Therefore, four more years of education increase the predicted wage by 4(0.54) 􏱪 2.16, or $2.16 per hour. These are fairly large effects. Because of the linear nature of (2.27), another year of education increases the wage by the same amount, regard- less of the initial level of education. In Section 2.4, we discuss some methods that allow for nonconstant marginal effects of our explanatory variables.
EXAMPLE 2.5 VOTING OUTCOMES AND CAMPAIGN EXPENDITURES
The file VOTE1.RAW contains data on election outcomes and campaign expenditures for 173 two-party races for the U.S. House of Representatives in 1988. There are two candi- dates in each race, A and B. Let voteA be the percentage of the vote received by Candidate A and shareA be the percentage of total campaign expenditures accounted for by Candi- date A. Many factors other than shareA affect the election outcome (including the quality of the candidates and possibly the dollar amounts spent by A and B). Nevertheless, we can estimate a simple regression model to find out whether spending more relative to one’s challenger implies a higher percentage of the vote.
The estimated equation using the 173 observations is
􏱱voteA 􏱪 26.81 􏱕 0.464 shareA [2.28]
n 􏱪 173.
This means that if Candidate A’s share of spending increases by one percentage point, Candi- date A receives almost one-half a percentage point (0.464) more of the total vote. Whether or not this is a causal effect is unclear, but it is not unbelievable. If shareA 􏱪 50, voteA is predicted to be about 50, or half the vote.
In some cases, regression analysis is not used to determine causality but to simply look at whether two variables are positively or negatively related, much like a standard correlation analysis. An example of this occurs in Computer Exercise C3, where you are asked to use
data from Biddle and Hamermesh (1990) on time spent sleeping and working to investi- gate the tradeoff between these two factors.
A Note on Terminology
In most cases, we will indicate the estimation of a relationship through OLS by writing an equation such as (2.26), (2.27), or (2.28). Sometimes, for the sake of brevity, it is useful to indicate that an OLS regression has been run without actually writing out the equation. We will often indicate that equation (2.23) has been obtained by OLS in saying that we run the regression of
y on x, [2.29]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
􏱱
wage 􏱪􏱦0.90 􏱕 0.54(8) 􏱪 3.42, or $3.42 per hour (in 1976 dollars).
EXPLORING FURTHER 2.3
In Example 2.5, what is the predicted vote for Candidate A if shareA 􏱪 60 (which means 60%)? Does this answer seem reasonable?

or simply that we regress y on x. The positions of y and x in (2.29) indicate which is the dependent variable and which is the independent variable: we always regress the depen- dent variable on the independent variable. For specific applications, we replace y and x with their names. Thus, to obtain (2.26), we regress salary on roe, or to obtain (2.28), we regress voteA on shareA.
When we use such terminology in (2.29), we will always mean that we plan to estimate the intercept, 􏱬ˆ0, along with the slope, 􏱬ˆ1. This case is appropriate for the vast majority of applications. Occasionally, we may want to estimate the relationship between y and x assuming that the intercept is zero (so that x 􏱪 0 implies that yˆ 􏱪 0); we cover this case briefly in Section 2.6. Unless explicitly stated otherwise, we always estimate an intercept along with a slope.
2.3 Properties of OLS on Any Sample of Data
In the previous section, we went through the algebra of deriving the formulas for the OLS intercept and slope estimates. In this section, we cover some further algebraic properties of the fitted OLS regression line. The best way to think about these proper- ties is to remember that they hold, by construction, for any sample of data. The harder task—considering the properties of OLS across all possible random samples of data—is postponed until Section 2.5.
Several of the algebraic properties we are going to derive will appear mundane. Nevertheless, having a grasp of these properties helps us to figure out what happens to the OLS estimates and related statistics when the data are manipulated in certain ways, such as when the measurement units of the dependent and independent variables change.
Fitted Values and Residuals
We assume that the intercept and slope estimates, 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1, have been obtained for the given sample of data. Given 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1, we can obtain the fitted value yˆi for each observa- tion. [This is given by equation (2.20).] By definition, each fitted value of yˆi is on the OLS regression line. The OLS residual associated with observation i, uˆi, is the difference be- tween yi and its fitted value, as given in equation (2.21). If uˆi is positive, the line underpre- dicts yi; if uˆi is negative, the line overpredicts yi. The ideal case for observation i is when uˆi 􏱪 0, but in most cases, every residual is not equal to zero. In other words, none of the data points must actually lie on the OLS line.
EXAMPLE 2.6 CEO SALARY AND RETURN ON EQUITY
Table 2.2 contains a listing of the first 15 observations in the CEO data set, along with the fitted values, called salaryhat, and the residuals, called uhat.
The first four CEOs have lower salaries than what we predicted from the OLS regres- sion line (2.26); in other words, given only the firm’s roe, these CEOs make less than what we predicted. As can be seen from the positive uhat, the fifth CEO makes more than pre- dicted from the OLS regression line.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 35

36 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
T A B L E 2 . 2 Fitted Values and Residuals for the First 15 CEOs
obsno roe salary salaryhat uhat
1
14.1
1095
1224.058
􏱦129.0581
2 10.9 1001 1164.854 􏱦163.8542
3
23.5
1122
1397.969
􏱦275.9692
4 5.9 578 1072.348 􏱦494.3484
5
13.8
1368
1218.508
149.4923
6 20.0 1145 1333.215 􏱦188.2151
7
16.4
1078
1266.611
􏱦188.6108
8 16.3 1094 1264.761 􏱦170.7606
9
10.5
1237
1157.454
79.54626
10 26.3 833 1449.773 􏱦616.7726
11
25.9
567
1442.372
􏱦875.3721
12 26.8 933 1459.023 􏱦526.0231
13
14.8
1339
1237.009
101.9911
14 22.3 937 1375.768 􏱦438.7678
15
56.3
2011
2004.808
6.191895
Algebraic Properties of OLS Statistics
There are several useful algebraic properties of OLS estimates and their associated statis- tics. We now cover the three most important of these.
(1) The sum, and therefore the sample average of the OLS residuals, is zero. Mathematically,
This property needs no proof; it follows immediately from the OLS first order condition (2.14), when we remember that the residuals are defined by uˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1xi. In other words, the OLS estimates 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 are chosen to make the residuals add up to zero (for any data set). This says nothing about the residual for any particular observation i.
(2) The sample covariance between the regressors and the OLS residuals is zero. This follows from the first order condition (2.15), which can be written in terms of the residuals as
∑n
i i􏱪1
∑n
ii i􏱪1
The sample average of the OLS residuals is zero, so the left-hand side of (2.31) is proportional to the sample covariance between xi and uˆi.
(3) The point (x ̄,y ̄) is always on the OLS regression line. In other words, if we take equation (2.23) and plug in x ̄ for x, then the predicted value is y ̄. This is exactly what equation (2.16) showed us.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
uˆ 􏱪 0. [2.30]
x uˆ 􏱪 0. [2.31]
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 37 EXAMPLE 2.7 WAGE AND EDUCATION
For the data in WAGE1.RAW, the average hourly wage in the sample is 5.90, rounded to
two decimal places, and the average education is 12.56. If we plug educ 􏱪 12.56 into the
OLS regression line (2.27), we get wage 􏱪 􏱦0.90 􏱕 0.54(12.56) 􏱪 5.8824, which equals 􏱱
5.9 when rounded to the first decimal place. These figures do not exactly agree because we have rounded the average wage and education, as well as the intercept and slope esti- mates. If we did not initially round any of the values, we would get the answers to agree more closely, but to little useful effect.
Writing each yi as its fitted value, plus its residual, provides another way to interpret an OLS regression. For each i, write
yi 􏱪 yˆi 􏱕 uˆi. [2.32] From property (1), the average of the residuals is zero; equivalently, the sample aver-
̄
age of the fitted values, yˆi, is the same as the sample average of the yi, or yˆ 􏱪 y ̄. Further,
properties (1) and (2) can be used to show that the sample covariance between yˆi and uˆi is zero. Thus, we can view OLS as decomposing each yi into two parts, a fitted value and a residual. The fitted values and residuals are uncorrelated in the sample.
Define the total sum of squares (SST), the explained sum of squares (SSE), and the residual sum of squares (SSR) (also known as the sum of squared residuals), as follows:
[2.33]
[2.34]
[2.35]
i􏱪1
SST is a measure of the total sample variation in the yi; that is, it measures how spread
out the yi are in the sample. If we divide SST by n 􏱦 1, we obtain the sample variance of y, as discussed in Appendix C. Similarly, SSE measures the sample variation in the yˆi (where we use the fact that yˆ ̄ 􏱪 y ̄), and SSR measures the sample variation in the uˆi . The total variation in y can always be expressed as the sum of the explained variation and the unexplained variation SSR. Thus,
SST 􏱪 SSE 􏱕 SSR. [2.36]
Proving (2.36) is not difficult, but it requires us to use all of the properties of the summa- tion operator covered in Appendix A. Write
∑n i􏱪1
( y 􏱦 y ̄ ) 2 􏱪 i
∑n
i􏱪1
[ ( y 􏱦 yˆ ) 􏱕 ( yˆ 􏱦 y ̄ ) ] 2 iii
􏱪 􏱪
[uˆ 􏱕 (yˆ 􏱦 y ̄)]2
uˆ 2 􏱕 2 uˆ ( yˆ 􏱦 y ̄ ) 􏱕
SST 􏱲 ∑n
(y 􏱦 y ̄)2. i
SSE 􏱲 SSR 􏱲
(yˆ 􏱦 y ̄)2.
∑n
ii i􏱪1
∑n
i􏱪1
i
i􏱪1 ∑n
uˆ2. i
∑n ∑n ∑n
( yˆ 􏱦 y ̄ ) 2 i
i
i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1
∑n
􏱪 S S R 􏱕 2 uˆ ( yˆ 􏱦 y ̄ ) 􏱕 S S E .
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
ii i􏱪1
ii

38 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Now, (2.36) holds if we show that
∑n
ii i􏱪1
uˆ (yˆ 􏱦 y ̄) 􏱪 0.
[2.37]
But we have already claimed that the sample covariance between the residuals and the fitted values is zero, and this covariance is just (2.37) divided by n􏱦1. Thus, we have established (2.36).
Some words of caution about SST, SSE, and SSR are in order. There is no uniform agreement on the names or abbreviations for the three quantities defined in equations (2.33), (2.34), and (2.35). The total sum of squares is called either SST or TSS, so there is little con- fusion here. Unfortunately, the explained sum of squares is sometimes called the “regression sum of squares.” If this term is given its natural abbreviation, it can easily be confused with the term “residual sum of squares.” Some regression packages refer to the explained sum of squares as the “model sum of squares.”
To make matters even worse, the residual sum of squares is often called the “error sum of squares.” This is especially unfortunate because, as we will see in Section 2.5, the errors and the residuals are different quantities. Thus, we will always call (2.35) the residual sum of squares or the sum of squared residuals. We prefer to use the abbreviation SSR to de- note the sum of squared residuals, because it is more common in econometric packages.
Goodness-of-Fit
So far, we have no way of measuring how well the explanatory or independent variable, x, explains the dependent variable, y. It is often useful to compute a number that summarizes how well the OLS regression line fits the data. In the following discussion, be sure to re- member that we assume that an intercept is estimated along with the slope.
Assuming that the total sum of squares, SST, is not equal to zero—which is true ex- cept in the very unlikely event that all the yi equal the same value—we can divide (2.36) by SST to get 1 􏱪 SSE/SST 􏱕 SSR/SST. The R-squared of the regression, sometimes called the coefficient of determination, is defined as
R2 􏱲 SSE/SST 􏱪 1 􏱦 SSR/SST. [2.38]
R2 is the ratio of the explained variation compared to the total variation; thus, it is interpreted as the fraction of the sample variation in y that is explained by x. The second equality in (2.38) provides another way for computing R2.
From (2.36), the value of R2 is always between zero and one, because SSE can be no greater than SST. When interpreting R2, we usually multiply it by 100 to change it into a percent: 100􏱳R2 is the percentage of the sample variation in y that is explained by x.
If the data points all lie on the same line, OLS provides a perfect fit to the data. In this case, R2 􏱪 1. A value of R2 that is nearly equal to zero indicates a poor fit of the OLS line: very little of the variation in the yi is captured by the variation in the yˆi (which all lie on the OLS regression line). In fact, it can be shown that R2 is equal to the square of the sample correlation coefficient between yi and yˆi. This is where the term “R-squared” came from. (The letter R was traditionally used to denote an estimate of a population correlation coefficient, and its usage has survived in regression analysis.)
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 39
EXAMPLE 2.8 CEO SALARY AND RETURN ON EQUITY In the CEO salary regression, we obtain the following:
􏱱salary 􏱪 963.191 􏱕 18.501 roe [2.39]
n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 0.0132.
We have reproduced the OLS regression line and the number of observations for clarity.
Using the R-squared (rounded to four decimal places) reported for this equation, we can see how much of the variation in salary is actually explained by the return on equity. The answer is: not much. The firm’s return on equity explains only about 1.3% of the variation in salaries for this sample of 209 CEOs. That means that 98.7% of the salary variations for these CEOs is left unexplained! This lack of explanatory power may not be too surpris- ing because many other characteristics of both the firm and the individual CEO should influence salary; these factors are necessarily included in the errors in a simple regression analysis.
In the social sciences, low R-squareds in regression equations are not uncommon, especially for cross-sectional analysis. We will discuss this issue more generally under multiple regression analysis, but it is worth emphasizing now that a seemingly low R-squared does not necessarily mean that an OLS regression equation is useless. It is still possible that (2.39) is a good estimate of the ceteris paribus relationship between salary and roe; whether or not this is true does not depend directly on the size of R- squared. Students who are first learning econometrics tend to put too much weight on the size of the R-squared in evaluating regression equations. For now, be aware that using R-squared as the main gauge of success for an econometric analysis can lead to trouble.
Sometimes, the explanatory variable explains a substantial part of the sample varia- tion in the dependent variable.
EXAMPLE 2.9 VOTING OUTCOMES AND CAMPAIGN EXPENDITURES
In the voting outcome equation in (2.28), R2 􏱪 0.856. Thus, the share of campaign ex- penditures explains over 85% of the variation in the election outcomes for this sample. This is a sizable portion.
2.4 Units of Measurement and Functional Form
Two important issues in applied economics are (1) understanding how changing the units of measurement of the dependent and/or independent variables affects OLS estimates and (2) knowing how to incorporate popular functional forms used in economics into regres- sion analysis. The mathematics needed for a full understanding of functional form issues is reviewed in Appendix A.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

40 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
The Effects of Changing Units of Measurement
on OLS Statistics
In Example 2.3, we chose to measure annual salary in thousands of dollars, and the return on equity was measured as a percentage (rather than as a decimal). It is crucial to know how salary and roe are measured in this example in order to make sense of the estimates in equation (2.39).
We must also know that OLS estimates change in entirely expected ways when the units of measurement of the dependent and independent variables change. In Example 2.3, suppose that, rather than measuring salary in thousands of dollars, we measure it in dollars. Let salardol be salary in dollars (salardol 􏱪 845,761 would be interpreted as $845,761). Of course, salardol has a simple relationship to the salary measured in thou- sands of dollars: salardol 􏱪 1,000􏱳salary. We do not need to actually run the regression of salardol on roe to know that the estimated equation is:
􏱱salardol 􏱪 963,191 􏱕 18,501 roe. [2.40]
We obtain the intercept and slope in (2.40) simply by multiplying the intercept and the slope in (2.39) by 1,000. This gives equations (2.39) and (2.40) the same interpretation. Looking at (2.40), if roe 􏱪 0, then 􏱱salardol 􏱪 963,191, so the predicted salary is $963,191 [the same value we obtained from equation (2.39)]. Furthermore, if roe increases by one, then the predicted salary increases by $18,501; again, this is what we concluded from our earlier analysis of equation (2.39).
Generally, it is easy to figure out what happens to the intercept and slope estimates when the dependent variable changes units of measurement. If the dependent variable is multiplied by the constant c—which means each value in the sample is multiplied by c—then the OLS intercept and slope estimates are also multiplied by c. (This assumes nothing has changed about the independent variable.) In the CEO salary example, c 􏱪 1,000 in moving from salary to salardol.
We can also use the CEO salary example to see what happens when we change the units of measurement of the independent variable. Define roedec 􏱪 roe/100 to be the decimal equivalent of roe; thus, roedec 􏱪 0.23 means a return on equity of 23%. To focus on changing the units of
measurement of the independent variable, we return to our original dependent vari- able, salary, which is measured in thousands of dollars. When we regress salary on roedec, we obtain
􏱱salary 􏱪 963.191 􏱕 1,850.1 roedec. [2.41]
The coefficient on roedec is 100 times the coefficient on roe in (2.39). This is as it should be. Changing roe by one percentage point is equivalent to 􏰧roedec 􏱪 0.01. From (2.41), if 􏰧roedec 􏱪 0.01, then 􏰧􏱱salary 􏱪 1,850.1(0.01) 􏱪 18.501, which is what is obtained by using (2.39). Note that, in moving from (2.39) to (2.41), the independent variable was divided by 100, and so the OLS slope estimate was multiplied by 100, preserving the in- terpretation of the equation. Generally, if the independent variable is divided or multiplied
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
EXPLORING FURTHER 2.4
Suppose that salary is measured in hun- dreds of dollars, rather than in thousands of dollars, say, salarhun. What will be the OLS intercept and slope estimates in the regres- sion of salarhun on roe?

by some nonzero constant, c, then the OLS slope coefficient is multiplied or divided by c, respectively.
The intercept has not changed in (2.41) because roedec 􏱪 0 still corresponds to a zero return on equity. In general, changing the units of measurement of only the independent variable does not affect the intercept.
In the previous section, we defined R-squared as a goodness-of-fit measure for OLS regression. We can also ask what happens to R2 when the unit of measurement of either the independent or the dependent variable changes. Without doing any algebra, we should know the result: the goodness-of-fit of the model should not depend on the units of measurement of our variables. For example, the amount of variation in salary explained by the return on equity should not depend on whether salary is measured in dollars or in thou- sands of dollars or on whether return on equity is a percentage or a decimal. This intuition can be verified mathematically: using the definition of R2, it can be shown that R2 is, in fact, invariant to changes in the units of y or x.
Incorporating Nonlinearities in Simple Regression
So far, we have focused on linear relationships between the dependent and indepen- dent variables. As we mentioned in Chapter 1, linear relationships are not nearly general enough for all economic applications. Fortunately, it is rather easy to incorporate many nonlinearities into simple regression analysis by appropriately defining the dependent and independent variables. Here, we will cover two possibilities that often appear in ap- plied work.
In reading applied work in the social sciences, you will often encounter regression equations where the dependent variable appears in logarithmic form. Why is this done? Recall the wage-education example, where we regressed hourly wage on years of educa- tion. We obtained a slope estimate of 0.54 [see equation (2.27)], which means that each additional year of education is predicted to increase hourly wage by 54 cents. Because of the linear nature of (2.27), 54 cents is the increase for either the first year of education or the twentieth year; this may not be reasonable.
Probably a better characterization of how wage changes with education is that each year of education increases wage by a constant percentage. For example, an increase in education from 5 years to 6 years increases wage by, say, 8% (ceteris paribus), and an increase in education from 11 to 12 years also increases wage by 8%. A model that gives (approximately) a constant percentage effect is
log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u, [2.42] where log(􏱳) denotes the natural logarithm. (See Appendix A for a review of logarithms.)
In particular, if 􏰧u 􏱪 0, then
%􏰧wage 􏱴 (100􏱳􏱬1)􏰧educ. [2.43]
Notice how we multiply 􏱬1 by 100 to get the percentage change in wage given one ad- ditional year of education. Since the percentage change in wage is the same for each additional year of education, the change in wage for an extra year of education increases
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 41

42
PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
FIGURE 2.6 wage 􏱪 exp(􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1educ), with 􏱮1 > 0.
wage
0 educ
EXAMPLE 2.10 A LOG WAGE EQUATION
Using the same data as in Example 2.4, but using log(wage) as the dependent variable, we
obtain the following relation􏱱ship:
log(wage) 􏱪 0.584 􏱕 0.083 educ [2.44]
n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 0.186.
The coefficient on educ has a percentage interpretation when it is multiplied by 100: 􏱵wage increases by 8.3% for every additional year of education. This is what economists mean when they refer to the “return to another year of education.”
It is important to remember that the main reason for using the log of wage in (2.42) is to impose a constant percentage effect of education on wage. Once equation (2.44) is obtained, the natural log of wage is rarely mentioned. In particular, it is not correct to say that another year of education increases log(wage) by 8.3%.
The intercept in (2.44) is not very meaningful, because it gives the predicted log(wage), when educ 􏱪 0. The R-squared shows that educ explains about 18.6% of the variation in log(wage) (not wage). Finally, equation (2.44) might not capture all of the nonlinearity in the relationship between wage and schooling. If there are “diploma ef- fects,” then the twelfth year of education—graduation from high school—could be worth much more than the eleventh year. We will learn how to allow for this kind of nonlinearity in Chapter 7.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

as education increases; in other words, (2.42) implies an increasing return to education. By exponentiating (2.42), we can write wage 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u). This equation is graphed in Figure 2.6, with u 􏱪 0.
Estimating a model such as (2.42) is straightforward when using simple regression. Just define the dependent variable, y, to be y 􏱪 log(wage). The independent variable is represented by x 􏱪 educ. The mechanics of OLS are the same as before: the intercept and slope estimates are given by the formulas (2.17) and (2.19). In other words, we obtain 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 from the OLS regression of log(wage) on educ.
Another important use of the natural log is in obtaining a constant elasticity model.
EXAMPLE 2.11 CEO SALARY AND FIRM SALES
We can estimate a constant elasticity model relating CEO salary to firm sales. The data set is the same one used in Example 2.3, except we now relate salary to sales. Let sales be an- nual firm sales, measured in millions of dollars. A constant elasticity model is
log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 u, [2.45]
where 􏱬1 is the elasticity of salary with respect to sales. This model falls under the simple regression model by defining the dependent variable to be y 􏱪 log(salary) and the inde- pendent variable to be x 􏱪 log(sales). Estimating this equation by OLS gives
􏱱log(salary) 􏱪 4.822 􏱕 0.257 log(sales) [2.46] n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 0.211.
The coefficient of log(sales) is the estimated elasticity of salary with respect to sales. It implies that a 1% increase in firm sales increases CEO salary by about 0.257%—the usual interpretation of an elasticity.
The two functional forms covered in this section will often arise in the remainder of this text. We have covered models containing natural logarithms here because they appear so frequently in applied work. The interpretation of such models will not be much differ- ent in the multiple regression case.
It is also useful to note what happens to the intercept and slope estimates if we change the units of measurement of the dependent variable when it appears in logarithmic form. Be- cause the change to logarithmic form approximates a proportionate change, it makes sense that nothing happens to the slope. We can see this by writing the rescaled variable as c1yi for each observation i. The original equation is log(yi) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui. If we add log(c1) to both sides, we get log(c1) 􏱕 log(yi) 􏱪 [log(c1) 􏱕 􏱬0] 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui, or log(c1yi) 􏱪 [log(c1) 􏱕 􏱬0] 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui . (Remember that the sum of the logs is equal to the log of their product, as shown in Appendix A.) Therefore, the slope is still 􏱬1, but the intercept is now log(c1) 􏱕 􏱬0. Similarly, if the independent variable is log(x), and we change the units of measurement of x before taking the log, the slope remains the same, but the intercept changes. You will be asked to verify these claims in Problem 9.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 43

44 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
T A B L E 2 . 3 Summary of Functional Forms Involving Logarithms
Dependent Independent Interpretation Model Variable Variable of 􏱮1
Level-level
y
x
􏰧y 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧x
Level-log
y
log(x)
􏰧y 􏱪 (􏱬1/100)%􏰧x
Log-level
log(y)
x
%􏰧y 􏱪 (100􏱬1)􏰧x
Log-log
log(y)
log(x)
%􏰧y 􏱪 􏱬1%􏰧x
We end this subsection by summarizing four combinations of functional forms avail- able from using either the original variable or its natural log. In Table 2.3, x and y stand for the variables in their original form. The model with y as the dependent variable and x as the independent variable is called the level-level model because each variable appears in its level form. The model with log(y) as the dependent variable and x as the independent vari- able is called the log-level model. We will not explicitly discuss the level-log model here, because it arises less often in practice. In any case, we will see examples of this model in later chapters.
The last column in Table 2.3 gives the interpretation of 􏱬1. In the log-level model, 100􏱳􏱬1 is sometimes called the semi-elasticity of y with respect to x. As we mentioned in Example 2.11, in the log-log model, 􏱬1 is the elasticity of y with respect to x. Table 2.3 warrants careful study, as we will refer to it often in the remainder of the text.
The Meaning of “Linear” Regression
The simple regression model that we have studied in this chapter is also called the simple linear regression model. Yet, as we have just seen, the general model also allows for certain nonlinear relationships. So what does “linear” mean here? You can see by look- ing at equation (2.1) that y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 u. The key is that this equation is linear in the parameters 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. There are no restrictions on how y and x relate to the original explained and explanatory variables of interest. As we saw in Examples 2.10 and 2.11, y and x can be natural logs of variables, and this is quite common in applications. But we need not stop there. For example, nothing prevents us from using simple regression
___
to estimate a model such as cons 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1√ inc 􏱕 u, where cons is annual consumption
and inc is annual income.
Whereas the mechanics of simple regression do not depend on how y and x are de-
fined, the interpretation of the coefficients does depend on their definitions. For successful empirical work, it is much more important to become proficient at interpreting coefficients than to become efficient at computing formulas such as (2.19). We will get much more practice with interpreting the estimates in OLS regression lines when we study multiple regression.
Plenty of models cannot be cast as a linear regression model because they are not linear in their parameters; an example is cons 􏱪 1/(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc) 􏱕 u. Estimation of such models takes us into the realm of the nonlinear regression model, which is beyond the scope of this text. For most applications, choosing a model that can be put into the linear regression framework is sufficient.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 45 2.5 Expected Values and Variances of the OLS Estimators
In Section 2.1, we defined the population model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 u, and we claimed that the key assumption for simple regression analysis to be useful is that the expected value of u given any value of x is zero. In Sections 2.2, 2.3, and 2.4, we discussed the algebraic prop- erties of OLS estimation. We now return to the population model and study the statistical properties of OLS. In other words, we now view 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 as estimators for the parameters 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 that appear in the population model. This means that we will study properties of the distributions of 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 over different random samples from the population. (Appendix C contains definitions of estimators and reviews some of their important properties.)
Unbiasedness of OLS
We begin by establishing the unbiasedness of OLS under a simple set of assumptions. For future reference, it is useful to number these assumptions using the prefix “SLR” for simple linear regression. The first assumption defines the population model.
Assumption SLR.1 Linear in Parameters
In the population model, the dependent variable, y, is related to the independent variable,
x, and the error (or disturbance), u, as
y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x􏱕u, [2.47]
where 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 are the population intercept and slope parameters, respectively.
To be realistic, y, x, and u are all viewed as random variables in stating the population model. We discussed the interpretation of this model at some length in Section 2.1 and gave several examples. In the previous section, we learned that equation (2.47) is not as restrictive as it initially seems; by choosing y and x appropriately, we can obtain interest- ing nonlinear relationships (such as constant elasticity models).
We are interested in using data on y and x to estimate the parameters 􏱬0 and, espe- cially, 􏱬1. We assume that our data were obtained as a random sample. (See Appendix C for a review of random sampling.)
We will have to address failure of the random sampling assumption in later chapters that deal with time series analysis and sample selection problems. Not all cross-sectional sam- ples can be viewed as outcomes of random samples, but many can be.
We can write (2.47) in terms of the random sample as
yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui, i 􏱪 1, 2, …, n, [2.48]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Assumption SLR.2 Random Sampling
We have a random sample of size n, {(xi,yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, …, n}, following the population model in equation (2.47).

46 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
F I G U R E 2 . 7 Graph of yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui.
y
yi
ui
PRF
E(y|x)5 01 1x
u1 y1
x1xi x
where ui is the error or disturbance for observation i (for example, person i, firm i, city i, and so on). Thus, ui contains the unobservables for observation i that affect yi. The ui should not be confused with the residuals, uˆi, that we defined in Section 2.3. Later on, we will explore the relationship between the errors and the residuals. For interpreting 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 in a particular application, (2.47) is most informative, but (2.48) is also needed for some of the statistical derivations.
The relationship (2.48) can be plotted for a particular outcome of data as shown in Figure 2.7.
As we already saw in Section 2.2, the OLS slope and intercept estimates are not defined unless we have some sample variation in the explanatory variable. We now add variation in the xi to our list of assumptions.
This is a very weak assumption—certainly not worth emphasizing, but needed never- theless. If x varies in the population, random samples on x will typically contain variation, unless the population variation is minimal or the sample size is small. Simple inspection of summary statistics on xi reveals whether Assumption SLR.3 fails: if the sample stan- dard deviation of xi is zero, then Assumption SLR.3 fails; otherwise, it holds.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Assumption SLR.3 Sample Variation in the Explanatory Variable The sample outcomes on x, namely, {xi, i 􏱪 1, …, n}, are not all the same value.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

. [2.49] Because we are now interested in the behavior of 􏱬ˆ1 across all possible samples, 􏱬ˆ1 is prop-
erly viewed as a random variable.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 47
Finally, in order to obtain unbiased estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1, we need to impose the zero conditional mean assumption that we discussed in some detail in Section 2.1. We now explicitly add it to our list of assumptions.
Assumption SLR.4 Zero Conditional Mean
The error u has an expected value of zero given any value of the explanatory variable. In other words,
E(u|x) 􏱪 0.
For a random sample, this assumption implies that E(ui􏰫xi) 􏱪 0, for all i 􏱪 1, 2, …, n.
In addition to restricting the relationship between u and x in the population, the zero conditional mean assumption—coupled with the random sampling assumption— allows for a convenient technical simplification. In particular, we can derive the statisti- cal properties of the OLS estimators as conditional on the values of the xi in our sample. Technically, in statistical derivations, conditioning on the sample values of the indepen- dent variable is the same as treating the xi as fixed in repeated samples, which we think of as follows. We first choose n sample values for x1, x2, …, xn. (These can be repeated.) Given these values, we then obtain a sample on y (effectively by obtaining a random sample of the ui). Next, another sample of y is obtained, using the same values for x1, x2, …, xn. Then another sample of y is obtained, again using the same x1, x2, …, xn.
And so on.
The fixed-in-repeated-samples scenario is not very realistic in nonexperimental con-
texts. For instance, in sampling individuals for the wage-education example, it makes little sense to think of choosing the values of educ ahead of time and then sampling in- dividuals with those particular levels of education. Random sampling, where individuals are chosen randomly and their wage and education are both recorded, is representative of how most data sets are obtained for empirical analysis in the social sciences. Once we assume that E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0, and we have random sampling, nothing is lost in derivations by treating the xi as nonrandom. The danger is that the fixed-in-repeated-samples assumption always implies that ui and xi are independent. In deciding when simple regression analy- sis is going to produce unbiased estimators, it is critical to think in terms of Assumption SLR.4.
Now, w∑e are ready to show that∑the OLS estimators are unbiased. To this end, we use the fact that n (x 􏱦 x ̄)(y 􏱦 y ̄) 􏱪 n (x 􏱦 x ̄)y (see Appendix A) to write the OLS slope
estimator in equation (2.19) as
ii
i􏱪1 i􏱪1
ii
􏱬1􏱪 i􏱪1 ˆ∑
∑n
ii
( x 􏱦 x ̄ ) y n
i􏱪1
( x 􏱦 x ̄ ) 2 i

48 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
We can write 􏱬ˆ1 in terms of the population coefficients and errors by substituting the
right-hand side of (2.48) into (2.49). We have
ii
∑n ∑n
(x 􏱦 x ̄)y (x 􏱦 x ̄)(􏱬 􏱕 􏱬 x 􏱕 u )
i01ii 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 i􏱪1 􏱪 i􏱪1 ,
[2.50]
SSTx SSTx
where we have defined the total variation in xi as SSTx􏱪∑ n (xi 􏱦 x ̄)2 to simplify the notation.
i􏱪1
(This is not quite the sample variance of the xi because we do not divide by n 􏱦 1.) Using
the algebra of the summation operator, write the numerator of 􏱬ˆ1 as
∑n ∑n ∑n
(x􏱦x ̄)􏱬 􏱕 (x􏱦x ̄)􏱬x􏱕
(x􏱦x ̄)u ii
i0
i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1
i1i
􏱪􏱬0 (x 􏱦x ̄)􏱕􏱬 (x 􏱦x ̄)x 􏱕
∑n ∑n ∑n
AsshowninAppendixA,∑n (xi􏱦x ̄)􏱪0and∑n (xi∑􏱦x ̄)xi􏱪∑n (xi􏱦x ̄)2 􏱪SSTx. i􏱪1 ˆ i􏱪1 n i􏱪1
Therefore, we can write the numerator of 􏱬 as 􏱬 SST 􏱕
(x 􏱦 x ̄)u . Putting this over ii
i1
i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1
(x 􏱦x ̄)u. ii
[2.51]
11x
( x 􏱦 x ̄ ) u ∑
n
x , the randomness in 􏱬ˆ is due entirely to the errors in the sample. The fact that these errors i1ˆ
are generally different from zero is what causes 􏱬 to differ from 􏱬 . 11
Using the representation in (2.52), we can prove the first important statistical property of OLS.
the denominator gives
∑n
i􏱪1
ii
SSTx i􏱪1
􏱬ˆ1 􏱪􏱬1 􏱕 i􏱪1
where d 􏱪 x 􏱦 x ̄. We now see that the estimator 􏱬ˆ equals the population slope, 􏱬 , plus a
ii
􏱪􏱬1􏱕(1/SSTx) du, ii
[2.52]
ii11
term that is a linear combination in the errors {u1, u2, …, un}. Conditional on the values of
THEOREM 2.1
UNBIASEDNESS OF OLS:
Using Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.4,
E(􏱬ˆ0) 􏱪 􏱬0, and E(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱬1, [2.53]
for any values of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. In other words, 􏱬ˆ0 is unbiased for 􏱬0, and 􏱬ˆ1 is unbiased for 􏱬1.
PROOF: In this proof, the expected values are conditional on the sample values of the in- dependent variable. Because SSTx and di are functions only of the xi, they are nonrandom in the conditioning. Therefore, from (2.52), and keeping the conditioning on {x1, x2, …, xn} implicit, we have
E(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 E[(1/SSTx)
∑n i􏱪1
d u]􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 (1/SST ) ii1x
∑n i􏱪1
E(d u) ii
􏱪􏱬1􏱕(1/SSTx)
∑n i􏱪1
dE(u)􏱪􏱬 􏱕(1/SST) ii1x
∑n i􏱪1
d􏱳0􏱪􏱬, i1
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 49
where we have used the fact that the expected value of each ui (conditional on {x1, x2, …, xn}) is zero under Assumptions SLR.2 and SLR.4. Since unbiasedness holds for any outcome on {x1, x2, …, xn}, unbiasedness also holds without conditioning on {x1, x2, …, xn}.
The proof for 􏱬ˆ0 is now straightforward. Average (2.48) across i to get y ̄ 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1x ̄ 􏱕 u ̄, and plug this into the formula for 􏱬ˆ0 :
􏱬ˆ 0 􏱪 y ̄ 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 1 x ̄ 􏱪 􏱮 0 􏱕 􏱮 1 x ̄ 􏱕 u ̄ 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 1 x ̄ 􏱪 􏱮 0 􏱕 ( 􏱮 1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 1 ) x ̄ 􏱕 u ̄ . Then, conditional on the values of the xi,
E(􏱬ˆ0) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 E[(􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1)x ̄] 􏱕 E(u ̄) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 E[(􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1)]x ̄,
since E(u ̄) 􏱪 0 by Assumptions SLR.2 and SLR.4. But, we showed that E(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱬1, which implies that E[(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬1)] 􏱪 0. Thus, E(􏱬ˆ0) 􏱪 􏱬0. Both of these arguments are valid for any values of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1, and so we have established unbiasedness.
Remember that unbiasedness is a feature of the sampling distributions of 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ0, which says nothing about the estimate that we obtain for a given sample. We hope that, if the sample we obtain is somehow “typical,” then our estimate should be “near” the population value. Unfortunately, it is always possible that we could obtain an unlucky sample that would give us a point estimate far from 􏱬1, and we can never know for sure whether this is the case. You may want to review the material on unbiased estimators in Appendix C, especially the simulation exercise in Table C.1 that illustrates the concept of unbiasedness.
Unbiasedness generally fails if any of our four assumptions fail. This means that it is important to think about the veracity of each assumption for a particular application. Assumption SLR.1 requires that y and x be linearly related, with an additive disturbance. This can certainly fail. But we also know that y and x can be chosen to yield interesting nonlinear relationships. Dealing with the failure of (2.47) requires more advanced meth- ods that are beyond the scope of this text.
Later, we will have to relax Assumption SLR.2, the random sampling assumption, for time series analysis. But what about using it for cross-sectional analysis? Random sampling can fail in a cross section when samples are not representative of the underlying population; in fact, some data sets are constructed by intentionally oversampling different parts of the population. We will discuss problems of nonrandom sampling in Chapters 9 and 17.
As we have already discussed, Assumption SLR.3 almost always holds in interesting regression applications. Without it, we cannot even obtain the OLS estimates.
The assumption we should concentrate on for now is SLR.4. If SLR.4 holds, the OLS estimators are unbiased. Likewise, if SLR.4 fails, the OLS estimators generally will be biased. There are ways to determine the likely direction and size of the bias, which we will study in Chapter 3.
The possibility that x is correlated with u is almost always a concern in simple regression analysis with nonexperimental data, as we indicated with several examples in Section 2.1. Using simple regression when u contains factors affecting y that are also
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

50
PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
correlated with x can result in spurious correlation: that is, we find a relationship between y and x that is really due to other unobserved factors that affect y and also happen to be correlated with x.
EXAMPLE 2.12 STUDENT MATH PERFORMANCE AND THE SCHOOL LUNCH PROGRAM
Let math10 denote the percentage of tenth graders at a high school receiving a passing score on a standardized mathematics exam. Suppose we wish to estimate the effect of the federally funded school lunch program on student performance. If anything, we expect the lunch program to have a positive ceteris paribus effect on performance: all other fac- tors being equal, if a student who is too poor to eat regular meals becomes eligible for the school lunch program, his or her performance should improve. Let lnchprg denote the percentage of students who are eligible for the lunch program. Then, a simple regression model is
math10 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lnchprg 􏱕 u, [2.54]
where u contains school and student characteristics that affect overall school performance. Using the data in MEAP93.RAW on 408 Michigan high schools for the 1992–1993 school year, we obtain
􏱱math10 􏱪 32.14 􏱦 0.319 lnchprg n 􏱪 408, R2 􏱪 0.171.
This equation predicts that if student eligibility in the lunch program increases by 10 percentage points, the percentage of students passing the math exam falls by about 3.2 percentage points. Do we really believe that higher participation in the lunch program actually causes worse performance? Almost certainly not. A better explanation is that the error term u in equation (2.54) is correlated with lnchprg. In fact, u contains factors such as the poverty rate of children attending school, which affects student performance and is highly correlated with eligibility in the lunch program. Variables such as school quality and resources are also contained in u, and these are likely correlated with lnchprg. It is important to remember that the estimate 􏱶0.319 is only for this particular sample, but its sign and magnitude make us suspect that u and x are correlated, so that simple regression is biased.
In addition to omitted variables, there are other reasons for x to be correlated with u in the simple regression model. Because the same issues arise in multiple regression analy- sis, we will postpone a systematic treatment of the problem until then.
Variances of the OLS Estimators
In addition to knowing that the sampling distribution of 􏱬ˆ1 is centered about 􏱬1 (􏱬ˆ1 is unbiased), it is important to know how far we can expect 􏱬ˆ1 to be away from 􏱬1 on average.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 51
Among other things, this allows us to choose the best estimator among all, or at least a broad class of, unbiased estimators. The measure of spread in the distribution of 􏱬ˆ1 (and 􏱬ˆ0) that is easiest to work with is the variance or its square root, the standard deviation. (See Appendix C for a more detailed discussion.)
It turns out that the variance of the OLS estimators can be computed under Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.4. However, these expressions would be somewhat complicated. Instead, we add an assumption that is traditional for cross-sectional analysis. This assumption states that the variance of the unobservable, u, conditional on x, is constant. This is known as the homoskedasticity or “constant variance” assumption.
Assumption SLR.5 Homoskedasticity
The error u has the same variance given any value of the explanatory variable. In other words,
Var(u􏱊x) 􏱪 􏱧2.
We must emphasize that the homoskedasticity assumption is quite distinct from the
zero conditional mean assumption, E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0. Assumption SLR.4 involves the expected
value of u, while Assumption SLR.5 concerns the variance of u (both conditional on x).
Recall that we established the unbiasedness of OLS without Assumption SLR.5: the
homoskedasticity assumption plays no role in showing that 􏱬ˆ and 􏱬ˆ are unbiased. We add
01ˆˆ
Assumption SLR.5 because it simplifies the variance calculations for 􏱬 and 􏱬 and because
01
it implies that ordinary least squares has certain efficiency properties, which we will see
in Chapter 3. If we were to assume that u and x are independent, then the distribution of u given x does not depend on x, and so E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 E(u) 􏱪 0 and Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧 2. But indepen- dence is sometimes too strong of an assumption.
Because Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 E(u2􏰫x) 􏱦 [E(u􏰫x)] 2 and E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0, 􏱧 2 􏱪 E(u2􏰫x), which means 􏱧 2 is also the unconditional expectation of u 2. Therefore, 􏱧 2 􏱪 E(u2) 􏱪 Var(u), because E(u) 􏱪 0. In other words, 􏱧 2 is the unconditional variance of u, and so 􏱧 2 is often called the error variance or disturbance variance. The square root of 􏱧 2, 􏱧, is the standard de- viation of the error. A larger 􏱧 means that the distribution of the unobservables affecting y is more spread out.
It is often useful to write Assumptions SLR.4 and SLR.5 in terms of the conditional mean and conditional variance of y:
E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x. [2.55] Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧 2. [2.56]
In other words, the conditional expectation of y given x is linear in x, but the variance of y given x is constant. This situation is graphed in Figure 2.8 where 􏱬0 􏱰 0 and 􏱬1 􏱰 0.
When Var(u􏰫x) depends on x, the error term is said to exhibit heteroskedasticity (or nonconstant variance). Because Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 Var(y􏰫x), heteroskedasticity is present whenever Var(y􏰫x) is a function of x.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

52
PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
F I G U R E 2 . 8 The simple regression model under homoskedasticity.
f(y|x)
x1
y
E(y|x)5 01 1x x
x2
x3
EXAMPLE 2.13 HETEROSKEDASTICITY IN A WAGE EQUATION
In order to get an unbiased estimator of the ceteris paribus effect of educ on wage, we must assume that E(u􏰫educ) 􏱪 0, and this implies E(wage􏰫educ) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ. If we also make the homoskedasticity assumption, then Var(u􏰫educ) 􏱪 􏱧 2 does not depend on the level of education, which is the same as assuming Var(wage􏰫educ) 􏱪 􏱧 2. Thus, while average wage is allowed to increase with education level—it is this rate of increase that we are interested in estimating—the variability in wage about its mean is assumed to be constant across all education levels. This may not be realistic. It is likely that people with more education have a wider variety of interests and job opportunities, which could lead to more wage vari- ability at higher levels of education. People with very low levels of education have fewer opportunities and often must work at the minimum wage; this serves to reduce wage vari- ability at low education levels. This situation is shown in Figure 2.9. Ultimately, whether Assumption SLR.5 holds is an empirical issue, and in Chapter 8 we will show how to test Assumption SLR.5.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 53
F I G U R E 2 . 9 Var(wage􏱘educ) increasing with educ.
f(wage|educ)
8
12
16
wage
E(wage|educ) 5
0 1 1educ
educ
With the homoskedasticity assumption in place, we are ready to prove the following:
THEOREM 2.2
SAMPLING VARIANCES OF THE OLS ESTIMATORS
Under Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.5,
􏱧2
Var(􏱬ˆ ) 􏱪 ∑ 􏱪 􏱧2/SST ,
[2.57]
[2.58]
ˆ∑
The starting point is equation (2.52): 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 (1/SSTx) n d u . Because 􏱬 is just a
and
where these are conditional on the sample values {x1, …, xn}.
1nx ( x 􏱦 x ̄ ) 2
i i􏱪1
Var(􏱬0) 􏱪 n ˆ∑
i i􏱪1
i􏱪1
,
􏱧2n􏱦1
∑n
i
PROOF: We derive the formula for Var(􏱬1), leaving the other derivation as Problem 10.
ii1 constant, and we are conditioning on the xi, SSTx and di 􏱪 xi 􏱦 x ̄ are also nonrandom.
x2 ( x 􏱦 x ̄ ) 2
i􏱪1
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

54 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Furthermore, because the ui are independent random variables across i (by random sampling), the variance of the sum is the sum of the variances. Using these facts, we have
ˆ ∑n ∑n
Var(􏱬1) 􏱪 (1/SSTx)2Var 􏱵 diui 􏱷 􏱪 (1/SSTx)2 􏱵 d2i Var(ui) 􏱷
i􏱪1
which is what we wanted to show.
i􏱪1
∑n
i􏱪1
􏱪 (1/SSTx)2 􏱵
2 2∑n 2 2 2 2
d2􏱧2 􏱷 [since Var(u ) 􏱪 􏱧2 for all i] ii
􏱪 􏱧 (1/SSTx) 􏱵 di 􏱷 􏱪 􏱧 (1/SSTx) SSTx 􏱪 􏱧 /SSTx, i􏱪1
Equations (2.57) and (2.58) are the “standard” formulas for simple regression analy- sis, which are invalid in the presence of heteroskedasticity. This will be important when we turn to confidence intervals and hypothesis testing in multiple regression analysis.
For most purposes, we are interested in Var(􏱬ˆ1). It is easy to summarize how this variance depends on the error variance, 􏱧2, and the total variation in {x1, x2, …, xn}, SSTx. First, the larger the error variance, the larger is Var( 􏱬ˆ1). This makes sense since more variation in the unobservables affecting y makes it more difficult to precisely estimate 􏱬1. On the other hand, more variability in the independent variable is preferred: as the vari- ability in the xi increases, the variance of 􏱬ˆ1 decreases. This also makes intuitive sense since the more spread out is the sample of independent variables, the easier it is to trace out the relationship between E(y􏰫x) and x. That is, the easier it is to estimate 􏱬1. If there is little variation in the xi, then it can be hard to pinpoint how E(y􏰫x) varies with x. As the sample size increases, so does the total variation in the xi. Therefore, a larger sample size results in a smaller variance for 􏱬ˆ1.
This analysis shows that, if we are interested in 􏱬1 and we have a choice, then we should choose the xi to be as spread out as possible. This is sometimes possible with experimental data, but rarely do we have this luxury in the so- cial sciences: usually, we must take the xi that we obtain via random sampling.
Sometimes, we have an opportunity to obtain larger sample sizes, although this can be costly.
For the purposes of constructing confidence intervals and deriving test statistics, we
will need to work with the standard deviations of 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ0, sd(􏱬ˆ1) and sd(􏱬ˆ0). Recall that
EXPLORING FURTHER 2.5
Show that, when estimating 􏱬0, it is best to have x ̄ 􏱪 0. What is Var(􏱬0) in this case? [Hint:
ˆ∑ Fn2 ∑or any sample of numbers, x 􏱸
n2 i􏱪1
i
i􏱪1(x 􏱦 x ̄) , with equality only if x ̄ 􏱪 0.] i
these are obtained by taking the square roots of the variances in (2.57) and (2.58). In ˆ _____ 2 _____
particular, sd(􏱬1) 􏱪 􏱧􏰩√SSTx, where 􏱧 is the square root of 􏱧 , and √SSTx is the square root of SSTx.
Estimating the Error Variance
The formulas in (2.57) and (2.58) allow us to isolate the factors that contribute to Var(􏱬ˆ ) and ˆ21
Var(􏱬).Buttheseformulasareunknown,exceptintheextremelyrarecasethat􏱧 isknown. 0
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 55 Nevertheless, we can use the data to estimate 􏱧 2, which then allows us to estimate Var( 􏱬ˆ1)
a n d V a r ( 􏱬ˆ ) . 0
This is a good place to emphasize the difference between the errors (or disturbances) and the residuals, since this distinction is crucial for constructing an estimator of 􏱧2. Equation (2.48) shows how to write the population model in terms of a randomly sampled observation as yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui, where ui is the error for observation i. We can also express yi in terms of its fitted value and residual as in equation (2.32): yi 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi 􏱕 uˆi. Comparing these two equations, we see that the error shows up in the equation contain- ing the population parameters, 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. On the other hand, the residuals show up in the estimated equation with 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1. The errors are never observed, while the residuals are computed from the data.
We can use equations (2.32) and (2.48) to write the residuals as a function of the errors:
or
uˆ i 􏱪 y i 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 1 x i 􏱪 ( 􏱬 0 􏱕 􏱬 1 x i 􏱕 u i ) 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 1 x i ,
uˆi 􏱪 ui 􏱦 (􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬0) 􏱦 (􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬1)xi. [2.59]
Although the expected value of 􏱬ˆ0 equals 􏱬0, and similarly for 􏱬ˆ1, uˆi is not the same as ui. The difference between them does have an expected value of zero.
Now that we understand the difference between the errors and the residuals∑, we can return to estimating 􏱧2. First, 􏱧2 􏱪 E(u2), so an unbiased “estimator” of 􏱧2 is n􏱦1 n u2.
i Unfortunately, this is not a true estimator, because we do not observe the errors ui. But,
i􏱪1
we do have estimates of the ui,∑namely, the OLS residuals uˆi. If we replace the errors with
the OLS residuals, we have n􏱦1 n uˆi2 􏱪 SSR/n. This is a true estimator, because it gives a i􏱪1
computable rule for any sample of data on x and y. One slight drawback to this estimator is that it turns out to be biased (although for large n the bias is small). Because it is easy to compute an unbiased estimator, we use that instead.
The estimator SSR/n is biased essentially because it does not account for two restric- tions that must be satisfied by the OLS residuals. These restrictions are given by the two OLS first order conditions:
One way to view these restrictions is this: if we know n 􏱦 2 of the residuals, we can
always get the other two residuals by using the restrictions implied by the first order con- ditions in (2.60). Thus, there are only n 􏱦 2 degrees of freedom in the OLS residuals, as opposed to n degrees of freedom in the errors. It is important to understand that if we replace uˆi with ui in (2.60), the restrictions would no longer hold.
The unbiased estimator of 􏱧2 that we will use makes a degrees of freedom adjustment:
i􏱪1
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
􏱧ˆ2 􏱪 (n􏱦2) putting “hats” over estimators.)
∑n
i􏱪1
uˆ 􏱪 0, i
∑n i􏱪1
x uˆ 􏱪 0. ii
[2.60]
1 ∑n
uˆi2􏱪SSR/(n􏱦2). [2.61] (This estimator is sometimes denoted as s2, but we continue to use the convention of

56 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
THEOREM 2.3
UNBIASED ESTIMATION OF 􏱧2
Under Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.5,
E(􏱧ˆ2) 􏱪 􏱧2.
PROOF: If we average equation (2.59) across all i and use the fact that the OLS residuals average out to zero, we have 0 􏱪 u ̄ 􏱦 (􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬0) 􏱦 (􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬1)x ̄; subtracting this from (2.59) gives
ˆ 2∑2∑ˆ22 uˆi􏱪(ui􏱦u ̄)􏱦(􏱬1􏱦􏱬1)(xi􏱦x ̄).Therefore,uˆi 􏱪(ui􏱦u ̄) 􏱕(􏱬1􏱦􏱬1) (xi􏱦x ̄) 􏱦2(ui􏱦u ̄)
n2n2ˆ2 (􏱬1 􏱦􏱬1)(xi 􏱦x ̄).Summingacrossalligives uˆ 􏱪 (u 􏱦u ̄) 􏱕(􏱬 􏱦􏱬)
∑ˆ ∑ i􏱪1i 11
i􏱪1 i
n (x􏱦x ̄)2 􏱦2(􏱬ˆ 􏱦􏱬) n u(x􏱦x ̄).Now,theexpectedvalueofthefirsttermis
i􏱪1i 11 (n 􏱦 1)􏱧 2, something that is shown in Appendix C. The expected value of the second term is
i􏱪1 i i 2ˆ2ˆ22∑
simply 􏱧 because E[(􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1) ] 􏱪 Var(􏱬1) 􏱪 􏱧 /sx . Finally, the third term can be written as
2(􏱬ˆ1􏱦􏱬1)2s2;takingexpectationsgives2􏱧2.PuttingthesethreetermstogethergivesE􏱹 n uˆ2􏱺􏱪
(n􏱦 1)􏱧2 􏱕 􏱧2 􏱦 2􏱧2 􏱪 (n􏱦 2)􏱧2, so that E[SSR/(n􏱦 2)] 􏱪 􏱧2.
i􏱪1 i
If 􏱧ˆ 2 is plugged into the variance formulas (2.57) and (2.58), then we have unbiased
estimators of Var(􏱬ˆ1) and Var(􏱬ˆ0). Later on, we will need estimators of the standard devia-
tions of 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ0, and this requires estimating 􏱧. The natural estimator of 􏱧 is ___
􏱧ˆ 􏱪√􏱧ˆ2 [2.62]
and is called the standard error of the regression (SER). (Other names for 􏱧ˆ are the standard error of the estimate and the root mean squared error, but we will not use these.) Although􏱧ˆ isnotanunbiasedestimatorof􏱧,wecanshowthatitisaconsistentestimator of 􏱧 (see Appendix C), and it will serve our purposes well.
The estimate 􏱧ˆ is interesting because it is an estimate of the standard deviation in
the unobservables affecting y; equivalently, it estimates the standard deviation in y af-
ter the effect of x has been taken out. Most regression packages report the value of 􏱧ˆ
along with the R-squared, intercept, slope, and other OLS statistics (under one of the
several names listed above). For now, our primary interest is in using 􏱧ˆ to estimate the ˆ ˆ ˆ _____
standard deviations of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. Since sd( 􏱬1) 􏱪 􏱧 􏰩√ SSTx , the natural estimator of sd(􏱬ˆ1) is
1 √ x /􏱹∑ 􏱺
ˆ _____ n
se(􏱬 ) 􏱪 􏱧ˆ􏰩 SST 􏱪 􏱧ˆ (x 􏱦 x ̄)2
1/2 ;
this is called the standard error of 􏱬ˆ1. Note that se(􏱬ˆ1) is viewed as a random variable when we think of running OLS over different samples of y; this is true because 􏱧ˆ varies with different samples. For a given sample, se(􏱬ˆ1) is a number, just as 􏱬ˆ1 is simply a num- ber when we compute it from the given data.
Similarly, se(􏱬ˆ0) is obtained from sd(􏱬ˆ0) by replacing 􏱧 with 􏱧ˆ . The standard error of any estimate gives us an idea of how precise the estimator is. Standard errors play a cen- tral role throughout this text; we will use them to construct test statistics and confidence intervals for every econometric procedure we cover, starting in Chapter 4.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
i i􏱪1

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 57 2.6 Regression through the Origin and
Regression on a Constant
In rare cases, we wish to impose the restriction that, when x 􏱪 0, the expected value of y is zero. There are certain relationships for which this is reasonable. For example, if income (x) is zero, then income tax revenues (y) must also be zero. In addition, there are settings where a model that originally has a nonzero intercept is transformed into a model without an intercept.
Formally, we now choose a slope estimator, which we call 􏱬 ̃1, and a line of the form ̃y 􏱪 􏱬 ̃ x, [2.63]
where the tildes over 􏱬 ̃ and y ̃ are used to distinguish this problem from the much more 1
common problem of estimating an intercept along with a slope. Obtaining (2.63) is called regression through the origin because the line (2.63) passes through the point x 􏱪 0, y ̃ 􏱪 0. To obtain the slope estimate in (2.63), we still rely on the method of ordinary least squares, which in this case minimizes the sum of squared residuals:
∑n ̃2
(yi 􏱦 􏱬1xi) . [2.64]
i􏱪1
Using one-variable calculus, it can be shown that 􏱬 ̃ must solve the first order condition:
From this, we can solve for 􏱬 ̃ :
∑n
xy ii
, provided that not all the xi are zero, a case we rule out.
i􏱪1 1
∑n ̃ ii1i
[2.65]
[2.66]
̃∑
i i􏱪1
􏱬 􏱪 i􏱪1 1n
1
1 x(y 􏱦􏱬x)􏱪0.
x2
Note how 􏱬 ̃ compares with the slope estimate when we also estimate the intercept
1
(rather than set it equal to zero). These two estimates are the same if, and only if, x ̄ 􏱪 0.
[See equation (2.49) for 􏱬ˆ .] Obtaining an estimate of 􏱬 using regression through the ori- 11
gin is not done very often in applied work, and for good reason: if the intercept 􏱬0 􏱻 0, then 􏱬 ̃ is a biased estimator of 􏱬 . You will be asked to prove this in Problem 8.
11
In cases where regression through the origin is deemed appropriate, one must be care-
ful in interpreting the R-squared that is typically reported with such regressions. Usually, unless stated otherwise, the R-squared is obtained without removing the sample average of {yi : i 􏱪 1, …, n} in obtaining SST. In other words, the R-squared is computed as
∑n ̃2 (y 􏱦 􏱬 x ) i1i
i􏱪1 1􏱦∑
n i􏱪1
. [2.67] yi2
The numerator here makes sense because it is the sum of squared residuals, but the denominator acts as if we know the average value of y in the population is zero. One
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

58 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
reason this version of the R-squared is used is that if we use the usual total sum of squares,
that is, we compute R-squared as ∑ n ̃2
it can actually be negative. If expression (2.68) is negative then it means that using the sample average yˉ to predict yi provides a better fit than using xi in a regression through the origin. Therefore, (2.68) is actually more attractive than equation (2.67) because equation (2.68) tells us whether using x is better than ignoring x altogether.
This discussion about regression through the origin, and different ways to measure goodness-of-fit, prompts another question: what happens if we only regress on a constant? That is, we set the slope to zero (which means we need not even have an x) and estimate an intercept only? The answer is simple: the intercept is y ̄. This fact is usually shown in basic statistics, where it is shown that the constant that produces the smallest sum of squared deviations is always the sample average. In this light, equation (2.68) can be seen as comparing regression on x through the origin with regression only on a constant.
Summary
We have introduced the simple linear regression model in this chapter, and we have covered its basic properties. Given a random sample, the method of ordinary least squares is used to estimate the slope and intercept parameters in the population model. We have demonstrated the algebra of the OLS regression line, including computation of fitted values and residuals, and the obtaining of predicted changes in the dependent variable for a given change in the indepen- dent variable. In Section 2.4, we discussed two issues of practical importance: (1) the behavior of the OLS estimates when we change the units of measurement of the dependent variable or the independent variable and (2) the use of the natural log to allow for constant elasticity and constant semi-elasticity models.
In Section 2.5, we showed that, under the four Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.4, the OLS
estimators are unbiased. The key assumption is that the error term u has zero mean given any value
of the independent variable x. Unfortunately, there are reasons to think this is false in many social
science applications of simple regression, where the omitted factors in u are often correlated with x.
When we add the assumption that the variance of the error given x is constant, we get simple formu-
las for the sampling variances of the OLS estimators. As we saw, the variance of the slope estimator
􏱬ˆ increasesastheerrorvarianceincreases,anditdecreaseswhenthereismoresamplevariationin 1
the independent variable. We also derived an unbiased estimator for 􏰴2 􏱪 Var(u).
In Section 2.6, we briefly discussed regression through the origin, where the slope estimator is obtained under the assumption that the intercept is zero. Sometimes, this is useful,
but it appears infrequently in applied work.
Much work is left to be done. For example, we still do not know how to test hypotheses
about the population parameters, 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. Thus, although we know that OLS is unbiased for the population parameters under Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.4, we have no way of drawing inferences about the population. Other topics, such as the efficiency of OLS relative to other possible procedures, have also been omitted.
The issues of confidence intervals, hypothesis testing, and efficiency are central to mul- tiple regression analysis as well. Since the way we construct confidence intervals and test
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
i􏱪1
[2.68]
1􏱦∑_ (y 􏱦y )2
(y 􏱦 􏱬 x ) i1i
.
n
i i􏱪1

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 59
statistics is very similar for multiple regression—and because simple regression is a special case of multiple regression—our time is better spent moving on to multiple regression, which is much more widely applicable than simple regression. Our purpose in Chapter 2 was to get you thinking about the issues that arise in econometric analysis in a fairly simple setting.
THE GAUSS-MARKOV ASSUMPTIONS FOR SIMPLE REGRESSION
For convenience, we summarize the Gauss-Markov assumptions that we used in this chapter. It is important to remember that only SLR.1 through SLR.4 are needed to show 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 are unbiased. We added the homoskedasticity assumption, SLR.5, to obtain the usual OLS vari- ance formulas (2.57) and (2.58).
Assumption SLR.1 (Linear in Parameters)
In the population model, the dependent variable, y, is related to the independent variable, x, and the error (or disturbance), u, as
y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 u,
where 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 are the population intercept and slope parameters, respectively.
Assumption SLR.2 (Random Sampling)
We have a random sample of size n, {(xi,yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, …, n}, following the population model in Assumption SLR.1.
Assumption SLR.3 (Sample Variation in the Explanatory Variable)
The sample outcomes on x, namely, {xi, i 􏱪 1, …, n}, are not all the same value.
Assumption SLR.4 (Zero Conditional Mean)
The error u has an expected value of zero given any value of the explanatory variable. In other words,
E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0.
The error u has the same variance given any value of the explanatory variable. In other words,
Assumption SLR.5 (Homoskedasticity)
Key Terms
Coefficient of Determination Constant Elasticity Model Control Variable
Covariate
Degrees of Freedom Dependent Variable Elasticity
Error Term (Disturbance) Error Variance
Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2.
Explained Sum of Squares (SSE)
Explained Variable Explanatory Variable
First Order Conditions Fitted Value
Gauss-Markov Assumptions Heteroskedasticity Homoskedasticity
Independent Variable Intercept Parameter
Mean Independent
OLS Regression Line Ordinary Least Squares (OLS) Population Regression
Function (PRF) Predicted Variable Predictor Variable
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

60 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Regressand
Regression through the Origin Regressor
Residual
Residual Sum of Squares (SSR) Response Variable
R-squared
Problems
Sample Regression Function (SRF)
Semi-elasticity
Simple Linear Regression
Model
Slope Parameter Standard Error of 􏱬ˆ1
Standard Error of the Regression (SER)
Sum of Squared Residuals (SSR)
Total Sum of Squares (SST) Zero Conditional Mean
Assumption
1 Let kids denote the number of children ever born to a woman, and let educ denote years of education for the woman. A simple model relating fertility to years of education is
kids 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u,
where u is the unobserved error.
(i) What kinds of factors are contained in u? Are these likely to be correlated with level
of education?
(ii) Will a simple regression analysis uncover the ceteris paribus effect of education
on fertility? Explain.
2 In the simple linear regression model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 u, suppose that E(u) 􏱻 0. Letting 􏱮0 􏱪 E(u), show that the model can always be rewritten with the same slope, but a new intercept and error, where the new error has a zero expected value.
3 ThefollowingtablecontainstheACTscoresandtheGPA(gradepointaverage)foreight college students. Grade point average is based on a four-point scale and has been rounded to one digit after the decimal.
Student
GPA
ACT
1
2.8
21
2 3.4 24
3
3.0
26
4 3.5 27
5
3.6
29
6 3.0 25
7
2.7
25
8 3.7 30
(i) Estimate the relationship between GPA and ACT using OLS; that is, obtain the intercept and slope estimates in the equation
􏱱GPA 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1ACT.
Comment on the direction of the relationship. Does the intercept have a useful in- terpretation here? Explain. How much higher is the GPA predicted to be if the ACT score is increased by five points?
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 61
(ii) Compute the fitted values and residuals for each observation, and verify that the residuals (approximately) sum to zero.
(iii) What is the predicted value of GPA when ACT 􏱪 20?
(iv) How much of the variation in GPA for these eight students is explained by ACT?
Explain.
4 ThedatasetBWGHT.RAWcontainsdataonbirthstowomenintheUnitedStates.Two variables of interest are the dependent variable, infant birth weight in ounces (bwght), and an explanatory variable, average number of cigarettes the mother smoked per day during pregnancy (cigs). The following simple regression was estimated using data on n 􏱪 1,388 births:
􏱱bwght 􏱪 119.77 􏱦 0.514 cigs
(i) What is the predicted birth weight when cigs 􏱪 0? What about when cigs 􏱪 20 (one pack per day)? Comment on the difference.
(ii) Does this simple regression necessarily capture a causal relationship between the child’s birth weight and the mother’s smoking habits? Explain.
(iii) To predict a birth weight of 125 ounces, what would cigs have to be? Comment.
(iv) The proportion of women in the sample who do not smoke while pregnant is about
.85. Does this help reconcile your finding from part (iii)?
5 In the linear consumption function
cons 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 􏱬 inc, 􏱱 ˆ0 ˆ1
the (estimated) marginal propensity to consume (MPC) out of income is simply the slope,
ˆ 􏱱ˆˆ
􏱬 , while the average propensity to consume (APC) is cons􏱆inc 􏱪 􏱬 􏱆inc 􏱕 􏱬 . Using obser-
1
vations for 100 families on annual income and consumption (both measured in dollars), the following equation is obtained:
cons 􏱪 􏱦124.84 􏱕 0.853 inc 􏱱
n 􏱪 100, R2 􏱪 0.692.
(i) Interpret the intercept in this equation, and comment on its sign and magnitude.
(ii) What is the predicted consumption when family income is $30,000?
(iii) With inc on the x-axis, draw a graph of the estimated MPC and APC.
6 Usingdatafrom1988forhousessoldinAndover,Massachusetts,fromKielandMcClain (1995), the following equation relates housing price (price) to the distance from a recently built garbage incinerator (dist):
􏱱log(price) 􏱪 9.40 􏱕 0.312 log(dist) n 􏱪 135, R2 􏱪 0.162.
(i) Interpret the coefficient on log(dist). Is the sign of this estimate what you expect it to be?
(ii) Do you think simple regression provides an unbiased estimator of the ceteris paribus elasticity of price with respect to dist? (Think about the city’s decision on where to put the incinerator.)
(iii) What other factors about a house affect its price? Might these be correlated with dis- tance from the incinerator?
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
01

62 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
7 Consider the savings function
sav 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 u, u 􏱪 √inc·e,
where e is a random variable with E(e) 􏱪 0 and Var(e) 􏱪 􏱧2e. Assume that e is independent of inc.
(i) Show that E(u􏰫inc) 􏱪 0, so that the key zero conditional mean assumption (Assumption
SLR.4) is satisfied. [Hint: If e is independent of inc, then E(e􏰫inc) 􏱪 E(e).]
(ii) Show that Var(u􏰫inc) 􏱪 􏱧2einc, so that the homoskedasticity Assumption SLR.5 is
violated. In particular, the variance of sav increases with inc. [Hint: Var(e􏰫inc) 􏱪
Var(e), if e and inc are independent.]
(iii) Provide a discussion that supports the assumption that the variance of savings
increases with family income.
8 Considerthestandardsimpleregressionmodely􏱪􏱬0􏱕􏱬1x􏱕uundertheGauss-Markov Assumptions SLR.1 through SLR.5. The usual OLS estimators 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 are unbiased for their respective population parameters. Let 􏱬 ̃ 1 be the estimator of 􏱬1 obtained by assuming the intercept is zero (see Section 2.6).
(i) Find E(􏱬 ̃1) in terms of the xi, 􏱬0, and 􏱬1. Verify that 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased for 􏱬1 when the population intercept (􏱬0) is zero. Are there other cases where 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased?
9 (i)
Let 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 be the intercept and slope from the regression of yi on xi, using n observations. Let c1 and c2, with c2 􏱻 0, be constants. Let 􏱬 ̃0 and 􏱬 ̃1 be the in- tercept and slope from the regression of c1yi on c2xi. Show that 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 (c1/c2)􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬 ̃0 􏱪 c1􏱬ˆ0, thereby verifying the claims on units of measurement in Section 2.4. [Hint: To obtain 􏱬 ̃1, plug the scaled versions of x and y into (2.19). Then, use (2.17) for 􏱬 ̃0, being sure to plug in the scaled x and y and the correct slope.]
i
ˆ ̃ 11
̃∑
(ii) Find the variance of 􏱬 . (Hint: The variance does not depend on 􏱬 .)
(iii)∑ ̃ 1 ˆ
Show that Var(􏱬 ) 􏰯 Var(􏱬 ). [Hint: For any sample of data,
n0 2
n 21 1
i􏱪1 (x 􏱦 x ̄) , with strict inequality unless x ̄ 􏱪 0.]
x 􏱸 i
i􏱪1
(iv) Comment on the tradeoff between bias and variance when choosing between 􏱬 and 􏱬 .
(ii) Now, let 􏱬 ̃0 and 􏱬 ̃1 be from the regression of (c1 􏱕 yi) on (c2 􏱕 xi) (with no restriction on c1 or c2). Show that 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬 ̃0 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 c1 􏱦 c2􏱬ˆ1.
(iii) Now, let 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 be the OLS estimates from the regression log(yi) on xi, where we
must assume yi 􏱰 0 for all i. For c1 􏱰 0, let 􏱬 ̃0 and 􏱬 ̃1 be the intercept and slope from
the regression of log(c y ) on x . Show that 􏱬 ̃ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ and 􏱬 ̃ 􏱪 log(c ) 􏱕 􏱬ˆ . 1ii ̃1 ̃1010
(iv) Now, assuming that xi 􏱰 0 for all i, let 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 be the intercept and slope from the regression of yi on log(c2 xi). How do 􏱬 ̃0 and 􏱬 ̃1 compare with the intercept and slope from the regression of yi on log(xi)?
10 Let 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 be the OLS intercept and slope estimators, respectively, and let u ̄ be the
sample average of the errors (not the residua∑ls!).
(ii) Use part (i), along with n w 􏱪 0, to show that 􏱬ˆ and u ̄ are uncorrelated. [Hint: i1
n
(i) Showthat􏱬1canbewrittenas􏱬1􏱪􏱬1􏱕 i􏱪1wuwherew􏱪d/SST andd􏱪x􏱦x ̄.
ˆ∑
ˆ
iiiixii
i􏱪1 ˆ .
You are being asked to show that E[( 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1) u ̄] 􏱪 0.]
(iii) Show that 􏱬ˆ0 can be written as 􏱬ˆ0 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 u ̄ 􏱦 (􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬1)x ̄.
(iv) Use parts (ii) and (iii) to show that Var(􏱬ˆ0) 􏱪 􏱧2/n 􏱕 􏱧2(x ̄)2/SSTx.
(v) Do the algebra to sim∑plify the expression in part (iv) to equation (2.58).
[Hint: SSTx /n 􏱪 n􏱦1 n x 2 􏱦 (x ̄)2.]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
i􏱪1
i
___

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 63
11 SupposeyouareinterestedinestimatingtheeffectofhoursspentinanSATpreparation course (hours) on total SAT score (sat). The population is all college-bound high school seniors for a particular year.
(i) Suppose you are given a grant to run a controlled experiment. Explain how you would
structure the experiment in order to estimate the causal effect of hours on sat.
(ii) Consider the more realistic case where students choose how much time to spend in a preparation course, and you can only randomly sample sat and hours from the popu-
lation. Write the population model as
sat􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1hours􏱪u
where, as usual in a model with an intercept, we can assume E(u) 􏱪 0. List at least two factors contained in u. Are these likely to have positive or negative correlation with hours?
(iii) In the equation from part (ii), what should be the sign of 􏱬1 if the preparation course is effective?
(iv) In the equation from part (ii), what is the interpretation of 􏱬0?
12 ConsidertheproblemdescribedattheendofSection2.6:runningaregressionandonly estimating an intercept.
(i) Given a sample {yi : i 􏱪 1, 2, . . . , n}, let 􏱬 ̃0 be the solution to
∑n ̃– b0i􏱪1
Show that 􏱬 􏱪 y, that is, the sample average minimizes the sum of squared residuals. 0
Computer Exercises
C1 The data in 401K.RAW are a subset of data analyzed by Papke (1995) to study the rela- tionship between participation in a 401(k) pension plan and the generosity of the plan. The variable prate is the percentage of eligible workers with an active account; this is the variable we would like to explain. The measure of generosity is the plan match rate, mrate. This variable gives the average amount the firm contributes to each worker’s plan for each $1 contribution by the worker. For example, if mrate 􏱪 0.50, then a $1 contribution by the worker is matched by a 50¢ contribution by the firm.
(i) Find the average participation rate and the average match rate in the sample of plans.
(ii) Now, estimate the simple regression equation
p􏱱rate 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1 mrate,
and report the results along with the sample size and R-squared.
(iii) Interpret the intercept in your equation. Interpret the coefficient on mrate.
(iv) Find the predicted prate when mrate 􏱪 3.5. Is this a reasonable prediction?
Explain what is happening here.
(v) How much of the variation in prate is explained by mrate? Is this a lot in your
opinion?
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
min
(y 􏱦 b )2. i0
(Hint: You may use one-variable calculus or you can show the result directly by add-
ing and subtracting y_ inside the squared residual and then doing a little algebra.) (ii) Define residuals u ̃ i 􏱪 yi 􏱦 y_. Argue that these residuals always sum to zero.

64 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
C2 The data set in CEOSAL2.RAW contains information on chief executive officers for U.S. corporations. The variable salary is annual compensation, in thousands of dollars, and ceoten is prior number of years as company CEO.
(i) Find the average salary and the average tenure in the sample.
(ii) How many CEOs are in their first year as CEO (that is, ceoten 􏱪 0)? What is the longest tenure as a CEO?
(iii) Estimate the simple regression model
log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1ceoten 􏱕 u,
and report your results in the usual form. What is the (approximate) predicted per- centage increase in salary given one more year as a CEO?
C3 Use the data in SLEEP75.RAW from Biddle and Hamermesh (1990) to study whether there is a tradeoff between the time spent sleeping per week and the time spent in paid work. We could use either variable as the dependent variable. For concreteness, estimate the model
sleep 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1totwrk 􏱕 u,
where sleep is minutes spent sleeping at night per week and totwrk is total minutes worked during the week.
(i) Report your results in equation form along with the number of observations and
R2. What does the intercept in this equation mean?
(ii) If totwrk increases by 2 hours, by how much is sleep estimated to fall? Do you
find this to be a large effect?
C4 Use the data in WAGE2.RAW to estimate a simple regression explaining monthly salary (wage) in terms of IQ score (IQ).
(i) Find the average salary and average IQ in the sample. What is the sample standard
deviation of IQ? (IQ scores are standardized so that the average in the population
is 100 with a standard deviation equal to 15.)
(ii) Estimate a simple regression model where a one-point increase in IQ changes
wage by a constant dollar amount. Use this model to find the predicted increase in wage for an increase in IQ of 15 points. Does IQ explain most of the variation in wage?
(iii) Now, estimate a model where each one-point increase in IQ has the same percent- age effect on wage. If IQ increases by 15 points, what is the approximate percent- age increase in predicted wage?
C5 For the population of firms in the chemical industry, let rd denote annual expenditures on research and development, and let sales denote annual sales (both are in millions of dollars).
(i) Write down a model (not an estimated equation) that implies a constant elasticity
between rd and sales. Which parameter is the elasticity?
(ii) Now, estimate the model using the data in RDCHEM.RAW. Write out the esti-
mated equation in the usual form. What is the estimated elasticity of rd with respect to sales? Explain in words what this elasticity means.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

C6 We used the data in MEAP93.RAW for Example 2.12. Now we want to explore the relationship between the math pass rate (math10) and spending per student (expend).
(i) Do you think each additional dollar spent has the same effect on the pass rate, or
does a diminishing effect seem more appropriate? Explain.
(ii) In the population model
math10 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 log(expend ) 􏱕 u,
argue that 􏱬1/10 is the percentage point change in math10 given a 10% increase in
expend.
(iii) Use the data in MEAP93.RAW to estimate the model from part (ii). Report the
estimated equation in the usual way, including the sample size and R-squared.
(iv) How big is the estimated spending effect? Namely, if spending increases by 10%,
what is the estimated percentage point increase in math10?
(v) One might worry that regression analysis can produce fitted values for math10
that are greater than 100. Why is this not much of a worry in this data set?
C7 Use the data in CHARITY.RAW [obtained from Franses and Paap (2001)] to answer the following questions:
(i) What is the average gift in the sample of 4,268 people (in Dutch guilders)? What
percentage of people gave no gift?
(ii) What is the average mailings per year? What are the minimum and maximum values?
(iii) Estimate the model
gift 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1mailsyear 􏱕 u
by OLS and report the results in the usual way, including the sample size and
R-squared.
(iv) Interpret the slope coefficient. If each mailing costs one guilder, is the charity ex-
pected to make a net gain on each mailing? Does this mean the charity makes a net
gain on every mailing? Explain.
(v) What is the smallest predicted charitable contribution in the sample? Using this
simple regression analysis, can you ever predict zero for gift?
C8 To complete this exercise you need a software package that allows you to generate data from the uniform and normal distributions.
(i) Start by generating 500 observations xi – the explanatory variable – from the
uniform distribution with range [0,10]. (Most statistical packages have a command for the Uniform[0,1] distribution; just multiply those observations by 10.) What are the sample mean and sample standard deviation of the xi?
(ii) Randomly generate 500 errors, ui, from the Normal[0,36] distribution. (If you generate a Normal[0,1], as is commonly available, simply multiply the outcomes by six.) Is the sample average of the ui exactly zero? Why or why not? What is the sample standard deviation of the ui?
(iii) Now generate the yi as
yi 􏱪1􏱕2xi 􏱕ui 􏱲􏱮0 􏱕􏱮1xi 􏱕ui;
that is, the population intercept is one and the population slope is two. Use the data to run the regression of yi on xi. What are your estimates of the intercept and slope? Are they equal to the population values in the above equation? Explain.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 65

66 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
(iv) Obtain the OLS residuals, uˆi, and verify that equation (2.60) hold (subject to rounding error).
(v) Compute the same quantities in equation (2.60) but use the errors ui in place of the residuals. Now what do you conclude?
(vi) Repeat parts (i), (ii), and (iii) with a new sample of data, starting with generating the xi. Now what do you obtain for 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1? Why are these different from what you obtained in part (iii)?
APPENDIX 2A
Minimizing the Sum of Squared Residuals
We show that the OLS estimates 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 do minimize the sum of squared residuals, as asserted in Section 2.2. Formally, the problem is to characterize the solutions 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 to the minimization problem
min ∑n
b ,b (yi 􏱦 b0 􏱦 b1xi)2,
0 1 i􏱪1
where b0 and b1 are the dummy arguments for the optimization problem; for simplicity,
call this function Q(b0, b1). By a fundamental result from multivariable calculus (see Appendix A ), a necessary condition for 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 to solve the minimization problem is that the partial derivatives of Q(b0, b1) with respect to b0 and b1 must be zero when evaluated at 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1: ∂Q(􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1)/∂b0 􏱪 0 and ∂Q(􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1)/∂b1 􏱪 0. Using the chain rule from calculus, these two equations become
∑n ˆˆ
􏱦2 (yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi) 􏱪 0
i􏱪1
∑n ˆˆ
􏱦2 xi(yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi) 􏱪 0. i􏱪1
These two equations are just (2.14) and (2.15) multiplied by 􏱦2n and, therefore, are solved by the same 􏱬ˆ and 􏱬ˆ .
01
How do we know that we have actually minimized the sum of squared residuals?
The first order conditions are necessary but not sufficient conditions. One way to verify that we have minimized the sum of squared residuals is to write, for any b0 and b1,
∑n ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ 2 Q(b0,b1)􏱪 [yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi 􏱕 (􏱬0 􏱦 b0) 􏱕 (􏱬1 􏱦 b1)xi]
i􏱪1
∑n ˆ ˆ 2
􏱪 [ uˆ i 􏱕 ( 􏱬 0 􏱦 b 0 ) 􏱕 ( 􏱬 1 􏱦 b 1 ) x i ] i􏱪1
∑n ˆ ˆ ∑n ˆ ˆ ∑n
􏱪 uˆi2 􏱕n(􏱬0􏱦b0)2 􏱕(􏱬1􏱦b1)2 xi2 􏱕2(􏱬0􏱦b0)(􏱬1􏱦b1) xi,
i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 2 The Simple Regression Model 67
where we have used equations (2.30) and (2.31). The first term does not depend on b0 or b1, while the sum of the last three terms can be written as
∑n ˆ ˆ 2 [(􏱬0 􏱦 b0) 􏱕 (􏱬1 􏱦 b1)xi] ,
i􏱪1
as can be verified by straightforward algebra. Because this is a sum of squared
terms, the smallest it can be is zero. Therefore, it is smallest when b0 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 and b 1 􏱪 􏱬ˆ 1 .
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

68
In Chapter 2, we learned how to use simple regression analysis to explain a dependent variable, y, as a function of a single independent variable, x. The primary drawback in using simple regression analysis for empirical work is that it is very difficult to draw ceteris paribus conclusions about how x affects y: the key assumption, SLR.4 —that all other factors affecting y are uncorrelated with x—is often unrealistic.
Multiple regression analysis is more amenable to ceteris paribus analysis because it allows us to explicitly control for many other factors that simultaneously affect the dependent variable. This is important both for testing economic theories and for evaluat- ing policy effects when we must rely on nonexperimental data. Because multiple regres- sion models can accommodate many explanatory variables that may be correlated, we can hope to infer causality in cases where simple regression analysis would be misleading.
Naturally, if we add more factors to our model that are useful for explaining y, then more of the variation in y can be explained. Thus, multiple regression analysis can be used to build better models for predicting the dependent variable.
An additional advantage of multiple regression analysis is that it can incorporate fairly general functional form relationships. In the simple regression model, only one function of a single explanatory variable can appear in the equation. As we will see, the multiple regression model allows for much more flexibility.
Section 3.1 formally introduces the multiple regression model and further discusses the advantages of multiple regression over simple regression. In Section 3.2, we demon- strate how to estimate the parameters in the multiple regression model using the method of ordinary least squares. In Sections 3.3, 3.4, and 3.5, we describe various statistical proper- ties of the OLS estimators, including unbiasedness and efficiency.
The multiple regression model is still the most widely used vehicle for empirical analysis in economics and other social sciences. Likewise, the method of ordinary least squares is popularly used for estimating the parameters of the multiple regression model.
CHAPTER
3
Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 69 3.1 Motivation for Multiple Regression
The Model with Two Independent Variables
We begin with some simple examples to show how multiple regression analysis can be used to solve problems that cannot be solved by simple regression.
The first example is a simple variation of the wage equation introduced in Chapter 2 for obtaining the effect of education on hourly wage:
wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 u, [3.1]
where exper is years of labor market experience. Thus, wage is determined by the two explanatory or independent variables, education and experience, and by other unobserved factors, which are contained in u. We are still primarily interested in the effect of educ on wage, holding fixed all other factors affecting wage; that is, we are interested in the parameter 􏱬1.
Compared with a simple regression analysis relating wage to educ, equation (3.1) effectively takes exper out of the error term and puts it explicitly in the equation. Because exper appears in the equation, its coefficient, 􏱬2, measures the ceteris paribus effect of exper on wage, which is also of some interest.
Not surprisingly, just as with simple regression, we will have to make assumptions about how u in (3.1) is related to the independent variables, educ and exper. However, as we will see in Section 3.2, there is one thing of which we can be confident: because (3.1) contains experience explicitly, we will be able to measure the effect of education on wage, holding experience fixed. In a simple regression analysis—which puts exper in the error term—we would have to assume that experience is uncorrelated with education, a tenuous assumption.
As a second example, consider the problem of explaining the effect of per student spending (expend ) on the average standardized test score (avgscore) at the high school level. Suppose that the average test score depends on funding, average family income (avginc), and other unobserved factors:
avgscore 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1expend 􏱕 􏱬2avginc 􏱕 u. [3.2]
The coefficient of interest for policy purposes is 􏱬1, the ceteris paribus effect of expend on avgscore. By including avginc explicitly in the model, we are able to control for its effect on avgscore. This is likely to be important because average family income tends to be correlated with per student spending: spending levels are often determined by both prop- erty and local income taxes. In simple regression analysis, avginc would be included in the error term, which would likely be correlated with expend, causing the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 in the two-variable model to be biased.
In the two previous similar examples, we have shown how observable factors other than the variable of primary interest [educ in equation (3.1) and expend in equation (3.2)] can be included in a regression model. Generally, we can write a model with two indepen- dent variables as
y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1×1 􏱕􏱬2×2 􏱕u,
􏱬1 measures the change in y with respect to x1, holding other factors fixed.
􏱬2 measures the change in y with respect to x2, holding other factors fixed.
[3.3]
where
􏱬0 is the intercept.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

70 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Multiple regression analysis is also useful for generalizing functional relationships between variables. As an example, suppose family consumption (cons) is a quadratic function of family income (inc):
cons 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2inc2 􏱕 u, [3.4]
where u contains other factors affecting consumption. In this model, consumption depends on only one observed factor, income; so it might seem that it can be handled in a simple regression framework. But the model falls outside simple regression because it contains two functions of income, inc and inc2 (and therefore three parameters, 􏱬0, 􏱬1, and 􏱬2). Nevertheless, the consumption function is easily written as a regression model with two independent variables by letting x1 􏱪 inc and x2 􏱪 inc2.
Mechanically, there will be no difference in using the method of ordinary least squares (introduced in Section 3.2) to estimate equations as different as (3.1) and (3.4). Each equa- tion can be written as (3.3), which is all that matters for computation. There is, however, an important difference in how one interprets the parameters. In equation (3.1), 􏱬1 is the ceteris paribus effect of educ on wage. The parameter 􏱬1 has no such interpretation in (3.4). In other words, it makes no sense to measure the effect of inc on cons while holding inc2 fixed, because if inc changes, then so must inc2! Instead, the change in consumption with respect to the change in income—the marginal propensity to consume—is approximated by
_∆_c_o_n_s 􏱴 􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2inc. ∆inc
See Appendix A for the calculus needed to derive this equation. In other words, the marginal effect of income on consumption depends on 􏱬2 as well as on 􏱬1 and the level of income. This example shows that, in any particular application, the definitions of the inde- pendent variables are crucial. But for the theoretical development of multiple regression, we can be vague about such details. We will study examples like this more completely in Chapter 6.
In the model with two independent variables, the key assumption about how u is related to x1 and x2 is
E(u􏰫x1, x2) 􏱪 0. [3.5]
The interpretation of condition (3.5) is similar to the interpretation of Assumption SLR.4 for simple regression analysis. It means that, for any values of x1 and x2 in the population, the average of the unobserved factors is equal to zero. As with simple regression, the important part of the assumption is that the expected value of u is the same for all combi- nations of x1 and x2; that this common value is zero is no assumption at all as long as the intercept 􏱬0 is included in the model (see Section 2.1).
How can we interpret the zero conditional mean assumption in the previous exam- ples? In equation (3.1), the assumption is E(u􏰫educ,exper) 􏱪 0. This implies that other factors affecting wage are not related on average to educ and exper. Therefore, if we think innate ability is part of u, then we will need average ability levels to be the same across all combinations of education and experience in the working population. This may or may not be true, but, as we will see in Section 3.3, this is the question we need to ask in order to determine whether the method of ordinary least squares produces unbiased estimators.
The example measuring student performance [equation (3.2)] is similar to the wage equation. The zero conditional mean assumption is E(u􏰫expend, avginc) 􏱪 0, which means that other factors affecting test scores—school or student characteristics—are, on average, unrelated to per-student funding and average family income.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3
Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 71
When applied to the quadratic con- sumption function in (3.4), the zero con- ditional mean assumption has a slightly different interpretation. Written literally, equation (3.5) becomes E(u􏰫inc,inc2) 􏱪 0. Since inc2 is known when inc is known, including inc2 in the expectation is redundant: E(u􏰫inc,inc2) 􏱪 0 is the same as E(u􏰫inc) 􏱪 0. Nothing is wrong with putting inc2 along with inc in the expec- tation when stating the assumption, but E(u􏰫inc) 􏱪 0 is more concise.
The Model with k Independent Variables
Once we are in the context of multiple regression, there is no need to stop with two inde- pendent variables. Multiple regression analysis allows many observed factors to affect y. In the wage example, we might also include amount of job training, years of tenure with the current employer, measures of ability, and even demographic variables like the num- ber of siblings or mother’s education. In the school funding example, additional variables might include measures of teacher quality and school size.
The general multiple linear regression model (also called the multiple regression model) can be written in the population as
EXPLORING FURTHER 3.1
A simple model to explain city murder rates (murdrate) in terms of the probability of conviction (prbconv) and average sentence length (avgsen) is
murdrate 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1prbconv 􏱕 􏱬2avgsen 􏱕 u.
What are some factors contained in u? Do you think the key assumption (3.5) is likely to hold?
where
y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1×1 􏱕􏱬2×2 􏱕􏱬3×3 􏱕…􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u,
[3.6]
􏱬0 is the intercept.
􏱬1 is the parameter associated with x1.
􏱬2 is the parameter associated with x2, and so on.
Since there are k independent variables and an intercept, equation (3.6) contains k 􏱕 1 (unknown) population parameters. For shorthand purposes, we will sometimes refer to the parameters other than the intercept as slope parameters, even though this is not always literally what they are. [See equation (3.4), where neither 􏱬1 nor 􏱬2 is itself a slope, but together they determine the slope of the relationship between consumption and income.]
The terminology for multiple regression is similar to that for simple regression and is given in Table 3.1. Just as in simple regression, the variable u is the error term or disturbance. It contains factors other than x1, x2, …, xk that affect y. No matter how many explanatory variables we include in our model, there will always be factors we cannot include, and these are collectively contained in u.
When applying the general multiple regression model, we must know how to interpret the parameters. We will get plenty of practice now and in subsequent chapters, but it is useful at this point to be reminded of some things we already know. Suppose that CEO salary (salary) is related to firm sales (sales) and CEO tenure (ceoten) with the firm by
log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2ceoten 􏱕 􏱬3ceoten2 􏱕 u. [3.7]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

72 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
T A B L E 3 . 1 Terminology for Multiple Regression
y x1, x2, …, xk
Dependent variable
Independent variables
Explained variable
Explanatory variables
Response variable
Control variables
Predicted variable
Predictor variables
Regressand
Regressors
This fits into the multiple regression model (with k 􏱪 3) by defining y 􏱪 log(salary), x1 􏱪 log(sales), x2 􏱪 ceoten, and x3 􏱪 ceoten2. As we know from Chapter 2, the parameter 􏱬1 is the (ceteris paribus) elasticity of salary with respect to sales. If 􏱬3 􏱪 0, then 100􏱬2 is approximately the ceteris paribus percentage increase in salary when ceoten increases by one year. When 􏱬3 􏱻 0, the effect of ceoten on salary is more complicated. We will post- pone a detailed treatment of general models with quadratics until Chapter 6.
Equation (3.7) provides an important reminder about multiple regression analysis. The term “linear” in a multiple linear regression model means that equation (3.6) is linear in the parameters, 􏱬j. Equation (3.7) is an example of a multiple regression model that, while linear in the 􏱬j, is a nonlinear relationship between salary and the variables sales and ceoten. Many applications of multiple linear regression involve nonlinear relation- ships among the underlying variables.
The key assumption for the general multiple regression model is easy to state in terms of a conditional expectation:
E(u􏰫x1, x2, …, xk) 􏱪 0. [3.8]
At a minimum, equation (3.8) requires that all factors in the unobserved error term be uncorrelated with the explanatory variables. It also means that we have correctly accounted for the functional relationships between the explained and explanatory variables. Any problem that causes u to be correlated with any of the independent variables causes (3.8) to fail. In Section 3.3, we will show that assumption (3.8) implies that OLS is unbiased and will derive the bias that arises when a key variable has been omitted from the equation. In Chapters 15 and 16, we will study other reasons that might cause (3.8) to fail and show what can be done in cases where it does fail.
3.2 Mechanics and Interpretation of Ordinary Least Squares
We now summarize some computational and algebraic features of the method of ordinary least squares as it applies to a particular set of data. We also discuss how to interpret the estimated equation.
Obtaining the OLS Estimates
We first consider estimating the model with two independent variables. The estimated OLS equation is written in a form similar to the simple regression case:
yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2, [3.9]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 73
where
􏱬ˆ0 􏱪 the estimate of 􏱬0. 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 the estimate of 􏱬1. 􏱬ˆ2 􏱪 the estimate of 􏱬2.
But how do we obtain 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, and 􏱬ˆ2? The method of ordinary least squares chooses the estimates to minimize the sum of squared residuals. That is, given n observations on y, x1, and x2, {(xi1, xi2, yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, …, n}, the estimates 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, and 􏱬ˆ2 are chosen simultane- ously to make
∑n ˆˆˆ2
(yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi1 􏱦 􏱬2xi2) [3.10]
i􏱪1
as small as possible.
To understand what OLS is doing, it is important to master the meaning of the index-
ing of the independent variables in (3.10). The independent variables have two subscripts here, i followed by either 1 or 2. The i subscript refers to the observation number. Thus, the sum in (3.10) is over all i 􏱪 1 to n observations. The second index is simply a method of distinguishing between different independent variables. In the example relating wage to educ and exper, xi1 􏱪 educi is education for person i in the sample, and∑xi2n􏱪 experi is experience for person i. The sum of squared residuals in equation (3.10) is i􏱪1 (wagei 􏱦 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1educi 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2experi)2. In what follows, the i subscript is reserved for indexing the observation number. If we write xij, then this means the ith observation on the jth indepen- dent variable. (Some authors prefer to switch the order of the observation number and the variable number, so that x1i is observation i on variable one. But this is just a matter of notational taste.) ˆ ˆ ˆ
In the general case with k independent variables, we seek estimates 􏱬0, 􏱬1, …, 􏱬k in the equation
yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2 􏱕 … 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk. [3.11] The OLS estimates, k 􏱕 1 of them, are chosen to minimize the sum of squared residuals:
∑n ˆˆ ˆ2
(yi 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xi1 􏱦…􏱦􏱬kxik) . [3.12]
i􏱪1
This minimization problem can be solved using multivariable calculus (see Appendix 3A).
This leads to k 􏱕 1 linear equations in k 􏱕 1 unknowns 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, …, 􏱬ˆk: ∑n ˆˆ ˆ
(yi 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xi1 􏱦…􏱦􏱬kxik)􏱪0 i􏱪1
∑n ˆˆ ˆ
xi1(yi 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xi1 􏱦…􏱦􏱬kxik)􏱪0
i􏱪1
i􏱪1
∑n ˆˆ ˆ
[3.13]
These are often called the OLS first order conditions. As with the simple regression model in Section 2.2, the OLS first order conditions can be obtained by the method of
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
xi2(yi 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xi1 􏱦…􏱦􏱬kxik)􏱪0 ∑n ˆˆ ˆ
xik(yi 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xi1 􏱦…􏱦􏱬kxik)􏱪0. i􏱪1
.. .

74 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
moments: under assumption (3.8), E(u) 􏱪 0 and E(xju) 􏱪 0, where j 􏱪 1, 2, …, k. The equations in (3.13) are the sample counterparts of these population moments, although we have omitted the division by the sample size n.
For even moderately sized n and k, solving the equations in (3.13) by hand calculations is tedious. Nevertheless, modern computers running standard statistics and econometrics software can solve these equations with large n and k very quickly.
There is only one slight caveat: we must assume that the equations in (3.13) can be solved uniquely for the ˆ􏱬j. For now, we just assume this, as it is usually the case in well-specified models. In Section 3.3, we state the assumption needed for unique OLS estimates to exist (see Assumption MLR.3).
As in simple regression analysis, equation (3.11) is called the OLS regression line or the sample regression function (SRF). We will call 􏱬ˆ0 the OLS intercept estimate and 􏱬ˆ1, … , 􏱬ˆk the OLS slope estimates (corresponding to the independent variables x1, x2, …, xk).
To indicate that an OLS regression has been run, we will either write out equation (3.11) with y and x1, …, xk replaced by their variable names (such as wage, educ, and exper), or we will say that “we ran an OLS regression of y on x1, x2, …, xk” or that “we regressed y on x1, x2, …, xk.” These are shorthand for saying that the method of or- dinary least squares was used to obtain the OLS equation (3.11). Unless explicitly stated otherwise, we always estimate an intercept along with the slopes.
Interpreting the OLS Regression Equation
More important than the details underlying the computation of the 􏱬ˆj is the interpretation of the estimated equation. We begin with the case of two independent variables:
yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2. [3.14]
The intercept ˆ􏱬0 in equation (3.14) is the predicted value of y when x1 􏱪 0 and x2 􏱪 0. Sometimes, setting x1 and x2 both equal to zero is an interesting scenario; in other cases, it will not make sense. Nevertheless, the intercept is always needed to obtain a prediction of y from the OLS regression line, as (3.14) makes clear.
The estimates 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 have partial effect, or ceteris paribus, interpretations. From equation (3.14), we have
∆yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1∆x1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2∆x2,
so we can obtain the predicted change in y given the changes in x1 and x2. (Note how the intercept has nothing to do with the changes in y.) In particular, when x2 is held fixed, so that ∆x2 􏱪 0, then
∆ yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ 1 ∆ x 1 ,
holding x2 fixed. The key point is that, by including x2 in our model, we obtain a coeffi- cient on x1 with a ceteris paribus interpretation. This is why multiple regression analysis is so useful. Similarly,
∆ yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ 2 ∆ x 2 ,
holding x1 fixed.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 75 EXAMPLE 3.1 DETERMINANTS OF COLLEGE GPA
The variables in GPA1.RAW include the college grade point average (colGPA), high school GPA (hsGPA), and achievement test score (ACT) for a sample of 141 students from a large university; both college and high school GPAs are on a four-point scale. We obtain the following OLS regression line to predict college GPA from high school GPA and achievement test score:
􏱱colGPA 􏱪 1.29 􏱕 .453 hsGPA 􏱕 .0094 ACT n 􏱪 141.
[3.15]
How do we interpret this equation? First, the intercept 1.29 is the predicted college GPA if hsGPA and ACT are both set as zero. Since no one who attends college has either a zero high school GPA or a zero on the achievement test, the intercept in this equation is not, by itself, meaningful.
More interesting estimates are the slope coefficients on hsGPA and ACT. As expected, there is a positive partial relationship between colGPA and hsGPA: Holding ACT fixed, another point on hsGPA is associated with .453 of a point on the college GPA, or almost half a point. In other words, if we choose two students, A and B, and these students have the same ACT score, but the high school GPA of Student A is one point higher than the high school GPA of Student B, then we predict Student A to have a college GPA .453 higher than that of Student B. (This says nothing about any two actual people, but it is our best prediction.)
The sign on ACT implies that, while holding hsGPA fixed, a change in the ACT score of 10 points—a very large change, since the maximum ACT score is 36 and the average score in the sample is about 24 with a standard deviation less than three—affects colGPA by less than one-tenth of a point. This is a small effect, and it suggests that, once high school GPA is accounted for, the ACT score is not a strong predictor of college GPA. (Naturally, there are many other factors that contribute to GPA, but here we focus on statistics available for high school students.) Later, after we discuss statistical inference, we will show that not only is the coefficient on ACT practically small, it is also statisti- cally insignificant.
If we focus on a simple regression analysis relating colGPA to ACT only, we obtain 􏱱colGPA 􏱪 2.40 􏱕 .0271 ACT
n 􏱪 141;
thus, the coefficient on ACT is almost three times as large as the estimate in (3.15). But this equation does not allow us to compare two people with the same high school GPA; it corresponds to a different experiment. We say more about the differences between multiple and simple regression later.
The case with more than two independent variables is similar. The OLS regression line is
yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2 􏱕 … 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk. [3.16] Written in terms of changes,
∆yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1∆x1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2∆x2 􏱕 … 􏱕 􏱬ˆk∆xk. [3.17]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

76 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
The coefficient on x1 measures the change in yˆ due to a one-unit increase in x1, holding all
other independent variables fixed. That is,
∆yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1∆x1, [3.18]
holding x2, x3, …, xk fixed. Thus, we have controlled for the variables x2, x3, …, xk when estimating the effect of x1 on y. The other coefficients have a similar interpretation.
The following is an example with three independent variables.
EXAMPLE 3.2 HOURLY WAGE EQUATION
Using the 526 observations on workers in WAGE1.RAW, we include educ (years of educa- tion), exper (years of labor market experience), and tenure (years with the current employer) in an equation explaining log(wage). The estimated equation is
􏱱log(wage) 􏱪 .284 􏱕 .092 educ 􏱕 .0041 exper 􏱕 .022 tenure n 􏱪 526.
[3.19]
As in the simple regression case, the coefficients have a percentage interpretation. The only difference here is that they also have a ceteris paribus interpretation. The coefficient .092 means that, holding exper and tenure fixed, another year of education is predicted to increase log(wage) by .092, which translates into an approximate 9.2% [100(.092)] increase in wage. Alternatively, if we take two people with the same levels of experience and job tenure, the coefficient on educ is the proportionate difference in predicted wage when their education levels differ by one year. This measure of the return to education at least keeps two important productivity factors fixed; whether it is a good estimate of the ceteris paribus return to another year of education requires us to study the statistical properties of OLS (see Section 3.3).
On the Meaning of “Holding Other Factors Fixed”
in Multiple Regression
The partial effect interpretation of slope coefficients in multiple regression analysis can cause some confusion, so we provide a further discussion now.
In Example 3.1, we observed that the coefficient on ACT measures the predicted dif- ference in colGPA, holding hsGPA fixed. The power of multiple regression analysis is that it provides this ceteris paribus interpretation even though the data have not been collected in a ceteris paribus fashion. In giving the coefficient on ACT a partial effect interpretation, it may seem that we actually went out and sampled people with the same high school GPA but possibly with different ACT scores. This is not the case. The data are a random sample from a large university: there were no restrictions placed on the sample values of hsGPA or ACT in obtaining the data. Rarely do we have the luxury of holding certain variables fixed in obtaining our sample. If we could collect a sample of individuals with the same high school GPA, then we could perform a simple regression analysis relating colGPA to ACT. Multiple regression effectively allows us to mimic this situation without restricting the values of any independent variables.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 77
The power of multiple regression analysis is that it allows us to do in nonexperimental environments what natural scientists are able to do in a controlled laboratory setting: keep other factors fixed.
Changing More Than One Independent Variable
Simultaneously
Sometimes, we want to change more than one independent variable at the same time to find the resulting effect on the dependent variable. This is easily done using equation (3.17). For example, in equation (3.19), we can obtain the estimated effect on wage when an individual stays at the same firm for another year: exper (general workforce experience) and tenure both increase by one year. The total effect (holding educ fixed) is
∆􏱱log(wage) 􏱪 .0041 ∆exper 􏱕 .022 ∆tenure 􏱪 .0041 􏱕 .022 􏱪 .0261,
or about 2.6%. Since exper and tenure each increase by one year, we just add the coefficients
on exper and tenure and multiply by 100 to turn the effect into a percentage. OLS Fitted Values and Residuals
After obtaining the OLS regression line (3.11), we can obtain a fitted or predicted value for each observation. For observation i, the fitted value is simply
yˆi 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2xi2 􏱕 … 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxik, [3.20]
which is just the predicted value obtained by plugging the values of the independent variables for observation i into equation (3.11). We should not forget about the intercept in obtaining the fitted values; otherwise, the answer can be very misleading. As an example, if in (3.15), hsGPAi 􏱪 3.5 and ACTi 􏱪 24, 􏱱colGPAi 􏱪 1.29 􏱕 .453(3.5) 􏱕 .0094(24) 􏱪 3.101 (rounded to three places after the decimal).
Normally, the actual value yi for any observation i will not equal the predicted value, ˆyi: OLS minimizes the average squared prediction error, which says nothing about the prediction error for any particular observation. The residual for observation i is defined just as in the simple regression case,
uˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 yˆi. [3.21]
There is a residual for each observation. If uˆi 􏱰 0, then yˆi is below yi, which means that, for this observation, yi is underpredicted. If uˆi 􏱷 0, then yi 􏱷 yˆi, and yi is overpredicted.
The OLS fitted values and residuals have some important properties that are immediate
extensions from the single variable case:
1. The sample average of the residuals is zero and so y 􏱪 yˆ.
2. The sample covariance between each independent variable and the OLS residuals is zero. Consequently, the sample covariance between the OLS fitted values and the OLS residuals is zero.
3. Thepoint(_x,_x,…,_x,_y)isalwaysontheOLSregressionline:_y􏱪􏱬ˆ 􏱕􏱬ˆ_x 􏱕 12k 011
􏱬ˆ _x 􏱕 … 􏱕 􏱬ˆ _x . 22 kk
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
__

78 PART 1
Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
variable has zero sample covariance with uˆi. Property (3) follows immediately from property (1).
A “Partialling Out” Interpretation of Multiple Regression
When applying OLS, we do not need to know explicit formulas for the 􏱬ˆj that solve the system of equations in (3.13). Nevertheless, for certain derivations, we do need explicit formulas for the 􏱬ˆj. These formulas also shed further light on the workings of OLS.
[3.22]
Consider again the case with k 􏱪 2 independent variables, yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2. For concreteness, we focus on 􏱬ˆ1. One way to express 􏱬ˆ1 is
∑n ∑n
􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏱵 rˆi1y 􏱷􏱆􏱵 i
rˆ2 􏱷, i1
i􏱪1
where the rˆi1 are the OLS residuals from a simple regression of x1 on x2, using the sample
at hand. We regress our first independent variable, x1, on our second independent variable, x2, and then obtain the residuals (y plays no role here). Equation (3.22) shows that we can then do a simple regression of y on rˆ1 to obtain 􏱬ˆ1. (Note that the residuals rˆi1 have a zero sample average, and so 􏱬ˆ1 is the usual slope estimate from simple regression.) ˆ
The representation in equation (3.22) gives another demonstration of 􏱬1’s partial effect interpretation. The residuals rˆi1 are the part of xi1 that is uncorrelated with xi2. Another way of saying this is that ˆri1 is xi1 after the effects of xi2 have been partialled out, or netted out. Thus, 􏱬ˆ1 measures the sample relationship between y and x1 after x2 has been partialled out.
In simple regression analysis, there is no partialling out of other variables because no other variables are included in the regression. Computer Exercise C5 steps you through the partialling out process using the wage data from Example 3.2. For practical purposes, the important thing is that 􏱬ˆ1 in the equation yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2 measures the change in y given a one-unit increase in x1, holding x2 fixed. ˆ
In the general model with k explanatory variables, 􏱬1 can still be written as in equation (3.22), but the residuals rˆi1 come from the regression of x1 on x2, …, xk. Thus, 􏱬ˆ1 measures the effect of x1 on y after x2, …, xk have been partialled or netted out.
Comparison of Simple and Multiple Regression Estimates
Two special cases exist in which the simple regression of y on x1 will produce the same OLS estimate on x1 as the regression of y on x1 and x2. To be more precise, write the simple regression of y on x1 as y ̃ 􏱪 􏱬 ̃0 􏱕 􏱬 ̃1×1, and write the multiple regression as yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2. We know that the simple regression coefficient 􏱬 ̃1 does not usually equal the multiple
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
i􏱪1
The first two properties are immedi-
ate consequences of the set of equations
used to obtain the OLS estimates. The
first equation in (3.13) says that the sum
EXPLORING FURTHER 3.2
In Example 3.1, the OLS fitted line explain- ing college GPA in terms of high school GPA and ACT score is
􏱱colGPA 􏱪 1.29 􏱕 .453 hsGPA 􏱕 .0094 ACT.
If the average high school GPA is about 3.4 and the average ACT score is about 24.2, what is the average college GPA in the sample?
of the residuals is zero. ∑The remaining
equations are of the form n x uˆ 􏱪 0,
i􏱪1
which implies that each independent
ij i

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 79 regression coefficient 􏱬ˆ1. It turns out there is a simple relationship between ̃􏱬1 and ˆ􏱬1,
which allows for interesting comparisons between simple and multiple regression:
􏱬 ̃1 􏱪􏱬ˆ1 􏱕􏱬ˆ2􏱛 ̃1, [3.23]
where 􏱛 ̃1 is the slope coefficient from the simple regression of xi2 on xi1, i 􏱪 1, …, n. This equation shows how 􏱬 ̃1 differs from the partial effect of x1 on yˆ. The confounding term is the partial effect of x2 on yˆ times the slope in the sample regression of x2 on x1. (See Section 3A.4 in the chapter appendix for a more general verification.)
The relationship between 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬ˆ1 also shows there are two distinct cases where they are equal:
1. The partial effect of x2 on yˆ is zero in the sample. That is, 􏱬ˆ2 􏱪 0.
2. x1 and x2 are uncorrelated in the sample. That is, 􏱛 ̃1 􏱪 0.
Even though simple and multiple regression estimates are almost never identical, we
can use the above formula to characterize why they might be either very different or quite similar. For example, if 􏱬ˆ2 is small, we might expect the multiple and simple regression estimates of 􏱬1 to be similar. In Example 3.1, the sample correlation between hsGPA and ACT is about 0.346, which is a nontrivial correlation. But the coefficient on ACT is fairly little. It is not surprising to find that the simple regression of colGPA on hsGPA produces a slope estimate of .482, which is not much different from the estimate .453 in (3.15).
EXAMPLE 3.3 PARTICIPATION IN 401(k) PENSION PLANS
We use the data in 401K.RAW to estimate the effect of a plan’s match rate (mrate) on the participation rate (prate) in its 401(k) pension plan. The match rate is the amount the firm contributes to a worker’s fund for each dollar the worker contributes (up to some limit); thus, mrate 􏱪 .75 means that the firm contributes 75¢ for each dollar contributed by the worker. The participation rate is the percentage of eligible workers having a 401(k) account. The variable age is the age of the 401(k) plan. There are 1,534 plans in the data set, the average prate is 87.36, the average mrate is .732, and the average age is 13.2.
Regressing prate on mrate, age gives
p􏱱rate 􏱪 80.12 􏱕 5.52 mrate 􏱕 .243 age
n 􏱪 1,534.
Thus, both mrate and age have the expected effects. What happens if we do not control for age? The estimated effect of age is not trivial, and so we might expect a large change in the estimated effect of mrate if age is dropped from the regression. However, the simple regression of prate on mrate yields 􏱱prate 􏱪 83.08 􏱕 5.86 mrate. The simple regression estimate of the effect of mrate on prate is clearly different from the multiple regression estimate, but the difference is not very big. (The simple regression estimate is only about 6.2% larger than the multiple regression estimate.) This can be explained by the fact that the sample correlation between mrate and age is only .12.
In the case with k independent variables, the simple regression of y on x1 and the mul- tiple regression of y on x1, x2, …, xk produce an identical estimate of x1 only if (1) the OLS coefficients on x2 through xk are all zero or (2) x1 is uncorrelated with each of x2, …, xk.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

80 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Neither of these is very likely in practice. But if the coefficients on x2 through xk are small, or the sample correlations between x1 and the other independent variables are in- substantial, then the simple and multiple regression estimates of the effect of x1 on y can be similar.
Goodness-of-Fit
As with simple regression, we can define the total sum of squares (SST), the explained sum of squares (SSE), and the residual sum of squares or sum of squared residuals
(SSR) as
Using the same argument as in the simple regression case, we can show that SST 􏱪 SSE 􏱕 SSR.
SST 􏱲
SSE 􏱲
SSR 􏱲
∑n _2 (yi 􏱦 y)
i􏱪1 ∑n
[3.24] [3.25] [3.26]
[3.27]
i􏱪1 ____________
2 _∑ ∑
i􏱪1
∑n _
i i􏱪1
In other words, the total variation in {yi} is the sum of the total variations in {yˆi} and in {uˆi}. Assuming that the total variation in y is nonzero, as is the case unless yi is constant in
the sample, we can divide (3.27) by SST to get
SSR/SST 􏱕 SSE/SST 􏱪 1.
Just as in the simple regression case, the R-squared is defined to be
R2 􏱲 SSE/SST 􏱪 1 􏱦 SSR/SST, [3.28]
and it is interpreted as the proportion of the sample variation in yi that is explained by the OLS regression line. By definition, R2 is a number between zero and one.
R2 can also be shown to equal the squared correlation coefficient between the actual yi and the fitted values yˆi. That is,
∑n _ _2 􏱵 (yi􏱦y)(yˆi􏱦yˆ)􏱷
(yˆi 􏱦 y)2 uˆ 2.
___________ R􏱪n_n_. [3.29]
􏱵 (y􏱦y)2􏱷􏱵 (yˆ􏱦yˆ)2􏱷
i
i􏱪1 i􏱪1
i
[We have put the average of the yˆi in (3.29) to be true to the formula for a correlation coef- ficient; we know that this average equals _y because the sample average of the residuals is zero and yi 􏱪 yˆi 􏱕 uˆi.]
An important fact about R2 is that it never decreases, and it usually increases when another independent variable is added to a regression. This algebraic fact follows because, by definition, the sum of squared residuals never increases when additional regressors are added to the model. For example, the last digit of one’s social security number has nothing to do with one’s hourly wage, but adding this digit to a wage equation will increase the R2 (by a little, at least).
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 81
The fact that R2 never decreases when any variable is added to a regression makes it a poor tool for deciding whether one variable or several variables should be added to a model. The factor that should determine whether an explanatory variable belongs in a model is whether the explanatory variable has a nonzero partial effect on y in the popu- lation. We will show how to test this hypothesis in Chapter 4 when we cover statisti- cal inference. We will also see that, when used properly, R2 allows us to test a group of variables to see if it is important for explaining y. For now, we use it as a goodness-of-fit measure for a given model.
EXAMPLE 3.4 DETERMINANTS OF COLLEGE GPA
From the grade point average regression that we did earlier, the equation with R2 is
􏱱colGPA 􏱪 1.29 􏱕 .453 hsGPA 􏱕 .0094 ACT n 􏱪 141, R2 􏱪 .176.
This means that hsGPA and ACT together explain about 17.6% of the variation in college GPA for this sample of students. This may not seem like a high percentage, but we must remember that there are many other factors—including family background, personality, quality of high school education, affinity for college—that contribute to a student’s college performance. If hsGPA and ACT explained almost all of the variation in colGPA, then performance in college would be preordained by high school performance!
Example 3.5 deserves a final word of caution. The fact that the four explanatory variables included in the second regression explain only about 4.2% of the variation in narr86 does not necessarily mean that the equation is useless. Even though these variables collectively do not explain much of the variation in arrests, it is still possible that the OLS estimates are reliable estimates of the ceteris paribus effects of each independent variable on narr86. As we will see, whether this is the case does not directly depend on the size of R2. Generally, a low R2 indicates that it is hard to predict individual outcomes on y with much accuracy, something we study in more detail in Chapter 6. In the arrest example, the small R2 reflects what we already suspect in the social sciences: it is generally very difficult to predict individual behavior.
Regression through the Origin
Sometimes, an economic theory or common sense suggests that 􏱬0 should be zero, and so we should briefly mention OLS estimation when the intercept is zero. Specifically, we now seek an equation of the form
̃y􏱪 􏱬 ̃1×1 􏱕 􏱬 ̃2×2 􏱕 … 􏱕 􏱬 ̃k xk, [3.30]
where the symbol “~” over the estimates is used to distinguish them from the OLS esti- mates obtained along with the intercept [as in (3.11)]. In (3.30), when x1 􏱪 0, x2 􏱪 0, …, xk 􏱪 0, the predicted value is zero. In this case, 􏱬 ̃1, …, 􏱬 ̃k are said to be the OLS estimates from the regression of y on x1, x2, …, xk through the origin.
The OLS estimates in (3.30), as always, minimize the sum of squared residuals, but with the intercept set at zero. You should be warned that the properties of OLS that we derived earlier no longer hold for regression through the origin. In particular, the OLS
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

82
PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 3.5 EXPLAINING ARREST RECORDS
CRIME1.RAW contains data on arrests during the year 1986 and other information on 2,725 men born in either 1960 or 1961 in California. Each man in the sample was arrested at least once prior to 1986. The variable narr86 is the number of times the man was arrested during 1986: it is zero for most men in the sample (72.29%), and it varies from 0 to 12. (The percentage of men arrested once during 1986 was 20.51.) The variable pcnv is the proportion (not percentage) of arrests prior to 1986 that led to conviction, avgsen is average sentence length served for prior convictions (zero for most people), ptime86 is months spent in prison in 1986, and qemp86 is the number of quarters during which the man was employed in 1986 (from zero to four).
A linear model explaining arrests is
narr86 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 pcnv 􏱕 􏱬2avgsen 􏱕 􏱬3 ptime86 􏱕 􏱬4qemp86 􏱕 u,
where pcnv is a proxy for the likelihood for being convicted of a crime and avgsen is a measure of expected severity of punishment, if convicted. The variable ptime86 captures the incarcerative effects of crime: if an individual is in prison, he cannot be arrested for a crime outside of prison. Labor market opportunities are crudely captured by qemp86.
First, we estimate the model without the variable avgsen. We obtain 􏱱narr86 􏱪 .712 􏱦 .150 pcnv 􏱦 .034 ptime86 􏱦 .104 qemp86
n 􏱪 2,725, R2 􏱪 .0413.
This equation says that, as a group, the three variables pcnv, ptime86, and qemp86 explain about 4.1% of the variation in narr86.
Each of the OLS slope coefficients has the anticipated sign. An increase in the proportion of convictions lowers the predicted number of arrests. If we increase pcnv by .50 (a large increase in the probability of conviction), then, holding the other factors fixed, ∆􏱱narr86 􏱪 􏱦.150(.50) 􏱪 􏱦.075. This may seem unusual because an arrest cannot change by a fraction. But we can use this value to obtain the predicted change in expected arrests for a large group of men. For example, among 100 men, the predicted fall in arrests when pcnv increases by .50 is 􏱦7.5.
Similarly, a longer prison term leads to a lower predicted number of arrests. In fact, if ptime86 increases from 0 to 12, predicted arrests for a particular man fall by .034(12) 􏱪 .408. Another quarter in which legal employment is reported lowers predicted arrests by .104, which would be 10.4 arrests among 100 men.
If avgsen is added to the model, we know that R2 will increase. The estimated equation is
􏱱narr86 􏱪 .707 􏱦 .151 pcnv 􏱕 .0074 avgsen 􏱦 .037 ptime86 􏱦 .103 qemp86 n 􏱪 2,725, R2 􏱪 .0422.
Thus, adding the average sentence variable increases R2 from .0413 to .0422, a practically small effect. The sign of the coefficient on avgsen is also unexpected: it says that a longer average sentence length increases criminal activity.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 83 residuals no longer have a zero sample average. F∑urther, if R2 is defined as 1 􏱦 SSR/
SST,whereSSTisgivenin(3.24)andSSRisnow n (y 􏱦􏱬 ̃ x 􏱦…􏱦􏱬 ̃ x )2,then i 1 i1 k ik
2 i􏱪1_
R can actually be negative. This means that the sample average, y, “explains” more
of the variation in the yi than the explanatory variables. Either we should include an intercept in the regression or conclude that the explanatory variables poorly explain y. To always have a nonnegative R-squared, some economists prefer to calculate R2 as the squared correlation coefficient between the actual and fitted values of y, as in (3.29). (In this case, the average fitted value must be computed directly since it no longer equals y_.) However, there is no set rule on computing R-squared for regression through the origin.
One serious drawback with regression through the origin is that, if the intercept 􏱬0 in the population model is different from zero, then the OLS estimators of the slope parameters will be biased. The bias can be severe in some cases. The cost of estimating an intercept when 􏱬0 is truly zero is that the variances of the OLS slope estimators are larger.
3.3 The Expected Value of the OLS Estimators
We now turn to the statistical properties of OLS for estimating the parameters in an under- lying population model. In this section, we derive the expected value of the OLS estima- tors. In particular, we state and discuss four assumptions, which are direct extensions of the simple regression model assumptions, under which the OLS estimators are unbiased for the population parameters. We also explicitly obtain the bias in OLS when an impor- tant variable has been omitted from the regression.
You should remember that statistical properties have nothing to do with a particular sample, but rather with the property of estimators when random sampling is done repeat- edly. Thus, Sections 3.3, 3.4, and 3.5 are somewhat abstract. Although we give examples of deriving bias for particular models, it is not meaningful to talk about the statistical properties of a set of estimates obtained from a single sample.
The first assumption we make simply defines the multiple linear regression (MLR) model.
Assumption MLR.1 Linear in Parameters The model in the population can be written as
y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1×1 􏱕􏱬2×2 􏱕…􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, [3.31]
where 􏱬0, 􏱬1, …, 􏱬k are the unknown parameters (constants) of interest and u is an unobserved random error or disturbance term.
Equation (3.31) formally states the population model, sometimes called the true model, to allow for the possibility that we might estimate a model that differs from (3.31). The key feature is that the model is linear in the parameters 􏱬0, 􏱬1, …, 􏱬k. As we know, (3.31) is quite flexible because y and the independent variables can be arbitrary functions of the underlying variables of interest, such as natural logarithms and squares [see, for example, equation (3.7)].
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

84 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Assumption MLR.2 Random Sampling
We have a random sample of n observations, {(xi1, xi2, …, xik, yi ): i 􏱪 1, 2, …, n}, following the population model in Assumption MLR.1.
Sometimes, we need to write the equation for a particular observation i: for a randomly drawn observation from the population, we have
yi 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xi1 􏱕􏱬2xi2 􏱕…􏱕􏱬kxik 􏱕ui. [3.32] Remember that i refers to the observation, and the second subscript on x is the variable
number. For example, we can write a CEO salary equation for a particular CEO i as
log(salaryi) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(salesi) 􏱕 􏱬2ceoteni 􏱕 􏱬3ceoteni2 􏱕 ui . [3.33]
The term ui contains the unobserved factors for CEO i that affect his or her salary. For applications, it is usually easiest to write the model in population form, as in (3.31). It contains less clutter and emphasizes the fact that we are interested in estimating a population relationship. ˆ ˆ ˆ ˆ
In light of model (3.31), the OLS estimators 􏱬0, 􏱬1, 􏱬2, …, 􏱬k from the regression of y on x1, …, xk are now considered to be estimators of 􏱬0, 􏱬1, …, 􏱬k. In Section 3.2, we saw that OLS chooses the intercept and slope estimates for a particular sample so that the residuals average to zero and the sample correlation between each independent vari- able and the residuals is zero. Still, we did not include conditions under which the OLS estimates are well defined for a given sample. The next assumption fills that gap.
Assumption MLR.3 is more complicated than its counterpart for simple regression because we must now look at relationships between all independent variables. If an independent variable in (3.31) is an exact linear combination of the other independent variables, then we say the model suffers from perfect collinearity, and it cannot be estimated by OLS.
It is important to note that Assumption MLR.3 does allow the independent variables to be correlated; they just cannot be perfectly correlated. If we did not allow for any corre- lation among the independent variables, then multiple regression would be of very limited use for econometric analysis. For example, in the model relating test scores to educational expenditures and average family income,
avgscore 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1expend 􏱕 􏱬2avginc 􏱕 u,
we fully expect expend and avginc to be correlated: school districts with high average family incomes tend to spend more per student on education. In fact, the primary motiva- tion for including avginc in the equation is that we suspect it is correlated with expend, and so we would like to hold it fixed in the analysis. Assumption MLR.3 only rules out perfect correlation between expend and avginc in our sample. We would be very unlucky
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Assumption MLR.3 No Perfect Collinearity
In the sample (and therefore in the population), none of the independent variables is constant, and there are no exact linear relationships among the independent variables.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 85
to obtain a sample where per student expenditures are perfectly correlated with average family income. But some correlation, perhaps a substantial amount, is expected and certainly allowed.
The simplest way that two independent variables can be perfectly correlated is when one variable is a constant multiple of another. This can happen when a researcher inad- vertently puts the same variable measured in different units into a regression equation. For example, in estimating a relationship between consumption and income, it makes no sense to include as independent variables income measured in dollars as well as income measured in thousands of dollars. One of these is redundant. What sense would it make to hold income measured in dollars fixed while changing income measured in thousands of dollars?
We already know that different nonlinear functions of the same variable can appear among the regressors. For example, the model cons 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2inc2 􏱕 u does not violate Assumption MLR.3: even though x2 􏱪 inc2 is an exact function of x1 􏱪 inc, inc2 is not an exact linear function of inc. Including inc2 in the model is a useful way to gen- eralize functional form, unlike including income measured in dollars and in thousands of dollars.
Common sense tells us not to include the same explanatory variable measured in dif- ferent units in the same regression equation. There are also more subtle ways that one independent variable can be a multiple of another. Suppose we would like to estimate an extension of a constant elasticity consumption function. It might seem natural to specify a model such as
log(cons) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(inc) 􏱕 􏱬2log(inc2) 􏱕 u, [3.34]
where x1 􏱪 log(inc) and x2 􏱪 log(inc2). Using the basic properties of the natural log (see Appendix A), log(inc2) 􏱪 2􏱳log(inc). That is, x2 􏱪 2×1, and naturally this holds for all observations in the sample. This violates Assumption MLR.3. What we should do instead is include [log(inc)]2, not log(inc2), along with log(inc). This is a sensible extension of the constant elasticity model, and we will see how to interpret such models in Chapter 6.
Another way that independent variables can be perfectly collinear is when one inde- pendent variable can be expressed as an exact linear function of two or more of the other independent variables. For example, suppose we want to estimate the effect of campaign spending on campaign outcomes. For simplicity, assume that each election has two candi- dates. Let voteA be the percentage of the vote for Candidate A, let expendA be campaign expenditures by Candidate A, let expendB be campaign expenditures by Candidate B, and let totexpend be total campaign expenditures; the latter three variables are all measured in dollars. It may seem natural to specify the model as
voteA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1expendA 􏱕 􏱬2expendB 􏱕 􏱬3totexpend 􏱕 u, [3.35]
in order to isolate the effects of spending by each candidate and the total amount of spend- ing. But this model violates Assumption MLR.3 because x3 􏱪 x1 􏱕 x2 by definition. Trying to interpret this equation in a ceteris paribus fashion reveals the problem. The parameter of 􏱬1 in equation (3.35) is supposed to measure the effect of increasing expenditures by Candidate A by one dollar on Candidate A’s vote, holding Candidate B’s spending and total spending fixed. This is nonsense, because if expendB and totexpend are held fixed, then we cannot increase expendA.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

86 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
The solution to the perfect collinearity in (3.35) is simple: drop any one of the three variables from the model. We would probably drop totexpend, and then the coefficient on expendA would measure the effect of increasing expenditures by A on the percentage of the vote received by A, holding the spending by B fixed.
The prior examples show that Assumption MLR.3 can fail if we are not careful in specifying our model. Assumption MLR.3 also fails if the sample size, n, is too small in relation to the number of parameters being estimated. In the general regression model in equation (3.31), there are k 􏱕 1 parameters, and MLR.3 fails if n 􏱷 k 􏱕 1. Intuitively, this makes sense: to estimate k 􏱕 1 parameters, we need at least k 􏱕 1 observations. Not surprisingly, it is better to have as many observations as possible, something we will see with our variance calculations in Section 3.4.
If the model is carefully specified and n 􏱸 k 􏱕 1, Assumption MLR.3 can fail in rare cases due to bad luck in col- lecting the sample. For example, in a wage equation with education and ex- perience as variables, it is possible that we could obtain a random sample where each individual has exactly twice as much education as years of experience.
This scenario would cause Assumption MLR.3 to fail, but it can be considered very un- likely unless we have an extremely small sample size.
The final, and most important, assumption needed for unbiasedness is a direct exten- sion of Assumption SLR.4.
One way that Assumption MLR.4 can fail is if the functional relationship between the explained and explanatory variables is misspecified in equation (3.31): for example, if we forget to include the quadratic term inc2 in the consumption function cons 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2inc2 􏱕 u when we estimate the model. Another functional form misspecification occurs when we use the level of a variable when the log of the variable is what actually shows up in the population model, or vice versa. For example, if the true model has log(wage) as the dependent variable but we use wage as the dependent variable in our regression analysis, then the estimators will be biased. Intuitively, this should be pretty clear. We will discuss ways of detecting functional form misspecification in Chapter 9.
Omitting an important factor that is correlated with any of x1, x2, …, xk causes Assumption MLR.4 to fail also. With multiple regression analysis, we are able to include many factors among the explanatory variables, and omitted variables are less likely to be a problem in multiple regression analysis than in simple regression analysis. Nevertheless, in any application, there are always factors that, due to data limitations or ignorance, we will not be able to include. If we think these factors should be controlled for and they are
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
EXPLORING FURTHER 3.3
In the previous example, if we use as ex- planatory variables expendA, expendB, and shareA, where shareA 􏱪 100􏱳(expendA/ totexpend) is the percentage share of total campaign expenditures made by Candidate A, does this violate Assumption MLR.3?
Assumption MLR.4 Zero Conditional Mean
The error u has an expected value of zero given any values of the independent variables. In other words,
E(u􏰫x1, x2, …, xk) 􏱪 0. [3.36]

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 87
correlated with one or more of the independent variables, then Assumption MLR.4 will be violated. We will derive this bias later.
There are other ways that u can be correlated with an explanatory variable. In Chapters 9 and 15, we will discuss the problem of measurement error in an explanatory variable. In Chapter 16, we cover the conceptually more difficult problem in which one or more of the explanatory variables is determined jointly with y—as occurs when we view quantities and prices as being determined by the intersection of supply and demand curves. We must postpone our study of these problems until we have a firm grasp of multiple regression analysis under an ideal set of assumptions.
When Assumption MLR.4 holds, we often say that we have exogenous explanatory variables. If xj is correlated with u for any reason, then xj is said to be an endogenous explanatory variable. The terms “exogenous” and “endogenous” originated in simultane- ous equations analysis (see Chapter 16), but the term “endogenous explanatory variable” has evolved to cover any case in which an explanatory variable may be correlated with the error term.
Before we show the unbiasedness of the OLS estimators under MLR.1 to MLR.4, a word of caution. Beginning students of econometrics sometimes confuse Assumptions MLR.3 and MLR.4, but they are quite different. Assumption MLR.3 rules out certain relationships among the independent or explanatory variables and has nothing to do with the error, u. You will know immediately when carrying out OLS estimation whether or not Assumption MLR.3 holds. On the other hand, Assumption MLR.4—the much more important of the two—restricts the relationship between the unobserved factors in u and the explanatory variables. Unfortunately, we will never know for sure whether the average value of the unobserved factors is unrelated to the explanatory variables. But this is the critical assumption.
We are now ready to show unbiasedness of OLS under the first four multiple regres- sion assumptions. As in the simple regression case, the expectations are conditional on the values of the explanatory variables in the sample, something we show explicitly in Appendix 3A but not in the text.
THEOREM 3.1
UNBIASEDNESS OF OLS
Under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4,
E(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 􏱬j, j 􏱪 0, 1, …, k, [3.37]
for any values of the population parameter 􏱬j. In other words, the OLS estimators are unbiased estimators of the population parameters.
In our previous empirical examples, Assumption MLR.3 has been satisfied (because we have been able to compute the OLS estimates). Furthermore, for the most part, the samples are randomly chosen from a well-defined population. If we believe that the speci- fied models are correct under the key Assumption MLR.4, then we can conclude that OLS is unbiased in these examples.
Since we are approaching the point where we can use multiple regression in serious empirical work, it is useful to remember the meaning of unbiasedness. It is tempting, in examples such as the wage equation in (3.19), to say something like “9.2% is an unbiased
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

88 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
estimate of the return to education.” As we know, an estimate cannot be unbiased: an estimate is a fixed number, obtained from a particular sample, which usually is not equal to the population parameter. When we say that OLS is unbiased under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4, we mean that the procedure by which the OLS estimates are obtained is unbiased when we view the procedure as being applied across all possible random samples. We hope that we have obtained a sample that gives us an estimate close to the population value, but, unfortunately, this cannot be assured. What is assured is that we have no reason to believe our estimate is more likely to be too big or more likely to be too small.
Including Irrelevant Variables in a Regression Model
One issue that we can dispense with fairly quickly is that of inclusion of an irrelevant variable or overspecifying the model in multiple regression analysis. This means that one (or more) of the independent variables is included in the model even though it has no partial effect on y in the population. (That is, its population coefficient is zero.)
To illustrate the issue, suppose we specify the model as
y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1×1 􏱕􏱬2×2 􏱕􏱬3×3 􏱕u, [3.38]
and this model satisfies Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4. However, x3 has no effect on y after x1 and x2 have been controlled for, which means that 􏱬3 􏱪 0. The variable x3 may or may not be correlated with x1 or x2; all that matters is that, once x1 and x2 are controlled for, x3 has no effect on y. In terms of conditional expectations, E(y􏰫x1, x2, x3) 􏱪 E(y􏰫x1, x2) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1×1 􏱕 􏱬2×2.
Because we do not know that 􏱬3 􏱪 0, we are inclined to estimate the equation includ- ing x3:
yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1×1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2×2 􏱕 􏱬ˆ3×3. [3.39]
We have included the irrelevant variable, x3, in our regression. What is the effect of including x3 in (3.39) when its coefficient in the population model (3.38) is zero? In terms of the unbiasedness of 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2, there is no effect. This conclusion requires no special derivation, as it follows immediately from Theorem 3.1. Remember, unbiasedness means E(ˆ􏱬j) 􏱪 􏱬j for any value of 􏱬j, including 􏱬j 􏱪 0. Thus, we can conclude that E(ˆ􏱬0) 􏱪 􏱬0, E(ˆ􏱬1) 􏱪 􏱬1, E(ˆ􏱬2) 􏱪 􏱬2, and E(ˆ􏱬3) 􏱪 0 (for any values of 􏱬0, 􏱬1, and 􏱬2). Even though 􏱬ˆ3 itself will never be exactly zero, its average value across all random samples will be zero.
The conclusion of the preceding example is much more general: including one or more irrelevant variables in a multiple regression model, or overspecifying the model, does not affect the unbiasedness of the OLS estimators. Does this mean it is harmless to include irrelevant variables? No. As we will see in Section 3.4, including irrelevant vari- ables can have undesirable effects on the variances of the OLS estimators.
Omitted Variable Bias: The Simple Case
Now suppose that, rather than including an irrelevant variable, we omit a variable that actually belongs in the true (or population) model. This is often called the problem of excluding a relevant variable or underspecifying the model. We claimed in Chapter 2
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 89
and earlier in this chapter that this problem generally causes the OLS estimators to be biased. It is time to show this explicitly and, just as importantly, to derive the direction and size of the bias.
Deriving the bias caused by omitting an important variable is an example of misspecification analysis. We begin with the case where the true population model has two explanatory variables and an error term:
y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1×1 􏱕􏱬2×2 􏱕u, [3.40]
and we assume that this model satisfies Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4.
Suppose that our primary interest is in 􏱬1, the partial effect of x1 on y. For example, y is hourly wage (or log of hourly wage), x1 is education, and x2 is a measure of innate abil- ity. In order to get an unbiased estimator of 􏱬1, we should run a regression of y on x1 and x2 (which gives unbiased estimators of 􏱬0, 􏱬1, and 􏱬2). However, due to our ignorance or data unavailability, we estimate the model by excluding x2. In other words, we perform a
simple regression of y on x1 only, obtaining the equation
y ̃􏱪􏱬 ̃0 􏱕􏱬 ̃1×1. [3.41]
We use the symbol “~” rather than “^” to emphasize that 􏱬 ̃1 comes from an underspecified model.
When first learning about the omitted variable problem, it can be difficult to distin- guish between the underlying true model, (3.40) in this case, and the model that we actu- ally estimate, which is captured by the regression in (3.41). It may seem silly to omit the variable x2 if it belongs in the model, but often we have no choice. For example, suppose that wage is determined by
wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2abil 􏱕 u. [3.42] Since ability is not observed, we instead estimate the model
wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 v,
where v 􏱪 􏱬2abil 􏱕 u. The estimator of 􏱬1 from the simple regression of wage on educ is what we are calling 􏱬 ̃1. ̃
We derive the expected value of 􏱬1 conditional on the sample values of x1 and x2. Deriving this expectation is not difficult because 􏱬 ̃1 is just the OLS slope estimator from a simple regression, and we have already studied this estimator extensively in Chapter 2. The difference here is that we must analyze its properties when the simple regression model is misspecified due to an omitted variable.
As it turns out, we have done almost all of the work to derive the bias in the simple regression estimator of ̃􏱬1. From equation (3.23) we have the algebraic relationship 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2􏱛 ̃1, where 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 are the slope estimators (if we could have them) from the multiple regression
yi onxi1,xi2,i􏱪1,…,n [3.43] and 􏱛!1 is the slope from the simple regression
xi2 onxi1,i􏱪1,…,n. [3.44] Because 􏱛1 depends only on the independent variables in the sample, we treat it as
! ̃
fixed (nonrandom) when computing E(􏱬1). Further, since the model in (3.40) satisfies
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

90 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data
Assumptions MLR.1 to MLR.4, we know that 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 would be unbiased for 􏱬1 and 􏱬2,
respectively. Therefore,
E(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱪 E(􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2􏱛!1) 􏱪 E(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱕 E(􏱬ˆ2)􏱛!1 􏱪􏱬1 􏱕􏱬2􏱛!1,
which implies the bias in 􏱬 ̃1 is
Bias(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱪 E(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱦 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2􏱛!1.
[3.45] [3.46]
Because the bias in this case arises from omitting the explanatory variable x2, the term on the right-hand side of equation (3.46) is often called the omitted variable bias.
From equation (3.46), we see that there are two cases where 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased. The first is pretty obvious: if 􏱬2 􏱪 0—so that x2 does not appear in the true model (3.40)—then 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased. We already know this f!rom the simple regression analysis in Chapter 2. The second case is more interesting. If 􏱛1 􏱪 0, then 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased for 􏱬1, even if 􏱬2 􏱻 0.
! Because 􏱛!1 is the sample covariance between x1 and x2 over the sample variance of x1, 􏱛1 􏱪 0 if, and only if, x1 and x2 are uncorrelated in the sample. Thus, we have the impor- tant conclusion that, if x1 and x2 are uncorrelated in the sample, then 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased. This is not surprising: in Section 3.2, we showed that the simple regression estimator 􏱬 ̃1 and the multiple regression estimator 􏱬ˆ1 are the same when x1 and x2 are uncorrelated in the sample. [We can also show that 􏱬 ̃1 is unbiased without conditioning on the xi2 if E(x2􏰫x1) 􏱪 E(x2); then, for estimating 􏱬1, leaving x2 in the error term does not violate the zero condi- tional mean assumption for the error, once we adjust the intercept.]
When x1 and x2 are correlated, 􏱛 !1 has the same sign as the correlation between x1 and x2: 􏱛 ̃ 􏱰 0 if x and x are positively correlated and 􏱛 ! 􏱷 0 if x and x are negatively correlated. The
112 ̃11!2
sign of the bias in 􏱬1 depends on the signs of both 􏱬2 and 􏱛1 and is summarized in Table 3.2
for the four ̃possible cases when there is bias. Table 3.2 warrants careful study. For example, the bias in 􏱬1 is positive if 􏱬2 􏱰 0 (x2 has a positive effect on y) and x1 and x2 are positively correlated, the bias is negative if 􏱬2 􏱰 0 and x1 and x2 are negatively correlated, and so on.
Table 3.2 summarizes the direction of the bias, but the size of the bias is also very important. A small bias of either sign need not be a cause for concern. For example, if the return to education in the population is 8.6% and the bias in the OLS estimator is 0.1% (a tenth of one percentage point), then we would not be very concerned. On the other hand, a bias on the order of three percentage points would be much more serious. The size of the bias is determined by the sizes of 􏱬2 and 􏱛!1.
In practice, since 􏱬2 is an unknown population parameter, we cannot be certain whether 􏱬2 is positive or negative. Nevertheless, we usually have a pretty good idea about the direction of the partial effect of x2 on y. Further, even though the sign of the correlation between x1 and x2 cannot be known if x2 is not observed, in many cases, we can make an educated guess about whether x1 and x2 are positively or negatively correlated.
In the wage equation (3.42), by definition, more ability leads to higher productivity and therefore higher wages: 􏱬2 􏱰 0. Also, there are reasons to believe that educ and abil are positively correlated: on average, individuals with more innate ability choose higher
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
T A B L E 3 . 2 Summary of Bias in 􏱬~1 when x2 Is Omitted in Estimating Eqution (3.40)
Corr(x1, x2) 􏱆 0 Corr(x1, x2) 􏱼 0
􏱬2 > 0
Positive bias
Negative bias
􏱬2 < 0 Negative bias Positive bias © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 91 levels of education. Thus, the OLS estimates from the simple regression equation wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 v are on average too large. This does not mean that the estimate obtained from our sample is too big. We can only say that if we collect many random samples and obtain the simple regression estimates each time, then the average of these estimates will be greater than 􏱬1. EXAMPLE 3.6 HOURLY WAGE EQUATION Suppose the model log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2abil 􏱕 u satisfies Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4. The data set in WAGE1.RAW does not contain data on ability, so we estimate 􏱬1 from the simple regression log(wage) 􏱪 .584 􏱕 .083 educ n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .186. [3.47] This is the result from only a single sample, so we cannot say that .083 is greater than 􏱬1; the true return to education could be lower or higher than 8.3% (and we will never know for sure). Nevertheless, we know that the average of the estimates across all random samples would be too large. As a second example, suppose that, at the elementary school level, the average score for students on a standardized exam is determined by avgscore 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1expend 􏱕 􏱬2 povrate 􏱕 u, [3.48] where expend is expenditure per student and povrate is the poverty rate of the children in the school. Using school district data, we only have observations on the percentage of students with a passing grade and per student expenditures; we do not have information on poverty rates. Thus, we estimate 􏱬1 from the simple regression of avgscore on expend. We can again obtain the likely bias in ̃􏱬1. First, 􏱬2 is probably negative: There is ample evidence that children living in poverty score lower, on average, on standardized tests. Second, the average expenditure per student is probably negatively correlated with the poverty rate: The higher the poverty rate, the lower the average per student spending, so that Corr(x1, x2) 􏱷 0. From Table 3.2, 􏱬 ̃1 will have a positive bias. This observation has important implications. It could be that the true effect of spending is zero; that is, 􏱬1 􏱪 0. However, the simple regression estimate of 􏱬1 will usually be greater than zero, and this could lead us to conclude that expenditures are important when they are not. When reading and performing empirical work in economics, it is important to master the terminology associated with biased estimators. In the context of omitting a variable from model (3.40), if E(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱰 􏱬1, then we say that 􏱬 ̃1 has an upward bias. When E(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱷 􏱬1, 􏱬 ̃1 has a downward bias. These definitions are the same whether 􏱬1 is positive or negative. The phrase biased toward zero refers to cases where E(􏱬 ̃1) is closer to zero than is 􏱬1. There- fore, if 􏱬1 is positive, then 􏱬 ̃1 is biased toward zero if it has a downward bias. On the other hand, if 􏱬1 􏱷 0, then 􏱬 ̃1 is biased toward zero if it has an upward bias. Omitted Variable Bias: More General Cases Deriving the sign of omitted variable bias when there are multiple regressors in the estimated model is more difficult. We must remember that correlation between a single Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 92 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data explanatory variable and the error generally results in all OLS estimators being biased. For example, suppose the population model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u [3.49] satisfies Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4. But we omit x3 and estimate the model as y ̃ 􏱪 􏱬 ̃0 􏱕 􏱬 ̃1x1 􏱕 􏱬 ̃2x2. [3.50] Now, suppose that x2 and x3 are uncorrelated, but that x1 is correlated with x3. In other words, x1 is correlated with the omitted variable, but x2 is not. It is tempting to think that, while 􏱬 ̃1 is probably biased based on the derivation in the previous subsection, 􏱬 ̃2 is unbi- ased because x2 is uncorrelated with x3. Unfortunately, this is not generally the case: both 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬 ̃2 will normally be biased. The only exception to this is when x1 and x2 are also uncorrelated. Even in the fairly simple model above, it can be difficult to obtain the direction of bias in 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬 ̃2. This is because x1, x2, and x3 can all be pairwise correlated. Nevertheless, an approximation is often practically useful. If we assume that x1 and x2 are uncorrelated, then we can study the bias in 􏱬 ̃1 as if x2 were absent from both the population and the estimated models. In fact, when x1 and x2 are uncorrelated, it can be shown that ___i􏱪__1________________ E(􏱬 ̃)􏱪􏱬􏱕􏱬∑ . 113n_2 (x 􏱦x) This is just like equation (3.45), but 􏱬3 replaces 􏱬2, and x3 replaces x2 in regression (3.44). Therefore, the bias in 􏱬 ̃1 is obtained by replacing 􏱬2 with 􏱬3 and x2 with x3 in Table 3.2. If 􏱬3 􏱰 0 and Corr(x1, x3) 􏱰 0, the bias in 􏱬 ̃1 is positive, and so on. As an example, suppose we add exper to the wage model: wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3abil 􏱕 u. If abil is omitted from the model, the estimators of both 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 are biased, even if we assume exper is uncorrelated with abil. We are mo ̃stly interested in the return to educa- tion, so it would be nice if we could conclude that 􏱬1 has an upward or a downward bias due to omitted ability. This conclusion is not possible without further assumptions. As an approximation, let us suppose that, in addition to exper and abil being uncorrelated, educ and exper are also uncorrelated. (In reality, they are som ̃ewhat negatively correlated.) Since 􏱬3 􏱰 0 and educ and abil are positively correlated, 􏱬1 would have an upward bias, just as if exper were not in the model. The reasoning used in the previous example is often followed as a rough guide for obtaining the likely bias in estimators in more complicated models. Usually, the focus is on the relationship between a particular explanatory variable, say, x1, and the key omit- ted factor. Strictly speaking, ignoring all other explanatory variables is a valid practice only when each one is uncorrelated with x1, but it is still a useful guide. Appendix 3A contains a more careful analysis of omitted variable bias with multiple explanatory variables. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∑n _ (xi1 􏱦 x1)xi3 i1 1 i􏱪1 CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 93 3.4 The Variance of the OLS Estimators We now obtain the variance of the OLS estimators so that, in addition to knowing the central tendencies of the 􏱬ˆj, we also have a measure of the spread in its sampling distribution. Before finding the variances, we add a homoskedasticity assumption, as in Chapter 2. We do this for two reasons. First, the formulas are simplified by imposing the constant error variance assumption. Second, in Section 3.5, we will see that OLS has an important efficiency property if we add the homoskedasticity assumption. In the multiple regression framework, homoskedasticity is stated as follows: Assumption MLR.5 means that the variance in the error term, u, conditional on the explanatory variables, is the same for all combinations of outcomes of the explanatory variables. If this assumption fails, then the model exhibits heteroskedasticity, just as in the two-variable case. In the equation wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 u, homoskedasticity requires that the variance of the unobserved error u does not depend on the levels of education, experience, or tenure. That is, Var(u􏰫educ, exper, tenure) 􏱪 􏱧2. If this variance changes with any of the three explanatory variables, then heteroskedasticity is present. Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5 are collectively known as the Gauss-Markov assumptions (for cross-sectional regression). So far, our statements of the assumptions are suitable only when applied to cross-sectional analysis with random sampling. As we will see, the Gauss-Markov assumptions for time series analysis, and for other situa- tions such as panel data analysis, are more difficult to state, although there are many similarities. In the discussion that follows, we will use the symbol x to denote the set of all in- dependent variables, (x1, ..., xk). Thus, in the wage regression with educ, exper, and ten- ure as independent variables, x 􏱪 (educ, exper, tenure). Then we can write Assumptions MLR.1 and MLR.4 as E(y􏰫x)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk, Assumption MLR.5 Homoskedasticity The error u has the same variance given any values of the explanatory variables. In other words, Var(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱧2. and Assumption MLR.5 is the same as Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2. Stating the assumptions in this way clearly illustrates how Assumption MLR.5 differs greatly from Assumption MLR.4. Assumption MLR.4 says that the expected value of y, given x, is linear in the parameters, but it certainly depends on x1, x2, ..., xk. Assumption MLR.5 says that the variance of y, given x, does not depend on the values of the independent variables. We can now obtain the variances of the 􏱬ˆj, where we again condition on the sample values of the independent variables. The proof is in the appendix to this chapter. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 94 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data THEOREM 3.2 SAMPLING VARIANCES OF THE OLS SLOPE ESTIMATORS Under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5, conditional on the sample values of the independent variables, ˆ 2 , ____􏱧______ [3.51] Var(􏱬 ) 􏱪 j SSTj(1 􏱦 R2j ) forj􏱪1,2,...,k,whereSSTj 􏱪∑n (x 􏱶x_)2 isthetotalsamplevariationinx,and i􏱪1ij j j Rj2 is the R-squared from regressing xj on all other independent variables (and including an intercept). The careful reader may be wondering whether there is a simple formula for the vari- ance of 􏱬ˆj where we do not condition on the sample outcomes of the explanatory variables. The answer is: None that is useful. The formula in (3.51) is a highly nonlinear function of the xij, making averaging out across the population distribution of the explanatory vari- ables virtually impossible. Fortunately, for any practical purpose equation (3.51) is what we want. Even when we turn to approximate, large-sample properties of OLS in Chapter 5 it turns out that (3.51) estimates the quantity we need for large-sample analysis, provided Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5 hold. Before we study equation (3.51) in more detail, it is important to know that all of the Gauss-Markov assumptions are used in obtaining this formula. Whereas we did not need the homoskedasticity assumption to conclude that OLS is unbiased, we do need it to vali- date equation (3.51). ˆ The size of Var(􏱬j) is practically important. A larger variance means a less precise estimator, and this translates into larger confidence intervals and less accurate hypotheses tests (as we will see in Chapter 4). In the next subsection, we discuss the elements com- prising (3.51). The Components of the OLS Variances: Multicollinearity Equation (3.51) shows that the variance of 􏱬ˆj depends on three factors: 􏱧2, SSTj, and R2j . Remember that the index j simply denotes any one of the independent variables (such as education or poverty rate). We now consider each of the factors affecting Var(􏱬ˆj) in turn. The Error Variance, 􏱧2. From equation (3.51), a larger 􏱧2 means larger variances for the OLS estimators. This is not at all surprising: more “noise” in the equation (a larger 􏱧2) makes it more difficult to estimate the partial effect of any of the independent variables on y, and this is reflected in higher variances for the OLS slope estimators. Because 􏱧2 is a feature of the population, it has nothing to do with the sample size. It is the one component of (3.51) that is unknown. We will see later how to obtain an unbiased estimator of 􏱧2. For a given dependent variable y, there is really only one way to reduce the error variance, and that is to add more explanatory variables to the equation (take some factors out of the error term). Unfortunately, it is not always possible to find additional legitimate factors that affect y. The Total Sample Variation in xj , SSTj. From equation (3.51), we see that the larger the total variation in xj is, the smaller is Var(􏱬ˆj). Thus, everything else being equal, for Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 95 estimating 􏱬j we prefer to have as much sample variation in xj as possible. We already discovered this in the simple regression case in Chapter 2. Although it is rarely possible for us to choose the sample values of the independent variables, there is a way to increase the sample variation in each of the independent variables: increase the sample size. In fact, when one samples randomly from a population, SSTj increases without bound as the sample size gets larger and larger. This is the component of the variance that systemati- cally depends on the sample size. When SSTj is small, Var(􏱬ˆj) can get very large, but a small SSTj is not a violation of Assumption MLR.3. Technically, as SSTj goes to zero, Var(􏱬ˆj) approaches infinity. The extreme case of no sample variation in xj, SSTj 􏱪 0, is not allowed by Assumption MLR.3. The Linear Relationships among the Independent Variables, R2j . The term R2j in equa- tion (3.51) is the most difficult of the three components to understand. This term does not appear in simple regression analysis because there is only one independent variable in such cases. It is important to see that this R-squared is distinct from the R-squared in the regression of y on x1, x2, ..., xk: R2j is obtained from a regression involving only the inde- pendent variables in the original model, where xj plays the role of a dependent variable. Consider first the k 􏱪 2 case: y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 􏱬2x2 􏱕 u. Then, Var(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱧2/[SST1(1 􏱦 R21)], where R21 is the R-squared from the simple regression of x1 on x2 (and an intercept, as always). Because the R-squared measures goodness-of-fit, a value of R21 close to one indicates that x2 explains much of the variation in x1 in the sample. This means that x1 and x2 are highly correlated. ˆ As R21 increases to one, Var(􏱬1) gets larger and larger. Thus, a high degree of linear relationship between x1 and x2 can lead to large variances for the OLS slope estimators. (A similar argument applies to 􏱬ˆ2.) See Figure 3.1 for the relationship between Var(􏱬ˆ1) and the R-squared from the regression of x1 on x2. In the general case, Rj2 is the proportion of the total variation in xj that can be explained by the other iˆndependent variables appearing in the equation. For a given 􏱧2 and SSTj, the smallest Var(􏱬j) is obtained when Rj2 􏱪 0, which happens if, and only if, xj has zero sample correlation with every other independent variable. This is the best case for estimating 􏱬j, but it is rarely encountered. The other extreme case, R2j 􏱪 1, is ruled out by Assumption MLR.3, because R2j 􏱪 1 means that, in the sample, xj is a perfect linear combination of some of the other indepen- dent variables in the regression. A more relevant case is when R2j is “close” to one. From equation (3.51) and Figure 3.1, we see that this can cause Var(􏱬ˆj) to be large: Var(􏱬ˆj) 􏱽 􏱵 as R2j 􏱽 1. High (but not perfect) correlation between two or more independent variables is called multicollinearity. Before we discuss the multicollinearity issue further, it is important to be very clear on one thing: A case where R2j is close to one is not a violation of Assumption MLR.3. Since multicollinearity violates none of our assumptions, the “problem” of multicol- linearity is not really well defined. When we say that multicollinearity arises for estimat- ing 􏱬j when R2j is “close” to one, we put “close” in quotation marks because there is no absolute number that we can cite to conclude that multicollinearity is a problem. For ex- ample,R2j 􏱪.9meansthat90%ofthesamplevariationinxjcanbeexplainedbytheother independent variables in the regression model. Unquestionably, this means that xj has a strong lineaˆr relationship to the other independent variables. But whether this translates into a Var(􏱬j) that is too large to be useful depends on the sizes of 􏱧2 and SSTj. As we Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 96 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data FIGURE 3.1 Var(􏱬ˆ ) as a function of R . 11 2 Var( ˆ1) 0 R12 1 will see in Chapter 4, for statistical inference, what ultimately matters is how big 􏱬ˆj is in relation to its standard deviation. ˆ Just as a large value of R2j can cause a large Var(􏱬j), so can a small value of SSTj. Therefore, a small sample size can lead to large sampling variances, too. Worrying about high degrees of correlation among the independent variables in the sample is really no dif- ferent from worrying about a small sample size: both work to increase Var(􏱬ˆj). The famous University of Wisconsin econometrician Arthur Goldberger, reacting to econometricians’ obsession with multicollinearity, has (tongue in cheek) coined the term micronumerosity, which he defines as the “problem of small sample size.” [For an engaging discussion of multicollinearity and micronumerosity, see Goldberger (1991).] Although the problem of multicollinearity cannot be clearly defined, one thing is clear: everything else being equal, for estimating 􏱬j, it is better to have less correlation between xj and the other independent variables. This observation often leads to a discussion of how to “solve” the multicollinearity problem. In the social sciences, where we are usually pas- sive collectors of data, there is no good way to reduce variances of unbiased estimators other than to collect more data. For a given data set, we can try dropping other independent variables from the model in an effort to reduce multicollinearity. Unfortunately, dropping a variable that belongs in the population model can lead to bias, as we saw in Section 3.3. Perhaps an example at this point will help clarify some of the issues raised concern- ing multicollinearity. Suppose we are interested in estimating the effect of various school expenditure categories on student performance. It is likely that expenditures on teacher Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 97 salaries, instructional materials, athletics, and so on are highly correlated: Wealthier schools tend to spend more on everything, and poorer schools spend less on everything. Not surprisingly, it can be difficult to estimate the effect of any particular expenditure category on student performance when there is little variation in one category that cannot largely be explained by variations in the other expenditure categories (this leads to high Rj2 for each of the expenditure variables). Such multicollinearity problems can be mitigated by collecting more data, but in a sense we have imposed the problem on ourselves: we are asking questions that may be too subtle for the available data to answer with any preci- sion. We can probably do much better by changing the scope of the analysis and lumping all expenditure categories together, since we would no longer be trying to estimate the partial effect of each separate category. Another important point is that a high degree of correlation between certain indepen- dentvariables can be irrelevant as to how well we can estimate other parameters in the model. For example, consider a model with three independent variables: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u, where x2 and x3 are highly correlated. Then Var(􏱬ˆ2) and Var(􏱬ˆ3) may be large. But the amount of correlation between x2 and x3 has no direct effect on Var(􏱬ˆ1). In fact, if x1 is uncorrelated with x2 and x3, then R21 􏱪 0 and Var(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱧2/SST1, regardless of how much correlation there is between x2 and x3. If 􏱬1 is the parameter of interest, we do not really care about the amount of correlation between x2 and x3. The previous observation is important because economists often include many control variables in order to isolate the causal effect of a particular variable. For example, in looking at the relationship between loan approval rates and percent- age of minorities in a neighborhood, we might include variables like average in- come, average housing value, measures of creditworthiness, and so on, because these factors need to be accounted for in order to draw causal conclusions about discrimination. Income, housing prices, and cred- itworthiness are generally highly correlated with each other. But high correlations among these controls do not make it more difficult to determine the effects of discrimination. Some researchers find it useful to compute statistics intended to determine the severity of multicollinearity in a given application. Unfortunately, it is easy to misuse such statistics because, as we have discussed, we cannot specify how much correlation among explanatory variables is “too much.” Some multicollinearity “diagnostics” are omnibus statistics in the sense that they detect a strong linear relationship among any subset of explanatory variables. For reasons that we just saw, such statistics are of questionable value because they might reveal a “problem” simply because two control variables, whose coefficients we do not care about, are highly correlated. [Probably the most common omnibus multicollinearity statistic is the so-called condition number, which is defined in terms of the full data matrix and is beyond the scope of this text. See, for example, Belsley, Kuh, and Welsh (1980).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 3.4 Suppose you postulate a model explain- ing final exam score in terms of class at- tendance. Thus, the dependent variable is final exam score, and the key explanatory variable is number of classes attended. To control for student abilities and efforts outside the classroom, you include among the explanatory variables cumulative GPA, SAT score, and measures of high school performance. Someone says, “You can- not hope to learn anything from this exer- cise because cumulative GPA, SAT score, and high school performance are likely to be highly collinear.” What should be your response? 98 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Somewhat more useful, but still prone to misuse, are statistics for individual coef- ficients. The most common of these is the variance inflation factor (VIF), which is obtained directly from equation (3.51). The VIF for slope coefficient j is simply VIFj 􏱪 1 / ( 1 􏱦 R 2j ) , p r e c i s e l y t h e t e r m i n V a r ( 􏱬ˆ j ) t h a t i s d e t e r m i n e d b y c o r r e l a t i o n b e t w e e n x j a n d the other explanatory variables. We can write Var(􏱬ˆj) in equation (3.51) as 2 Var(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 __􏱧__ ∙ VIFj, which shows that VIFj is the factor by which Var(􏱬ˆj) is higher because xj is not uncor- related with the other explanatory variables. Because VIFj is a function of R2j —indeed, Figure 3.1 is essentially a graph of VIF1—our previous discussion can be cast entirely in terms of the VIF. For example, if we had the choice, we would like VIFj to be smaller (other things equal). But we rarely have the choice. If we think certain explanatory vari- ables need to be included in a regression to infer causality of xj, then we are hesitant to drop them, and whether we think VIFj is “too high” cannot really affect that decision. If, say, our main interest is in the causal effect of x1 on y, then we should ignore entirely the VIFs of other coefficients. Finally, setting a cutoff value for VIF above which we conclude multicollinearity is a “problem” is arbitrary and not especially helpful. Some- times the value 10 is chosen: If VIFj is above 10 (equivalently, R2j is above .9), then we conclude that multicollinearity is a “problem” for estimating 􏱬j. But a VIFj above 10 does not mean that the standard deviation of 􏱬ˆj is too large to be useful because the standard deviation also depends on 􏱧 and SSTj, and the latter can be increased by increasing the sample size. Therefore, just as with looking at the size of R2j directly, looking at the size of VIFj is of limited use, although one might want to do so out of curiosity. Variances in Misspecified Models The choice of whether to include a particular variable in a regression model can be made by analyzing the tradeoff between bias and variance. In Section 3.3, we derived the bias induced by leaving out a relevant variable when the true model contains two explanatory variables. We continue the analysis of this model by comparing the variances of the OLS estimators. Write the true population model, which satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕u. We consider two estimators of 􏱬1. The estimator 􏱬ˆ1 comes from the multiple regression yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x2. [3.52] In other words, we include x2, along with x1, in the regression model. The estimator 􏱬 ̃1 is obtained by omitting x2 from the model and running a simple regression of y on x1: y ̃􏱪􏱬 ̃0 􏱕􏱬 ̃1x1. [3.53] When 􏱬2 􏱻 0, equation (3.53) excludes a r ̃elevant variable from the model and, as we saw in Sˆection 3.3, this induces a bias in 􏱬1 unless x1 and x2 are uncorrelated. On the other hand, 􏱬1 is unbiased for 􏱬1 for any value of 􏱬2, including 􏱬2 􏱪 0. It follows that, if bias is used as the only criterion, 􏱬ˆ1 is preferred to 􏱬 ̃1. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. SSTj CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 99 The conclusion that 􏱬ˆ1 is always preferred to 􏱬 ̃1 does not carry over when we bring variance into the picture. Conditioning on the values of x1 and x2 in the sample, we have, from (3.51), Var(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱧2/[SST1(1 􏱦 R21)], [3.54] where SST1 is the total variation in x1, and R21 is the R-squared from the regression of x1 on x2. Further, a simple modification of the proof in Chapter 2 for two-variable regression shows that Var(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱪 􏱧2/SST1. [3.55] Comparing (3.55) to (3.54) shows that Var(􏱬 ̃1) is always smaller than Var(􏱬ˆ1), unless x1 and x2 are uncorrelated in the sample, in which case the two estimators 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬ˆ1 are the same. Assuming that x1 and x2 are not uncorrelated, we can draw the following conclusions: 1. When 􏱬2 􏱻 0, 􏱬 ̃1 is biased, 􏱬ˆ1 is unbiased, and Var(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱷 Var(􏱬ˆ1). 2. When 􏱬2 􏱪 0, 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬ˆ1 are both unbiased, and Var(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱷 Var(􏱬ˆ1). From the second conclusion, it is clear that 􏱬 ̃1 is preferred if 􏱬2 􏱪 0. Intuitively, if x2 does not have a partial effect on y, then including it in the model can only exacerbate the multi- collinearity problem, which leads to a less efficient estimator of 􏱬1. A higher variance for the estimator of 􏱬1 is the cost of including an irrelevant variable in a model. The case where 􏱬2 􏱻 0 is more difficult. Leaving x2 out of the model results in a biased estimator of 􏱬1. Traditionally, econometricians have suggested comparing the likely size of the bias due to omitting x2 with the reduction in the variance—summarized in the size of R12—to decide whether x2 should be included. However, when 􏱬2 􏱻 0, there are two favorable reasons for including x2 in the model. The most important of these is that any bias in 􏱬 ̃1 does not shrink as the sample size grows; in fact, the bias does not necessarily follow any pattern. Therefore, we can usefully think of the bias as being roughly the same for any sample size. On the other hand, Var(􏱬 ̃1) and Var(􏱬ˆ1) both shrink to zero as n gets large, which means that the multicollinearity induced by adding x2 becomes less important as the sample size grows. In large samples, we would prefer 􏱬ˆ1. The other reason for favoring 􏱬ˆ1 is more subtle. The variance formula in (3.55) is con- ditional on the values of xi1 and xi2 in the sample, which provides the best scenario for 􏱬 ̃1. When 􏱬2 􏱻 0, the variance of ̃􏱬1 conditional only on x1 is larger than that presented in (3.55). Intuitively, when 􏱬2 􏱻 0 and x2 is excluded from the model, the error variance in- creases because the error effectively contains part of x2. But (3.55) ignores the error vari- ance increase because it treats both regressors as nonrandom. A full discussion of which independent variables to condition on would lead us too far astray. It i ̃s sufficient to say that (3.55) is too generous when it comes to measuring the precision in 􏱬1. Estimating 􏱧2: Standard Errors of the OLS Estimators We now show how to choosˆe an unbiased estimator of 􏱧2, which then allows us to obtain unbiased estimators of Var(􏱬j). 2∑2 2 Because 􏱧 􏱪 E(u ), an unbiased “estimator” of 􏱧 is the sample average of the u2. Unfortunately, this is not a true estimator because we do not i Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. squared errors: n􏱦1 n i􏱪1 observe the ui. Nevertheless, recall that the errors can be written as ui 􏱪 yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi1 􏱦 100 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 􏱬2xi2 􏱦...􏱦􏱬kxik,andsothereasonwedonotobservetheui isthatwedonotknowthe 􏱬j. When we replace each 􏱬j with its OLS estimator, we get the OLS residuals: uˆi 􏱪yi 􏱦􏱬ˆ0 􏱦􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱦􏱬ˆ2xi2 􏱦...􏱦􏱬ˆkxik. It seems natural to estimate 􏱧2 by replacing ui with the uˆi. In the simple regression case, we saw that this leads to a biased estimator. The unbiased estimator of 􏱧2 in the general multiple regression case is 􏱧ˆ2 􏱪􏱵 uˆ2􏱷􏱆(n􏱦k􏱦1)􏱪SSR (n􏱦k􏱦1). [3.56] ∑n i i􏱪1 􏱆 We already encountered this estimator in the k 􏱪 1 case in simple regression. The term n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 in (3.56) is the degrees of freedom (df ) for the general OLS problem with n observations and k independent variables. Since there are k 􏱕 1 param- eters in a regression model with k independent variables and an intercept, we can write df 􏱪 n 􏱦 (k 􏱕 1) 􏱪 (number of observations) 􏱦 (number of estimated parameters). This is the easiest way to compute the degrees of freedom in a particular application: count the number of parameters, including the intercept, and subtract this amount from the number of observations. (In the rare case that an intercept is not estimated, the number of parameters decreases by one.) Technically, the division by n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 in (3.56) comes from the fact that the ex- pected value of the sum of squared residuals is E(SSR) 􏱪 (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)􏱧2. Intuitively, we can figure out why the degrees of freedom adjustment is necessary∑by returning to ∑the first order conditions for the OLS estimators. These can be written n uˆ 􏱪 0 and i􏱪1 i􏱪1 x uˆ 􏱪0,wherej􏱪1,2,...,k.Thus,inobtainingtheOLSestimates,k􏱕1re- n ij i strictions are imposed on the OLS residuals. This means that, given n 􏱦 (k 􏱕 1) of the residuals, the remaining k 􏱕 1 residuals are known: there are only n 􏱦 (k 􏱕 1) degrees of freedom in the residuals. (This can be contrasted with the errors ui, which have n degrees of freedom in the sample.) For reference, we summarize this discussion with Theorem 3.3. We proved this theo- rem for the case of simple regression analysis in Chapter 2 (see Theorem 2.3). (A general proof that requires matrix algebra is provided in Appendix E.) The positive square root of 􏱧ˆ2, denoted 􏱧ˆ, is called the standard error of the regression (SER). The SER is an estimator of the standard deviation of the error term. This estimate is usually reported by regression packages, although it is called different things by differ- ent packages. (In addition to SER, 􏱧ˆ is also called the standard error of the estimate and the root mean squared error.) Note that ˆ􏱧 can either decrease or increase when another independent variable is added to a regression (for a given sample). This is because, although SSR must fall when another explanatory variable is added, the degrees of freedom also falls by one. Because Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i [3.57] THEOREM 3.3 UNBIASED ESTIMATION OF 􏰴2 Under the Gauss-Markov assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5, E(􏱧ˆ2) 􏱪 􏱧2. of 􏱬ˆj: CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 101 SSR is in the numerator and df is in the denominator, we cannot tell beforehand which effect will dominate. For constructing confidence intervals and conducting tests in Chapter 4, we will need to estimate the standard deviation of 􏱬ˆj, which is just the square root of the variance: sd(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 􏱧/[SSTj(1 􏱦 R2j )]1/2. Since 􏱧 is unknown, we replace it with its estimator, 􏱧ˆ. This gives us the standard error se(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 􏱧ˆ/[SSTj(1 􏱦 R2j )]1/2. [3.58] Just as the OLS estimates can be obtained for any given sample, so can the standard errors. Since se(􏱬ˆj) depends on 􏱧ˆ, the standard error has a sampling distribution, which will play a role in Chapter 4. We should emphasize one thing about standard errors. Because (3.58) is obtained directly from the variance formula in (3.51), and because (3.51) relies on the homoske- dasticity Assumption MLR.5, it follows that the standard error formula in (3.58) is not a valid estimator of sd(􏱬ˆj) if the errors exhibit heteroskedasticity. Thus, while the presence of heteroskedasticity does not cause bias in the 􏱬ˆj, it does lead to bias in the usual formula for Var(􏱬ˆj), which then invalidates the standard errors. This is important because any re- gression package computes (3.58) as the default standard error for each coefficient (with a somewhat different representation for the intercept). If we suspect heteroskedasticity, then the “usual” OLS standard errors are invalid, and some corrective action should be taken. We will see in Chapter 8 what methods are available for dealing with heteroskedasticity. For some purposes it is helpful to write the total sum of squares is divided by n rather than n − 1. The importance of equation (3.59) is that it shows how the sample size, n, directly affects the standard errors. The other three terms in the formula—􏱧ˆ, sd(xj), and R2j —will change with different samples, but as se(􏱬ˆ ) 􏱪 _______􏱧ˆ_______ . j __ [3.59] √nsd(xj)√1 􏱦 R2j ________________ in which we take sd(xj) 􏱪 √n􏱦1∑ n (x 􏱦 _x )2 to be the sample standard deviation where i􏱪1 ij j n gets large they settle down to constants. Therefore, we can see from equation (3.59) that __ the standard errors shrink to zero at the rate 1/√n. This formula demonstrates the value of getting more data: the precision of the 􏱬ˆj increases as n increases. (By contrast, recall that unbiasedness holds for any sample size subject to being able to compute the estimators.) We will talk more about large sample properties of OLS in Chapter 5. 3.5 Efficiency of OLS: The Gauss-Markov Theorem In this section, we state and discuss the important Gauss-Markov Theorem, which justifies the use of the OLS method rather than using a variety of competing estimators. We know one justification for OLS already: under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4, OLS is unbiased. However, there are many unbiased estimators of the 􏱬j under these assumptions (for example, see Problem 13). Might there be other unbiased estimators with variances smaller than the OLS estimators? If we limit the class of competing estimators appropriately, then we can show that OLS is best within this class. Specifically, we will argue that, under Assumptions MLR.1 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 102 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data through MLR.5, the OLS estimator ˆ􏱬j for 􏱬j is the best linear unbiased estimator (BLUE). To state the theorem, we need to understand each component of the acronym “BLUE.” First, we know what an estimator is: it is a rule that can be applied to any sample of data to produce an estimate. We also know what an unbiased estimator is: in the current context, an estimator, say, 􏱬 ̃j, of 􏱬j is an unbiased estimator of 􏱬j if E(􏱬 ̃j) 􏱪 􏱬j for any 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k. ̃ What about the meaning of the term “linear”? In the current context, an estimator 􏱬j of 􏱬j is linear if, and only if, it can be expressed as a linear function of the data on the de- pendent variable: ̃ ∑n 􏱬j 􏱪 wijyi, [3.60] i􏱪1 where each wij can be a function of the sample values of all the independent variables. The OLS estimators are linear, as can be seen from equation (3.22). Finally, how do we define “best”? For the current theorem, best is defined as having Now, let 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, ..., 􏱬ˆk denote the OLS estimators in model (3.31) under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5. The Gauss-Markov Theorem says that, for any estimator 􏱬 ̃j that is linear and unbiased, Var(􏱬ˆj) 􏰯 Var(􏱬 ̃j), and the inequality is usually strict. In other words, in the class of linear unbiased estimators, OLS has the smallest variance (under the five Gauss-Markov assumptions). Actually, the theorem says more than this. If we want to estimate any linear function of the 􏱬j, then the corresponding linear combination of the OLS estimators achieves the smallest variance among all linear unbiased estimators. We conclude with a theorem, which is proven in Appendix 3A. It is because of this theorem that Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5 are known as the Gauss-Markov assumptions (for cross-sectional analysis). The importance of the Gauss-Markov Theorem is that, when the standard set of assumptions holds, we need not look for alternative unbiased estimators of the form in (3.60): none will be better than OLS. Equivalently, if we are presented with an estimator that is both linear and unbiased, then we know that the variance of this estimator is at least as large as the OLS variance; no additional calculation is needed to show this. For our purposes, Theorem 3.4 justifies the use of OLS to estimate multiple regres- sion models. If any of the Gauss-Markov assumptions fail, then this theorem no longer holds. We already know that failure of the zero conditional mean assumption (Assumption MLR.4) causes OLS to be biased, so Theorem 3.4 also fails. We also know that heteroske- dasticity (failure of Assumption MLR.5) does not cause OLS to be biased. However, OLS no longer has the smallest variance among linear unbiased estimators in the presence of heteroskedasticity. In Chapter 8, we analyze an estimator that improves upon OLS when we know the brand of heteroskedasticity. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the smallest variance. Given two unbiased estimators, it is logical to prefer the one with the smallest variance (see Appendix C). THEOREM 3.4 GAUSS-MARKOV THEOREM Under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5, ˆ􏱬0, ˆ􏱬1, ..., ˆ􏱬k are the best linear unbiased estimators (BLUEs) of 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k, respectively. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 103 3.6 Some Comments on the Language of Multiple Regression Analysis It is common for beginners, and not unheard of for experienced empirical researchers, to report that they “estimated an OLS model.” While we can usually figure out what some- one means by this statement, it is important to understand that it is wrong—on more than just an aesthetic level—and reflects a misunderstanding about the components of a mul- tiple regression analysis. The first thing to remember is that ordinary least squares (OLS) is an estima- tion method, not a model. A model describes an underlying population and depends on unknown parameters. The linear model that we have been studying in this chapter can be written—in the population—as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, (3.61) where the parameters are the 􏱬j. Importantly, we can talk about the meaning of the 􏱬j without ever looking at data. It is true we cannot hope to learn much about the 􏱬j without data, but the interpretation of the 􏱬j is obtained from the linear model in equation (3.61). Once we have a sample of data we can estimate the parameters. While it is true that we have so far only discussed OLS as a possibility, there are actually many more ways to use the data than we can even list. We have focused on OLS due to its widespread use, which is justified by using the statistical considerations we covered previously in this chapter. But the various justifications for OLS rely on the assumptions we have made (MLR.1 through MLR.5). As we will see in later chapters, under different assumptions different estimation methods are preferred—even though our model can still be represented by equation (3.61). Just a few examples include weighted least squares in Chapter 8, least absolute deviations in Chapter 9, and instrumental variables in Chapter 15. One might argue that the discussion here is overlay pedantic, and that the phrase “estimating an OLS model” should be taken as a useful shorthand for “I estimated a linear model by OLS.” This stance has some merit, but we must remember that we have studied the properties of the OLS estimators under different assumptions. For example, we know OLS is unbiased under the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions, but it has no special ef- ficiency properties without Assumption MLR.5. We have also seen, through the study of the omitted variables problem, that OLS is biased if we do not have Assumption MLR.4. The problem with using imprecise language is that it leads to vagueness on the most im- portant considerations: What assumptions are being made on the underlying linear model? The issue of the assumptions we are using is conceptually different from the estimator we wind up applying. Ideally, one writes down an equation like (3.61), with variable names that are easy to decipher, such as math4 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1classize4 􏱕 􏱬2math3 􏱕 􏱬3log(income) 􏱕 􏱬4motheduc 􏱕 􏱬5 fatheduc 􏱕 u (3.62) if we are trying to explain outcomes on a fourth-grade math test. Then, in the context of equation (3.62), one includes a discussion of whether it is reasonable to maintain Assump- tion MLR.4, focusing on the factors that might still be in u and whether more compli- cated functional relationships are needed (a topic we study in detail in Chapter 6). Next, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 104 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data one describes the data source (which ideally is obtained via random sampling) as well as the OLS estimates obtained from the sample. A proper way to introduce a discussion of the estimates is to say “I estimated equation (3.62) by ordinary least squares. Under the assumption that no important variables have been omitted from the equation, and assum- ing random sampling, the OLS estimator of the class size effect, 􏱬1, is unbiased. If the error term u has constant variance, the OLS estimator is actually best linear unbiased.” As we will see in Chapters 4 and 5, we can often say even more about OLS. Of course, one might want to admit that while controlling for third-grade math score, family income, and parents’ education might account for important differences across students, it might not be enough—for example, u can include motivation of the student or parents—in which case OLS might be biased. A more subtle reason for being careful in distinguishing between an underlying population model and an estimation method used to estimate a model is that estimation methods such as OLS can be used as essentially an exercise in curve fitting or prediction, without explicitly worrying about an underlying model and the usual statistical properties of unbiasedness and efficiency. For example, we might just want to use OLS to estimate a line that allows us to predict future college GPA for a set of high school students with given characteristics. Summary 1. The multiple regression model allows us to effectively hold other factors fixed while examining the effects of a particular independent variable on the dependent variable. It explicitly allows the independent variables to be correlated. 2. Although the model is linear in its parameters, it can be used to model nonlinear relation- ships by appropriately choosing the dependent and independent variables. 3. The method of ordinary least squares is easily applied to estimate the multiple regression model. Each slope estimate measures the partial effect of the corresponding independent variable on the dependent variable, holding all other independent variables fixed. 4. R2 is the proportion of the sample variation in the dependent variable explained by the independent variables, and it serves as a goodness-of-fit measure. It is important not to put too much weight on the value of R2 when evaluating econometric models. 5. Under the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions (MLR.1 through MLR.4), the OLS esti- mators are unbiased. This implies that including an irrelevant variable in a model has no effect on the unbiasedness of the intercept and other slope estimators. On the other hand, omitting a relevant variable causes OLS to be biased. In many circumstances, the direction of the bias can be determined. 6. UnderthefiveGauss-Markovassumptions,thevarianceofanOLSslopeestimatorisgiven by Var(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 􏱧2/[SSTj(1 􏱦 R2j )]. As the error variance 􏱧2 increases, so does Var(􏱬ˆj), while Var(􏱬ˆj)decreasesasthesamplevariationinxj,SSTj,increases.ThetermR2j measuresthe amount of collinearity between xj and the other explanatory variables. As R2j approaches one, Var(􏱬ˆj) is unbounded. 7. Adding an irrelevant variable to an equation generally increases the variances of the remaining OLS estimators because of multicollinearity. 8. Under the Gauss-Markov assumptions (MLR.1 through MLR.5), the OLS estimators are the best linear unbiased estimators (BLUEs). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 105 THE GAUSS-MARKOV ASSUMPTIONS The following is a summary of the five Gauss-Markov assumptions that we used in this chap- ter. Remember, the first four were used to establish unbiasedness of OLS, whereas the fifth was added to derive the usual variance formulas and to conclude that OLS is best linear unbiased. Assumption MLR.1 (Linear in Parameters) The model in the population can be written as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, where 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k are the unknown parameters (constants) of interest and u is an unobserved random error or disturbance term. Assumption MLR.2 (Random Sampling) We have a random sample of n observations, {(xi1, xi2, ..., xik, yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}, following the population model in Assumption MLR.1. Assumption MLR.3 (No Perfect Collinearity) In the sample (and therefore in the population), none of the independent variables is constant, and there are no exact linear relationships among the independent variables. Assumption MLR.4 (Zero Conditional Mean) The error u has an expected value of zero given any values of the independent variables. In other words, E(u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 0. Assumption MLR.5 (Homoskedasticity) The error u has the same variance given any value of the explanatory variables. In other words, Key Terms Best Linear Unbiased Estimator (BLUE) Biased Toward Zero Ceteris Paribus Degrees of Freedom (df ) Disturbance Downward Bias Endogenous Explanatory Variable Error Term Excluding a Relevant Variable Exogenous Explanatory Variable Var(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱧2. Explained Sum of Squares (SSE) First Order Conditions Gauss-Markov Assumptions Gauss-Markov Theorem Inclusion of an Irrelevant Variable Intercept Micronumerosity Misspecification Analysis Multicollinearity Multiple Linear Regression Model Multiple Regression Analysis OLS Intercept Estimate OLS Regression Line OLS Slope Estimate Omitted Variable Bias Ordinary Least Squares Overspecifying the Model Partial Effect Perfect Collinearity Population Model Residual Residual Sum of Squares Sample Regression Function (SRF) Slope Parameter Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 106 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Standard Deviation of 􏱬ˆj Standard Error of 􏱬ˆj Standard Error of the Regression (SER) Problems 1 Using the data in GPA2.RAW on 4,137 college students, the following equation was esti- mated by OLS: 􏱱colgpa 􏱪 1.392 􏱦 .0135 hsperc 􏱕 .00148 sat n 􏱪 4,137, R2 􏱪 .273, where colgpa is measured on a four-point scale, hsperc is the percentile in the high school graduating class (defined so that, for example, hsperc 􏱪 5 means the top 5% of the class), and sat is the combined math and verbal scores on the student achievement test. (i) Why does it make sense for the coefficient on hsperc to be negative? (ii) What is the predicted college GPA when hsperc 􏱪 20 and sat 􏱪 1,050? (iii) Suppose that two high school graduates, A and B, graduated in the same percentile from high school, but Student A’s SAT score was 140 points higher (about one stan- dard deviation in the sample). What is the predicted difference in college GPA for these two students? Is the difference large? (iv) Holding hsperc fixed, what difference in SAT scores leads to a predicted colgpa dif- ference of .50, or one-half of a grade point? Comment on your answer. 2 The data in WAGE2.RAW on working men was used to estimate the following equation: 􏱱educ 􏱪 10.36 􏱦 .094 sibs 􏱕 .131 meduc 􏱕 .210 feduc n 􏱪 722, R2 􏱪 .214, where educ is years of schooling, sibs is number of siblings, meduc is mother’s years of schooling, and feduc is father’s years of schooling. (i) Does sibs have the expected effect? Explain. Holding meduc and feduc fixed, by how much does sibs have to increase to reduce predicted years of education by one year? (A noninteger answer is acceptable here.) (ii) Discuss the interpretation of the coefficient on meduc. (iii) Suppose that Man A has no siblings, and his mother and father each have 12 years of education. Man B has no siblings, and his mother and father each have 16 years of education. What is the predicted difference in years of education between B and A? 3 ThefollowingmodelisasimplifiedversionofthemultipleregressionmodelusedbyBid- dle and Hamermesh (1990) to study the tradeoff between time spent sleeping and working and to look at other factors affecting sleep: sleep 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1totwrk 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 u, where sleep and totwrk (total work) are measured in minutes per week and educ and age are measured in years. (See also Computer Exercise C3 in Chapter 2.) (i) If adults trade off sleep for work, what is the sign of 􏱬1? (ii) What signs do you think 􏱬2 and 􏱬3 will have? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Sum of Squared Residuals (SSR) Total Sum of Squares (SST) True Model Underspecifying the Model Upward Bias Variance Inflation Factor (VIF) CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 107 (iii) Using the data in SLEEP75.RAW, the estimated equation is 􏱱sleep 􏱪 3,638.25 􏱦 .148 totwrk 􏱦 11.13 educ 􏱕 2.20 age n 􏱪 706, R2 􏱪 .113. If someone works five more hours per week, by how many minutes is sleep predicted to fall? Is this a large tradeoff? (iv) Discuss the sign and magnitude of the estimated coefficient on educ. (v) Would you say totwrk, educ, and age explain much of the variation in sleep? What other factors might affect the time spent sleeping? Are these likely to be correlated with totwrk? 4 The median starting salary for new law school graduates is determined by log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1LSAT 􏱕 􏱬2GPA 􏱕 􏱬3log(libvol) 􏱕 􏱬4log(cost) 􏱕 􏱬5rank 􏱕 u, where LSAT is the median LSAT score for the graduating class, GPA is the median college GPA for the class, libvol is the number of volumes in the law school library, cost is the an- nual cost of attending law school, and rank is a law school ranking (with rank 􏱪 1 being the best). (i) Explain why we expect 􏱬5 􏰯 0. (ii) What signs do you expect for the other slope parameters? Justify your answers. (iii) Using the data in LAWSCH85.RAW, the estimated equation is 􏱱log(salary) 􏱪 8.34 􏱕 .0047 LSAT 􏱕 .248 GPA 􏱕 .095 log(libvol) 􏱕 .038 log(cost) 􏱦 .0033 rank n 􏱪 136, R2 􏱪 .842. What is the predicted ceteris paribus difference in salary for schools with a median GPA different by one point? (Report your answer as a percentage.) (iv) Interpret the coefficient on the variable log(libvol). (v) Would you say it is better to attend a higher ranked law school? How much is a difference in ranking of 20 worth in terms of predicted starting salary? 5 Inastudyrelatingcollegegradepointaveragetotimespentinvariousactivities,youdis- tribute a survey to several students. The students are asked how many hours they spend each week in four activities: studying, sleeping, working, and leisure. Any activity is put into one of the four categories, so that for each student, the sum of hours in the four activi- ties must be 168. (i) In the model GPA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1study 􏱕 􏱬2sleep 􏱕 􏱬3work 􏱕 􏱬4leisure 􏱕 u, does it make sense to hold sleep, work, and leisure fixed, while changing study? (ii) Explain why this model violates Assumption MLR.3. (iii) How could you reformulate the model so that its parameters have a useful interpreta- tion and it satisfies Assumption MLR.3? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 108 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 6 Consider the multiple regression model containing three independent variables, under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u. You are interested in estimating the sum of the parameters on x1 and x2; call this 􏰩1􏱪􏱬1􏱕􏱬2.ˆ ˆ ˆ (i) Show that 􏰩1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2 is an unbiased estimator of 􏰩1. (ii) Find Var(􏰩ˆ1) in terms of Var(􏱬ˆ1), Var(􏱬ˆ2), and Corr(􏱬ˆ1, 􏱬ˆ2). 7 Which of the following can cause OLS estimators to be biased? (i) Heteroskedasticity. (ii) Omitting an important variable. (iii) A sample correlation coefficient of .95 between two independent variables both in- cluded in the model. 8 Supposethataverageworkerproductivityatmanufacturingfirms(avgprod)dependson two factors, average hours of training (avgtrain) and average worker ability (avgabil ): avgprod 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1avgtrain 􏱕 􏱬2avgabil 􏱕 u. Assume that this equation satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions. If grants have been given to firms whose workers have less than average ability, so that avgtrain and avgabil are negatively correlated, what is the likely bias in 􏱬 ̃1 obtained from the simple regression of avgprod on avgtrain? 9 The following equation describes the median housing price in a community in terms of amount of pollution (nox for nitrous oxide) and the average number of rooms in houses in the community (rooms): log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(nox) 􏱕 􏱬2rooms 􏱕 u. (i) What are the probable signs of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2? What is the interpretation of 􏱬1? Explain. (ii) Why might nox [or more precisely, log(nox)] and rooms be negatively correlated? If this is the case, does the simple regression of log(price) on log(nox) produce an up- ward or a downward biased estimator of 􏱬1? (iii) Using the data in HPRICE2.RAW, the following equations were estimated: 􏱱log(price) 􏱪 11.71 􏱦 1.043 log(nox), n 􏱪 506, R2 􏱪 .264. 􏱱log(price) 􏱪 9.23 􏱦 .718 log(nox) 􏱕 .306 rooms, n 􏱪 506, R2 􏱪 .514. Is the relationship between the simple and multiple regression estimates of the elasticity of price with respect to nox what you would have predicted, given your an- swer in part? (ii) Does this mean that 􏱦.718 is definitely closer to the true elasticity than 􏱦1.043? 10 Supposethatyouareinterestedinestimatingtheceterisparibusrelationshipbetweenyand x1. For this purpose, you can collect data on two control variables, x2 and x3. (For concrete- ness, you might think of y as final exam score, x1 as class attendance, x2 as GPA up through Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 109 the previous semester, and x3 as SAT or ACT score.) Let 􏱬 ̃1 be the simple regression estimate from y on x1 and let 􏱬ˆ1 be the multiple regression estimate from y on x1, x2, x3. (i) If x1 is highly correlated with x2 and x3 in the sample, and x2 and x3 have large partial effects on y, would you expect 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬ˆ1 to be similar or very different? Explain. (ii) If x1 is almost uncorrelated with x2 and x3, but x2 and x3 are highly correlated, will 􏱬 ̃1 and 􏱬ˆ1 tend to be similar or very different? Explain. (iii) If x1 is highly correlated with x2 and x3, and x2 and x3 have small partial effects on y, would you expect se(􏱬 ̃1) or se(􏱬ˆ1) to be smaller? Explain. (iv) If x1 is almost uncorrelated with x2 and x3, x2 and x3 have large partial effects on y, and x2 and x3 are highly correlated, would you expect se(􏱬 ̃1) or se(􏱬ˆ1) to be smaller? Explain. 11 Suppose that the population model determining y is y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u, and this model satisifies Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4. However, we estimate the model that omits x3. Let 􏱬 ̃0, 􏱬 ̃1, and 􏱬 ̃2 be the OLS estimators from the regression of y on x1 and x2. Show that the expected value of 􏱬 ̃1 (given the values of the independent variables in the sample) is ∑ n rˆ x 1_____ E(􏱬 ̃ ) 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 􏱬 _i􏱪_∑ , 113n rˆ2 where the rˆi1 are the OLS residuals from the regression of x1 on x2. [Hint: The formula for 􏱬 ̃1 comes from equation (3.22). Plug yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 􏱬2xi2 􏱕 􏱬3xi3 􏱕 ui into this equa- tion. After some algebra, take the expectation treating xi3 and rˆi1 as nonrandom.] 12 Thefollowingequationrepresentstheeffectsoftaxrevenuemixonsubsequentemploy- ment growth for the population of counties in the United States: growth 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1shareP 􏱕 􏱬2shareI 􏱕 􏱬3shareS 􏱕 other factors, where growth is the percentage change in employment from 1980 to 1990, shareP is the share of property taxes in total tax revenue, shareI is the share of income tax revenues, and shareS is the share of sales tax revenues. All of these variables are measured in 1980. The omitted share, shareF, includes fees and miscellaneous taxes. By definition, the four shares add up to one. Other factors would include expenditures on education, infrastructure, and so on (all measured in 1980). (i) Why must we omit one of the tax share variables from the equation? (ii) Give a careful interpretation of 􏱬1. 13 (i) Consider the simple regression model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 u under the first four Gauss- Markov assumptions. For some function g(x), for example g(x) 􏱪 x2 or g(x) 􏱪 log(1 􏱕 x2), define zi 􏱪 g(xi). Define a slope estimator as ∑n _ 􏱆∑n _ 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪􏱵 (zi 􏱦z)yi􏱷 􏱵 (zi 􏱦z)xi􏱷. i􏱪1 Show that ̃􏱬1 is linear and unbiased. Remember, because E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0, you can treat both xi and zi as nonrandom in your derivation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i􏱪1 i1 i3 i1 i􏱪1 110 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (ii) Add the homoskedasticity assumption, MLR.5. Show that i ∑n ∑n Var(􏱬 ̃1)􏱪􏱧2􏱵 (z 􏱦_z)2􏱷􏱆􏱵 (z 􏱦_z)x􏱷2. ii i􏱪1 (iii) Show directly that, under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, Var(􏱬ˆ1) 􏰯 Var(􏱬 ̃1), where 􏱬ˆ1 is the OLS estimator. [Hint: The Cauchy-Schwartz inequality in Appendix B implies that 􏱦1∑n _ _2 􏱦1∑n _2 􏱦1∑n _2 􏱵n (zi 􏱦 z)(xi 􏱦x)􏱷 􏰯􏱵n (zi 􏱦z) 􏱷􏱵n (xi 􏱦x) 􏱷; i􏱪1 i􏱪1 notice that we can drop _x from the sample covariance.] Computer Exercises C1 A problem of interest to health officials (and others) is to determine the effects of smok- ing during pregnancy on infant health. One measure of infant health is birth weight; a birth weight that is too low can put an infant at risk for contracting various illnesses. Since factors other than cigarette smoking that affect birth weight are likely to be cor- related with smoking, we should take those factors into account. For example, higher income generally results in access to better prenatal care, as well as better nutrition for the mother. An equation that recognizes this is bwght 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1cigs 􏱕 􏱬2 faminc 􏱕 u. (i) What is the most likely sign for 􏱬2? (ii) Do you think cigs and faminc are likely to be correlated? Explain why the correla- tion might be positive or negative. (iii) Now, estimate the equation with and without faminc, using the data in BWGHT .RAW. Report the results in equation form, including the sample size and R-squared. Discuss your results, focusing on whether adding faminc substantially changes the estimated effect of cigs on bwght. C2 Use the data in HPRICE1.RAW to estimate the model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sqrft 􏱕 􏱬2bdrms 􏱕 u, where price is the house price measured in thousands of dollars. (i) Write out the results in equation form. (ii) What is the estimated increase in price for a house with one more bedroom, hold- ing square footage constant? (iii) What is the estimated increase in price for a house with an additional bedroom that is 140 square feet in size? Compare this to your answer in part (ii). (iv) What percentage of the variation in price is explained by square footage and num- ber of bedrooms? (v) The first house in the sample has sqrft 􏱪 2,438 and bdrms 􏱪 4. Find the predicted selling price for this house from the OLS regression line. (vi) Theactualsellingpriceofthefirsthouseinthesamplewas$300,000(soprice􏱪 300). Find the residual for this house. Does it suggest that the buyer underpaid or overpaid for the house? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i􏱪1 i􏱪1 CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 111 C3 The file CEOSAL2.RAW contains data on 177 chief executive officers and can be used to examine the effects of firm performance on CEO salary. (i) Estimate a model relating annual salary to firm sales and market value. Make the model of the constant elasticity variety for both independent variables. Write the results out in equation form. (ii) Add profits to the model from part (i). Why can this variable not be included in logarithmic form? Would you say that these firm performance variables explain most of the variation in CEO salaries? (iii) Add the variable ceoten to the model in part (ii). What is the estimated percentage return for another year of CEO tenure, holding other factors fixed? (iv) Find the sample correlation coefficient between the variables log(mktval) and profits. Are these variables highly correlated? What does this say about the OLS estimators? C4 Use (i) Obtain the minimum, maximum, and average values for the variables atndrte, priGPA, and ACT. (ii) Estimate the model atndrte 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1priGPA 􏱕 􏱬2 ACT 􏱕 u, and write the results in equation form. Interpret the intercept. Does it have a useful meaning? (iii) Discuss the estimated slope coefficients. Are there any surprises? (iv) What is the predicted atndrte if priGPA 􏱪 3.65 and ACT 􏱪 20? What do you make of this result? Are there any students in the sample with these values of the explanatory variables? (v) If Student A has priGPA 􏱪 3.1 and ACT 􏱪 21 and Student B has priGPA 􏱪 2.1 and ACT 􏱪 26, what is the predicted difference in their attendance rates? C5 Confirm the partialling out interpretation of the OLS estimates by explicitly doing the partialling out for Example 3.2. This first requires regressing educ on exper and tenure and saving the residuals, rˆ1. Then, regress log(wage) on rˆ1. Compare the coefficient on ˆr1 with the coefficient on educ in the regression of log(wage) on educ, exper, and tenure. the data in ATTEND.RAW for this exercise. C6 Use the data set in WAGE2.RAW for this problem. As usual, be sure all of the follow- ing regressions contain an intercept. ̃ (i) Run a simple regression of IQ on educ to obtain the slope coefficient, say, 􏱛1. (ii) Run the simple regression of log(wage) on educ, and obtain the slope coefficient, 􏱬 ̃1. (iii) Run the multiple regression of log(wage) on educ and IQ, and obtain the slope coefficients, 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2, respectively. (iv) Verify that 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2􏱛 ̃1. C7 Use the data in MEAP93.RAW to answer this question. (i) Estimate the model math10 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(expend) 􏱕 􏱬2lnchprg 􏱕 u, and report the results in the usual form, including the sample size and R-squared. Are the signs of the slope coefficients what you expected? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 112 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (ii) What do you make of the intercept you estimated in part (i)? In particular, does it make sense to set the two explanatory variables to zero? [Hint: Recall that log(1)􏱪0.] (iii) Now run the simple regression of math10 on log(expend), and compare the slope coefficient with the estimate obtained in part (i). Is the estimated spending effect now larger or smaller than in part (i)? (iv) Find the correlation between lexpend 􏱪 log(expend) and lnchprg. Does its sign make sense to you? (v) Use part (iv) to explain your findings in part (iii). C8 Use the data in DISCRIM.RAW to answer this question. These are ZIP code–level data on prices for various items at fast-food restaurants, along with characteristics of the zip code population, in New Jersey and Pennsylvania. The idea is to see whether fast-food restaurants charge higher prices in areas with a larger concentration of blacks. (i) Find the average values of prpblck and income in the sample, along with their standard deviations. What are the units of measurement of prpblck and income? (ii) Consider a model to explain the price of soda, psoda, in terms of the proportion of the population that is black and median income: psoda 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1prpblck 􏱕 􏱬2income 􏱕 u. Estimate this model by OLS and report the results in equation form, including the sample size and R-squared. (Do not use scientific notation when reporting the esti- mates.) Interpret the coefficient on prpblck. Do you think it is economically large? (iii) Compare the estimate from part (ii) with the simple regression estimate from psoda on prpblck. Is the discrimination effect larger or smaller when you control for income? (iv) A model with a constant price elasticity with respect to income may be more appropriate. Report estimates of the model log(psoda) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1prpblck 􏱕 􏱬2log(income) 􏱕 u. If prpblck increases by .20 (20 percentage points), what is the estimated percent- age change in psoda? (Hint: The answer is 2.xx, where you fill in the “xx.”) (v) Now add the variable prppov to the regression in part (iv). What happens to 􏱬ˆprpblck? (vi) Find the correlation between log(income) and prppov. Is it roughly what you expected? (vii) Evaluate the following statement: “Because log(income) and prppov are so highly correlated, they have no business being in the same regression.” C9 Use the data in CHARITY.RAW to answer the following questions: (i) Estimate the equation gift 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1mailsyear 􏱕 􏱬2 giftlast 􏱕 􏱬3 propresp 􏱕 u by OLS and report the results in the usual way, including the sample size and R-squared. How does the R-squared compare with that from the simple regression that omits giftlast and propresp? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 113 (ii) Interpret the coefficient on mailsyear. Is it bigger or smaller than the correspond- ing simple regression coefficient? (iii) Interpret the coefficient on propresp. Be careful to notice the units of measure- ment of propresp. (iv) Now add the variable avggift to the equation. What happens to the estimated effect of mailsyear? (v) In the equation from part (iv), what has happened to the coefficient on giftlast? What do you think is happening? C10 Use the data in HTV.RAW to answer this question. The data set includes information on wages, education, parents’ education, and several other variables for 1,230 working men in 1991. (i) What is the range of the educ variable in the sample? What percentage of men completed 12th grade but no higher grade? Do the men or their parents have, on average, higher levels of education? (ii) Estimate the regression model educ 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1motheduc 􏱕 􏱬2 fatheduc 􏱕 u by OLS and report the results in the usual form. How much sample variation in educ is explained by parents’ education? Interpret the coefficient on motheduc. (iii) Add the variable abil (a measure of cognitive ability) to the regression from part (ii), and report the results in equation form. Does “ability” help to explain variations in education, even after controlling for parents’ education? Explain. (iv) (Requirescalculus)Nowestimateanequationwhereabilappearsinquadraticform: educ 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1motheduc 􏱕 􏱬2 fatheduc 􏱕 􏱬3abil 􏱕 􏱬4abil2 􏱕 u. Using the estimates 􏱬ˆ3 and 􏱬ˆ4, use calculus to find the value of abil, call it abil*, where educ is minimized. (The other coefficients and values of parents’ education variables have no effect; we are holding parents’ education fixed.) Notice that abil is measured so that negative values are permissible. You might also verify that the second derivative is positive so that you do indeed have a minimum. (v) Argue that only a small fraction of men in the sample have “ability” less than the value calculated in part (iv). Why is this important? (vi) If you have access to a statistical program that includes graphing capabilities, use the estimates in part (iv) to graph the relationship beween the predicted educa- tion and abil. Let motheduc and fatheduc have their average values in the sample, 12.18 and 12.45, respectively. APPENDIX 3A 3A.1 Derivation of the First Order Conditions in Equation (3.13) The analysis is very similar to the simple regression case. We must characterize the solutions to the problem ∑n min (y 􏱦 b 􏱦 b x 􏱦 ... 􏱦 b x )2. b0, b1 ..., bk i􏱪1 i 0 1 i1 k ik Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 114 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Taking the partial derivatives with respect to each of the bj (see Appendix A), evaluating them at the solutions, and setting them equal to zero gives j 􏱪 1, ..., k. 􏱦2 x (y 􏱦 􏱬 􏱦 􏱬 x 􏱦 ... 􏱦 􏱬 x ) 􏱪 0, ij i 0 1 i1 k ik ∑ i􏱪1 n 􏱦 2 ∑ ( y 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 􏱦 􏱬ˆ x 􏱦 ... 􏱦 􏱬ˆ x ) 􏱪 0 i01i1 kik i􏱪1 nˆˆˆ for all Canceling the 􏱦2 gives the first order conditions in (3.13). 3A.2 Derivation of Equation (3.22) To derive (3.22), write xi1 in terms of its fitted value and its residual from the regression ofx1 onx2,...,xk:xi1 􏱪xˆi1 􏱕rˆi1,foralli􏱪1,...,n.Now,plugthisintothesecondequa- tion in (3.13): [3.63] ∑ i􏱪1 nˆˆˆ (xˆ 􏱕rˆ)(y􏱦􏱬􏱦􏱬x 􏱦...􏱦􏱬x)􏱪0. i1 i1i 0 1i1 kik By the definition of the OLS residual uˆi∑, since xˆi1 is just a linear function of the explana- tory variables xi2, ..., xik, it follows that n xˆi1uˆi 􏱪 0. Therefore, equation (3.63) can be expressed as i􏱪1 ∑n ˆˆ ˆ rˆi1(yi 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xi1 􏱦...􏱦􏱬kxik)􏱪0. [3.64] i􏱪1 ∑n Since the rˆi1 are the residuals from regressin∑g x1 on x2, ..., xk, i􏱪1 xij rˆi1 􏱪 0, for all j 􏱪 2, ...,∑k. Therefore, (3.64) is equivalent to n rˆ ( y 􏱦 􏱬ˆ x ) 􏱪 0. Finally, we use the i􏱪1i1i 1i1 xˆ rˆ 􏱪 0, which means that 􏱬ˆ solves fact that n i􏱪1 i1 i1 1 ∑we can write y as in (3.32); substitute 1 this for y in (3.22). Then, using n i􏱪1 ˆr 􏱪 0, [3.65] ninin i1 ∑n ˆ rˆi1(yi 􏱦 􏱬1rˆi1) 􏱪 0. i􏱪1 Now, straightforward algebra gives (3.22), provided, of course, that ∑ n rˆ2 􏱰 0; this is ensured by Assumption MLR.3. 3A.3 Proof of Theorem 3.1 We prove Theorem 3.1 for􏱬ˆ1; the proof for the other slope parameters is virtually identical. (See Appendix E for a more succinct proof using matrices.) Under Assumption MLR.3, x rˆ 􏱪 0, for all j 􏱪 2, ..., k, and x rˆ 􏱪 rˆ2 , we have i􏱪1 ij i1 i􏱪1 i1 i1 i􏱪1 i1 ∑ˆ∑∑ the OLS estimators exist, and we can write 􏱬 as in (3.22). Under Assumption MLR.1, ∑n 􏱬ˆ1􏱪􏱬1􏱕􏱵 rˆu􏱷􏱆􏱵 rˆ2􏱷. i1 i i􏱪1 ∑n i􏱪1 i1 i􏱪1 i1 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 115 Now, under Assumptions MLR.2 and MLR.4, the expected value of each ui, given all independent variables in the sample, is zero. Since the rˆi1 are just functions of the sample independent variables, it follows that E(􏱬ˆ1􏰫X)􏱪􏱬1􏱕􏱵 rˆE(u􏰫X)􏱷􏱆􏱵 rˆ2􏱷 ∑n i1 i ∑n i􏱪1 i1 i􏱪1 ∑n 􏱪􏱬1􏱕􏱵 rˆ·0􏱷􏱆􏱵 rˆ2􏱷􏱪􏱬 where X denotes the data on all independent variables and E(􏱬ˆ1􏰫X) is the expected value of 􏱬ˆ1, given xi1, ..., xik, for all i 􏱪 1, ..., n. This completes the proof. 3A.4 General Omitted Variable Bias We can derive the omitted variable bias in the general model in equation (3.31) under the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions. In particular, let the 􏱬ˆj, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k be the OLS estimators from the regression using the full set of explanatory variables. Let the 􏱬 ̃j, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k 􏱦 1 be the OLS estimators from the regression that leaves out xk. Let 􏱛 ̃j, j 􏱪 1, ..., k 􏱦 1 be the slope coefficient on xj in the auxiliary regression of xik on xi1, xi2, ... xi, k􏱦1, i 􏱪 1, ..., n. A useful fact is that 􏱬 ̃j 􏱪 􏱬ˆj 􏱕 􏱬ˆk 􏱛 ̃j. [3.66] This shows explicitly that, when we do not control for xk in the regression, the estimated partial effect of xj equals the partial effect when we include xk plus the partial effect of xk on yˆ times the partial relationship between the omitted variable, xk, and xj, j 􏱷 k. Condi- tional on the entire set of explanatory variables, X, we know that the 􏱬ˆj are all unbiased for the corresponding 􏱬j, j 􏱪 1, ..., k. Further, since 􏱛 ̃j is just a function of X, we have i1 i􏱪1 ∑n i􏱪1 i1 1, E(􏱬 ̃j|X) 􏱪 E(􏱬ˆj|X) 􏱕 E(􏱬ˆk|X)􏱛 ̃j 􏱪 􏱬 j 􏱕 􏱬 k 􏱛 ̃ j . [3.67] Equation (3.67) shows that ̃􏱬j is biased for 􏱬j unless 􏱬k 􏱪 0—in which case xk has no partial effect in the population—or 􏱛 ̃j equals zero, which means that xik and xij are par- tially uncorrelated in the sample. The key to obtaining equation (3.67) is equation (3.66). To show equation (3.66) ̃, we can use equation (3.22) a couple of times. For simplicity, we look at j 􏱪 1. Now, 􏱬1 is the slope coefficient in the simple regression of yi on r ̃i1, i 􏱪 1, ..., n, where the r ̃i1 are the OLS residuals from t ̃he r∑egression of xi1 on xi2, xi3, ..., xi,k􏱦1. Consider the numerator of the expression for 􏱬1: n r ̃ y . But for each i, we ˆˆ ˆ i􏱪1i1i ˆ ∑n r ̃i1xi1􏱷􏱕􏱬k 􏱵 r ̃i1xik􏱷. [3.68] i􏱪1 canwriteyi 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xi1 􏱕...􏱕 􏱬kxik 􏱕uˆi andpluginforyi.Now,bypropertiesofthe OLS residuals, the ̃ri1 have zero sample average and are uncorrelated with xi2, xi3, ..., xi,k􏱦1 in the sample. Similarly, the uˆi have zero sample average and zero sample correla- tion with xi1, xi2, ..., xik. It follows that the r ̃i1 and uˆi are uncorrelated in the sample (since the r ̃i1 are just linear combinations of xi1, xi2, ..., xi,k􏱦1). So ∑n ˆ ∑n r ̃i1yi 􏱪􏱬1􏱵 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 116 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Now, ∑ n r ̃ x 􏱪 ∑ n r ̃2 , which is also the denominator of 􏱬 ̃ . Therefore, we have i􏱪1 i1 i1 i􏱪1 i1 1 shown that 3A.6 Proof of Theorem 3.4 ∑n 􏱬 ̃1􏱪􏱬ˆ1􏱕􏱬ˆk􏱵 r ̃x􏱷􏱆􏱵 r ̃􏱷 2 i1, Again, we prove this for j 􏱪 1. Write ˆ􏱬1 as in equation (3.65). Now, under MLR.5, Var(ui􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2, for all i 􏱪 1, ..., n. Under random sampling, the ui are independent, even conditional on X, and the rˆi1 are nonrandom conditional on X. Therefore, 􏱪 􏱬ˆ 1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ k 􏱛 ̃ 1 . This is the relationship we wanted to show. 3A.5 Proof of Theorem 3.2 i1 ik i􏱪1 ∑n ∑n2 ˆ2􏱆2 􏱵i􏱪1 􏱷􏱵 􏱷 Var(􏱬1􏰫X)􏱪 rˆi1 Var(u􏰫X) rˆi1 i i􏱪1 nnn ∑2 2􏱆∑22 2􏱆∑2 􏱪􏱵 rˆi1􏱧􏱷􏱵 rˆi1􏱷􏱪􏱧 􏱵 rˆi1􏱷 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i1 1 2 k i􏱪1 ∑Now, since ˆr is the sum of squared residuals from regressing x on x , ..., x , ∑n i􏱪1 1 1 2 n rˆ2i1 􏱪 SST (1 􏱦 R2). This completes the proof. We show that, for any other linear unbiased estimator 􏱬 ̃1 of 􏱬1, Var(􏱬 ̃1) 􏱸 Var(􏱬ˆ1), where 􏱬ˆ1 is the OLS estimator. The focus on j 􏱪 1 is without loss of generality. For 􏱬 ̃1 as in equation (3.60), we can plug in for yi to obtain ̃∑n ∑n ∑n ∑n ∑n 􏱬1 􏱪􏱬0 wi1 􏱕􏱬1 wi1xi1 􏱕􏱬2 wi1xi2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬k wi1xik 􏱕 wi1ui. i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 Now, since the wi1 are functions of the xij, i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i1 1 ∑n ∑n ∑n i1 ik ∑n ∑n E(􏱬 ̃1􏰫X)􏱪􏱬0 w 􏱕􏱬 wx 􏱕􏱬 wx 􏱕...􏱕􏱬 wx 􏱕 wE(u􏰫X) i1 i i1i1 2 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i1 i2 k i􏱪1 􏱪􏱬0 w 􏱕􏱬 w x 􏱕􏱬 w x 􏱕...􏱕􏱬 i1 1 ∑n ∑n ∑n ∑n w x i1 ik i1i1 2 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 because E(ui􏰫X) 􏱪 0, for all i 􏱪 1, ..., n under MLR.2 and MLR.4. Therefore, for E(􏱬 ̃1􏰫X) to equal 􏱬1 for any values of the parameters, we must have i1 ∑n ∑n ∑n 􏱪 0, j 􏱪 2, ..., k. [3.69] w 􏱪 0, w x 􏱪 1, w x i1 ij i1 i1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 Now, let rˆi1 be the residuals from the regression of xi1 on xi2, ..., xik. Then, from (3.69), it follows that ∑n i1ˆ i1 i􏱪1 ∑n i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i1 i2 k i􏱪1 . i􏱪1 wr 􏱪1 [3.70] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 3 Multiple Regression Analysis: Estimation 117 because xi1 􏱪 ˆxi1 􏱕 ˆri1 and ∑ n wi1ˆxi1 􏱪 0. Now, consider the difference between i􏱪1 Var(􏱬 ̃1􏰫X) and Var(􏱬ˆ1􏰫X) under MLR.1 through MLR.5: 􏱧2 w2􏱦􏱧2􏱆􏱵 rˆ2􏱷. Because of (3.70), we can write the difference in (3.71), without 􏱧2, as But (3.72) is simply ∑n where ˆ􏰸1 􏱪 􏱵∑ n i􏱪1 wi1rˆil 􏱷􏱆􏱵∑ n i􏱪1 rˆ2i1 􏱷, as can be seen by squaring each term in (3.73), ∑n ∑n [3.71] [3.72] [3.73] i1 i􏱪1 i1 i􏱪1 ∑n ∑n 2 􏱆 ∑n w2 􏱦 w rˆ rˆ2 . i1 i􏱪1 􏱵i􏱪1 􏱷􏱵􏱷 (w 􏱦􏰸ˆrˆ)2, i1 1 i1 i􏱪1 summing, and then canceling terms. Because (3.73) is just the sum of squared residu- als from the simple regression of wi1 on rˆi1—remember that the sample average of rˆi1 is zero—(3.73) must be nonnegative. This completes the proof. i1 il i1 i􏱪1 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference This chapter continues our treatment of multiple regression analysis. We now turn to the problem of testing hypotheses about the parameters in the population regres- sion model. We begin by finding the distributions of the OLS estimators under the added assumption that the population error is normally distributed. Sections 4.2 and 4.3 cover hypothesis testing about individual parameters, while Section 4.4 discusses how to test a single hypothesis involving more than one parameter. We focus on testing multiple restrictions in Section 4.5 and pay particular attention to determining whether a group of independent variables can be omitted from a model. 4.1 Sampling Distributions of the OLS Estimators Up to this point, we have formed a set of assumptions under which OLS is unbiased; we have also derived and discussed the bias caused by omitted variables. In Section 3.4, we obtained the variances of the OLS estimators under the Gauss-Markov assumptions. In Section 3.5, we showed that this variance is smallest among linear unbiased estimators. Knowing the expected value and variance of the OLS estimators is useful for describ- ing the precision of the OLS estimators. However, in order to perform statistical inference, we need to know more than just the first two moments of 􏱬ˆj; we need to know the full sam- pling distribution of the 􏱬ˆj. Even under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the distribution of 􏱬ˆj can have virtually any shape. When we condition on the values of the independent variables in our sample, it is clear that the sampling distributions of the OLS estimators depend on the underlying dis- tribution of the errors. To make the sampling distributions of the 􏱬ˆj tractable, we now as- sume that the unobserved error is normally distributed in the population. We call this the normality assumption. Assumption MLR.6 Normality The population error u is independent of the explanatory variables x1, x2, ..., xk and is normally distributed with zero mean and variance 􏱧 2: u ~ Normal(0,􏱧2). 118 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 119 Assumption MLR.6 is much stronger than any of our previous assumptions. In fact, since u is independent of the xj under MLR.6, E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 E(u) 􏱪 0 and Var(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 Var(u) 􏱪 􏱧2. Thus, if we make Assumption MLR.6, then we are necessarily assum- ing MLR.4 and MLR.5. To emphasize that we are assuming more than before, we will refer to the full set of Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6. For cross-sectional regression applications, Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6 are called the classical linear model (CLM) assumptions. Thus, we will refer to the model under these six assumptions as the classical linear model. It is best to think of the CLM assumptions as containing all of the Gauss-Markov assumptions plus the assumption of a normally distributed error term. Under the CLM assumptions, the OLS estimators 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, ..., 􏱬ˆk have a stronger efficiency property than they would under the Gauss-Markov assumptions. It can be shown that the OLS estimators are the minimum variance unbiased estimators, which means that OLS has the smallest variance among unbiased estimators; we no longer have to restrict our comparison to estimators that are linear in the yi. This property of OLS under the CLM assumptions is discussed further in Appendix E. A succinct way to summarize the population assumptions of the CLM is y􏰫x ~ Normal(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 􏱬2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk,􏱧2), where x is again shorthand for (x1, ..., xk). Thus, conditional on x, y has a normal distribu- tion with mean linear in x1, ..., xk and a constant variance. For a single independent vari- able x, this situation is shown in Figure 4.1. F I G U R E 4 . 1 The homoskedastic normal distribution with a single explanatory variable. f(ylx) y E(y|x)5 01 1x x x1 x2 normal distributions x3 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 120 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The argument justifying the normal distribution for the errors usually runs something like this: Because u is the sum of many different unobserved factors affecting y, we can invoke the central limit theorem (see Appendix C) to conclude that u has an approximate normal distribution. This argument has some merit, but it is not without weaknesses. First, the factors in u can have very different distributions in the population (for example, ability and quality of schooling in the error in a wage equation). Although the central limit theo- rem (CLT) can still hold in such cases, the normal approximation can be poor depending on how many factors appear in u and how different their distributions are. A more serious problem with the CLT argument is that it assumes that all unob- served factors affect y in a separate, additive fashion. Nothing guarantees that this is so. If u is a complicated function of the unobserved factors, then the CLT argument does not really apply. In any application, whether normality of u can be assumed is really an empirical matter. For example, there is no theorem that says wage conditional on educ, exper, and tenure is normally distributed. If anything, simple reasoning suggests that the op- posite is true: Since wage can never be less than zero, it cannot, strictly speaking, have a normal distribution. Further, because there are minimum wage laws, some fraction of the population earns exactly the minimum wage, which also violates the normality as- sumption. Nevertheless, as a practical matter, we can ask whether the conditional wage distribution is “close” to being normal. Past empirical evidence suggests that normality is not a good assumption for wages. Often, using a transformation, especially taking the log, yields a distribution that is closer to normal. For example, something like log(price) tends to have a distribu- tion that looks more normal than the distribution of price. Again, this is an empirical issue. We will discuss the consequences of nonnormality for statistical inference in Chapter 5. There are some examples where MLR.6 is clearly false. Whenever y takes on just a few values it cannot have anything close to a normal distribution. The dependent variable in Example 3.5 provides a good example. The variable narr86, the number of times a young man was arrested in 1986, takes on a small range of integer values and is zero for most men. Thus, narr86 is far from being normally distributed. What can be done in these cases? As we will see in Chapter 5—and this is important—nonnormality of the errors is not a serious problem with large sample sizes. For now, we just make the normality assumption. Normality of the error term translates into normal sampling distributions of the OLS estimators: THEOREM 4.1 NORMAL SAMPLING DISTRIBUTIONS Under the CLM assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6, conditional on the sample values of the independent variables, 􏱬ˆj ~ Normal[􏱬j,Var(􏱬ˆj)], [4.1] where Var(􏱬ˆj) was given in Chapter 3 [equation (3.51)]. Therefore, (􏱬ˆj – 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬ˆj) ~ Normal(0,1). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 121 The proof of (4.1) is not that difficult, given the properties of n∑ormally distributed random variablesinAppendixB.Each􏱬ˆj canbewrittenas􏱬ˆj 􏱪􏱬j 􏱕 n w u,wherew 􏱪rˆ / iji ijij residual from the regression of the xj on all the other independent variables, th i􏱪1 SSRj, rˆij is the i and SSRj is the sum of squared residuals from this regression [see equation (3.62)]. Since the wij depend only on the independent vari- ables, they can be treated as nonrandom. Thus, 􏱬ˆj is just a linear combination of the errors in the sample, {ui: i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}. Under Assumption MLR.6 (and the ran- dom sampling Assumption MLR.2), the errors are independent, identically dis- tributed Normal(0,􏱧2) random variables. An important fact about independent nor- mal random variables is that a linear combination of such random variables is normally dis- tributed (see Appendix B). This basically completes the proof. In Section 3.3, we showed that E(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 􏱬j, and we derived Var(􏱬ˆj) in Section 3.4; there is no need to re-derive these facts. The second part of this theorem follows immediately from the fact that when we stan- dardize a normal random variable by subtracting off its mean and dividing by its standard deviation, we end up with a standard normal random variable. The conclusions of Theorem 4.1 can be strengthened. In addition to (4.1), any linear combination of the 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, ..., 􏱬ˆk is also normally distributed, and any subset of the 􏱬ˆj has a joint normal distribution. These facts underlie the testing results in the remainder of this chapter. In Chapter 5, we will show that the normality of the OLS estimators is still approximately true in large samples even without normality of the errors. 4.2 Testing Hypotheses about a Single Population Parameter: The t Test This section covers the very important topic of testing hypotheses about any single param- eter in the population regression function. The population model can be written as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, [4.2] and we assume that it satisfies the CLM assumptions. We know that OLS produces unbiased estimators of the 􏱬j . In this section, we study how to test hypotheses about a particular 􏱬j . For a full understanding of hypothesis testing, one must remember that the 􏱬j are unknown features of the population, and we will never know them with certainty. Nevertheless, we can hypothesize about the value of 􏱬j and then use statistical inference to test our hypothesis. In order to construct hypotheses tests, we need the following result: EXPLORING FURTHER 4.1 Suppose that u is independent of the expla- natory variables, and it takes on the values 􏱦2, 􏱦1, 0, 1, and 2 with equal probability of 1/5. Does this violate the Gauss-Markov assumptions? Does this violate the CLM assumptions? THEOREM 4.2 t DISTRIBUTION FOR THE STANDARDIZED ESTIMATORS Under the CLM assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6, (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) ~ tn–k–1 􏱪 tdf, [4.3] where k 􏱕 1 is the number of unknown parameters in the population model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk 􏱕 u (k slope parameters and the intercept 􏱬0) and n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 is the degrees of freedom (df ). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 122 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data This result differs from Theorem 4.1 in some notable respects. Theorem 4.1 showed that, under the CLM assumptions, (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬ˆj) 􏰺 Normal(0,1). The t distribution in (4.3) comes from the fact that the constant 􏱧 in sd(􏱬ˆj) has been replaced with the random vari- able 􏱧ˆ. The proof that this leads to a t distribution with n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 degrees of freedom is dif- ficult and not especially instructive. Essentially, the proof shows that (4.3) can be written as the ratio of the standard normal random variable (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬ˆj) over the square root of 􏱧ˆ 2/􏱧 2. These random variables can be shown to be independent, and (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) 􏱧ˆ 2/ 􏱧 2 􏱷 􏰨2n􏱦k􏱦1. The result then follows from the definition of a t random variable (see Section B.5). Theorem 4.2 is important in that it allows us to test hypotheses involving the 􏱬j . In most applications, our primary interest lies in testing the null hypothesis H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0, [4.4] where j corresponds to any of the k independent variables. It is important to understand what (4.4) means and to be able to describe this hypothesis in simple language for a par- ticular application. Since 􏱬j measures the partial effect of xj on (the expected value of) y, after controlling for all other independent variables, (4.4) means that, once x1, x2, ..., xj􏱦1, xj􏱕1, ..., xk have been accounted for, xj has no effect on the expected value of y. We can- not state the null hypothesis as “xj does have a partial effect on y” because this is true for any value of 􏱬j other than zero. Classical testing is suited for testing simple hypotheses like (4.4). As an example, consider the wage equation log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 u. The null hypothesis H0: 􏱬2 􏱪 0 means that, once education and tenure have been accounted for, the number of years in the workforce (exper) has no effect on hourly wage. This is an economically interesting hypothesis. If it is true, it implies that a person’s work history prior to the current employment does not affect wage. If 􏱬2 􏱰 0, then prior work experi- ence contributes to productivity, and hence to wage. You probably remember from your statistics course the rudiments of hypothesis test- ing for the mean from a normal population. (This is reviewed in Appendix C.) The me- chanics of testing (4.4) in the multiple regression context are very similar. The hard part is obtaining the coefficient estimates, the standard errors, and the critical values, but most of this work is done automatically by econometrics software. Our job is to learn how regres- sion output can be used to test hypotheses of interest. The statistic we use to test (4.4) (against any alternative) is called “the” t statistic or “the” t ratio of 􏱬ˆj and is defined as t􏱬ˆj 􏱲 􏱬ˆj/se(􏱬ˆj). [4.5] We have put “the” in quotation marks because, as we will see shortly, a more general form of the t statistic is needed for testing other hypotheses about 􏱬j. For now, it is important to know that (4.5) is suitable only for testing (4.4). For particular applications, it is helpful to index t statistics using the name of the independent variable; for example, teduc would be the t statistic for 􏱬ˆeduc. ˆ ˆ The t statistic for 􏱬j is simple to compute given 􏱬j and its standard error. In fact, most regression packages do the division for you and report the t statistic along with each coefficient and its standard error. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 123 Before discussing how to use (4.5) formally to test H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0, it is useful to see why t􏱬ˆj hasfeaturesthatmakeitreasonableasateststatistictodetect􏱬j􏱻0.First,sincese(􏱬ˆj)is alwayspositive,t􏱬ˆj hasthesamesignas􏱬ˆj:if􏱬ˆjispositive,thensoist􏱬ˆj,andif􏱬ˆjisnegative, so is t􏱬ˆj. Second, for a given value of se(􏱬ˆj), a larger value of 􏱬ˆj leads to larger values of t􏱬ˆj. If 􏱬ˆj becomes more negative, so does t􏱬ˆj. Since we are testing H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0, it is only natural to look at our unbiased estima- tor of 􏱬j , 􏱬ˆ j , for guidance. In any interesting application, the point estimate 􏱬ˆ j will never exactly be zero, whether or not H0 is true. The question is: How far is 􏱬ˆj from zero? A sample value of 􏱬ˆj very far from zero provides evidence against H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0. However, we must recognize that there is a sampling error in our estimate 􏱬ˆ j , so the size of 􏱬ˆ j must be weighed against its sampling error. Since the standard error of 􏱬ˆj is an estimate of the standard deviation of 􏱬ˆj, t􏱬ˆj measures how many estimated standard deviations 􏱬ˆj is away from zero. This is precisely what we do in testing whether the mean of a population is zero, usingthestandardtstatisticfromintroductorystatistics.Valuesoft􏱬ˆj sufficientlyfarfromzerowill result in a rejection of H0. The precise rejection rule depends on the alternative hypothesis and the chosen significance level of the test. Determining a rule for rejecting (4.4) at a given significance level—that is, the probability of rejecting H0 when it is true—requires knowing the sampling distribution of t􏱬ˆj when H0 is true. From Theorem 4.2, we know this to be tn􏱦k􏱦1. This is the key theoreti- cal result needed for testing (4.4). Before proceeding, it is important to remember that we are testing hypotheses about the population parameters. We are not testing hypotheses about the estimates from a par- ticular sample. Thus, it never makes sense to state a null hypothesis as “H0: 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 0” or, even worse, as “H0: .237 􏱪 0” when the estimate of a parameter is .237 in the sample. We are testing whether the unknown population value, 􏱬1, is zero. Some treatments of regression analysis define the t statistic as the absolute value of (4.5), so that the t statistic is always positive. This practice has the drawback of making testing against one-sided alternatives clumsy. Throughout this text, the t statistic always has the same sign as the corresponding OLS coefficient estimate. Testing against One-Sided Alternatives To determine a rule for rejecting H0, we need to decide on the relevant alternative hypothesis. First, consider a one-sided alternative of the form H1: 􏱬j 􏱰 0. [4.6] When we state the alternative as in equation (4.6), we are really saying that the null hypothesis is H0: 􏱬j 􏰯 0. For example, if 􏱬j is the coefficient on education in a wage regression, we only care about detecting that 􏱬j is different from zero when 􏱬j is actually positive. You may remember from introductory statistics that the null value that is hard- est to reject in favor of (4.6) is 􏱬j 􏱪 0. In other words, if we reject the null 􏱬j 􏱪 0 then we automatically reject 􏱬j 􏱷 0. Therefore, it suffices to act as if we are testing H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬j 􏱰 0, effectively ignoring 􏱬j 􏱷 0, and that is the approach we take in this book. How should we choose a rejection rule? We must first decide on a significance level (“level” for short) or the probability of rejecting H0 when it is in fact true. For concreteness, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 124 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data suppose we have decided on a 5% significance level, as this is the most popular choice. Thus, we are willing to mistakenly reject H0 when it is true 5% of the time. Now, while t􏱬ˆj has a t distribution under H0—so that it has zero mean—under the alternative 􏱬j 􏱰 0, the ex- pectedvalueoft􏱬ˆj ispositive.Thus,wearelookingfora“sufficientlylarge”positivevalue of t􏱬ˆj in order to reject H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 in favor of H1: 􏱬j 􏱰 0. Negative values of t􏱬ˆj provide no evidence in favor of H1. The definition of “sufficiently large,” with a 5% significance level, is the 95th percen- tile in a t distribution with n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 degrees of freedom; denote this by c. In other words, the rejection rule is that H0 is rejected in favor of H1 at the 5% significance level if t􏱬ˆj 􏱰c. [4.7] By our choice of the critical value c, rejection of H0 will occur for 5% of all random samples when H0 is true. The rejection rule in (4.7) is an example of a one-tailed test. To obtain c, we only need the significance level and the degrees of freedom. For example, for a 5% level test andwithn􏱦k􏱦1􏱪28degreesoffreedom,thecriticalvalueisc􏱪1.701.Ift􏱬ˆj 􏰯1.701,then we fail to reject H0 in favor of (4.6) at the 5% level. Note that a negative value for t􏱬ˆj, no matter how large in absolute value, leads to a failure in rejecting H0 in favor of 4.6). (See Figure 4.2.) FIGURE 4.2 5% rejection rule for the alternative H1: 􏱬j 􏱆 0 with 28 df. 0 area = .05 1.701 rejection region Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 125 The same procedure can be used with other significance levels. For a 10% level test and if df 􏱪 21, the critical value is c 􏱪 1.323. For a 1% significance level and if df 􏱪 21, c 􏱪 2.518. All of these critical values are obtained directly from Table G.2. You should note a pattern in the critical values: As the significance level falls, the critical value in- creases,sothatwerequirealargerandlargervalueoft􏱬ˆj inordertorejectH0.Thus,ifH0 is rejected at, say, the 5% level, then it is automatically rejected at the 10% level as well. It makes no sense to reject the null hypothesis at, say, the 5% level and then to redo the test to determine the outcome at the 10% level. As the degrees of freedom in the t distribution get large, the t distribution approaches the standard normal distribution. For example, when n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 120, the 5% criti- cal value for the one-sided alternative (4.7) is 1.658, compared with the standard normal value of 1.645. These are close enough for practical purposes; for degrees of freedom greater than 120, one can use the standard normal critical values. EXAMPLE 4.1 HOURLY WAGE EQUATION Using the data in WAGE1.RAW gives the estimated equation 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 .284 􏱕 .092 educ 􏱕 .0041 exper 􏱕 .022 tenure (.104) (.007) (.0017) (.003) n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .316, where standard errors appear in parentheses below the estimated coefficients. We will follow this convention throughout the text. This equation can be used to test whether the return to exper, controlling for educ and tenure, is zero in the population, against the alter- native that it is positive. Write this as H0: 􏱬exper 􏱪 0 versus H1: 􏱬exper 􏱰 0. (In applications, indexing a parameter by its associated variable name is a nice way to label parameters, since the numerical indices that we use in the general model are arbitrary and can cause confusion.) Remember that 􏱬exper denotes the unknown population parameter. It is non- sense to write “H0: .0041 􏱪 0” or “H0: 􏱬ˆexper 􏱪 0.” Since we have 522 degrees of freedom, we can use the standard normal critical val- ues. The 5% critical value is 1.645, and the 1% critical value is 2.326. The t statistic for 􏱬ˆexper is texper 􏱪 .0041/.0017 􏱿 2.41, and so 􏱬ˆexper, or exper, is statistically significant even at the 1% level. We also say that “􏱬ˆexper is statistically greater than zero at the 1% significance level.” The estimated return for another year of experience, holding tenure and education fixed, is not especially large. For example, adding three more years increases log(wage) by 3(.0041) 􏱪 .0123, so wage is only about 1.2% higher. Nevertheless, we have persua- sively shown that the partial effect of experience is positive in the population. The one-sided alternative that the parameter is less than zero, H1: 􏱬j 􏱷 0, [4.8] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 126 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data also arises in applications. The rejection rule for alternative (4.8) is just the mirror image of the previous case. Now, the critical value comes from the left tail of the t distribution. In practice, it is easiest to think of the rejection rule as t􏱬ˆj 􏱷􏱦c, [4.9] where c is the critical value for the al- ternative H1: 􏱬j 􏱰 0. For simplicity, we always assume c is positive, since this is how critical values are reported in t tables, and so the critical value 􏱦c is a negative number. For example, if the significance level is 5% and the degrees of free- dom is 18, then c 􏱪 1.734, and so H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 is rejected in favor of H1: 􏱬j 􏱷0atthe5%levelift􏱬ˆj 􏱷􏱦1.734.It is important to remember that, to reject H0 against the negative alternative (4.8), we must get a negative t statistic. A posi- tive t ratio, no matter how large, provides no evidence in favor of (4.8). The rejec- tion rule is illustrated in Figure 4.3. EXPLORING FURTHER 4.2 Let community loan approval rates be de- termined by apprate 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1percmin 􏱕 􏱬2avginc 􏱕 􏱬3avgwlth 􏱕 􏱬4avgdebt 􏱕 u, where percmin is the percentage minority in the community, avginc is average income, avgwlth is average wealth, and avgdebt is some measure of average debt obligations. How do you state the null hypothesis that there is no difference in loan rates across neighborhoods due to racial and ethnic composition, when average income, average wealth, and average debt have been con- trolled for? How do you state the alternative that there is discrimination against minorities in loan approval rates? FIGURE 4.3 5% rejection rule for the alternative H1: 􏱬j 􏱼 0 with 18 df. area = .05 rejection region 0 –1.734 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 127 EXAMPLE 4.2 STUDENT PERFORMANCE AND SCHOOL SIZE There is much interest in the effect of school size on student performance. (See, for ex- ample, The New York Times Magazine, 5/28/95.) One claim is that, everything else being equal, students at smaller schools fare better than those at larger schools. This hypothesis is assumed to be true even after accounting for differences in class sizes across schools. The file MEAP93.RAW contains data on 408 high schools in Michigan for the year 1993. We can use these data to test the null hypothesis that school size has no effect on standardized test scores against the alternative that size has a negative effect. Performance is measured by the percentage of students receiving a passing score on the Michigan Educa- tional Assessment Program (MEAP) standardized tenth-grade math test (math10). School size is measured by student enrollment (enroll). The null hypothesis is H0: 􏱬enroll 􏱪 0, and the alternative is H1: 􏱬enroll 􏱷 0. For now, we will control for two other factors, average annual teacher compensation (totcomp) and the number of staff per one thousand students (staff ). Teacher compensation is a measure of teacher quality, and staff size is a rough measure of how much attention students receive. The estimated equation, with standard errors in parentheses, is 􏱾math10 􏱪 2.274 􏱕 .00046 totcomp 􏱕 .048 staff 􏱦 .00020 enroll (6.113) (.00010) (.040) (.00022) n 􏱪 408, R2 􏱪 .0541. The coefficient on enroll, 􏱦.00020, is in accordance with the conjecture that larger schools hamper performance: higher enrollment leads to a lower percentage of students with a passing tenth-grade math score. (The coefficients on totcomp and staff also have the signs we expect.) The fact that enroll has an estimated coefficient different from zero could just be due to sampling error; to be convinced of an effect, we need to conduct a t test. Since n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 408 􏱦 4 􏱪 404, we use the standard normal critical value. At the 5% level, the critical value is 􏱦1.65; the t statistic on enroll must be less than 􏱦1.65 to reject H0 at the 5% level. The t statistic on enroll is 􏱦.00020/.00022 􏱿 􏱦.91, which is larger than 􏱦1.65: we fail to reject H0 in favor of H1 at the 5% level. In fact, the 15% critical value is 􏱦1.04, and since 􏱦.91 􏱰 􏱦1.04, we fail to reject H0 even at the 15% level. We conclude that enroll is not statistically significant at the 15% level. The variable totcomp is statistically significant even at the 1% significance level because its t statistic is 4.6. On the other hand, the t statistic for staff is 1.2, and so we cannot reject H0: 􏱬staff 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬staff 􏱰 0 even at the 10% significance level. (The critical value is c 􏱪 1.28 from the standard normal distribution.) To illustrate how changing functional form can affect our conclusions, we also esti- mate the model with all independent variables in logarithmic form. This allows, for exam- ple, the school size effect to diminish as school size increases. The estimated equation is n 􏱪 408, R2 􏱪 .0654. The t statistic on log(enroll) is about 􏱦1.87; since this is below the 5% critical value 􏱦1.65, we reject H0: 􏱬log(enroll) 􏱪 0 in favor of H1: 􏱬log(enroll) 􏱷 0 at the 5% level. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 math10 􏱪 􏱦207.66 􏱕 21.16 log(totcomp) 􏱕 3.98 log(staff ) 􏱦 1.29 log(enroll) (48.70) (4.06) (4.19) (0.69) 128 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data In Chapter 2, we encountered a model where the dependent variable appeared in its original form (called level form), while the independent variable appeared in log form (called level-log model). The interpretation of the parameters is the same in the multiple regression context, except, of course, that we can give the parameters a ceteris paribus interpretation. Holding totcomp and staff fixed, we have 􏰧􏱾math10 􏱪 􏱦1.29[􏰧log(enroll)], so that 􏰧􏱾math10 􏱿 􏱦(1.29/100)(%􏰧enroll) 􏱴 􏱦.013(%􏰧enroll). Once again, we have used the fact that the change in log(enroll), when multiplied by 100, is approximately the percentage change in enroll. Thus, if enrollment is 10% higher at a school, 􏱾math10 is predicted to be .013(10) 􏱪 0.13 percentage points lower (math10 is measured as a percentage). Which model do we prefer: the one using the level of enroll or the one using log(enroll )? In the level-level model, enrollment does not have a statistically significant effect, but in the level-log model it does. This translates into a higher R-squared for the level-log model, which means we explain more of the variation in math10 by using enroll in logarithmic form (6.5% to 5.4%). The level-log model is preferred because it more closely captures the relationship between math10 and enroll. We will say more about us- ing R-squared to choose functional form in Chapter 6. Two-Sided Alternatives In applications, it is common to test the null hypothesis H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 against a two-sided alternative; that is, H1: 􏱬j 􏱻 0. [4.10] Under this alternative, xj has a ceteris paribus effect on y without specifying whether the effect is positive or negative. This is the relevant alternative when the sign of 􏱬j is not well determined by theory (or common sense). Even when we know whether 􏱬j is positive or negative under the alternative, a two-sided test is often prudent. At a minimum, using a two-sided alternative prevents us from looking at the estimated equation and then basing the alternative on whether 􏱬ˆj is positive or negative. Using the regression estimates to help us formulate the null or alternative hypotheses is not allowed because classical statisti- cal inference presumes that we state the null and alternative about the population before looking at the data. For example, we should not first estimate the equation relating math performance to enrollment, note that the estimated effect is negative, and then decide the relevant alternative is H1: 􏱬enroll 􏱷 0. When the alternative is two-sided, we are interested in the absolute value of the t sta- tistic. The rejection rule for H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 against (4.10) is 􏰫t􏱬ˆj􏰫 􏱰 c, [4.11] where 􏰫􏱳􏰫 denotes absolute value and c is an appropriately chosen critical value. To find c, we again specify a significance level, say 5%. For a two-tailed test, c is chosen to make the area in each tail of the t distribution equal 2.5%. In other words, c is the 97.5th percen- tileinthetdistributionwithn􏱦k􏱦1degreesoffreedom.Whenn􏱦k􏱦1􏱪25,the5% critical value for a two-sided test is c 􏱪 2.060. Figure 4.4 provides an illustration of this distribution. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 129 FIGURE 4.4 5% rejection rule for the alternative H1: 􏱬j 􏲀 0 with 25 df. area = .025 rejection –2.06 region 0 area = .025 rejection region 2.06 When a specific alternative is not stated, it is usually considered to be two-sided. In the remainder of this text, the default will be a two-sided alternative, and 5% will be the default significance level. When carrying out empirical econometric analysis, it is always a good idea to be explicit about the alternative and the significance level. If H0 is rejected in favor of (4.10) at the 5% level, we usually say that “xj is statistically significant, or statistically different from zero, at the 5% level.” If H0 is not rejected, we say that “xj is statistically insignificant at the 5% level.” EXAMPLE 4.3 DETERMINANTS OF COLLEGE GPA We use GPA1.RAW to estimate a model explaining college GPA (colGPA), with the aver- age number of lectures missed per week (skipped) as an additional explanatory variable. The estimated model is n 􏱪 141, R2 􏱪 .234. We can easily compute t statistics to see which variables are statistically significant, using a two-sided alternative in each case. The 5% critical value is about 1.96, since the degrees Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 colGPA 􏱪 1.39 􏱕 .412 hsGPA 􏱕 .015 ACT 􏱦 .083 skipped (.33) (.094) (.011) (.026) © Cengage Learning, 2013 130 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data of freedom (141 􏱦 4 􏱪 137) is large enough to use the standard normal approximation. The 1% critical value is about 2.58. The t statistic on hsGPA is 4.38, which is significant at very small significance lev- els. Thus, we say that “hsGPA is statistically significant at any conventional significance level.” The t statistic on ACT is 1.36, which is not statistically significant at the 10% level against a two-sided alternative. The coefficient on ACT is also practically small: a 10- point increase in ACT, which is large, is predicted to increase colGPA by only .15 points. Thus, the variable ACT is practically, as well as statistically, insignificant. The coefficient on skipped has a t statistic of 􏱦.083/.026 􏱪 􏱦3.19, so skipped is sta- tistically significant at the 1% significance level (3.19 􏱰 2.58). This coefficient means that another lecture missed per week lowers predicted colGPA by about .083. Thus, holding hsGPA and ACT fixed, the predicted difference in colGPA between a student who misses no lectures per week and a student who misses five lectures per week is about .42. Re- member that this says nothing about specific students; rather, .42 is the estimated average across a subpopulation of students. In this example, for each variable in the model, we could argue that a one-sided alternative is appropriate. The variables hsGPA and skipped are very significant us- ing a two-tailed test and have the signs that we expect, so there is no reason to do a one-tailed test. On the other hand, against a one-sided alternative (􏱬3 􏱰 0), ACT is significant at the 10% level but not at the 5% level. This does not change the fact that the coefficient on ACT is pretty small. Testing Other Hypotheses about 􏱬j Although H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 is the most common hypothesis, we sometimes want to test whether 􏱬j is equal to some other given constant. Two common examples are 􏱬j 􏱪 1 and 􏱬j 􏱪 􏱦1. Generally, if the null is stated as H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 aj, [4.12] where aj is our hypothesized value of 􏱬j, then the appropriate t statistic is t 􏱪 (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 aj)􏱆se(􏱬ˆj). As before, t measures how many estimated standard deviations ˆ􏱬j is away from the hypothesized value of 􏱬j. The general t statistic is usefully written as (estimate 􏱦 hypothesized value) t 􏱪 ___________________________ . [4.13] standard error Under (4.12), this t statistic is distributed as tn􏱦k􏱦1 from Theorem 4.2. The usual t statistic is obtained when aj 􏱪 0. We can use the general t statistic to test against one-sided or two-sided alternatives. For example, if the null and alternative hypotheses are H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 1 and H1: 􏱬j 􏱰 1, then we find the critical value for a one-sided alternative exactly as before: the difference is in how we compute the t statistic, not in how we obtain the appropriate c. We reject H0 in favor of H1 if t 􏱰 c. In this case, we would say that “􏱬ˆj is statistically greater than one” at the appropriate significance level. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 131 EXAMPLE 4.4 CAMPUS CRIME AND ENROLLMENT Consider a simple model relating the annual number of crimes on college campuses (crime) to student enrollment (enroll): log(crime) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(enroll) 􏱕 u. This is a constant elasticity model, where 􏱬1 is the elasticity of crime with respect to en- rollment. It is not much use to test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0, as we expect the total number of crimes to increase as the size of the campus increases. A more interesting hypothesis to test would be that the elasticity of crime with respect to enrollment is one: H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 1. This means that a 1% increase in enrollment leads to, on average, a 1% increase in crime. A notewor- thy alternative is H1: 􏱬1 􏱰 1, which implies that a 1% increase in enrollment increases campus crime by more than 1%. If 􏱬1 􏱰 1, then, in a relative sense—not just an absolute sense—crime is more of a problem on larger campuses. One way to see this is to take the exponential of the equation: crime 􏱪 exp(􏱬0)enroll􏱬1exp(u). (See Appendix A for properties of the natural logarithm and exponential functions.) For 􏱬0 􏱪 0 and u 􏱪 0, this equation is graphed in Figure 4.5 for 􏱬1 􏱷 1, 􏱬1 􏱪 1, and 􏱬1 􏱰 1. F I G U R E 4 . 5 Graph of crime 􏱪 enroll 􏱬1 for 􏱬1 􏱼 1, 􏱬1 􏱪 1, and 􏱬1 􏱆 1. crime 1 > 1
1 =1
1 <1 0 0 enroll Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 132 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data We test 􏱬1 􏱪 1 against 􏱬1 􏱰 1 using data on 97 colleges and universities in the United States for the year 1992, contained in the data file CAMPUS.RAW. The data come from the FBI’s Uniform Crime Reports, and the average number of campus crimes in the sam- ple is about 394, while the average enrollment is about 16,076. The estimated equation (with estimates and standard errors rounded to two decimal places) is 􏱾log(crime) 􏱪 􏱦6.63 􏱕 1.27 log(enroll ) (1.03) (0.11) [4.14] n􏱪97,R2 􏱪.585. The estimated elasticity of crime with respect to enroll, 1.27, is in the direction of the alternative 􏱬1 􏱰 1. But is there enough evidence to conclude that 􏱬1 􏱰 1? We need to be careful in testing this hypothesis, especially because the statistical output of standard regression packages is much more complex than the simplified output reported in equa- tion (4.14). Our first instinct might be to construct “the” t statistic by taking the coefficient on log(enroll) and dividing it by its standard error, which is the t statistic reported by a regression package. But this is the wrong statistic for testing H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 1. The correct t sta- tistic is obtained from (4.13): we subtract the hypothesized value, unity, from the estimate and divide the result by the standard error of 􏱬ˆ1: t 􏱪 (1.27 􏱦 1)/.11 􏱪 .27/.11 􏱴 2.45. The one-sided 5% critical value for a t distribution with 97 􏱦 2 􏱪 95 df is about 1.66 (using df􏱪120),soweclearlyreject􏱬1 􏱪1infavorof􏱬1 􏱰1atthe5%level.Infact,the1% critical value is about 2.37, and so we reject the null in favor of the alternative at even the 1% level. We should keep in mind that this analysis holds no other factors constant, so the elas- ticity of 1.27 is not necessarily a good estimate of ceteris paribus effect. It could be that larger enrollments are correlated with other factors that cause higher crime: larger schools might be located in higher crime areas. We could control for this by collecting data on crime rates in the local city. For a two-sided alternative, for example H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 􏱦1, H1: 􏱬j 􏱻 􏱦1, we still compute the t statistic as in (4.13): t 􏱪 (􏱬ˆj 􏱕 1)/se(􏱬ˆj) (notice how subtracting 􏱦1 means adding 1). The rejection rule is the usual one for a two-sided test: reject H0 if 􏰫t􏰫 􏱰 c, where c is a two- tailed critical value. If H0 is rejected, we say that “􏱬ˆj is statistically different from negative one” at the appropriate significance level. EXAMPLE 4.5 HOUSING PRICES AND AIR POLLUTION For a sample of 506 communities in the Boston area, we estimate a model relating me- dian housing price (price) in the community to various community characteristics: nox is the amount of nitrogen oxide in the air, in parts per million; dist is a weighted distance of the community from five employment centers, in miles; rooms is the average number of rooms in houses in the community; and stratio is the average student-teacher ratio of schools in the community. The population model is log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(nox) 􏱕 􏱬2log(dist) 􏱕 􏱬3rooms 􏱕 􏱬4stratio 􏱕 u. Thus, 􏱬1 is the elasticity of price with respect to nox. We wish to test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦1 against the alternative H1: 􏱬1 􏱻 􏱦1. The t statistic for doing this test is t 􏱪 (􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 1)/se(􏱬ˆ1). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 133 Using the data in HPRICE2.RAW, the estimated model is 􏱾log(price) 􏱪 11.08 􏱦.954 log(nox) 􏱦 .134 log(dist) 􏱕.255 rooms 􏱦 .052 stratio (0.32) (.117) (.043) (.019) (.006) n 􏱪 506, R2 􏱪 .581. The slope estimates all have the anticipated signs. Each coefficient is statistically different from zero at very small significance levels, including the coefficient on log(nox). But we do not want to test that 􏱬1 􏱪 0. The null hypothesis of interest is H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦1, with cor- responding t statistic (􏱦.954 􏱕 1)/.117 􏱪 .393. There is little need to look in the t table for a critical value when the t statistic is this small: the estimated elasticity is not statistically different from 􏱦1 even at very large significance levels. Controlling for the factors we have included, there is little evidence that the elasticity is different from 􏱦1. Computing p-Values for t Tests So far, we have talked about how to test hypotheses using a classical approach: after stat- ing the alternative hypothesis, we choose a significance level, which then determines a critical value. Once the critical value has been identified, the value of the t statistic is compared with the critical value, and the null is either rejected or not rejected at the given significance level. Even after deciding on the appropriate alternative, there is a component of arbitrari- ness to the classical approach, which results from having to choose a significance level ahead of time. Different researchers prefer different significance levels, depending on the particular application. There is no “correct” significance level. Committing to a significance level ahead of time can hide useful information about the outcome of a hypothesis test. For example, suppose that we wish to test the null hypothesis that a parameter is zero against a two-sided alternative, and with 40 degrees of freedom we obtain a t statistic equal to 1.85. The null hypothesis is not rejected at the 5% level, since the t statistic is less than the two-tailed critical value of c 􏱪 2.021. A researcher whose agenda is not to reject the null could simply report this outcome along with the estimate: the null hypothesis is not rejected at the 5% level. Of course, if the t statistic, or the coefficient and its standard error, are reported, then we can also determine that the null hypothesis would be rejected at the 10% level, since the 10% critical value is c 􏱪 1.684. Rather than testing at different significance levels, it is more informative to answer the following question: Given the observed value of the t statistic, what is the smallest significance level at which the null hypothesis would be rejected? This level is known as the p-value for the test (see Appendix C). In the previous example, we know the p-value is greater than .05, since the null is not rejected at the 5% level, and we know that the p-value is less than .10, since the null is rejected at the 10% level. We obtain the actual p-value by computing the probability that a t random variable, with 40 df, is larger than 1.85 in absolute value. That is, the p-value is the significance level of the test when we use the value of the test statistic, 1.85 in the above example, as the critical value for the test. This p-value is shown in Figure 4.6. Because a p-value is a probability, its value is always between zero and one. In order to compute p-values, we either need extremely detailed printed tables of the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 134 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data F I G U R E 4 . 6 Obtaining the p-value against a two-sided alternative, when t 􏱪 1.85 and df 􏱪 40. area = .9282 area = .0359 area = .0359 –1.85 0 1.85 t distribution—which is not very practical—or a computer program that computes areas under the probability density function of the t distribution. Most modern regression pack- ages have this capability. Some packages compute p-values routinely with each OLS regression, but only for certain hypotheses. If a regression package reports a p-value along with the standard OLS output, it is almost certainly the p-value for testing the null hypoth- esis H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 against the two-sided alternative. The p-value in this case is P(􏰫T􏰫 􏱰 􏰫t􏰫), [4.15] where, for clarity, we let T denote a t distributed random variable with n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 degrees of freedom and let t denote the numerical value of the test statistic. The p-value nicely summarizes the strength or weakness of the empirical evidence against the null hypothesis. Perhaps its most useful interpretation is the following: the p-value is the probability of observing a t statistic as extreme as we did if the null hypoth- esis is true. This means that small p-values are evidence against the null; large p-values provide little evidence against H0. For example, if the p-value 􏱪 .50 (reported always as a decimal, not a percentage), then we would observe a value of the t statistic as extreme as we did in 50% of all random samples when the null hypothesis is true; this is pretty weak evidence against H0. In the example with df 􏱪 40 and t 􏱪 1.85, the p-value is computed as p-value 􏱪 P(􏰫T 􏰫 􏱰 1.85) 􏱪 2P(T 􏱰 1.85) 􏱪 2(.0359) 􏱪 .0718, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 135 where P(T 􏱰 1.85) is the area to the right of 1.85 in a t distribution with 40 df. (This value was computed using the econometrics package Stata; it is not available in Table G.2.) This means that, if the null hypothesis is true, we would observe an absolute value of the t sta- tistic as large as 1.85 about 7.2 percent of the time. This provides some evidence against the null hypothesis, but we would not reject the null at the 5% significance level. The previous example illustrates that once the p-value has been computed, a classical test can be carried out at any desired level. If 􏱮 denotes the significance level of the test (in decimal form), then H0 is rejected if p-value 􏱷 􏱮; otherwise, H0 is not rejected at the 100􏱳􏱮% level. Computing p-values for one-sided alternatives is also quite simple. Suppose, for ex- ample, that we test H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬j 􏱰 0. If 􏱬ˆj 􏱷 0, then computing a p-value is not important: we know that the p-value is greater than .50, which will never cause us to reject H0 in favor of H1. If 􏱬ˆj 􏱰 0, then t 􏱰 0 and the p-value is just the probability that a t random variable with the appropriate df exceeds the value t. Some regression packages only compute p-values for two-sided alternatives. But it is simple to obtain the one-sided p-value: just divide the two-sided p-value by 2. ˆ If the alternative is H1: 􏱬j 􏱷 0, it makes sense to compute a p-value if 􏱬j 􏱷 0 (and hence t 􏱷 0): p-value 􏱪 P(T 􏱷 t) 􏱪 P(T 􏱰 􏰫t􏰫) because the t distribution is symmetric about zero. Again, this can be obtained as one-half of the p-value for the two-tailed test. Because you will quickly become familiar with the magnitudes of t statis- tics that lead to statistical significance, especially for large sample sizes, it is not always crucial to report p-values for t statistics. But it does not hurt to report them. Further, when we discuss F test- ing in Section 4.5, we will see that it is important to compute p-values, because critical values for F tests are not so easily memorized. A Reminder on the Language of Classical Hypothesis Testing When H0 is not rejected, we prefer to use the language “we fail to reject H0 at the x% level,” rather than “H0 is accepted at the x% level.” We can use Example 4.5 to illustrate why the former statement is preferred. In this example, the estimated elasticity of price with respect to nox is 􏱦.954, and the t statistic for testing H0: 􏱬nox 􏱪 􏱦1 is t 􏱪 .393; therefore, we can- not reject H0. But there are many other values for 􏱬nox (more than we can count) that cannot be rejected. For example, the t statistic for H0: 􏱬nox 􏱪 􏱦.9 is (􏱦.954 􏱕 .9)/.117 􏱪 􏱦.462, and so this null is not rejected either. Clearly 􏱬nox 􏱪 􏱦1 and 􏱬nox 􏱪 􏱦.9 cannot both be true, so it makes no sense to say that we “accept” either of these hypotheses. All we can say is that the data do not allow us to reject either of these hypotheses at the 5% significance level. Economic, or Practical, versus Statistical Significance Because we have emphasized statistical significance throughout this section, now is a good time to remember that we should pay attention to the magnitude of the coefficient estimates in addition to the size of the t statistics. The statistical significance of a variable xj is determined entirely by the size of t􏱬ˆj, whereas the economic significance or practical significance of a variable is related to the size (and sign) of 􏱬ˆj. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 4.3 Suppose you estimate a regression model and obtain 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 .56 and p-value 􏱪 .086 for testing H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱻 0. What is the p-value for testing H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱰 0? 136 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Recall that the t statistic for testing H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 is defined by dividing the estimate by itsstandarderror:t􏱬ˆj 􏱪􏱬ˆj/se(􏱬ˆj).Thus,t􏱬ˆj canindicatestatisticalsignificanceeitherbecause 􏱬ˆj is “large” or because se(􏱬ˆj) is “small.” It is important in practice to distinguish between these reasons for statistically significant t statistics. Too much focus on statistical signifi- cance can lead to the false conclusion that a variable is “important” for explaining y even though its estimated effect is modest. EXAMPLE 4.6 PARTICIPATION RATES IN 401(k) PLANS In Example 3.3, we used the data on 401(k) plans to estimate a model describing participa- tion rates in terms of the firm’s match rate and the age of the plan. We now include a mea- sure of firm size, the total number of firm employees (totemp). The estimated equation is p􏱾rate 􏱪 80.29 􏱕 5.44 mrate 􏱕 .269 age 􏱦 .00013 totemp (0.78) (0.52) (.045) (.00004) n 􏱪 1,534, R2 􏱪 .100. The smallest t statistic in absolute value is that on the variable totemp: t 􏱪 􏱦.00013/.00004 􏱪 􏱦3.25, and this is statistically significant at very small significance levels. (The two-tailed p-value for this t statistic is about .001.) Thus, all of the variables are statistically significant at rather small significance levels. How big, in a practical sense, is the coefficient on totemp? Holding mrate and age fixed, if a firm grows by 10,000 employees, the participation rate falls by 10,000(.00013) 􏱪 1.3 percentage points. This is a huge increase in number of employees with only a mod- est effect on the participation rate. Thus, although firm size does affect the participation rate, the effect is not practically very large. The previous example shows that it is especially important to interpret the magnitude of the coefficient, in addition to looking at t statistics, when working with large samples. With large sample sizes, parameters can be estimated very precisely: Standard errors are often quite small relative to the coefficient estimates, which usually results in statistical significance. Some researchers insist on using smaller significance levels as the sample size increases, partly as a way to offset the fact that standard errors are getting smaller. For example, if we feel comfortable with a 5% level when n is a few hundred, we might use the 1% level when n is a few thousand. Using a smaller significance level means that eco- nomic and statistical significance are more likely to coincide, but there are no guarantees: In the previous example, even if we use a significance level as small as .1% (one-tenth of 1%), we would still conclude that totemp is statistically significant. Most researchers are also willing to entertain larger significance levels in applica- tions with small sample sizes, reflecting the fact that it is harder to find significance with smaller sample sizes (the critical values are larger in magnitude, and the estimators are less precise). Unfortunately, whether or not this is the case can depend on the researcher’s underlying agenda. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 137 EXAMPLE 4.7 EFFECT OF JOB TRAINING ON FIRM SCRAP RATES The scrap rate for a manufacturing firm is the number of defective items—products that must be discarded—out of every 100 produced. Thus, for a given number of items produced, a decrease in the scrap rate reflects higher worker productivity. We can use the scrap rate to measure the effect of worker training on productivity. Using the data in JTRAIN.RAW, but only for the year 1987 and for nonunionized firms, we obtain the following estimated equation: 􏱾log(scrap) 􏱪 12.46 􏱦 .029 hrsemp 􏱦 .962 log(sales) 􏱕 .761 log(employ) (5.69) (.023) (.453) (.407) n 􏱪29,R2 􏱪.262. The variable hrsemp is annual hours of training per employee, sales is annual firm sales (in dollars), and employ is the number of firm employees. For 1987, the average scrap rate in the sample is about 4.6 and the average of hrsemp is about 8.9. The main variable of interest is hrsemp. One more hour of training per employee lowers log(scrap) by .029, which means the scrap rate is about 2.9% lower. Thus, if hrsemp increases by 5—each employee is trained 5 more hours per year—the scrap rate is estimated to fall by 5(2.9) 􏱪 14.5%. This seems like a reasonably large effect, but whether the additional training is worthwhile to the firm depends on the cost of training and the benefits from a lower scrap rate. We do not have the numbers needed to do a cost benefit analysis, but the estimated effect seems nontrivial. What about the statistical significance of the training variable? The t statistic on hrsemp is 􏱦.029/.023 􏱪 􏱦1.26, and now you probably recognize this as not being large enough in magnitude to conclude that hrsemp is statistically significant at the 5% level. In fact, with 29 􏱦 4 􏱪 25 degrees of freedom for the one-sided alternative, H1: 􏱬hrsemp 􏱷 0, the 5% critical value is about 􏱦1.71. Thus, using a strict 5% level test, we must conclude that hrsemp is not statistically significant, even using a one-sided alternative. Because the sample size is pretty small, we might be more liberal with the signifi- cance level. The 10% critical value is 􏱦1.32, and so hrsemp is almost significant against the one-sided alternative at the 10% level. The p-value is easily computed as P(T25 􏱷 􏱦1.26) 􏱪 .110. This may be a low enough p-value to conclude that the estimated effect of training is not just due to sampling error, but opinions would legitimately differ on whether a one-sided p-value of .11 is sufficiently small. Remember that large standard errors can also be a result of multicollinearity (high correlation among some of the independent variables), even if the sample size seems fairly large. As we discussed in Section 3.4, there is not much we can do about this problem other than to collect more data or change the scope of the analysis by dropping or com- bining certain independent variables. As in the case of a small sample size, it can be hard to precisely estimate partial effects when some of the explanatory variables are highly correlated. (Section 4.5 contains an example.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 138 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data We end this section with some guidelines for discussing the economic and statistical significance of a variable in a multiple regression model: 1. Check for statistical significance. If the variable is statistically significant, discuss the magnitude of the coefficient to get an idea of its practical or economic importance. This latter step can require some care, depending on how the independent and dependent variables appear in the equation. (In particular, what are the units of measurement? Do the variables appear in logarithmic form?) 2. If a variable is not statistically significant at the usual levels (10%, 5%, or 1%), you might still ask if the variable has the expected effect on y and whether that effect is practically large. If it is large, you should compute a p-value for the t statistic. For small sample sizes, you can sometimes make a case for p-values as large as .20 (but there are no hard rules). With large p-values, that is, small t statistics, we are treading on thin ice because the practically large estimates may be due to sampling error: A different random sample could result in a very different estimate. 3. It is common to find variables with small t statistics that have the “wrong” sign. For practical purposes, these can be ignored: we conclude that the variables are statistically insignificant. A significant variable that has the unexpected sign and a practically large effect is much more troubling and difficult to resolve. One must usually think more about the model and the nature of the data to solve such problems. Often, a counterin- tuitive, significant estimate results from the omission of a key variable or from one of the important problems we will discuss in Chapters 9 and 15. 4.3 Confidence Intervals Under the classical linear model assumptions, we can easily construct a confidence interval (CI) for the population parameter 􏱬j . Confidence intervals are also called interval estimates because they provide a range of likely values for the population parameter, and not just a point estimate.ˆ ˆ Using the fact that (􏱬j 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬j) has a t distribution with n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 degrees of free- dom [see (4.3)], simple manipulation leads to a CI for the unknown 􏱬j: a 95% confidence interval, given by 􏱬ˆj 􏲁 c􏱳se(􏱬ˆj), [4.16] where the constant c is the 97.5th percentile in a tn􏱦k􏱦1 distribution. More precisely, the lower and upper bounds of the confidence interval are given by 􏱬􏱦j 􏱲 􏱬ˆj 􏱦 c􏱳se(􏱬ˆj) and 􏱬􏰺j 􏱲 􏱬ˆj 􏱕 c􏱳se(􏱬ˆj), samples were obtained over and over again, with 􏱬􏱦j and 􏱬􏰺j computed each time, then the (unknown) population value 􏱬j would lie in the interval ( 􏱬􏱦j , 􏱬􏰺j) for 95% of the samples. Unfortunately, for the single sample that we use to construct the CI, we do not know Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. respectively. At this point, it is useful to review the meaning of a confidence interval. If random CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 139 whether 􏱬j is actually contained in the interval. We hope we have obtained a sample that is one of the 95% of all samples where the interval estimate contains 􏱬j , but we have no guarantee. Constructing a confidence interval is very simple when using current computing technology. Three quantities are needed: 􏱬ˆ j , se( 􏱬ˆ j ), and c. The coefficient estimate and its standard error are reported by any regression package. To obtain the value c, we must know the degrees of freedom, n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1, and the level of confidence—95% in this case. Then, the value for c is obtained from the tn􏱦k􏱦1 distribution. Asanexample,fordf􏱪n􏱦k􏱦1􏱪25,a95%confidenceintervalforany􏱬j is given by [􏱬ˆj 􏱦 2.06􏱳se(􏱬ˆj), 􏱬ˆj 􏱕 2.06􏱳se(􏱬ˆj)]. When n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱰 120, the tn􏱦k􏱦1 distribution is close enough to normal to use the 97.5th percentile in a standard normal distribution for constructing a 95% CI: 􏱬ˆj 􏲁 1.96􏱳se(􏱬ˆj). In fact, when n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱰 50, the value of c is so close to 2 that we can use a simple rule of thumb for a 95% confidence interval: 􏱬ˆj plus or minus two of its standard errors. For small degrees of freedom, the exact percentiles should be obtained from the t tables. It is easy to construct confidence intervals for any other level of confidence. For example, a 90% CI is obtained by choosing c to be the 95th percentile in the tn􏱦k􏱦1 distri- bution.Whendf􏱪n􏱦k􏱦1􏱪25,c􏱪1.71,andsothe90%CIis􏱬ˆj 􏲁1.71􏱳se(􏱬ˆj), which is necessarily narrower than the 95% CI. For a 99% CI, c is the 99.5th percentile in the t25 distribution. When df 􏱪 25, the 99% CI is roughly 􏱬ˆj 􏲁 2.79􏱳se(􏱬ˆj ), which is inevi- tably wider than the 95% CI. Many modern regression packages save us from doing any calculations by reporting a 95% CI along with each coefficient and its standard error. Once a confidence interval is constructed, it is easy to carry out two-tailed hypotheses tests. If the null hypothesis is H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 aj, then H0 is rejected against H1: 􏱬j 􏱻 aj at (say) the 5% significance level if, and only if, aj is not in the 95% confidence interval. EXAMPLE 4.8 MODEL OF R&D EXPENDITURES Economists studying industrial organization are interested in the relationship between firm size—often measured by annual sales—and spending on research and development (R&D). Typically, a constant elasticity model is used. One might also be interested in the ceteris paribus effect of the profit margin—that is, profits as a percentage of sales—on R&D spending. Using the data in RDCHEM.RAW on 32 U.S. firms in the chemical industry, we estimate the following equation (with standard errors in parentheses below the coefficients): The estimated elasticity of R&D spending with respect to firm sales is 1.084, so that, holding profit margin fixed, a 1% increase in sales is associated with a 1.084% increase in R&D spending. (Incidentally, R&D and sales are both measured in millions of dollars, but their units of measurement have no effect on the elasticity estimate.) We can construct a 95% confidence interval for the sales elasticity once we note that the estimated model has n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 32 􏱦 2 􏱦 1 􏱪 29 degrees of freedom. From Table G.2, we find the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 log(rd) 􏱪 􏱦4.38 􏱕 1.084 log(sales) 􏱕 .0217 profmarg (.47) (.060) (.0128) n􏱪32,R2 􏱪.918. 140 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 97.5th percentile in a t29 distribution: c 􏱪 2.045. Thus, the 95% confidence interval for 􏱬log(sales) is 1.084 􏲁 .060(2.045), or about (.961,1.21) That zero is well outside this interval is hardly surprising: we expect R&D spending to increase with firm size. More interest- ing is that unity is included in the 95% confidence interval for 􏱬log(sales), which means that we cannot reject H0: 􏱬log(sales) 􏱪 1 against H1: 􏱬log(sales) 􏱻 1 at the 5% significance level. In other words, the estimated R&D-sales elasticity is not statistically different from 1 at the 5% level. (The estimate is not practically different from 1, either.) The estimated coefficient on profmarg is also positive, and the 95% confidence interval for the population parameter, 􏱬profmarg, is .0217 􏲁 .0128(2.045), or about (􏱦.0045,.0479). In this case, zero is included in the 95% confidence interval, so we fail to reject H0: 􏱬profmarg 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬profmarg 􏱻 0 at the 5% level. Nevertheless, the t statistic is about 1.70, which gives a two-sided p-value of about .10, and so we would conclude that profmarg is statistically significant at the 10% level against the two-sided alternative, or at the 5% level against the one-sided alternative H1: 􏱬profmarg 􏱰 0. Plus, the economic size of the profit margin coefficient is not trivial: holding sales fixed, a one percentage point increase in profmarg is estimated to increase R&D spending by 100(.0217) 􏱴 2.2%. A complete anal- ysis of this example goes beyond simply stating whether a particular value, zero in this case, is or is not in the 95% confidence interval. You should remember that a confidence interval is only as good as the underlying assumptions used to construct it. If we have omitted important factors that are correlated with the explanatory variables, then the coefficient estimates are not reliable: OLS is biased. If heteroskedasticity is present—for instance, in the previous example, if the variance of log(rd) depends on any of the explanatory variables—then the standard error is not valid as an estimate of sd(􏱬ˆj) (as we discussed in Section 3.4), and the confidence interval com- puted using these standard errors will not truly be a 95% CI. We have also used the nor- mality assumption on the errors in obtaining these CIs, but, as we will see in Chapter 5, this is not as important for applications involving hundreds of observations. 4.4 Testing Hypotheses about a Single Linear Combination of the Parameters The previous two sections have shown how to use classical hypothesis testing or confidence intervals to test hypotheses about a single 􏱬j at a time. In applications, we must often test hypotheses involving more than one of the population parameters. In this section, we show how to test a single hypothesis involving more than one of the 􏱬j . Section 4.5 shows how to test multiple hypotheses. To illustrate the general approach, we will consider a simple model to compare the returns to education at junior colleges and four-year colleges; for simplicity, we refer to the latter as “universities.” [Kane and Rouse (1995) provide a detailed analysis of the returns to two- and four-year colleges.] The population includes working people with a high school degree, and the model is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1jc 􏱕 􏱬2univ 􏱕 􏱬3exper 􏱕 u, [4.17] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 141 where jc 􏱪 number of years attending a two-year college. univ 􏱪 number of years at a four-year college. exper 􏱪 months in the workforce. Note that any combination of junior college and four-year college is allowed, including jc 􏱪 0 and univ 􏱪 0. The hypothesis of interest is whether one year at a junior college is worth one year at a university: this is stated as H0:􏱬1 􏱪􏱬2. [4.18] Under H0 , another year at a junior college and another year at a university lead to the same ceteris paribus percentage increase in wage. For the most part, the alternative of interest is one-sided: a year at a junior college is worth less than a year at a university. This is stated as H1:􏱬1 􏱷􏱬2. [4.19] The hypotheses in (4.18) and (4.19) concern two parameters, 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 , a situation we have not faced yet. We cannot simply use the individual t statistics for 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 to test H0. However, conceptually, there is no difficulty in constructing a t statistic for testing (4.18). To do so, we rewrite the null and alternative as H0: 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬2 􏱪 0 and H1: 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬2 􏱷 0, res- pectively.Thetstatisticisbasedonwhethertheestimateddifference􏱬ˆ1 􏱦􏱬ˆ2 issufficiently less than zero to warrant rejecting (4.18) in favor of (4.19). To account for the sampling error in our estimators, we standardize this difference by dividing by the standard error: 􏱬ˆ 1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ 2 t 􏱪 _______________ . [4.20] Once we have the t statistic in (4.20), testing proceeds as before. We choose a significance level for the test and, based on the df, obtain a critical value. Because the alternative is of the form in (4.19), the rejection rule is of the form t 􏱷 􏱦c, where c is a positive value chosen from the appropriate t distribution. Or we compute the t statistic and then compute the p-value (see Section 4.2). The only thing that makes testing the equality of two different parameters more difficult than testing about a single 􏱬j is obtaining the standard error in the denominator of (4.20). Obtaining the numerator is trivial once we have performed the OLS regression. Using the data in TWOYEAR.RAW, which comes from Kane and Rouse (1995), we estimate equation (4.17): It is clear from (4.21) that jc and univ have both economically and statistically significant effects on wage. This is certainly of interest, but we are more concerned about testing whether the estimated difference in the coefficients is statistically significant. The differ- ence is estimated as 􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2 􏱪 􏱦.0102, so the return to a year at a junior college is about one percentage point less than a year at a university. Economically, this is not a trivial difference. The difference of 􏱦.0102 is the numerator of the t statistic in (4.20). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 se(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦􏱬ˆ2) log(wage) 􏱪 1.472 􏱕 .0667 jc 􏱕 .0769 univ 􏱕 .0049 exper (.021) (.0068) (.0023) (.0002) [4.21] n 􏱪 6,763, R2 􏱪 .222. 142 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Unfortunately, the regression results in equation (4.21) do not contain enough informa- tion to obtain the standard error of 􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2. It might be tempting to claim that se(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2) 􏱪 se(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱦 se(􏱬ˆ2), but this is not true. In fact, if we reversed the roles of 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2, we would wind up with a negative standard error of the difference using the difference in standard errors. Standard errors must always be positive because they are estimates of standard deviations. Although the standard error of the difference 􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2 certainly depends on se(􏱬ˆ1) and se(􏱬ˆ2), it does so in a somewhat complicated way. To find se(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2), we first obtain the variance of the difference. Using the results on variances in Appendix B, we have Var(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2) 􏱪 Var(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱕 Var(􏱬ˆ2) 􏱦 2 Cov(􏱬ˆ1,􏱬ˆ2). [4.22] Observe carefully how the two variances are added together, and twice the covariance is then subtracted. The standard deviation of 􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2 is just the square root of (4.22), and, since [se(􏱬ˆ1)]2 is an unbiased estimator of Var(􏱬ˆ1), and similarly for [se(􏱬ˆ2)]2, we have se(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2) 􏱪 {[se(􏱬ˆ1)]2 􏱕 [se(􏱬ˆ2)]2 􏱦 2s12}1/2, [4.23] where s12 denotes an estimate of Cov(􏱬ˆ1,􏱬ˆ2 ). We have not displayed a formula for Cov(􏱬ˆ1,􏱬ˆ2). Some regression packages have features that allow one to obtain s12, in which case one can compute the standard error in (4.23) and then the t statistic in (4.20). Appendix E shows how to use matrix algebra to obtain s12. Some of the more sophisticated econometrics programs include special commands that can be used for testing hypotheses about linear combinations. Here, we cover an approach that is simple to compute in virtually any statistical package. Rather than trying to compute se(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 􏱬ˆ2) from (4.23), it is much easier to estimate a different model that directly delivers the standard error of interest. Define a new parameter as the difference between 􏱬1 and 􏱬2: 􏰩1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬2. Then, we want to test H0: 􏰩1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏰩1 􏱷 0. [4.24] The t statistic in (4.20) in terms of 􏰩ˆ1 is just t 􏱪 􏰩ˆ1/se(􏰩ˆ1). The challenge is finding se(􏰩ˆ1). We can do this by rewriting the model so that 􏰩1 appears directly on one of the inde- pendent variables. Because 􏰩1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬2, we can also write 􏱬1 􏱪 􏰩1 􏱕 􏱬2. Plugging this into (4.17) and rearranging gives the equation log(wage)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕(􏰩1 􏱕􏱬2)jc􏱕􏱬2univ􏱕􏱬3exper􏱕u 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏰩1 jc􏱕􏱬2(jc􏱕univ)􏱕􏱬3exper􏱕u. [4.25] The key insight is that the parameter we are interested in testing hypotheses about, 􏰩1, now multiplies the variable jc. The intercept is still 􏱬0, and exper still shows up as being multiplied by 􏱬3. More importantly, there is a new variable multiplying 􏱬2, namely jc 􏱕 univ. Thus, if we want to directly estimate 􏰩1 and obtain the standard error 􏰩ˆ1, then we must construct the new variable jc 􏱕 univ and include it in the regression model in place of univ. In this example, the new variable has a natural interpretation: it is total years of college, so define totcoll 􏱪 jc 􏱕 univ and write (4.25) as log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏰩1 jc 􏱕 􏱬2totcoll 􏱕 􏱬3exper 􏱕 u. [4.26] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 143 The parameter 􏱬1 has disappeared from the model, while 􏰩1 appears explicitly. This model is really just a different way of writing the original model. The only reason we have defined this new model is that, when we estimate it, the coefficient on jc is 􏰩ˆ1, and, more impor- tantly, se(􏰩ˆ1) is reported along with the estimate. The t statistic that we want is the one reported by any regression package on the variable jc (not the variable totcoll). When we do this with the 6,763 observations used earlier, the result is 􏱾 log(wage) 􏱪 1.472 􏱦 .0102 jc 􏱕 .0769 totcoll 􏱕 .0049 exper (.021) (.0069) (.0023) (.0002) n 􏱪 6,763, R2 􏱪 .222. [4.27] The only number in this equation that we could not get from (4.21) is the standard error for the estimate 􏱦.0102, which is .0069. The t statistic for testing (4.18) is 􏱦.0102/.0069 􏱪 􏱦1.48. Against the one-sided alternative (4.19), the p-value is about .070, so there is some, but not strong, evidence against (4.18). The intercept and slope estimate on exper, along with their standard errors, are the same as in (4.21). This fact must be true, and it provides one way of checking whether the transformed equation has been properly estimated. The coefficient on the new variable, totcoll, is the same as the coefficient on univ in (4.21), and the standard error is also the same. We know that this must happen by comparing (4.17) and (4.25). It is quite simple to compute a 95% confidence interval for 􏰩1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬2. Using the standard normal approximation, the CI is obtained as usual: 􏰩ˆ1 􏲁 1.96 se(􏰩ˆ1), which in this case leads to 􏱦.0102 􏲁 .0135. The strategy of rewriting the model so that it contains the parameter of interest works in all cases and is easy to implement. (See Computer Exercises C1 and C3 for other examples.) 4.5 Testing Multiple Linear Restrictions: The F Test The t statistic associated with any OLS coefficient can be used to test whether the cor- responding unknown parameter in the population is equal to any given constant (which is usually, but not always, zero). We have just shown how to test hypotheses about a single linear combination of the 􏱬j by rearranging the equation and running a regression using transformed variables. But so far, we have only covered hypotheses involving a single restriction. Frequently, we wish to test multiple hypotheses about the underlying param- eters 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k . We begin with the leading case of testing whether a set of independent variables has no partial effect on a dependent variable. Testing Exclusion Restrictions We already know how to test whether a particular variable has no partial effect on the dependent variable: use the t statistic. Now, we want to test whether a group of variables has no effect on the dependent variable. More precisely, the null hypothesis is that a set of variables has no effect on y, once another set of variables has been controlled. As an illustration of why testing significance of a group of variables is useful, we con- sider the following model that explains major league baseball players’ salaries: log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 years 􏱕 􏱬2gamesyr 􏱕 􏱬3bavg 􏱕 􏱬4hrunsyr 􏱕 􏱬5rbisyr 􏱕 u, [4.28] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 144 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data where salary is the 1993 total salary, years is years in the league, gamesyr is average games played per year, bavg is career batting average (for example, bavg 􏱪 250), hrunsyr is home runs per year, and rbisyr is runs batted in per year. Suppose we want to test the null hypothesis that, once years in the league and games per year have been controlled for, the statistics measuring performance—bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr—have no effect on salary. Essentially, the null hypothesis states that productivity as measured by baseball statistics has no effect on salary. In terms of the parameters of the model, the null hypothesis is stated as H0:􏱬3 􏱪0,􏱬4 􏱪0,􏱬5 􏱪0. [4.29] The null (4.29) constitutes three exclusion restrictions: If (4.29) is true, then bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr have no effect on log(salary) after years and gamesyr have been controlled for and therefore should be excluded from the model. This is an example of a set of multiple restrictions because we are putting more than one restriction on the parameters in (4.28); we will see more general examples of multiple restrictions later. A test of multiple restric- tions is called a multiple hypotheses test or a joint hypotheses test. What should be the alternative to (4.29)? If what we have in mind is that “perfor- mance statistics matter, even after controlling for years in the league and games per year,” then the appropriate alternative is simply H1: H0 is not true. [4.30] The alternative (4.30) holds if at least one of 􏱬3, 􏱬4, or 􏱬5 is different from zero. (Any or all could be different from zero.) The test we study here is constructed to detect any viola- tion of H0. It is also valid when the alternative is something like H1: 􏱬3 􏱰 0, or 􏱬4 􏱰 0, or 􏱬5 􏱰 0, but it will not be the best possible test under such alternatives. We do not have the space or statistical background necessary to cover tests that have more power under multiple one-sided alternatives. How should we proceed in testing (4.29) against (4.30)? It is tempting to test (4.29) by using the t statistics on the variables bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr to determine whether each variable is individually significant. This option is not appropriate. A particular t statistic tests a hypothesis that puts no restrictions on the other parameters. Besides, we would have three outcomes to contend with—one for each t statistic. What would constitute rejection of (4.29) at, say, the 5% level? Should all three or only one of the three t statistics be required to be significant at the 5% level? These are hard questions, and fortunately we do not have to answer them. Furthermore, using separate t statistics to test a multiple hypothesis like (4.29) can be very misleading. We need a way to test the exclusion restrictions jointly. To illustrate these issues, we estimate equation (4.28) using the data in MLB1.RAW. This gives 􏱾log(salary) 􏱪 11.19 􏱕 .0689 years 􏱕 .0126 gamesyr (0.29) (.0121) (.0026) 􏱕 .00098 bavg 􏱕 .0144 hrunsyr 􏱕 .0108 rbisyr (.00110) (.0161) (.0072) n 􏱪 353, SSR 􏱪 183.186, R2 􏱪 .6278, [4.31] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 145 where SSR is the sum of squared residuals. (We will use this later.) We have left several terms after the decimal in SSR and R-squared to facilitate future comparisons. Equation (4.31) reveals that, whereas years and gamesyr are statistically significant, none of the variables bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr has a statistically significant t statistic against a two-sided alternative, at the 5% significance level. (The t statistic on rbisyr is the closest to being significant; its two-sided p-value is .134.) Thus, based on the three t statistics, it appears that we cannot reject H0. This conclusion turns out to be wrong. To see this, we must derive a test of multiple restrictions whose distribution is known and tabulated. The sum of squared residuals now turns out to provide a very convenient basis for testing multiple hypotheses. We will also show how the R-squared can be used in the special case of testing for exclusion restrictions. Knowing the sum of squared residuals in (4.31) tells us nothing about the truth of the hypothesis in (4.29). However, the factor that will tell us something is how much the SSR increases when we drop the variables bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr from the model. Remember that, because the OLS estimates are chosen to minimize the sum of squared residuals, the SSR always increases when variables are dropped from the model; this is an algebraic fact. The question is whether this increase is large enough, relative to the SSR in the model with all of the variables, to warrant rejecting the null hypothesis. The model without the three variables in question is simply log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1years 􏱕 􏱬2gamesyr 􏱕 u. [4.32] In the context of hypothesis testing, equation (4.32) is the restricted model for testing (4.29); model (4.28) is called the unrestricted model. The restricted model always has fewer parameters than the unrestricted model. When we estimate the restricted model using the data in MLB1.RAW, we obtain 􏱾log(salary) 􏱪 11.22 􏱕 .0713 years 􏱕 .0202 gamesyr (.11) (.0125) (.0013) [4.33] n 􏱪 353, SSR 􏱪 198.311, R2 􏱪 .5971. As we surmised, the SSR from (4.33) is greater than the SSR from (4.31), and the R-squared from the restricted model is less than the R-squared from the unrestricted model. What we need to decide is whether the increase in the SSR in going from the unrestricted model to the restricted model (183.186 to 198.311) is large enough to warrant rejection of (4.29). As with all testing, the answer depends on the significance level of the test. But we cannot carry out the test at a chosen significance level until we have a statistic whose distribution is known, and can be tabulated, under H0. Thus, we need a way to combine the information in the two SSRs to obtain a test statistic with a known distribution under H0. Because it is no more difficult, we might as well derive the test for the general case. Write the unrestricted model with k independent variables as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u; [4.34] the number of parameters in the unrestricted model is k 􏱕 1. (Remember to add one for the intercept.) Suppose that we have q exclusion restrictions to test: that is, the null hypothesis states that q of the variables in (4.34) have zero coefficients. For notational simplicity, assume that it is the last q variables in the list of independent variables: xk􏱦q􏱕1, ..., xk . (The order of the variables, of course, is arbitrary and unimportant.) The null hypothesis is stated as H0: 􏱬k􏱦q􏱕1 􏱪 0, ..., 􏱬k 􏱪 0, [4.35] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 146 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data which puts q exclusion restrictions on the model (4.34). The alternative to (4.35) is simply that it is false; this means that at least one of the parameters listed in (4.35) is different from zero. When we impose the restrictions under H0, we are left with the restricted model: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬k􏱦qxk􏱦q 􏱕u. [4.36] In this subsection, we assume that both the unrestricted and restricted models contain an intercept, since that is the case most widely encountered in practice. Now, for the test statistic itself. Earlier, we suggested that looking at the relative in- crease in the SSR when moving from the unrestricted to the restricted model should be informative for testing the hypothesis (4.35). The F statistic (or F ratio) is defined by (SSRr 􏱦 SSRur)􏱚q F 􏱲 ________________, [4.37] SSRur􏱚(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) where SSRr is the sum of squared residu- als from the restricted model and SSRur is the sum of squared residuals from the unrestricted model. You should immediately notice that, since SSRr can be no smaller than SSRur, the F statistic is always nonnegative (and almost always strictly positive). Thus, if you compute a negative F statistic, then something is wrong; the order of the SSRs in the numerator of F has usu- ally been reversed. Also, the SSR in the denominator of F is the SSR from the unrestricted model. The easiest way to remember where the SSRs appear is to think of F as measuring the relative increase in SSR when moving from the unrestricted to the restricted model. The difference in SSRs in the numerator of F is divided by q, which is the number of restrictions imposed in moving from the unrestricted to the restricted model (q independent variables are dropped). Therefore, we can write q 􏱪 numerator degrees of freedom 􏱪 dfr 􏱦 dfur , [4.38] which also shows that q is the difference in degrees of freedom between the restricted and unrestricted models. (Recall that df 􏱪 number of observations 􏱦 number of estimated parameters.) Since the restricted model has fewer parameters—and each model is esti- mated using the same n observations—dfr is always greater than dfur. The SSR in the denominator of F is divided by the degrees of freedom in the unre- stricted model: n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 denominator degrees of freedom 􏱪 dfur . [4.39] In fact, the denominator of F is just the unbiased estimator of 􏱧 2 􏱪 Var(u) in the unre- stricted model. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 4.4 Consider relating individual performance on a standardized test, score, to a variety of other variables. School factors include av- erage class size, per-student expenditures, average teacher compensation, and total school enrollment. Other variables specific to the student are family income, mother’s education, father’s education, and number of siblings. The model is score 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1classize 􏱕 􏱬2expend 􏱕 􏱬3tchcomp 􏱕 􏱬4enroll 􏱕 􏱬5 faminc 􏱕 􏱬6 motheduc 􏱕 􏱬7fatheduc 􏱕 􏱬8siblings 􏱕 u. State the null hypothesis that student-specific variables have no effect on standardized test performance once school-related factors have been controlled for. What are k and q for this example? Write down the restricted version of the model. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 147 In a particular application, computing the F statistic is easier than wading through the somewhat cumbersome notation used to describe the general case. We first obtain the degrees of freedom in the unrestricted model, dfur. Then, we count how many variables are excluded in the restricted model; this is q. The SSRs are reported with every OLS regres- sion, and so forming the F statistic is simple. In the major league baseball salary regression, n 􏱪 353, and the full model (4.28) contains six parameters. Thus, n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 dfur 􏱪 353 􏱦 6 􏱪 347. The restricted model (4.32) contains three fewer independent variables than (4.28), and so q 􏱪 3. Thus, we have all of the ingredi- ents to compute the F statistic; we hold off doing so until we know what to do with it. To use the F statistic, we must know its sampling distribution under the null in order to choose critical values and rejection rules. It can be shown that, under H0 (and assuming the CLM assumptions hold), F is distributed as an F random variable with (q,n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) degrees of freedom. We write this as F 􏱷 Fq,n􏱦k􏱦1. The distribution of Fq,n􏱦k􏱦1 is readily tabulated and available in statistical tables (see Table G.3) and, even more importantly, in statistical software. We will not derive the F distribution because the mathematics is very involved. Basically, it can be shown that equation (4.37) is actually the ratio of two independent chi-square random variables, divided by their respective degrees of freedom. The numerator chi-square random variable has q degrees of freedom, and the chi-square in the denominator has n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 degrees of freedom. This is the definition of an F distributed random variable (see Appendix B). It is pretty clear from the definition of F that we will reject H0 in favor of H1 when F is sufficiently “large.” How large depends on our chosen significance level. Suppose that we have decided on a 5% level test. Let c be the 95th percentile in the Fq,n􏱦k􏱦1 distribution. This critical value depends on q (the numerator df ) and n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 (the denominator df ). It is important to keep the numerator and denominator degrees of freedom straight. The 10%, 5%, and 1% critical values for the F distribution are given in Table G.3. The rejection rule is simple. Once c has been obtained, we reject H0 in favor of H1 at the chosen significance level if F 􏱰 c. [4.40] With a 5% significance level, q 􏱪 3, and n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 60, the critical value is c 􏱪 2.76. We would reject H0 at the 5% level if the computed value of the F statistic exceeds 2.76. The 5% critical value and rejection region are shown in Figure 4.7. For the same degrees of freedom, the 1% critical value is 4.13. In most applications, the numerator degrees of freedom (q) will be notably smaller than the denominator degrees of freedom (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1). Applications where n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 is small are unlikely to be successful because the parameters in the unrestricted model will probably not be precisely estimated. When the denominator df reaches about 120, the F distribution is no longer sensitive to it. (This is entirely analogous to the t distribution being well approximated by the standard normal distribution as the df gets large.) Thus, there is an entry in the table for the denominator df 􏱪 􏱵, and this is what we use with large samples (because n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 is then large). A similar statement holds for a very large numerator df, but this rarely occurs in applications. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 148 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data F I G U R E 4 . 7 The 5% critical value and rejection region in an F3,60 distribution. area = .95 0 area = .05 rejection region 2.76 If H0 is rejected, then we say that xk􏱦q􏱕1, ..., xk are jointly statistically significant (or just jointly significant) at the appropriate significance level. This test alone does not allow us to say which of the variables has a partial effect on y; they may all affect y or maybe only one affects y. If the null is not rejected, then the variables are jointly insignificant, which often justifies dropping them from the model. For the major league baseball example with three numerator degrees of freedom and 347 denominator degrees of freedom, the 5% critical value is 2.60, and the 1% critical value is 3.78. We reject H0 at the 1% level if F is above 3.78; we reject at the 5% level if F is above 2.60. We are now in a position to test the hypothesis that we began this section with: After controlling for years and gamesyr, the variables bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr have no effect on players’ salaries. In practice, it is easiest to first compute (SSRr 􏱦 SSRur)/SSRur and to multiply the result by (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)/q; the reason the formula is stated as in (4.37) is that it makes it easier to keep the numerator and denominator degrees of freedom straight. Using the SSRs in (4.31) and (4.33), we have (198.311 􏱦 183.186) F 􏱪 __________________ 􏱳 _3_4_7_ 􏱴 9.55. 183.186 3 This number is well above the 1% critical value in the F distribution with 3 and 347 degrees of freedom, and so we soundly reject the hypothesis that bavg, hrunsyr, and rbisyr have no effect on salary. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 149 The outcome of the joint test may seem surprising in light of the insignificant t statistics for the three variables. What is happening is that the two variables hrunsyr and rbisyr are highly correlated, and this multicollinearity makes it difficult to uncover the partial effect of each variable; this is reflected in the individual t statistics. The F statistic tests whether these variables (including bavg) are jointly significant, and multicollinearity between hrunsyr and rbisyr is much less relevant for testing this hypothesis. In Problem 16, you are asked to reestimate the model while dropping rbisyr, in which case hrunsyr becomes very significant. The same is true for rbisyr when hrunsyr is dropped from the model. The F statistic is often useful for testing exclusion of a group of variables when the variables in the group are highly correlated. For example, suppose we want to test whether firm performance affects the salaries of chief executive officers. There are many ways to measure firm performance, and it probably would not be clear ahead of time which measures would be most important. Since measures of firm performance are likely to be highly correlated, hoping to find individually significant measures might be asking too much due to multicollinearity. But an F test can be used to determine whether, as a group, the firm performance variables affect salary. Relationship between F and t Statistics We have seen in this section how the F statistic can be used to test whether a group of variables should be included in a model. What happens if we apply the F statistic to the case of testing significance of a single independent variable? This case is certainly not ruled out by the previous development. For example, we can take the null to be H0: 􏱬k 􏱪 0 and q 􏱪 1 (to test the single exclusion restriction that xk can be excluded from the model). From Section 4.2, we know that the t statistic on 􏱬k can be used to test this hypothesis. The question, then, is: Do we have two separate ways of testing hypotheses about a single coefficient? The answer is no. It can be shown that the F statistic for testing exclusion of a single variable is equal to the square of the corresponding t statistic. Since t2n􏱦k􏱦1 has an F1,n􏱦k􏱦1 distribution, the two approaches lead to exactly the same outcome, provided that the alternative is two-sided. The t statistic is more flexible for testing a single hypothesis because it can be directly used to test against one-sided alternatives. Since t statistics are also easier to obtain than F statistics, there is really no reason to use an F statistic to test hypotheses about a single parameter. We have already seen in the salary regressions for major league baseball players that two (or more) variables that each have insignificant t statistics can be jointly very signifi- cant. It is also possible that, in a group of several explanatory variables, one variable has a significant t statistic but the group of variables is jointly insignificant at the usual signifi- cance levels. What should we make of this kind of outcome? For concreteness, suppose that in a model with many explanatory variables we cannot reject the null hypothesis that 􏱬1, 􏱬2, 􏱬3, 􏱬4, and 􏱬5 are all equal to zero at the 5% level, yet the t statistic for 􏱬ˆ1 is significant at the 5% level. Logically, we cannot have 􏱬1 􏱻 0 but also have 􏱬1, 􏱬2, 􏱬3, 􏱬4, and 􏱬5 all equal to zero! But as a matter of testing, it is possible that we can group a bunch of insig- nificant variables with a significant variable and conclude that the entire set of variables is jointly insignificant. (Such possible conflicts between a t test and a joint F test give another example of why we should not “accept” null hypotheses; we should only fail to reject them.) The F statistic is intended to detect whether a set of coefficients is different from zero, but it is never the best test for determining whether a single coefficient is different from zero. The t test is best suited for testing a single hypothesis. (In statistical terms, an F statistic for Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 150 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data joint restrictions including 􏱬1 􏱪 0 will have less power for detecting 􏱬1 􏱻 0 than the usual t statistic. See Section C.6 in Appendix C for a discussion of the power of a test.) Unfortunately, the fact that we can sometimes hide a statistically significant variable along with some insignificant variables could lead to abuse if regression results are not carefully reported. For example, suppose that, in a study of the determinants of loan- acceptance rates at the city level, x1 is the fraction of black households in the city. Suppose that the variables x2, x3, x4, and x5 are the fractions of households headed by different age groups. In explaining loan rates, we would include measures of income, wealth, credit ratings, and so on. Suppose that age of household head has no effect on loan approval rates, once other variables are controlled for. Even if race has a marginally significant effect, it is possible that the race and age variables could be jointly insignificant. Someone wanting to conclude that race is not a factor could simply report something like “Race and age variables were added to the equation, but they were jointly insignificant at the 5% level.” Hopefully, peer review prevents these kinds of misleading conclusions, but you should be aware that such outcomes are possible. Often, when a variable is very statistically significant and it is tested jointly with another set of variables, the set will be jointly significant. In such cases, there is no logical inconsistency in rejecting both null hypotheses. The R-Squared Form of the F Statistic For testing exclusion restrictions, it is often more convenient to have a form of the F statis- tic that can be computed using the R-squareds from the restricted and unrestricted models. One reason for this is that the R-squared is always between zero and one, whereas the SSRs can be very large depending on the unit of measurement of y, making the calculation based on the SSRs tedious. Using the fact that SSRr 􏱪 SST(1 􏱦 Rr2 ) and SSRur 􏱪 SST(1 􏱦 R2ur), we can substitute into (4.37) to obtain (R2ur 􏱦 R2r )􏱚q (R2ur 􏱦 R2r )􏱚q F 􏱪 ___________________ 􏱪 ____________ [4.41] (1 􏱦 R2ur)􏱚(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) (1 􏱦 R2ur)􏱚dfur (note that the SST terms cancel everywhere). This is called the R-squared form of the F statistic. [At this point, you should be cautioned that although equation (4.41) is very convenient for testing exclusion restrictions, it cannot be applied for testing all linear restrictions. As we will see when we discuss testing general linear restrictions, the sum of squared residuals form of the F statistic is sometimes needed.] Because the R-squared is reported with almost all regressions (whereas the SSR is not), it is easy to use the R-squareds from the unrestricted and restricted models to test for exclusion of some variables. Particular attention should be paid to the order of the R-squareds in the numerator: the unrestricted R-squared comes first [contrast this with the SSRs in (4.37)]. Because R2ur 􏱰 R2r , this shows again that F will always be positive. In using the R-squared form of the test for excluding a set of variables, it is impor- tant to not square the R-squared before plugging it into formula (4.41); the squaring has already been done. All regressions report R2, and these numbers are plugged directly into (4.41). For the baseball salary example, we can use (4.41) to obtain the F statistic: (.6278 􏱦 .5971) F 􏱪 ______________ 􏱳 _3_4_7_ 􏱴 9.54, (1 􏱦 .6278) 3 which is very close to what we obtained before. (The difference is due to rounding error.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 151 EXAMPLE 4.9 PARENTS’ EDUCATION IN A BIRTH WEIGHT EQUATION As another example of computing an F statistic, consider the following model to explain child birth weight in terms of various factors: where parity 􏱪 faminc 􏱪 motheduc 􏱪 fatheduc 􏱪 bwght 􏱪 cigs 􏱪 bwght 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1cigs 􏱕 􏱬2 parity 􏱕 􏱬3 faminc 􏱕 􏱬4 motheduc 􏱕 􏱬5 fatheduc 􏱕 u, birth weight, in pounds. average number of cigarettes the mother smoked per day during pregnancy. the birth order of this child. annual family income. years of schooling for the mother. years of schooling for the father. [4.42] Let us test the null hypothesis that, after controlling for cigs, parity, and faminc, parents’ education has no effect on birth weight. This is stated as H0: 􏱬4 􏱪 0, 􏱬5 􏱪 0, and so there are q 􏱪 2 exclusion restrictions to be tested. There are k 􏱕 1 􏱪 6 parameters in the unrestricted model (4.42); so the df in the unrestricted model is n 􏱦 6, where n is the sample size. We will test this hypothesis using the data in BWGHT.RAW. This data set contains information on 1,388 births, but we must be careful in counting the observations used in testing the null hypothesis. It turns out that information on at least one of the variables motheduc and fatheduc is missing for 197 births in the sample; these observations cannot be included when estimating the unrestricted model. Thus, we really have n 􏱪 1,191 obser- vations, and so there are 1,191 􏱦 6 􏱪 1,185 df in the unrestricted model. We must be sure to use these same 1,191 observations when estimating the restricted model (not the full 1,388 observations that are available). Generally, when estimating the restricted model to compute an F test, we must use the same observations to estimate the unrestricted model; otherwise, the test is not valid. When there are no missing data, this will not be an issue. The numerator df is 2, and the denominator df is 1,185; from Table G.3, the 5% critical value is c 􏱪 3.0. Rather than report the complete results, for brevity, we present only the R-squareds. The R-squared for the full model turns out to be R2ur 􏱪 .0387. When motheduc and fatheduc are dropped from the regression, the R-squared falls to R2r 􏱪 .0364. Thus, the F statistic is F 􏱪 [(.0387 􏱦 .0364)/(1 􏱦 .0387)](1,185/2) 􏱪 1.42; since this is well below the 5% critical value, we fail to reject H0. In other words, motheduc and fatheduc are jointly insignificant in the birth weight equation. Computing p-Values for F Tests For reporting the outcomes of F tests, p-values are especially useful. Since the F distri- bution depends on the numerator and denominator df, it is difficult to get a feel for how strong or weak the evidence is against the null hypothesis simply by looking at the value of the F statistic and one or two critical values. In the F testing context, the p-value is defined as p-value 􏱪 P(􏲂 􏱰 F ), [4.43] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 152 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data where, for emphasis, we let 􏲂 denote an F random variable with (q,n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) degrees of freedom, and F is the actual value of the test statistic. The p-value still has the same interpretation as it did for t statistics: it is the probability of observ- ing a value of F at least as large as we did, given that the null hypothesis is true. A small p-value is evidence against H0. For example, p-value 􏱪 .016 means that the chance of observing a value of F as large as we did when the null hypothesis was true is only 1.6%; we usually reject H0 in such cases. If the p-value 􏱪.314, then the chance of observing a value of the F statistic as large as we did under the null hypothesis is 31.4%. Most would find this to be pretty weak evidence against H0. As with t testing, once the p-value has been computed, the F test can be carried out at any significance level. For example, if the p-value 􏱪 .024, we reject H0 at the 5% significance level but not at the 1% level. The p-value for the F test in Example 4.9 is .238, and so the null hypothesis that 􏱬motheduc and 􏱬fatheduc are both zero is not rejected at even the 20% significance level. Many econometrics packages have a built-in feature for testing multiple exclusion restrictions. These packages have several advantages over calculating the statistics by hand: we will less likely make a mistake, p-values are computed automatically, and the problem of missing data, as in Example 4.9, is handled without any additional work on our part. The F Statistic for Overall Significance of a Regression A special set of exclusion restrictions is routinely tested by most regression packages. These restrictions have the same interpretation, regardless of the model. In the model with k independent variables, we can write the null hypothesis as H0: x1, x2, ..., xk do not help to explain y. This null hypothesis is, in a way, very pessimistic. It states that none of the explanatory variables has an effect on y. Stated in terms of the parameters, the null is that all slope parameters are zero: H0:􏱬1 􏱪􏱬2 􏱪...􏱪􏱬k 􏱪0, [4.44] and the alternative is that at least one of the 􏱬j is different from zero. Another useful way of stating the null is that H0: E(y􏱊x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 E(y), so that knowing the values of x1, x2, ..., xk does not affect the expected value of y. There are k restrictions in (4.44), and when we impose them, we get the restricted model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕u; [4.45] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 4.5 The data in ATTEND.RAW were used to esti- mate the two equations 􏱾atndrte􏱪 47.13 􏱕 13.37 priGPA (2.87) (1.09) n􏱪680,R2 􏱪.183 and 􏱾atndrte 􏱪 75.70 􏱕 17.26 priGPA 􏱦 1.72 ACT (3.88) (1.08) (?) n 􏱪 680, R2 􏱪 .291, where, as always, standard errors are in parentheses; the standard error for ACT is missing in the second equation. What is the t statistic for the coefficient on ACT ? (Hint: First compute the F statistic for significance of ACT.) CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 153 all independent variables have been dropped from the equation. Now, the R-squared from estimating (4.45) is zero; none of the variation in y is being explained because there are no explanatory variables. Therefore, the F statistic for testing (4.44) can be written as R2􏱚k __________________, [4.46] (1 􏱦 R2)􏱚(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) where R2 is just the usual R-squared from the regression of y on x1, x2, ..., xk. Most regression packages report the F statistic in (4.46) automatically, which makes it tempting to use this statistic to test general exclusion restrictions. You must avoid this temptation. The F statistic in (4.41) is used for general exclusion restrictions; it depends on the R-squareds from the restricted and unrestricted models. The special form of (4.46) is valid only for testing joint exclusion of all independent variables. This is sometimes called determining the overall significance of the regression. If we fail to reject (4.44), then there is no evidence that any of the independent variables help to explain y. This usually means that we must look for other variables to explain y. For Example 4.9, the F statistic for testing (4.44) is about 9.55 with k 􏱪 5 and n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 􏱪 1,185 df. The p-value is zero to four places after the decimal point, so that (4.44) is rejected very strongly. Thus, we conclude that the variables in the bwght equation do explain some variation in bwght. The amount explained is not large: only 3.87%. But the seemingly small R-squared results in a highly significant F statistic. That is why we must compute the F sta- tistic to test for joint significance and not just look at the size of the R-squared. Occasionally, the F statistic for the hypothesis that all independent variables are jointly insignificant is the focus of a study. Problem 10 asks you to use stock return data to test whether stock returns over a four-year horizon are predictable based on informa- tion known only at the beginning of the period. Under the efficient markets hypothesis, the returns should not be predictable; the null hypothesis is precisely (4.44). Testing General Linear Restrictions Testing exclusion restrictions is by far the most important application of F statistics. Sometimes, however, the restrictions implied by a theory are more complicated than just excluding some independent variables. It is still straightforward to use the F statistic for testing. As an example, consider the following equation: log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(assess) 􏱕 􏱬2log(lotsize) 􏱕 􏱬3log(sqrft) 􏱕 􏱬4bdrms 􏱕 u, where price 􏱪 house price. assess 􏱪 the assessed housing value (before the house was sold). lotsize 􏱪 size of the lot, in feet. sqrft 􏱪 square footage. bdrms 􏱪 number of bedrooms. [4.47] Now, suppose we would like to test whether the assessed housing price is a rational valua- tion. If this is the case, then a 1% change in assess should be associated with a 1% change in price; that is, 􏱬1 􏱪 1. In addition, lotsize, sqrft, and bdrms should not help to explain Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 154 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data log(price), once the assessed value has been controlled for. Together, these hypotheses can be stated as H0:􏱬1 􏱪1,􏱬2 􏱪0,􏱬3 􏱪0,􏱬4 􏱪0. [4.48] Four restrictions have to be tested; three are exclusion restrictions, but 􏱬1 􏱪 1 is not. How can we test this hypothesis using the F statistic? As in the exclusion restriction case, we estimate the unrestricted model, (4.47) in this case, and then impose the restrictions in (4.48) to obtain the restricted model. It is the second step that can be a little tricky. But all we do is plug in the restrictions. If we write (4.47) as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕􏱬4x4 􏱕u, [4.49] then the restricted model is y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 x1 􏱕 u. Now, to impose the restriction that the coefficient on x1 is unity, we must estimate the following model: y􏱦x1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕u. [4.50] This is just a model with an intercept (􏱬0) but with a different dependent variable than in (4.49). The procedure for computing the F statistic is the same: estimate (4.50), obtain the SSR (SSRr), and use this with the unrestricted SSR from (4.49) in the F statistic (4.37). We are testing q 􏱪 4 restrictions, and there are n 􏱦 5 df in the unrestricted model. The F statistic is simply [(SSRr 􏱦 SSRur)/SSRur][(n 􏱦 5)/4]. Before illustrating this test using a data set, we must emphasize one point: we cannot use the R-squared form of the F statistic for this example because the dependent variable in (4.50) is different from the one in (4.49). This means the total sum of squares from the two regressions will be different, and (4.41) is no longer equivalent to (4.37). As a general rule, the SSR form of the F statistic should be used if a different dependent variable is needed in running the restricted regression. The estimated unrestricted model using the data in HPRICE1.RAW is 􏱾log(price) 􏱪 .264 􏱕 1.043 log(assess) 􏱕 .0074 log(lotsize) (.570) (.151) (.0386) 􏱦 .1032 log(sqrft) 􏱕 .0338 bdrms (.1384) (.0221) n 􏱪 88, SSR 􏱪 1.822, R2 􏱪 .773. If we use separate t statistics to test each hypothesis in (4.48), we fail to reject each one. But rationality of the assessment is a joint hypothesis, so we should test the restrictions jointly. The SSR from the restricted model turns out to be SSRr 􏱪 1.880, and so the F sta- tistic is [(1.880 􏱦 1.822)/1.822](83/4) 􏱪 .661. The 5% critical value in an F distribution with (4,83) df is about 2.50, and so we fail to reject H0. There is essentially no evidence against the hypothesis that the assessed values are rational. 4.6 Reporting Regression Results We end this chapter by providing a few guidelines on how to report multiple regression results for relatively complicated empirical projects. This should help you to read published works in the applied social sciences, while also preparing you to write your own empirical Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 155 papers. We will expand on this topic in the remainder of the text by reporting results from various examples, but many of the key points can be made now. Naturally, the estimated OLS coefficients should always be reported. For the key variables in an analysis, you should interpret the estimated coefficients (which often requires knowing the units of measurement of the variables). For example, is an estimate an elasticity, or does it have some other interpretation that needs explanation? The economic or practical importance of the estimates of the key variables should be discussed. The standard errors should always be included along with the estimated coeffi- cients. Some authors prefer to report the t statistics rather than the standard errors (and sometimes just the absolute value of the t statistics). Although nothing is really wrong with this, there is some preference for reporting standard errors. First, it forces us to think carefully about the null hypothesis being tested; the null is not always that the population parameter is zero. Second, having standard errors makes it easier to compute confidence intervals. The R-squared from the regression should always be included. We have seen that, in addition to providing a goodness-of-fit measure, it makes calculation of F statis- tics for exclusion restrictions simple. Reporting the sum of squared residuals and the standard error of the regression is sometimes a good idea, but it is not crucial. The num- ber of observations used in estimating any equation should appear near the estimated equation. If only a couple of models are being estimated, the results can be summarized in equa- tion form, as we have done up to this point. However, in many papers, several equations are estimated with many different sets of independent variables. We may estimate the same equation for different groups of people, or even have equations explaining different dependent variables. In such cases, it is better to summarize the results in one or more tables. The dependent variable should be indicated clearly in the table, and the independent variables should be listed in the first column. Standard errors (or t statistics) can be put in parentheses below the estimates. EXAMPLE 4.10 SALARY-PENSION TRADEOFF FOR TEACHERS Let totcomp denote average total annual compensation for a teacher, including salary and all fringe benefits (pension, health insurance, and so on). Extending the standard wage equation, total compensation should be a function of productivity and perhaps other char- acteristics. As is standard, we use logarithmic form: log(totcomp) 􏱪 f ( productivity characteristics,other factors), where f (􏱳) is some function (unspecified for now). Write benefits totcomp 􏱪 salary 􏱕 benefits 􏱪 salary 􏱵1 􏱕 _______ 􏱷. salary This equation shows that total compensation is the product of two terms: salary and 1 􏱕 b/s, where b/s is shorthand for the “benefits to salary ratio.” Taking the log of this equation gives Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 156 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data log(totcomp) 􏱪 log(salary) 􏱕 log(1 􏱕 b/s). Now, for “small” b/s, log(1 􏱕 b/s) 􏱴 b/s; we will use this approximation. This leads to the econometric model log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1(b/s) 􏱕 other factors. Testing the salary-benefits tradeoff then is the same as a test of H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦1 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱻 􏱦1. We use the data in MEAP93.RAW to test this hypothesis. These data are averaged at the school level, and we do not observe very many other factors that could affect total compensation. We will include controls for size of the school (enroll ), staff per thousand students (staff ), and measures such as the school dropout and graduation rates. The average b/s in the sample is about .205, and the largest value is .450. The estimated equations are given in Table 4.1, where standard errors are given in parentheses below the coefficient estimates. The key variable is b/s, the benefits- salary ratio. From the first column in Table 4.1, we see that, without controlling for any other factors, the OLS coefficient for b/s is 􏱦.825. The t statistic for testing the null hypothesis H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦1 is t 􏱪 (􏱦.825 􏱕 1)/.200 􏱪 .875, and so the simple regression fails to reject H0. After adding controls for school size and staff size (which roughly captures the number of students taught by each teacher), the estimate of the b/s coefficient becomes 􏱦.605. Now, the test of 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦1 gives a t statistic of about 2.39; thus, H0 is re- jected at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative. The variables log(enroll) and log(staff ) are very statistically significant. EXPLORING FURTHER 4.6 How does adding droprate and gradrate affect the estimate of the salary-benefits tradeoff? Are these variables jointly signifi- cant at the 5% level? What about the 10% level? T A B L E 4 . 1 Testing the Salary-Benefits Tradeoff Dependent Variable: log(salary) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) b/s 􏱦.825 (.200) 􏱦.605 (.165) 􏱦.589 (.165) log(enroll) —— .0874 (.0073) .0881 (.0073) log(staff ) —— 􏱦.222 (.050) 􏱦.218 (.050) droprate —— —— 􏱦.00028 (.00161) gradrate —— —— .00097 .00066) intercept 10.523 (0.042) 10.884 (0.252) 10.738 (0.258) Observations R-squared 408 .040 408 .353 408 .361 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 157 Summary In this chapter, we have covered the very important topic of statistical inference, which allows us to infer something about the population model from a random sample. We summarize the main points: 1. Under the classical linear model assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6, the OLS estimators are normally distributed. 2. Under the CLM assumptions, the t statistics have t distributions under the null hypothesis. 3. We use t statistics to test hypotheses about a single parameter against one- or two-sided alternatives, using one- or two-tailed tests, respectively. The most common null hypothesis is H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0, but we sometimes want to test other values of 􏱬j under H0. 4. In classical hypothesis testing, we first choose a significance level, which, along with the df and alternative hypothesis, determines the critical value against which we compare the t statistic. It is more informative to compute the p-value for a t test—the smallest signifi- cance level for which the null hypothesis is rejected—so that the hypothesis can be tested at any significance level. 5. Under the CLM assumptions, confidence intervals can be constructed for each 􏱬j. These CIs can be used to test any null hypothesis concerning 􏱬j against a two-sided alternative. 6. Single hypothesis tests concerning more than one 􏱬j can always be tested by rewriting the model to contain the parameter of interest. Then, a standard t statistic can be used. 7. The F statistic is used to test multiple exclusion restrictions, and there are two equivalent forms of the test. One is based on the SSRs from the restricted and unrestricted models. A more convenient form is based on the R-squareds from the two models. 8. WhencomputinganFstatistic,thenumeratordfisthenumberofrestrictionsbeingtested, while the denominator df is the degrees of freedom in the unrestricted model. 9. The alternative for F testing is two-sided. In the classical approach, we specify a significance level which, along with the numerator df and the denominator df, deter- mines the critical value. The null hypothesis is rejected when the statistic, F, exceeds the critical value, c. Alternatively, we can compute a p-value to summarize the evidence against H0. 10. General multiple linear restrictions can be tested using the sum of squared residuals form of the F statistic. 11. The F statistic for the overall significance of a regression tests the null hypothesis that all slope parameters are zero, with the intercept unrestricted. Under H0, the explanatory variables have no effect on the expected value of y. THE CLASSICAL LINEAR MODEL ASSUMPTIONS Now is a good time to review the full set of classical linear model (CLM) assumptions for cross-sectional regression. Following each assumption is a comment about its role in multiple regression analysis. Assumption MLR.1 (Linear in Parameters) The model in the population can be written as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, where 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k are the unknown parameters (constants) of interest and u is an unobserved random error or disturbance term. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 158 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Assumption MLR.1 describes the population relationship we hope to estimate, and explicitly sets out the 􏱬j—the ceteris paribus population effects of the xj on y—as the param- eters of interest. Assumption MLR.2 (Random Sampling) We have a random sample of n observations, {(xi1, xi2, ..., xik, yi): i 􏱪 1, ..., n}, following the population model in Assumption MLR.1. This random sampling assumption means that we have data that can be used to estimate the 􏱬j, and that the data have been chosen to be representative of the population described in Assumption MLR.1. Assumption MLR.3 (No Perfect Collinearity) In the sample (and therefore in the population), none of the independent variables is constant, and there are no exact linear relationships among the independent variables. Once we have a sample of data, we need to know that we can use the data to compute the OLS estimates, the 􏱬ˆj. This is the role of Assumption MLR.3: if we have sample variation in each independent variable and no exact linear relationships among the independent variables, we can compute the 􏱬ˆj. Assumption MLR.4 (Zero Conditional Mean) The error u has an expected value of zero given any values of the explanatory variables. In other words, E(u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 0. As we discussed in the text, assuming that the unobserved factors are, on average, unrelated to the explanatory variables is key to deriving the first statistical property of each OLS estimator: its unbiasedness for the corresponding population parameter. Of course, all of the previous assumptions are used to show unbiasedness. Assumption MLR.5 (Homoskedasticity) The error u has the same variance given any values of the explanatory variables. In other words, Var(u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱧2. Compared with Assumption MLR.4, the homoskedasticity assumption is of secondary importance; in particular, Assumption MLR.5 has no bearing on the unbiasedness of the 􏱬ˆj. Still, homoskedasticity has two important implications: (1) We can derive formulas for the sampling variances whose components are easy to characterize; (2) We can conclude, under the Gauss- Markov assumptions MLR.1 to MLR.5, that the OLS estimators have smallest variance among all linear, unbiased estimators. Assumption MLR.6 (Normality) The population error u is independent of the explanatory variables x1, x2, ..., xk and is normally distributed with zero mean and variance 􏱧 2: u ~ Normal(0, 􏱧 2). In this chapter, we added Assumption MLR.6 to obtain the exact sampling distributions of t statistics and F statistics, so that we can carry out exact hypotheses tests. In the next chapter, we will see that MLR.6 can be dropped if we have a reasonably large sample size. Assumption MLR.6 does imply a stronger efficiency property of OLS: the OLS estimators have smallest variance among all unbiased estimators; the comparison group is no longer restricted to esti- mators linear in the {yi: i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Key Terms Alternative Hypothesis Classical Linear Model Classical Linear Model (CLM) Assumptions Confidence Interval (CI) Critical Value Denominator Degrees of Freedom Economic Significance Exclusion Restrictions F Statistic Joint Hypotheses Test Jointly Insignificant Problems Jointly Statistically Significant Minimum Variance Unbiased Estimators Multiple Hypotheses Test Multiple Restrictions Normality Assumption Null Hypothesis Numerator Degrees of Freedom One-Sided Alternative One-Tailed Test Overall Significance of the Regression p-Value Practical Significance R-squared Form of the F Statistic Rejection Rule Restricted Model Significance Level Statistically Insignificant Statistically Significant t Ratio t Statistic Two-Sided Alternative Two-Tailed Test Unrestricted Model CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 159 1 Which of the following can cause the usual OLS t statistics to be invalid (that is, not to have t distributions under H0)? (i) Heteroskedasticity. (ii) A sample correlation coefficient of .95 between two independent variables that are in the model. (iii) Omitting an important explanatory variable. 2 ConsideranequationtoexplainsalariesofCEOsintermsofannualfirmsales,returnon equity (roe, in percentage form), and return on the firm’s stock (ros, in percentage form): log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2roe 􏱕 􏱬3ros 􏱕 u. (i) In terms of the model parameters, state the null hypothesis that, after controlling for sales and roe, ros has no effect on CEO salary. State the alternative that better stock market performance increases a CEO’s salary. (ii) Using the data in CEOSAL1.RAW, the following equation was obtained by OLS: 􏱾log(salary) 􏱪 4.32 􏱕 .280 log(sales) 􏱕 .0174 roe 􏱕 .00024 ros (.32) (.035) (.0041) (.00054) n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 .283. By what percentage is salary predicted to increase if ros increases by 50 points? Does ros have a practically large effect on salary? (iii) Test the null hypothesis that ros has no effect on salary against the alternative that ros has a positive effect. Carry out the test at the 10% significance level. (iv) Would you include ros in a final model explaining CEO compensation in terms of firm performance? Explain. 3 The variable rdintens is expenditures on research and development (R&D) as a percentage of sales. Sales are measured in millions of dollars. The variable profmarg is profits as a percentage of sales. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 160 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Using the data in RDCHEM.RAW for 32 firms in the chemical industry, the following equation is estimated: (i) Interpret the coefficient on log(sales). In particular, if sales increases by 10%, what is the estimated percentage point change in rdintens? Is this an economically large effect? (ii) Test the hypothesis that R&D intensity does not change with sales against the alter- native that it does increase with sales. Do the test at the 5% and 10% levels. (iii) Interpret the coefficient on profmarg. Is it economically large? (iv) Does profmarg have a statistically significant effect on rdintens? 4 Arerentratesinfluencedbythestudentpopulationinacollegetown?Letrentbetheaver- age monthly rent paid on rental units in a college town in the United States. Let pop denote the total city population, avginc the average city income, and pctstu the student population as a percentage of the total population. One model to test for a relationship is log(rent) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(pop) 􏱕 􏱬2log(avginc) 􏱕 􏱬3pctstu 􏱕 u. (i) State the null hypothesis that size of the student body relative to the population has no ceteris paribus effect on monthly rents. State the alternative that there is an effect. (ii) What signs do you expect for 􏱬1 and 􏱬2? (iii) The equation estimated using 1990 data from RENTAL.RAW for 64 college towns is What is wrong with the statement: “A 10% increase in population is associated with about a 6.6% increase in rent”? (iv) Test the hypothesis stated in part (i) at the 1% level. 5 ConsidertheestimatedequationfromExample4.3,whichcanbeusedtostudytheeffects of skipping class on college GPA: (i) Using the standard normal approximation, find the 95% confidence interval for 􏱬hsGPA. (ii) Can you reject the hypothesis H0: 􏱬hsGPA 􏱪 .4 against the two-sided alternative at the 5% level? (iii) Can you reject the hypothesis H0: 􏱬hsGPA 􏱪 1 against the two-sided alternative at the 5% level? 6 In Section 4.5, we used as an example testing the rationality of assessments of housing prices. There, we used a log-log model in price and assess [see equation (4.47)]. Here, we use a level-level formulation. (i) In the simple regression model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1assess 􏱕 u, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 rdintens 􏱪 .472 􏱕 .321 log(sales) 􏱕 .050 profmarg (1.369) (.216) (.046) n􏱪32,R2 􏱪.099. 􏱾 log(rent)􏱪 .043 􏱕 .066 log(pop)􏱕 .507 log(avginc)􏱕 .0056 pctstu (.844) (.039) (.081) (.0017) n􏱪64,R2 􏱪.458. 􏱾 colGPA􏱪 1.39 􏱕 .412 hsGPA􏱕 .015 ACT􏱦 .083 skipped (.33) (.094) (.011) (.026) n 􏱪 141, R2 􏱪 .234. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 161 the assessment is rational if 􏱬1 􏱪 1 and 􏱬0 􏱪 0. The estimated equation is n 􏱪 88, SSR 􏱪 165,644.51, R2 􏱪 .820. First, test the hypothesis that H0: 􏱬0 􏱪 0 against the two-sided alternative. Then, test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 1 against the two-sided alternative. What do you conclude? (ii) To test the joint hypothesis that 􏱬0 􏱪∑0 and 􏱬1 􏱪 1, we need the SSR in the restricted model. This amounts to computing n (pricei 􏱦 assessi)2, where i􏱪1 n 􏱪 88, since the residuals in the restricted model are just pricei 􏱦 assessi. (No es- timation is needed for the restricted model because both parameters are specified under H0.) This turns out to yield SSR 􏱪 209,448.99. Carry out the F test for the joint hypothesis. (iii) Now, test H0: 􏱬2 􏱪 0, 􏱬3 􏱪 0, and 􏱬4 􏱪 0 in the model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1assess 􏱕 􏱬2lotsize 􏱕 􏱬3sqrft 􏱕 􏱬4bdrms 􏱕 u. The R-squared from estimating this model using the same 88 houses is .829. (iv) If the variance of price changes with assess, lotsize, sqrft, or bdrms, what can you say about the F test from part (iii)? 7 In Example 4.7, we used data on nonunionized manufacturing firms to estimate the relationship between the scrap rate and other firm characteristics. We now look at this ex- ample more closely and use all available firms. 􏱾 price􏱪􏱦14.47 􏱕 .976 assess (16.27) (.049) (i) The population model estimated in Example 4.7 can be written as log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1hrsemp 􏱕 􏱬2log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬3log(employ) 􏱕 u. Using the 43 observations available for 1987, the estimated equation is Compare this equation to that estimated using only the 29 nonunionized firms in the sample. Show that the population model can also be written as log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1hrsemp 􏱕 􏱬2log(sales/employ) 􏱕 􏰩3log(employ) 􏱕 u, where 􏰩3 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 􏱬3. [Hint: Recall that log(x2/x3) 􏱪 log(x2) 􏱦 log(x3).] Interpret the (ii) 􏱾 log(scrap)􏱪 11.74 􏱦 .042 hrsemp􏱦 .951 log(sales)􏱕 .992 log(employ) (4.57) (.019) (.370) (.360) n􏱪43,R2 􏱪.310. hypothesis H0: 􏰩3 􏱪 0. (iii) When the equation from part (ii) is estimated, we obtain Controlling for worker training and for the sales-to-employee ratio, do bigger firms have larger statistically significant scrap rates? (iv) Test the hypothesis that a 1% increase in sales/employ is associated with a 1% drop in the scrap rate. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 log(scrap)􏱪 11.74 􏱦 .042 hrsemp􏱦 .951 log(sales/employ)􏱕 .041 log(employ) (4.57) (.019) (.370) (.205) n􏱪43,R2 􏱪.310. 162 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 8 Considerthemultipleregressionmodelwiththreeindependentvariables,undertheclassi- cal linear model assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u. You would like to test the null hypothesis H0: 􏱬1 􏱦 3􏱬2 􏱪 1. (i) Let 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 denote the OLS estimators of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2. Find Var(􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 3􏱬ˆ2) in terms of the variances of 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 and the covariance between them. What is the standard error of 􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 3􏱬ˆ2? (ii) Write the t statistic for testing H0: 􏱬1 􏱦 3􏱬2 􏱪 1. (iii) Define 􏰩1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱦 3􏱬2 and 􏰩ˆ1 􏱪 􏱬ˆ1 􏱦 3􏱬ˆ2. Write a regression equation involving 􏱬0, 􏰩1, 􏱬2, and 􏱬3 that allows you to directly obtain 􏰩ˆ1 and its standard error. 9 In Problem 3 in Chapter 3, we estimated the equation 􏱾 sleep 􏱪 3,638.25 􏱦 .148 totwrk 􏱦 11.13 educ 􏱕 2.20 age (112.28) (.017) (5.88) (1.45) n 􏱪 706, R2 􏱪 .113, where we now report standard errors along with the estimates. (i) Is either educ or age individually significant at the 5% level against a two-sided alter- native? Show your work. (ii) Dropping educ and age from the equation gives n 􏱪 706, R2 􏱪 .103. Are educ and age jointly significant in the original equation at the 5% level? Justify your answer. (iii) Does including educ and age in the model greatly affect the estimated tradeoff between sleeping and working? (iv) Suppose that the sleep equation contains heteroskedasticity. What does this mean about the tests computed in parts (i) and (ii)? 10 Regression analysis can be used to test whether the market efficiently uses information in valuing stocks. For concreteness, let return be the total return from holding a firm’s stock over the four-year period from the end of 1990 to the end of 1994. The efficient mar- kets hypothesis says that these returns should not be systematically related to information known in 1990. If firm characteristics known at the beginning of the period help to predict stock returns, then we could use this information in choosing stocks. For 1990, let dkr be a firm’s debt to capital ratio, let eps denote the earnings per share, let netinc denote net income, and let salary denote total compensation for the CEO. (i) Using the data in RETURN.RAW, the following equation was estimated: r􏱾eturn􏱪 􏱦14.37 􏱕 .321 dkr􏱕 .043 eps􏱦 .0051 netinc􏱕 .0035 salary (6.89) (.201) (.078) (.0047) (.0022) n 􏱪 142, R2 􏱪 .0395. Test whether the explanatory variables are jointly significant at the 5% level. Is any explanatory variable individually significant? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 sleep􏱪 3,586.38 􏱦 .151 totwrk (38.91) (.017) CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 163 (ii) Now, reestimate the model using the log form for netinc and salary: r􏱾eturn􏱪􏱦36.30 􏱕 .327 dkr􏱕 .069 eps􏱦 4.74 log(netinc)􏱕 7.24 log(salary) (39.37) (.203) (.080) (3.39) (6.31) n 􏱪 142, R2 􏱪 .0330. Do any of your conclusions from part (i) change? (iii) In this sample, some firms have zero debt and others have negative earnings. Should we try to use log(dkr) or log(eps) in the model to see if these improve the fit? Explain. (iv) Overall, is the evidence for predictability of stock returns strong or weak? 11 ThefollowingtablewascreatedusingthedatainCEOSAL2.RAW,wherestandarderrors are in parentheses below the coefficients: Dependent Variable: log(salary) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) log(sales) .224 (.027) .158 (.040) .188 (.040) log(mktval) —— .112 .100 (.050) (.049) profmarg —— 􏱦.0023 (.0022) 􏱦.0022 (.0021) ceoten —— —— .0171 (.0055) comten —— —— 􏱦.0092 (.0033) intercept 4.94 4.62 4.57 (0.20) (0.25) (0.25) Observations R-squared 177 .281 177 .304 177 .353 The variable mktval is market value of the firm, profmarg is profit as a percentage of sales, ceoten is years as CEO with the current company, and comten is total years with the company. (i) Comment on the effect of profmarg on CEO salary. (ii) Does market value have a significant effect? Explain. (iii) Interpret the coefficients on ceoten and comten. Are these explanatory variables sta- tistically significant? (iv) What do you make of the fact that longer tenure with the company, holding the other factors fixed, is associated with a lower salary? 12 ThefollowinganalysiswasobtainedusingdatainMEAP93.RAW,whichcontainsschool- level pass rates (as a percent) on a 10th grade math test. (i) The variable expend is expenditures per student, in dollars, and math10 is the pass rate on the exam. The following simple regression relates math10 to lexpend 􏱶 log(expend): 􏱾 math10􏱪 􏱦69.34 􏱕 11.16 lexpend (25.53) (3.17) n 􏱪 408, R2 􏱪 .0297 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 164 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Interpret the coefficient on lexpend. In particular, if expend increases by 10%, what is the estimated percentage point change in math10? What do you make of the large negative intercept estimate? (The minimum value of lexpend is 8.11 and its average value is 8.37.) (ii) Does the small R-squared in part (i) imply that spending is correlated with other fac- tors affecting math10? Explain. Would you expect the R-squared to be much higher if expenditures were randomly assigned to schools—that is, independent of other school and student characteristics—rather than having the school districts determine spending? (iii) When log of enrollment and the percent of students eligible for the federal free lunch program are included, the estimated equation becomes Comment on what happens to the coefficient on lexpend. Is the spending coefficient still statistically different from zero? (iv) What do you make of the R-squared in part (iii)? What are some other factors that could be used to explain math10 (at the school level)? Computer Exercises C1 The following model can be used to study whether campaign expenditures affect election outcomes: voteA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(expendA) 􏱕 􏱬2log(expendB) 􏱕 􏱬3 prtystrA 􏱕 u, where voteA is the percentage of the vote received by Candidate A, expendA and expendB are campaign expenditures by Candidates A and B, and prtystrA is a measure of party strength for Candidate A (the percentage of the most recent presidential vote that went to A’s party). (i) What is the interpretation of 􏱬1? (ii) In terms of the parameters, state the null hypothesis that a 1% increase in A’s ex- penditures is offset by a 1% increase in B’s expenditures. (iii) Estimate the given model using the data in VOTE1.RAW and report the results in usual form. Do A’s expenditures affect the outcome? What about B’s expendi- tures? Can you use these results to test the hypothesis in part (ii)? (iv) Estimate a model that directly gives the t statistic for testing the hypothesis in part (ii). What do you conclude? (Use a two-sided alternative.) C2 Use the data in LAWSCH85.RAW for this exercise. (i) Using the same model as in Problem 4 in Chapter 3, state and test the null hypothesis that the rank of law schools has no ceteris paribus effect on median starting salary. (ii) Are features of the incoming class of students—namely, LSAT and GPA— individually or jointly significant for explaining salary? (Be sure to account for missing data on LSAT and GPA.) (iii) Test whether the size of the entering class (clsize) or the size of the faculty ( faculty) needs to be added to this equation; carry out a single test. (Be careful to account for missing data on clsize and faculty.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 math10􏱪 􏱦23.14 􏱕 7.75 lexpend􏱦1.26 lenroll􏱦.324 lnchprg (24.99) (3.04) (0.58) (0.36) n 􏱪 408, R2 􏱪 .1893 CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 165 (iv) What factors might influence the rank of the law school that are not included in the salary regression? C3 Refer to Computer Exercise C2 in Chapter 3. Now, use the log of the housing price as the dependent variable: log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sqrft 􏱕 􏱬2bdrms 􏱕 u. (i) You are interested in estimating and obtaining a confidence interval for the percent- age change in price when a 150-square-foot bedroom is added to a house. In decimal form, this is 􏰩1 􏱪 150􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2. Use the data in HPRICE1.RAW to estimate 􏰩1. (ii) Write 􏱬2 in terms of 􏰩1 and 􏱬1 and plug this into the log(price) equation. (iii) Use part (ii) to obtain a standard error for 􏰩ˆ1 and use this standard error to construct a 95% confidence interval. C4 In Example 4.9, the restricted version of the model can be estimated using all 1,388 ob- servations in the sample. Compute the R-squared from the regression of bwght on cigs, parity, and faminc using all observations. Compare this to the R-squared reported for the restricted model in Example 4.9. C5 Use the data in MLB1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Use the model estimated in equation (4.31) and drop the variable rbisyr. What happens to the statistical significance of hrunsyr? What about the size of the coefficient on hrunsyr? (ii) Add the variables runsyr (runs per year), fldperc (fielding percentage), and sbasesyr (stolen bases per year) to the model from part (i). Which of these factors are individually significant? (iii) Inthemodelfrompart(ii),testthejointsignificanceofbavg,fldperc,andsbasesyr. C6 Use the data in WAGE2.RAW for this exercise. (i) Consider the standard wage equation log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 u. State the null hypothesis that another year of general workforce experience has the same effect on log(wage) as another year of tenure with the current employer. (ii) Test the null hypothesis in part (i) against a two-sided alternative, at the 5% signifi- cance level, by constructing a 95% confidence interval. What do you conclude? C7 Refer to the example used in Section 4.4. You will use the data set TWOYEAR.RAW. (i) The variable phsrank is the person’s high school percentile. (A higher number is better. For example, 90 means you are ranked better than 90 percent of your graduating class.) Find the smallest, largest, and average phsrank in the sample. (ii) Add phsrank to equation (4.26) and report the OLS estimates in the usual form. Is phsrank statistically significant? How much is 10 percentage points of high school rank worth in terms of wage? (iii) Does adding phsrank to (4.26) substantively change the conclusions on the returns to two- and four-year colleges? Explain. (iv) Thedatasetcontainsavariablecalledid.Explainwhyifyouaddidtoequation (4.17) or (4.26) you expect it to be statistically insignificant. What is the two-sided p-value? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 166 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data C8 The data set 401KSUBS.RAW contains information on net financial wealth (nettfa), age of the survey respondent (age), annual family income (inc), family size ( fsize), and participation in certain pension plans for people in the United States. The wealth and income variables are both recorded in thousands of dollars. For this question, use only the data for single-person households (so fsize 􏱪 1). (i) How many single-person households are there in the data set? (ii) Use OLS to estimate the model nettfa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2age 􏱕 u, and report the results using the usual format. Be sure to use only the single-person households in the sample. Interpret the slope coefficients. Are there any surprises in the slope estimates? (iii) Does the intercept from the regression in part (ii) have an interesting meaning? Explain. (iv) Find the p-value for the test H0: 􏱬2 􏱪 1 against H1: 􏱬2 􏱷 1. Do you reject H0 at the 1% significance level? (v) If you do a simple regression of nettfa on inc, is the estimated coefficient on inc much different from the estimate in part (ii)? Why or why not? C9 Use the data in DISCRIM.RAW to answer this question. (See also Computer Exercise C8 in Chapter 3.) (i) Use OLS to estimate the model log( psoda) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1prpblck 􏱕 􏱬2 log(income) 􏱕 􏱬3 prppov 􏱕 u, and report the results in the usual form. Is 􏱬ˆ1 statistically different from zero at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative? What about at the 1% level? (ii) What is the correlation between log(income) and prppov? Is each variable statistically significant in any case? Report the two-sided p-values. (iii) To the regression in part (i), add the variable log(hseval). Interpret its coefficient and report the two-sided p-value for H0: 􏱬log(hseval) 􏱪 0. (iv) In the regression in part (iii), what happens to the individual statistical significance of log(income) and prppov? Are these variables jointly significant? (Compute a p-value.) What do you make of your answers? (v) Given the results of the previous regressions, which one would you report as most reliable in determining whether the racial makeup of a zip code influences local fast-food prices? C10 Use the data in ELEM94_95 to answer this question. The findings can be compared with those in Table 4.1. The dependent variable lavgsal is the log of average teacher sal- ary and bs is the ratio of average benefits to average salary (by school). (i) Run the simple regression of lavgsal on bs. Is the estimated slope statistically different from zero? Is it statistically different from 􏱦1? (ii) Add the variables lenrol and lstaff to the regression from part (i). What happens to the coefficient on bs? How does the situation compare with that in Table 4.1? (iii) How come the standard error on the bs coefficient is smaller in part (ii) than in part (i)? (Hint: What happens to the error variance versus multicollinearity when lenrol and lstaff are added?) (iv) How come the coefficient on lstaff is negative? Is it large in magnitude? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 4 Multiple Regression Analysis: Inference 167 (v) Now add the variable lunch to the regression. Holding other factors fixed, are teachers being compensated for teaching students from disadvantaged back- grounds? Explain. (vi) Overall, is the pattern of results that you find with ELEM94_95.RAW consistent with the pattern in Table 4.1? C11 Use the data in HTV.RAW to answer this question. See also Computer Exercise C10 in Chapter 3. (i) Estimate the regression model educ 􏱶 􏱹0 􏱕 􏱹1motheduc 􏱕 􏱹2 fatheduc 􏱕 􏱹3abil 􏱕 􏱹4abil2 􏱕 u by OLS and report the results in the usual form. Test the null hypothesis that educ is linearly related to abil against the alternative that the relationship is quadratic. (ii) Using the equation in part (i), test H0: 􏱹1 􏱶 􏱹2 against a two-sided alternative. What is the p-value of the test? (iii) Add the two college tuition variables to the regression from part (i) and determine whether they are jointly statistically significant. (iv) What is the correlation between tuit17 and tuit18? Explain why using the average of the tuition over the two years might be preferred to adding each separately. What happens when you do use the average? (v) Do the findings for the average tuition variable in part (iv) make sense when interpreted causally? What might be going on? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 168 In Chapters 3 and 4, we covered what are called finite sample, small sample, or exact properties of the OLS estimators in the population model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u. [5.1] For example, the unbiasedness of OLS (derived in Chapter 3) under the first four Gauss- Markov assumptions is a finite sample property because it holds for any sample size n (subject to the mild restriction that n must be at least as large as the total number of parameters in the regression model, k 􏱕 1). Similarly, the fact that OLS is the best linear unbiased estimator under the full set of Gauss-Markov assumptions (MLR.1 through MLR.5) is a finite sample property. In Chapter 4, we added the classical linear model Assumption MLR.6, which states that the error term u is normally distributed and independent of the explanatory variables. This allowed us to derive the exact sampling distributions of the OLS estimators (condi- tional on the explanatory variables in the sample). In particular, Theorem 4.1 showed that the OLS estimators have normal sampling distributions, which led directly to the t and F distributions for t and F statistics. If the error is not normally distributed, the distribution of a t statistic is not exactly t, and an F statistic does not have an exact F distribution for any sample size. In addition to finite sample properties, it is important to know the asymptotic properties or large sample properties of estimators and test statistics. These properties are not defined for a particular sample size; rather, they are defined as the sample size grows without bound. Fortunately, under the assumptions we have made, OLS has satisfactory large sample properties. One practically important finding is that even without the normality assumption (Assumption MLR.6), t and F statistics have approximately t and F distributions, at least in large sample sizes. We discuss this in more detail in Section 5.2, after we cover the consistency of OLS in Section 5.1. CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 169 Because the material in this chapter is more difficult to understand, and because one can conduct empirical work without a deep understanding of its contents, this chapter may be skipped. However, we will necessarily refer to large sample properties of OLS when we relax the homoskedasticity assumption in Chapter 8 and when we delve into estimation using time series data in Part 2. Furthermore, virtually all advanced econometric methods derive their justification using large-sample analysis, so readers who will continue into Part 3 should be familiar with the contents of this chapter. 5.1 Consistency Unbiasedness of estimators, although important, cannot always be achieved. For example, as we discussed in Chapter 3, the standard error of the regression, 􏱧ˆ, is not an unbiased esti- mator for 􏱧, the standard deviation of the error u in a multiple regression model. Although the OLS estimators are unbiased under MLR.1 through MLR.4, in Chapter 11 we will find that there are time series regressions where the OLS estimators are not unbiased. Further, in Part 3 of the text, we encounter several other estimators that are biased yet useful. Although not all useful estimators are unbiased, virtually all economists agree that consistency is a minimal requirement for an estimator. The Nobel Prize–winning econome- trician Clive W. J. Granger once remarked, “If you can’t get it right as n goes to infinity,you shouldn’t be in this business.” The implication is that, if your estimator of a particular population parameter is not consistent, then you are wasting your time. There are a few different ways to describe consistency. Formal definitions and results are given in Appendix C; here, we focus on an intuitive understanding. For concreteness, let 􏱬ˆj be the OLS estimator of 􏱬j for some j. For each n, 􏱬ˆj has a probability distribution (representing its possible values in different random samples of size n). Because 􏱬ˆj is unbiased under Assump- tions MLR.1 through MLR.4, this distribution has mean value 􏱬j. If this estimator is con- sistent, then the distribution of 􏱬ˆj becomes more and more tightly distributed around 􏱬j as the sample size grows. As n tends to infinity, the distribution of 􏱬ˆj collapses to the single point 􏱬j . In effect, this means that we can make our estimator arbitrarily close to 􏱬j if we can collect as much data as we want. This convergence is illustrated in Figure 5.1. Naturally, for any application, we have a fixed sample size, which is a major reason an asymptotic property such as consistency can be difficult to grasp. Consistency involves a thought experiment about what would happen as the sample size gets large (while, at the same time, we obtain numerous random samples for each sample size). If obtaining more and more data does not generally get us closer to the parameter value of interest, then we are using a poor estimation procedure. Conveniently, the same set of assumptions implies both unbiasedness and consistency of OLS. We summarize with a theorem. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. THEOREM 5.1 CONSISTENCY OF OLS Under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4, the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆj is consistent for 􏱬j, for all j 􏱪 0,1, ..., k. 170 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data FIGURE 5.1 Sampling distributions of 􏱬ˆ1 for sample sizes n1 􏱼 n2 􏱼 n3. fˆ n3 n2 n1 1 ˆ1 A general proof of this result is most easily developed using the matrix algebra methods described in Appendices D and E. But we can prove Theorem 5.1 without difficulty in the case of the simple regression model. We focus on the slope estimator, 􏱬ˆ1. The proof starts out the same as the proof of unbiasedness: we write down the formula for􏱬ˆ1, and then plug in yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 ui: 􏱹∑ i􏱪1 nn 􏱬ˆ 1 􏱪 􏱪􏱬1􏱕n􏱦1 (x 􏱦x-)u n􏱦1 ( x 􏱦 x- ) y i1 1i ( x 􏱦 x- ) 2 i1 1 􏱺􏱚􏱹∑ i􏱪1 i1 1i 􏱹 ∑ 􏱺􏱚􏱹 ∑ nn (x 􏱦x-)2, i􏱪1 i􏱪1 where dividing both the numerator and denominator by n does not change the expression but allows us to directly apply the law of large numbers. When we apply the law of large numbers to the averages in the second part of equation (5.2), we conclude that the numera- tor and denominator converge in probability to the population quantities, Cov(x1,u) and Var(x1), respectively. Provided that Var(x1) 􏱻 0—which is assumed in MLR.3—we can use the properties of probability limits (see Appendix C) to get plim 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 Cov(x1,u)/Var(x1) 􏱪 􏱬1 because Cov(x1,u) 􏱪 0. [5.3] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱺 [5.2] i1 1 􏱺 © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 171 We have used the fact, discussed in Chapters 2 and 3, that E(u􏰫x1) 􏱪 0 (Assumption MLR.4) implies that x1 and u are uncorrelated (have zero covariance). As a technical matter, to ensure that the probability limits exist, we should assume that Var(x1) 􏱷 􏱵 and Var(u) 􏱷 􏱵 (which means that their probability distributions are not too spread out), but we will not worry about cases where these assumptions might fail. The previous arguments, and equation (5.3) in particular, show that OLS is consistent in the simple regression case if we assume only zero correlation. This is also true in the general case. We now state this as an assumption. Assumption MLR.4􏲃 is weaker than Assumption MLR.4 in the sense that the latter implies the former. One way to characterize the zero conditional mean assumption, E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 0, is that any function of the explanatory variables is uncorrelated with u. Assumption MLR.4􏲃 requires only that each xj is uncorrelated with u (and that u has a zero mean in the population). In Chapter 2 we actually motivated the OLS estimator for simple regression using Assumption MLR.4􏲃, and the first order conditions for OLS in the multiple regression case, given in equations (3.13), are simply the sample analogs of the popula- tion zero correlation assumptions (and zero mean assumption). Therefore, in some ways, Assumption MLR.4􏲃 is more natural an assumption because it leads directly to the OLS estimates. Further, when we think about violations of Assumption MLR.4, we usually think in terms of Cov(xj, u) 􏱻 0 for some j. So how come we have used Assumption MLR.4 until now? There are two reasons, both of which we have touched on earlier. First, OLS turns out to be biased (but consistent) under Assumption MLR.4􏲃 if E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) depends on any of the xj . Because we have previously focused on finite sample, or exact, sampling properties of the OLS estimators, we have needed the stronger zero conditional mean assumption. Second, and probably more important, is that the zero conditional mean assumption means that we have properly modeled the population regression function (PRF). That is, under Assumption MLR.4 we can write E(y􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk, and so we can obtain partial effects of the explanatory variables on the average or expected value of y. If we instead only assume Assumption MLR.4􏲃, 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk need not represent the population regression function, and we face the possibility that some nonlinear functions of the xj, such as x2j, could be correlated with the error u. A situation like this means that we have neglected nonlinearities in the model that could help us better explain y; if we knew that, we would usually include such nonlinear functions. In other words, most of the time we hope to get a good estimate of the PRF, and so the zero condi- tional mean assumption is natural. Nevertheless, the weaker zero correlation assumption turns out to be useful in interpreting OLS estimation of a linear model as providing the best linear approximation to the PRF. It is also used in more advanced settings, such as in Chapter 15, where we have no interest in modeling a PRF. For further discussion of this somewhat subtle point, see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 4). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Assumption MLR.4􏲃 Zero Mean and Zero Correlation E(u) 􏱪 0 and Cov(xj,u) 􏱪 0, for j 􏱪 1, 2, ..., k. 172 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Deriving the Inconsistency in OLS Just as failure of E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 0 causes bias in the OLS estimators, correlation between u and any of x1, x2, ..., xk generally causes all of the OLS estimators to be inconsistent. This simple but important observation is often summarized as: if the error is correlated with any of the independent variables, then OLS is biased and inconsistent. This is very unfortunate because it means that any bias persists as the sample size grows. In the simple regression case, we can obtain the inconsistency from the first part of equation (5.3), which holds whether or not u and x1 are uncorrelated. The inconsistency in 􏱬ˆ1 (sometimes loosely called the asymptotic bias) is plim􏱬ˆ1 􏱦􏱬1 􏱪Cov(x1,u)/Var(x1). [5.4] Because Var(x1) 􏱰 0, the inconsistency in 􏱬ˆ1 is positive if x1 and u are positively correlated, and the inconsistency is negative if x1 and u are negatively correlated. If the covariance between x1 and u is small relative to the variance in x1, the inconsistency can be negligible; unfortunately, we cannot even estimate how big the covariance is because u is unobserved. We can use (5.4) to derive the asymptotic analog of the omitted variable bias (see Table 3.2 in Chapter 3). Suppose the true model, y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕v, satisfies the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions. Then v has a zero mean and is uncorre- lated with x1 and x2. If 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, and 􏱬ˆ2 denote the OLS estimators from the regression of y on x1 and x2, then Theorem 5.1 implies that these estimators are consistent. If we omit x2 from the regression and do the simple regression of y on x1, then u 􏱪 􏱬2 x2 􏱕 v. Let 􏱬 ̃ 1 denote the simple regression slope estimator. Then where plim 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2􏱛1, [5.5] 􏱛1 􏱪Cov(x1,x2)/Var(x1). [5.6] Thus, for practical purposes, we can view the inconsistency as being the same as the bias. The difference is that the inconsistency is expressed in terms of the population variance of x1 and the population covariance between x1 and x2, while the bias is based on their sample counterparts (because we condition on the values of x1 and x2 in the sample). If x1 and x2 are uncorrelated (in the population), then 􏱛1 􏱪 0, and 􏱬 ̃1 is a consistent estimator of 􏱬1 (although not necessarily unbiased). If x2 has a positive partial effect on y, so that 􏱬2 􏱰 0, and x1 and x2 are positively correlated, so that 􏱛1 􏱰 0, then the inconsis- tency in 􏱬 ̃1 is positive. And so on. We can obtain the direction of the inconsistency or asymptotic bias from Table 3.2. If the covariance between x1 and x2 is small relative to the variance of x1, the inconsistency can be small. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 173 EXAMPLE 5.1 HOUSING PRICES AND DISTANCE FROM AN INCINERATOR Let y denote the price of a house ( price), let x1 denote the distance from the house to a new trash incinerator (distance), and let x2 denote the “quality” of the house (quality). The vari- able quality is left vague so that it can include things like size of the house and lot, number of bedrooms and bathrooms, and intangibles such as attractiveness of the neighborhood. If the incinerator depresses house prices, then 􏱬1 should be positive: everything else being equal, a house that is farther away from the incinerator is worth more. By definition, 􏱬2 is positive since higher quality houses sell for more, other factors being equal. If the incin- erator was built farther away, on average, from better homes, then distance and quality are positively correlated, and so 􏱛1 􏱰 0. A simple regression of price on distance [or log(price) on log(distance)] will tend to overestimate the effect of the incinerator: 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2􏱛1 􏱰 􏱬1. An important point about inconsis- tency in OLS estimators is that, by definition, the problem does not go away by adding more observations to the sample. If anything, the problem gets worse with more data: the OLS estimator gets closer and closer to 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2 􏱛1 as the sample size grows. Deriving the sign and magnitude of the inconsistency in the general k regressor case is harder, just as deriving the bias is more difficult. We need to remember that if we have the model in equation (5.1) where, say, x1 is correlated with u but the other independent variables are uncorrelated with u, all of the OLS estimators are generally inconsistent. For example, in the k 􏱪 2 case, y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕u, suppose that x2 and u are uncorrelated but x1 and u are correlated. Then the OLS estimators 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 will generally both be inconsistent. (The intercept will also be inconsistent.) The inconsistency in 􏱬ˆ2 arises when x1 and x2 are correlated, as is usually the case. If x1 and x2 are uncorrelated, then any correlation between x1 and u does not result in the inconsistency of 􏱬ˆ2: plim 􏱬ˆ2 􏱪 􏱬2. Further, the inconsistency in 􏱬ˆ1 is the same as in (5.4). The same statement holds in the general case: if x1 is correlated with u, but x1 and u are uncorrelated with the other independent variables, then only 􏱬ˆ1 is inconsistent, and the inconsistency is given by (5.4). The general case is very similar to the omitted variable case in Section 3A.4 of Appendix 3A. 5.2 Asymptotic Normality and Large Sample Inference Consistency of an estimator is an important property, but it alone does not allow us to perform statistical inference. Simply knowing that the estimator is getting closer to the population value as the sample size grows does not allow us to test hypotheses about the parameters. For testing, we need the sampling distribution of the OLS estimators. Under the classical linear model assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6, Theorem 4.1 shows that the sampling distributions are normal. This result is the basis for deriving the t and F distributions that we use so often in applied econometrics. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 5.1 Suppose that the model score 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1skipped 􏱕 􏱬2 priGPA 􏱕 satisfies the first four Gauss-Markov assump- tions, where score is score on a final exam, skipped is number of classes skipped, and priGPA is GPA prior to the current semester. If 􏱬~1 is from the simple regression of score on skipped, what is the direction of the asymp- totic bias in 􏱬~1? 174 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The exact normality of the OLS estimators hinges crucially on the normality of the distribution of the error, u, in the population. If the errors u1, u2, ..., un are random draws from some distribution other than the normal, the 􏱬ˆj will not be normally distributed, which means that the t statistics will not have t distributions and the F statistics will not have F distributions. This is a potentially serious problem because our inference hinges on being able to obtain critical values or p-values from the t or F distributions. Recall that Assumption MLR.6 is equivalent to saying that the distribution of y given x1, x2, ..., xk is normal. Because y is observed and u is not, in a particular application, it is much easier to think about whether the distribution of y is likely to be normal. In fact, we have already seen a few examples where y definitely cannot have a conditional normal distribution. A normally distributed random variable is symmetrically distributed about its mean, it can take on any positive or negative value (but with zero probability), and more than 95% of the area under the distribution is within two standard deviations. In Example 3.5, we estimated a model explaining the number of arrests of young men during a particular year (narr86). In the population, most men are not arrested during the year, and the vast majority are arrested one time at the most. (In the sample of 2,725 men in the data set CRIME1.RAW, fewer than 8% were arrested more than once during 1986.) Because narr86 takes on only two values for 92% of the sample, it cannot be close to being normally distributed in the population. In Example 4.6, we estimated a model explaining participation percentages ( prate) in 401(k) pension plans. The frequency distribution (also called a histogram) in Figure 5.2 shows FIGURE 5.2 Histogram of prate using the data in 401K.RAW. .8 .6 .4 .2 0 0 10 20 30 40 50 60 70 80 90 100 participation rate (in percentage form) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 proportion in cell CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 175 that the distribution of prate is heavily skewed to the right, rather than being normally distributed. In fact, over 40% of the observations on prate are at the value 100, indicat- ing 100% participation. This violates the normality assumption even conditional on the explanatory variables. We know that normality plays no role in the unbiasedness of OLS, nor does it affect the conclusion that OLS is the best linear unbiased estimator under the Gauss-Markov assumptions. But exact inference based on t and F statistics requires MLR.6. Does this mean that, in our analysis of prate in Example 4.6, we must abandon the t statistics for determining which variables are statistically significant? Fortunately, the answer to this question is no. Even though the yi are not from a normal distribution, we can use the central limit theorem from Appendix C to conclude that the OLS estimators satisfy asymptotic normality, which means they are approximately normally distributed in large enough sample sizes. THEOREM 5.2 ASYMPTOTIC NORMALITY OF OLS Under the Gauss-Markov Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5, __ˆ 22 22 (i) 􏱯 n ( 􏱬j 􏱦 􏱬j) ~a Normal(0,􏱧 /aj ), where 􏱧 /aj 􏱰 0 is the asymptotic variance of 􏱹∑ from regressing xj on the other independent variables. We say that 􏱬ˆj is asymptotically __ˆ 2 􏱦1 n 2 􏱯 n(􏱬j 􏱦 􏱬j); for the slope coefficients, aj 􏱪 plim n i􏱪1rˆ , where the rˆ are the residuals normally distributed (see Appendix C); (ii) 􏱧ˆ 2 is a consistent estimator of 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(u); (iii) For each j, and where se(􏱬ˆj) is the usual OLS standard error. 􏱺 (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬ˆj) ~a Normal(0,1) (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) ~a Normal(0,1), [5.7] ij ij The proof of asymptotic normality is somewhat complicated and is sketched in the appendix for the simple regression case. Part (ii) follows from the law of large numbers, and part (iii) follows from parts (i) and (ii) and the asymptotic properties discussed in Appendix C. Theorem 5.2 is useful because the normality assumption MLR.6 has been dropped; the only restriction on the distribution of the error is that it has finite variance, something we will always assume. We have also assumed zero conditional mean (MLR.4) and homo- skedasticity of u (MLR.5). In trying to understand the meaning of Theorem 5.2, it is important to keep separate the notions of the population distribution of the error term, u, and the sampling distributions of the 􏱬ˆj as the sample size grows. A common mistake is to think that something is happen- ing to the distribution of u—namely, that it is getting “closer” to normal—as the sample size grows. But remember that the population distribution is immutable and has nothing to do with the sample size. For example, we previously discussed narr86, the number of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 176 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data times a young man is arrested during the year 1986. The nature of this variable—it takes on small, nonnegative integer values—is fixed in the population. Whether we sample 10 men or 1,000 men from this population obviously has no effect on the population distribution. What Theorem 5.2 says is that, regardless of the population distribution of u, the OLS estimators, when properly standardized, have approximate standard normal distributions. This approximation comes about by the central limit theorem because the OLS estimators involve—in a complicated way—the use of sample averages. Effectively, the sequence of distributions of averages of the underlying errors is approaching normality for virtually any population distribution. ˆ Notice how the standardized 􏱬j has an asymptotic standard normal distribution whether we divide the difference 􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j by sd (􏱬ˆj) (which we do not observe because it depends on 􏱧) or by se(􏱬ˆj) (which we can compute from our data because it depends on 􏱧ˆ). In other words, from an asymptotic point of view it does not matter that we have to replace 􏱧 with 􏱧ˆ. Of course, replacing 􏱧 with 􏱧ˆ affects the exact distribution of the standardized 􏱬ˆj. We just saw in Chapter 4 that under the classical linear model assumptions, (􏱬ˆj − 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬ˆj) has an exact Normal(0,1) distribution and (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) has an exact tn􏱦k􏱦1 distribution. How should we use the result in equaton (5.7)? It may seem one consequence is that, if we are going to appeal to large-sample analysis, we should now use the standard normal distribution for inference rather than the t distribution. But from a practical perspective it is just as legitimate to write (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) ~a tn􏱦k􏱦1 􏱪 tdf, [5.8] because tdf approaches the Normal(0,1), distribution as df gets large. Because we know under the CLM the tn􏱦k􏱦1 holds exactly, it makes sense to treat (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) as a tn􏱦k􏱦1 random variable generally, even when MLR.6 does not hold. Equation (5.8) tells us that t testing and the construction of confidence intervals are carried out exactly as under the classical linear model assumptions. This means that our analysis of dependent variables like prate and narr86 does not have to change at all if the Gauss-Markov assumptions hold: in both cases, we have at least 1,500 observations, which is certainly enough to justify the approximation of the central limit theorem. If the sample size is not very large, then the t distribution can be a poor approximation to the distribution of the t statistics when u is not normally distributed. Unfortunately, there are no general prescriptions on how big the sample size must be before the approximation is good enough. Some econometricians think that n 􏱪 30 is satisfactory, but this cannot be sufficient for all possible distributions of u. Depending on the distribution of u, more observations may be necessary before the central limit theorem delivers a useful approxi- mation. Further, the quality of the approximation depends not just on n, but on the df, n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1: With more independent variables in the model, a larger sample size is usually needed to use the t approximation. Methods for inference with small degrees of freedom and nonnormal errors are outside the scope of this text. We will simply use the t statistics as we always have without worrying about the normality assumption. It is very important to see that Theorem 5.2 does require the homoskedasticity assumption (along with the zero conditional mean assumption). If Var(y􏰫x) is not constant, the usual t statistics and confidence intervals are invalid no matter how large the sample size is; the central limit theorem does not bail us out when it comes to heteroskedasticity. For this reason, we devote all of Chapter 8 to discussing what can be done in the presence of heteroskedasticity. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 177 One conclusion of Theorem 5.2 is that 􏱧ˆ2 is a consistent estimator of 􏱧2; we already know from Theorem 3.3 that 􏱧ˆ2 is unbiased for 􏱧2 under the Gauss-Markov assump- tions. The consistency implies that 􏱧ˆ is a consistent estimator of 􏱧, which is important in establishing the asymptotic normality result in equation (5.7). ˆ Remember that 􏱧ˆ appears in the standard error for each 􏱬j . In fact, the estimated variance of 􏱬ˆj is ˆ2 􏱾 _____􏱧ˆ______, [5.9] Var(􏱬j) 􏱪 SSTj(1 􏱦 R2j ) where SSTj is the total sum of squares of xj in the sample, and R2j is the R-squared from regressing xj on all of the other in- dependent variables. In Section 3.4, we studied each component of (5.9), which we will now expound on in the context of asymptotic analysis. As the sample size grows, 􏱧ˆ2 converges in probability to the constant 􏱧2. Further, R2j approaches a number strictly between zero and unity (so that 1 􏱦 R2j converges to some number between zero and one). The sample variance of xj is SSTj /n, and so SSTj /n converges to Var(xj) as the sample size grows. This means that SSTj grows at approximately the same rate as the sample size: SSTj 􏱴 n􏱧2j, where 􏱧2j is the population variance of xj. When we combine these facts, we find that 􏱾Var(􏱬ˆj) shrinks to zero at the rate of 1/n; this is why larger sample sizes are better. When u is not normally distributed, the square root of (5.9) is sometimes called the asymptotic standard error, and t statistics are called asymptotic t statistics. Because these are the same quantities we dealt with in Chapter 4, we will just call them standard errors and t statistics, with the understanding that sometimes they have only large-sample justification. A similar comment holds for an asymptotic confidence interval constructed from the asymptotic standard error. Using the preceding argument about the estimated variance, we can write where cj is a positive constant that does not depend on the sample size. In fact, the constant cj can be shown to be c 􏱪 ____􏱧____ j _____ 􏱧 j √ 1 􏱦 􏰴 2j where 􏱧 􏱪 sd(u), 􏱧j􏱪 sd(xj), and 􏰴2j is the population R-squared from regressing xj on the otherˆexplanatory variables. Just like studying equation (5.9) to see which variables affect Var(􏱬j) under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, we can use this expression for cj to study the impact of larger error standard deviation (􏱧), more population variation in xj (􏱧j), and multicollinearity in the population (􏰴2j ). Equation (5.10) is only an approximation, but it is a useful rule of thumb: standard errors can be expected to shrink at a rate that is the inverse of the square root of the sample size. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 5.2 In a regression model with a large sample size, what is an approximate 95% confi- dence interval for 􏱬ˆj under MLR.1 through MLR.5? We call this an asymptotic confi- dence interval. ˆ __ se(􏱬j) 􏱴 cj /􏱯 n, [5.10] 178 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 5.2 STANDARD ERRORS IN A BIRTH WEIGHT EQUATION We use the data in BWGHT.RAW to estimate a relationship where log of birth weight is the dependent variable, and cigarettes smoked per day (cigs) and log of family income are independent variables. The total number of observations is 1,388. Using the first half of the observations (694), the standard error for 􏱬ˆcigs is about .0013. The standard error using all of the observations is about .00086. The ratio of the latter standard error to the former _________ is .00086/.0013 􏱴 .662. This is pretty close to 􏱯694/1,388 􏱴 .707, the ratio obtained from the approximation in (5.10). In other words, equation (5.10) implies that the standard error using the larger sample size should be about 70.7% of the standard error using the smaller sample. This percentage is pretty close to the 66.2% we actually compute from the ratio of the standard errors. The asymptotic normality of the OLS estimators also implies that the F statistics have approximate F distributions in large sample sizes. Thus, for testing exclusion restrictions or other multiple hypotheses, nothing changes from what we have done before. Other Large Sample Tests: The Lagrange Multiplier Statistic Once we enter the realm of asymptotic analysis, other test statistics can be used for hypothesis testing. For most purposes, there is little reason to go beyond the usual t and F statistics: as we just saw, these statistics have large sample justification without the nor- mality assumption. Nevertheless, sometimes it is useful to have other ways to test multiple exclusion restrictions, and we now cover the Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistic, which has achieved some popularity in modern econometrics. The name “Lagrange multiplier statistic” comes from constrained optimization, a topic beyond the scope of this text. [See Davidson and MacKinnon (1993).] The name score statistic—which also comes from optimization using calculus—is used as well. Fortunately, in the linear regression framework, it is simple to motivate the LM statistic without delving into complicated mathematics. The form of the LM statistic we derive here relies on the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the same assumptions that justify the F statistic in large samples. We do not need the normality assumption. To derive the LM statistic, consider the usual multiple regression model with k inde- pendent variables: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u. [5.11] We would like to test whether, say, the last q of these variables all have zero population parameters: the null hypothesis is H0: 􏱬k􏱦q􏱕1 􏱪 0, ..., 􏱬k 􏱪 0, [5.12] which puts q exclusion restrictions on the model (5.11). As with F testing, the alternative to (5.12) is that at least one of the parameters is different from zero. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 179 The LM statistic requires estimation of the restricted model only. Thus, assume that we have run the regression y 􏱪 􏱬 ̃0 􏱕 􏱬 ̃1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬 ̃k􏱦qxk􏱦q 􏱕 ̃u, [5.13] where “~” indicates that the estimates are from the restricted model. In particular, u ̃ indi- cates the residuals from the restricted model. (As always, this is just shorthand to indicate that we obtain the restricted residual for each observation in the sample.) If the omitted variables xk􏱦q􏱕1 through xk truly have zero population coefficients, then, at least approximately, u ̃ should be uncorrelated with each of these variables in the sample. This suggests running a regression of these residuals on those independent vari- ables excluded under H0, which is almost what the LM test does. However, it turns out that, to get a usable test statistic, we must include all of the independent variables in the regression. (We must include all regressors because, in general, the omitted regressors in the restricted model are correlated with the regressors that appear in the restricted model.) Thus, we run the regression of u ̃ on x1, x2, ..., xk. [5.14] This is an example of an auxiliary regression, a regression that is used to compute a test statistic but whose coefficients are not of direct interest. How can we use the regression output from (5.14) to test (5.12)? If (5.12) is true, the R-squared from (5.14) should be “close” to zero, subject to sampling error, because u ̃ will be approximately uncorrelated with all the independent variables. The question, as always with hypothesis testing, is how to determine when the statistic is large enough to reject the null hypothesis at a chosen significance level. It turns out that, under the null hypothesis, the sample size multiplied by the usual R-squared from the auxiliary regression (5.14) is distributed asymptotically as a chi-square random variable with q degrees of freedom. This leads to a simple procedure for testing the joint significance of a set of q independent variables. The Lagrange Multiplier Statistic for q Exclusion Restrictions: (i) Regress y on the restricted set of independent variables and save the residuals, u ̃. (ii) Regress u ̃ on all of the independent variables and obtain the R-squared, say, R2u (to distin- guish it from the R-squareds obtained with y as the dependent variable). (iii) Compute LM 􏱪 nRu2 [the sample size times the R-squared obtained from step (ii)]. (iv) Compare LM to the appropriate critical value, c, in a 􏱚2q distribution; if LM 􏱰 c, the null hypothesis is rejected. Even better, obtain the p-value as the probability that a 􏱚2q random variable exceeds the value of the test statistic. If the p-value is less than the desired significance level, then H0 is rejected. If not, we fail to reject H0. The rejection rule is essentially the same as for F testing. Because of its form, the LM statistic is sometimes referred to as the n-R-squared statistic. Unlike with the F statistic, the degrees of freedom in the unrestricted model plays no role in carrying out the LM test. All that matters is the number of restrictions being tested (q), the size of the auxiliary R-squared (Ru2), and the sample size (n). The df in the unrestricted model plays no role because of the asymptotic nature of the LM statistic. But we must be sure to multiply R2u by the sample size to obtain LM; a seemingly low value of the R-squared can still lead to joint significance if n is large. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 180 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Before giving an example, a word of caution is in order. If in step (i), we mistak- enly regress y on all of the independent variables and obtain the residuals from this unrestricted regression to be used in step (ii), we do not get an interesting statistic: the resulting R-squared will be exactly zero! This is because OLS chooses the estimates so that the residuals are uncorrelated in samples with all included independent variables [see equations in (3.13)]. Thus, we can only test (5.12) by regressing the restricted re- siduals on all of the independent variables. (Regressing the restricted residuals on the restricted set of independent variables will also produce R2 􏱪 0.) EXAMPLE 5.3 ECONOMIC MODEL OF CRIME We illustrate the LM test by using a slight extension of the crime model from Example 3.5: narr86 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1pcnv 􏱕 􏱬2avgsen 􏱕 􏱬3tottime 􏱕 􏱬4ptime86 􏱕 􏱬5qemp86 􏱕 u, where narr86 􏱪 pcnv 􏱪 avgsen 􏱪 tottime 􏱪 ptime86 􏱪 qemp86 􏱪 the number of times a man was arrested. the proportion of prior arrests leading to conviction. average sentence served from past convictions. total time the man has spent in prison prior to 1986 since reaching the age of 18. months spent in prison in 1986. number of quarters in 1986 during which the man was legally employed. We use the LM statistic to test the null hypothesis that avgsen and tottime have no effect on narr86 once the other factors have been controlled for. In step (i), we estimate the restricted model by regressing narr86 on pcnv, ptime86, and qemp86; the variables avgsen and tottime are excluded from this regression. We obtain the residuals u ̃ from this regression, 2,725 of them. Next, we run the regression of u ̃ on pcnv, ptime86, qemp86, avgsen, and tottime; [5.15] as always, the order in which we list the independent variables is irrelevant. This second regression produces R2u, which turns out to be about .0015. This may seem small, but we must multiply it by n to get the LM statistic: LM 􏱪 2,725(.0015) 􏱴 4.09. The 10% critical value in a chi-square distribution with two degrees of freedom is about 4.61 (rounded to two decimal places; see Table G.4). Thus, we fail to reject the null hypothesis that 􏱬avgsen 􏱪 0 and 􏱬tottime 􏱪 0 at the 10% level. The p-value is P(􏱚2 􏱰 4.09) 􏱴 .129, so we would reject H0 at the 15% level. As a comparison, the F test for joint significance of avgsen and tottime yields a p-value of about .131, which is pretty close to that obtained using the LM statistic. This is not sur- prising since, asymptotically, the two statistics have the same probability of Type I error. (That is, they reject the null hypothesis with the same frequency when the null is true.) As the previous example suggests, with a large sample, we rarely see important dis- crepancies between the outcomes of LM and F tests. We will use the F statistic for the most part because it is computed routinely by most regression packages. But you should be aware of the LM statistic as it is used in applied work. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 181 One final comment on the LM statistic. As with the F statistic, we must be sure to use the same observations in steps (i) and (ii). If data are missing for some of the independent variables that are excluded under the null hypothesis, the residuals from step (i) should be obtained from a regression on the reduced data set. 5.3 Asymptotic Efficiency of OLS We know that, under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the OLS estimators are best linear unbiased. OLS is also asymptotically efficient among a certain class of estimators under the Gauss-Markov assumptions. A general treatment requires matrix algebra and advanced asymptotic analysis. First, we describe the result in the simple regression case. In the model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x􏱕u, [5.16] u has a zero conditional mean under MLR.4: E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0. This opens up a variety of con- sistent estimators for 􏱬0 and 􏱬1; as usual, we focus on the slope parameter, 􏱬1. Let g(x) be any function of x; for example, g(x) 􏱪 x2 or g(x) 􏱪 1/(1 􏱕 􏰫x􏰫). Then u is uncorrelated with g(x) (see Property CE.5 in Appendix B). Let zi 􏱪 g(xi) for all observations i. Then the estimator 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 i􏱪1 􏱺 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪􏱬1 􏱕 n􏱦1 􏱹 ∑ i􏱪1 (z 􏱦z-)u n􏱦1 (z 􏱦z-)x . 􏱹∑ (z 􏱦z-)y ii (z 􏱦z-)x [5.17] nn is consistent for 􏱬1, provided g(x) and x are correlated. [Remember, it is possible that g(x) and x are uncorrelated because correlation measures linear dependence.] To see this, we can plug in yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi 􏱕 ui and write 􏱬 ̃1 as ii 􏱺 [5.18] Now, we can apply the law of large numbers to the numerator and denominator, which con- verge in probability to Cov(z,u) and Cov(z,x), respectively. Provided that Cov(z,x) 􏱻 0— so that z and x are correlated—we have plim 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 Cov(z,u)/Cov(z,x) 􏱪 􏱬1, because Cov(z,u) 􏱪 0 under MLR.4. ̃ 􏱺􏱚􏱹∑ i􏱪1 nn It is more difficult to show that 􏱬1 is asymptotically normal. Nevertheless, using __ ̃ arguments similar to those in the appendix, it can be shown that 􏱯 n(􏱬1􏱦 􏱬1) is asymptoti- cally normal with mean zero and asymptotic variance 􏱧2Var(z)/[Cov(z, x)]2. The asymptotic variance of the OLS estimator is obtained when z 􏱪 x, in which case, Cov(z, x) 􏱪 Cov(x, x) 􏱪 __ˆ ˆ Var(x). Therefore, the asymptotic variance of 􏱯 n ( 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1), where 􏱬1 is the OLS estimator, is 􏱧2Var(x)/[Var(x)]2 􏱪 􏱧2/Var(x). Now, the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality (see Appendix B.4) 2 __ impliesthat[Cov(z,x)] 􏰯Var(z)Var(x),whichimpliesthattheasymptoticvarianceof􏱯n ˆ __ ̃ ( 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1) is no larger than that of 􏱯 n ( 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1). We have shown in the simple regression case that, under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the OLS estimator has a smaller Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱺􏱚􏱹 ∑ i􏱪1 ii ii 182 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data asymptotic variance than any estimator of the form (5.17). [The estimator in (5.17) is an example of an instrumental variables estimator, which we will study extensively in Chapter 15.] If the homoskedasticity assumption fails, then there are estimators of the form (5.17) that have a smaller asymptotic variance than OLS. We will see this in Chapter 8. The general case is similar but much more difficult mathematically. In the k regres- sor case, the class of consistent estimators is obtained by generalizing the OLS first order conditions: ∑n ̃ ̃ ̃ gj(xi)(yi 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1xi1 􏱦 ... 􏱦 􏱬k xik) 􏱪 0, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k, [5.19] i􏱪1 where gj(xi) denotes any function of all explanatory variables for observation i. As can be seen by comparing (5.19) with the OLS first order conditions in (3.13), we obtain the OLS estimators when g0(xi) 􏱪 1 and gj(xi) 􏱪 xij for j 􏱪 1, 2, ..., k. The class of estimators in (5.19) is infinite, because we can use any functions of the xij that we want. Proving consistency of the estimators in (5.19), let alone showing they are asymp- totically normal, is mathematically difficult. See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5). Summary The claims underlying the material in this chapter are fairly technical, but their practical im- plications are straightforward. We have shown that the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions imply that OLS is consistent. Furthermore, all of the methods of testing and constructing con- fidence intervals that we learned in Chapter 4 are approximately valid without assuming that the errors are drawn from a normal distribution (equivalently, the distribution of y given the explanatory variables is not normal). This means that we can apply OLS and use previous methods for an array of applications where the dependent variable is not even approximately normally distributed. We also showed that the LM statistic can be used instead of the F statistic for testing exclusion restrictions. Before leaving this chapter, we should note that examples such as Example 5.3 may very well have problems that do require special attention. For a variable such as narr86, which is zero or one for most men in the population, a linear model may not be able to adequately cap- ture the functional relationship between narr86 and the explanatory variables. Moreover, even if a linear model does describe the expected value of arrests, heteroskedasticity might be a problem. Problems such as these are not mitigated as the sample size grows, and we will return to them in later chapters. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. THEOREM 5.3 ASYMPTOTIC EFFICIENCY OF OLS Under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, let 􏱬 ̃j denote estimators that solve equations of the form (5.19) and let 􏱬ˆj denote the OLS estimators. Then for j 􏱪 0, 1, 2, ..., k, the OLS esti- __ ˆ __ ̃ mators have the smallest asymptotic variances: Avar 􏱯 n ( 􏱬j 􏱦 􏱬j) 􏰯 Avar 􏱯 n ( 􏱬j 􏱦 􏱬j). Key Terms Asymptotic Bias Asymptotic Confidence Interval Asymptotic Normality Asymptotic Properties Asymptotic Standard Error Problems Asymptotic t Statistics Asymptotic Variance Asymptotically Efficient Auxiliary Regression Consistency Inconsistency Lagrange Multiplier (LM) Statistic Large Sample Properties n-R-Squared Statistic Score Statistic CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 183 1 In the simple regression model under MLR.1 through MLR.4, we argued that the slope es- timator, 􏱬ˆ1, is consistent for 􏱬1. Using 􏱬ˆ0 􏱪 y- 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1x ̄1, show that plim 􏱬ˆ0 􏱪 􏱬0. [You need to use the consistency of 􏱬ˆ1 and the law of large numbers, along with the fact that 􏱬0 􏱪 E(y) 􏱪 􏱬1E(x1).] 2 Suppose that the model pctstck 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 funds 􏱕 􏱬2risktol 􏱕 u satisfies the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions, where pctstck is the percentage of a worker’s pension invested in the stock market, funds is the number of mutual funds that the worker can choose from, and risktol is some measure of risk tolerance (larger risktol means the person has a higher tolerance for risk). If funds and risktol are positively cor- related, what is the inconsistency in 􏱬 ̃1, the slope coefficient in the simple regression of pctstck on funds? 3 ThedatasetSMOKE.RAWcontainsinformationonsmokingbehaviorandothervariables for a random sample of single adults from the United States. The variable cigs is the (aver- age) number of cigarettes smoked per day. Do you think cigs has a normal distribution in the U.S. adult population? Explain. 4 Inthesimpleregressionmodel(5.16),underthefirstfourGauss-Markovassumptions,we showed that estimators of the form (5.17) are consistent for the slope, 􏱬1. Given such an estimator, define an estimator of 􏱬0 by 􏱬 ̃ 0 􏱪 y- 􏱦 􏱬 ̃ 1x ̄ . Show that plim 􏱬 ̃ 0 􏱪 􏱬0. Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in WAGE1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate the equation wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 u. Save the residuals and plot a histogram. (ii) Repeat part (i), but with log(wage) as the dependent variable. (iii) Would you say that Assumption MLR.6 is closer to being satisfied for the level- level model or the log-level model? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 184 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data C2 Use the data in GPA2.RAW for this exercise. (i) Using all 4,137 observations, estimate the equation colgpa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1hsperc 􏱕 􏱬2sat 􏱕 u and report the results in standard form. (ii) Reestimate the equation in part (i), using the first 2,070 observations. (iii) Find the ratio of the standard errors on hsperc from parts (i) and (ii). Compare this with the result from (5.10). C3 In equation (4.42) of Chapter 4, using the data set BWGHT.RAW, compute the LM sta- tistic for testing whether motheduc and fatheduc are jointly significant. In obtaining the residuals for the restricted model, be sure that the restricted model is estimated using only those observations for which all variables in the unrestricted model are available (see Example 4.9). C4 Several statistics are commonly used to detect nonnormality in underlying population distributions. Here we will study one that measures the amount of skewness in a dis- tribution. Recall that any normally distributed random variable is symmetric about its mean; therefore, if we standardize a symmetrically distributed random variable, say z 􏱪 (y 􏱦 􏱙y)/􏱧y, where 􏱙y 􏱪 E(y) and 􏱧y 􏱪 sd(y), then z has mean zero, variance one, and E(z3) 􏱪 0. Given a sample of data {yi : i 􏱪 1, ..., n}, we can standardize yi in the sample by using zi 􏱪 (yi 􏱦 􏱙ˆy)/􏱧ˆy, where 􏱙ˆy is the sample mean and 􏱧ˆy is the sample standard deviation. (We ignore the fact that the∑se are estimates based on the sample.) A sample statistic that measures skewness is n−1 n z3, or where n is replaced with (n i 􏱦 1) as a degrees-of-freedom adjustment. If y has a normal distribution in the popula- tion, the skewness measure in the sample for the standardized values should not differ significantly from zero. (i) First use the data set 401KSUBS.RAW, keeping only observations with fsize 􏱪 1. Find the skewness measure for inc. Do the same for log(inc). Which variable has more skewness and therefore seems less likely to be normally distributed? (ii) Next use BWGHT2.RAW. Find the skewness measures for bwght and log(bwght). What do you conclude? (iii) Evaluate the following statement: “The logarithmic transformation always makes a positive variable look more normally distributed.” (iv) If we are interested in the normality assumption in the context of regression, should we be evaluating the unconditional distributions of y and log(y)? Explain. C5 Consider the analysis in Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 4 using the data in HTV.RAW, where educ is the dependent variable in a regression. (i) How many different values are taken on by educ in the sample? Does educ have a continuous distribution? (ii) Plot a histogram of educ with a normal distribution overlay. Does the distribution of educ appear anything close to normal? (iii) Which of the CLM assumptions seems clearly violated in the model educ 􏱪 􏱹0 􏱕􏱹1motheduc 􏱕􏱹2 fatheduc 􏱕 􏱹3abil 􏱕 􏱹4abil2 􏱕u? How does this violation change the statistical inference procedures carried out in Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 4? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i􏱪1 CHAPTER 5 Multiple Regression Analysis: OLS Asymptotics 185 APPENDIX 5A Asymptotic Normality of OLS We sketch a proof of the asymptotic normality of OLS [Theorem 5.2(i)] in the simple regression case. Write the simple regression model as in equation (5.16). Then, by the usual algebra of simple regression, we can write 2􏱶􏱦1/2∑n -􏲄 ii __ ˆ 􏱯n(􏱬1􏱦􏱬1)􏱪(1/sx)n (x􏱦x)u , where we use sx2 to denote the sample variance of {xi: i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}. By the law of large numbers (see Appendix C), sx2 􏱽p 􏱧x2 􏱪 Var(x). Assumption MLR.3 rules out no perfect collinearity, which means that Var(x) ∑􏱰 0 (xi varies in the sam∑ple, and therefore x is not constan∑t in the population). Next, n􏱦1/2 n (x 􏱦 x-)u 􏱪 n􏱦1/2 n (x 􏱦 μ)u 􏱕 i􏱪1 i i i􏱪1 i i - 􏱦1/2 n ∑ (μ 􏱦 x)[n u], where μ 􏱪 E(x) is the population mean of x. Now {u} is a i sequence of i.i.d. random variables with mean zero and variance 􏱧2, and so n􏱦1/2 n u i􏱪1 i i􏱪1 i converges to the Normal(0,􏱧2) distribution as n 􏱽 􏱵; this is just the central limit theorem from Appendix C. By the law of large numbers, plim(μ 􏱦 x-) 􏱪 0. A standard result in as- ymptotic theory is that if plim(wn) 􏱪 0 and zn has an asymptotic normal distribution, then plim(wnzn) 􏱪 0. [S∑ee Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 3) for more discussion.] This implies that(μ􏱦x-)[n􏱦1/2 n u]haszeroplim.Next,{(x 􏱦μ)u:i􏱪1,2,...}isanindefinite i􏱪1i ii sequence of i.i.d. random variables with mean zero—because u and x are uncorrelated under Assumption MLR∑.4—and variance 􏱧2􏱧 2x by the homoskedasticity Assumption n 􏱦1/2 ∑ 2∑ MLR.5. Therefore, n (x 􏱦 μ)u has an asymptotic Normal(0,􏱧 􏱧2) distribution. i􏱪1i i x We just showed that the difference between n􏱦1/2 n (x 􏱦 x-)u and n􏱦1/2 n (x 􏱦 μ)u i􏱪1i i has zero plim. A result in asymptotic theory is that if zn has an asymptotic normal distri- i􏱪1i i bution and plim(vn 􏱦∑zn) 􏱪 0, then vn has the same asymptotic normal distribution as zn. It follows that n􏱦1/2 n (x 􏱦 x-)u also has an asymptotic Normal(0,􏱧2􏱧2) distribution. i􏱪1i i x Putting all of the pieces together gives __ ˆ 􏱯 n(􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1) 􏱪 (1/􏱧x ) n (x 􏱦 x)u - 􏲄 2 􏱶􏱦1/2∑n i􏱪1 ii 2 2 􏱶􏱦1/2∑n (xi 􏱦x)ui , - 􏲄 􏱕[(1/sx)􏱦(1/􏱧x)] n and since plim(1ˆ/sx2) 􏱪 1/􏱧x2, the second term has zero plim. Therefore, the asymptotic dis- tribution of 􏱯 n(􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬1) is Normal(0,{􏱧 􏱧x}/{􏱧x } ) 􏱪 Normal(0,􏱧 /􏱧x). This completes the proof in the simple regression case, as a12 􏱪 􏱧x2 in this case. See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 4) for the general case. i􏱪1 __ 2222 22 i􏱪1 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 186 In Chapter 2 on bivariate regression, we briefly discussed the effects of changing the units of measurement on the OLS intercept and slope estimates. We also showed that changing the units of measurement did not affect R-squared. We now return to the issue of data scaling and examine the effects of rescaling the dependent or independent variables on standard errors, t statistics, F statistics, and confidence intervals. We will discover that everything we expect to happen, does happen. When variables are rescaled, the coefficients, standard errors, confidence intervals, t statistics, and F statistics change in ways that preserve all measured effects and testing outcomes. Although this is no great surprise—in fact, we would be very worried if it were not the case—it is useful to see what occurs explicitly. Often, data scaling is used for cosmetic purposes, such as to reduce the number of zeros after a decimal point in an estimated coefficient. By judiciously choosing units of measurement, we can improve the appearance of an estimated equation while changing nothing that is essential. We could treat this problem in a general way, but it is much better illustrated with examples. Likewise, there is little value here in introducing an abstract notation. We begin with an equation relating infant birth weight to cigarette smoking and family income: where 􏱾bwght 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1cigs 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2 faminc, [6.1] bwght 􏱪 child birth weight, in ounces. cigs 􏱪 number of cigarettes smoked by the mother while pregnant, per day. faminc 􏱪 annual family income, in thousands of dollars. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues This chapter brings together several issues in multiple regression analysis that we could not conveniently cover in earlier chapters. These topics are not as fundamental as the material in Chapters 3 and 4, but they are important for applying multiple regression to a broad range of empirical problems. 6.1 Effects of Data Scaling on OLS Statistics Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 187 TABLE 6.1 Effects of Data Scaling Dependent Variable (1) bwght (2) bwghtlbs (3) bwght Independent Variables cigs 􏱦.4634 (.0916) 􏱦.0289 (.0057) — packs — — 􏱦9.268 (1.832) faminc .0927 (.0292) .0058 (.0018) .0927 (.0292) intercept 116.974 (1.049) 7.3109 (.0656) 116.974 (1.049) Observations 1,388 1,388 1,388 R-Squared .0298 .0298 .0298 SSR 557,485.51 2,177.6778 557,485.51 SER 20.063 1.2539 20.063 The estimates of this equation, obtained using the data in BWGHT.RAW, are given in the first column of Table 6.1. Standard errors are listed in parentheses. The estimate on cigs says that if a woman smoked 5 more cigarettes per day, birth weight is predicted to be about .4634(5) 􏱪 2.317 ounces less. The t statistic on cigs is 􏱦5.06, so the variable is very statistically significant. Now, suppose that we decide to measure birth weight in pounds, rather than in ounces. Let bwghtlbs 􏱪 bwght/16 be birth weight in pounds. What happens to our OLS statistics if we use this as the dependent variable in our equation? It is easy to find the effect on the coefficient estimates by simple manipulation of equation (6.1). Divide this entire equation by 16: 􏱾bwght/16 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0/16 􏱕 (􏱬ˆ1/16)cigs 􏱕 (􏱬ˆ2/16)faminc. Since the left-hand side is birth weight in pounds, it follows that each new coefficient will be the corresponding old coefficient divided by 16. To verify this, the regression of bwghtlbs on cigs, and faminc is reported in column (2) of Table 6.1. Up to four digits, the intercept and slopes in column (2) are just those in column (1) divided by 16. For example, the coefficient on cigs is now 􏱦.0289; this means that if cigs were higher by five, birth weight would be .0289(5) 􏱪 .1445 pounds lower. In terms of ounces, we have .1445(16) 􏱪 2.312, which is slightly different from the 2.317 we obtained earlier due to rounding error. The point is, once the effects are transformed into the same units, we get exactly the same answer, regardless of how the dependent variable is measured. What about statistical significance? As we expect, changing the dependent variable from ounces to pounds has no effect on how statistically important the independent variables are. The standard errors in column (2) are 16 times smaller than those in column (1). A few quick calculations show that the t statistics in column (2) are indeed identical to the t sta- tistics in column (1). The endpoints for the confidence intervals in column (2) are just the endpoints in column (1) divided by 16. This is because the CIs change by the same factor as the standard errors. [Remember that the 95% CI here is 􏱬ˆj 􏲁 1.96 se(􏱬ˆj).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 188 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data In terms of goodness-of-fit, the R-squareds from the two regressions are identical, as should be the case. Notice that the sum of squared residuals, SSR, and the standard error of the regression, SER, do differ across equations. These differences are easily explained. Let uˆi denote the residual for observation i in the original equation (6.1). Then the residual when bwghtlbs is the dependent variable is simply uˆi /16. Thus, the squared residual in the second equation is (uˆi /16)2 􏱪 uˆ2i /256. This is why the sum of squared residuals in column (2) is equal to the SSR in column (1) divided by 256. _______________ _________ SinceSER􏱪􏱧ˆ􏱪􏱯SSR/(n􏱦k􏱦1) 􏱪􏱯SSR/1,385,theSERincolumn(2)is16 times smaller than that in column (1). Another way to think about this is that the error in the equation with bwghtlbs as the dependent variable has a standard deviation 16 times smaller than the standard deviation of the original error. This does not mean that we have reduced the error by changing how birth weight is measured; the smaller SER simply reflects a difference in units of measurement. Next, let us return the dependent variable to its original units: bwght is measured in ounces. Instead, let us change the unit of measurement of one of the independent variables, cigs. Define packs to be the number of packs of cigarettes smoked per day. Thus, packs 􏱪 cigs/20. What happens to the coefficients and other OLS statistics now? Well, we can write 􏱾ˆˆˆˆˆˆ bwght 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 (20􏱬1)(cigs/20) 􏱕 􏱬2 faminc 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 (20􏱬1)packs 􏱕 􏱬2 faminc. Thus, the intercept and slope coefficient on faminc are unchanged, but the coefficient on packs is 20 times that on cigs. This is intuitively appealing. The results from the regression of bwght on packs and faminc are in column (3) of Table 6.1. Incidentally, remember that it would make no sense to include both cigs and packs in the same equation; this would in- duce perfect multicollinearity and would have no interesting meaning. Other than the coefficient on packs, there is one other statistic in column (3) that differs from that in column (1): the standard error on packs is 20 times larger than that on cigs in column (1). This means that the t statistic for testing the significance of cigarette smoking is the same whether we measure smoking in terms of cigarettes or packs. This is only natural. The previous example spells out most of the possibilities that arise when the dependent and independent variables are rescaled. Rescaling is often done with dollar amounts in economics, especially when the dollar amounts are very large. In Chapter 2, we argued that, if the dependent variable appears in logarithmic form, changing the unit of measurement does not affect the slope coefficient. The same is true here: changing the unit of measurement of the dependent variable, when it appears in logarithmic form, does not affect any of the slope estimates. This follows from the simple fact that log(c1yi) 􏱪 log(c1) 􏱕 log(yi) for any constant c1 􏱰 0. The new intercept will be log(c1) 􏱕 􏱬ˆ0. Similarly, changing the unit of measurement of any xj, where log(xj) appears in the regression, only affects the intercept. This corresponds to what we know about percentage changes and, in particular, elasticities: they are invariant to the units of measurement of either y or the xj. For example, if we had specified the dependent Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 6.1 In the original birth weight equation (6.1), suppose that faminc is measured in dollars rather than in thousands of dollars. Thus, define the variable fincdol 􏱪 1,000􏱳faminc. How will the OLS statistics change when fincdol is substituted for faminc? For the purpose of presenting the regression results, do you think it is better to measure income in dollars or in thousands of dollars? CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 189 variable in (6.1) to be log(bwght), estimated the equation, and then reestimated it with log(bwghtlbs) as the dependent variable, the coefficients on cigs and faminc would be the same in both regressions; only the intercept would be different. Beta Coefficients Sometimes, in econometric applications, a key variable is measured on a scale that is difficult to interpret. Labor economists often include test scores in wage equations, and the scale on which these tests are scored is often arbitrary and not easy to interpret (at least for economists!). In almost all cases, we are interested in how a particular individual’s score compares with the population. Thus, instead of asking about the effect on hourly wage if, say, a test score is 10 points higher, it makes more sense to ask what happens when the test score is one standard deviation higher. Nothing prevents us from seeing what happens to the dependent variable when an independent variable in an estimated model increases by a certain number of standard deviations, assuming that we have obtained the sample standard deviation (which is easy in most regression packages). This is often a good idea. So, for example, when we look at the effect of a standardized test score, such as the SAT score, on college GPA, we can find the standard deviation of SAT and see what happens when the SAT score increases by one or two standard deviations. Sometimes, it is useful to obtain regression results when all variables involved, the dependent as well as all the independent variables, have been standardized. A variable is standardized in the sample by subtracting off its mean and dividing by its standard devia- tion (see Appendix C). This means that we compute the z-score for every variable in the sample. Then, we run a regression using the z-scores. Why is standardization useful? It is easiest to start with the original OLS equation, with the variables in their original forms: yi 􏱪􏱬ˆ0 􏱕􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱕􏱬ˆ2xi2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬ˆkxik 􏱕uˆi. [6.2] We have included the observation subscript i to emphasize that our standardization is applied to all sample values. Now, if we average (6.2), use the fact that the uˆi have a zero sample average, and subtract the result from (6.2), we get yi 􏱦y-􏱪􏱬ˆ1(xi1 􏱦x-1)􏱕􏱬ˆ2(xi2 􏱦x-2)􏱕...􏱕􏱬ˆk(xik 􏱦x-k)􏱕uˆi. Now, let 􏱧ˆ y be the sample standard deviation for the dependent variable, let 􏱧ˆ 1 be the sample sd for x1, let 􏱧ˆ2 be the sample sd for x2, and so on. Then, simple algebra gives the equation ( yi 􏱦 y-)/􏱧ˆy 􏱪 (􏱧ˆ1/􏱧ˆy)􏱬ˆ1[(xi1 􏱦 x-1)/􏱧ˆ1] 􏱕 ... 􏱕 (􏱧ˆk/􏱧ˆy)􏱬ˆk[(xik 􏱦 x-k)/􏱧ˆk] 􏱕 (uˆi/􏱧ˆy). [6.3] Each variable in (6.3) has been standardized by replacing it with its z-score, and this has resulted in new slope coefficients. For example, the slope coefficient on (xi1 􏱦 x-1)/􏱧ˆ1 is (􏱧ˆ1/􏱧ˆy)􏱬ˆ1. This is simply the original coefficient, 􏱬ˆ1, multiplied by the ratio of the standard deviation of x1 to the standard deviation of y. The intercept has dropped out altogether. It is useful to rewrite (6.3), dropping the i subscript, as zy 􏱪 bˆ1z1 􏱕 bˆ2z2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 bˆkzk 􏱕 error, [6.4] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 190 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data where zy denotes the z-score of y, z1 is the z-score of x1, and so on. The new coeffi- cients are bˆj 􏱪(􏱧ˆj/􏱧ˆy)􏱬ˆj forj􏱪1,...,k. [6.5] These bˆj are traditionally called standardized coefficients or beta coefficients. (The latter name is more common, which is unfortunate because we have been using beta hat to denote the usual OLS estimates.) Beta coefficients receive their interesting meaning from equation (6.4): If x1 increases by one standard deviation, then yˆ changes by bˆ1 standard deviations. Thus, we are measur- ing effects not in terms of the original units of y or the xj, but in standard deviation units. Because it makes the scale of the regressors irrelevant, this equation puts the explanatory variables on equal footing. In a standard OLS equation, it is not possible to simply look at the size of different coefficients and conclude that the explanatory variable with the largest coefficient is “the most important.” We just saw that the magnitudes of coefficients can be changed at will by changing the units of measurement of the xj. But, when each xj has been standardized, comparing the magnitudes of the resulting beta coefficients is more compel- ling. When the regression equation has only a single explanatory variable, x1, its standardized coefficient is simply the sample correlation coefficient between y and x1, which means it must lie in the range −1 to 1. Even in situations where the coefficients are easily interpretable—say, the dependent variable and independent variables of interest are in logarithmic form, so the OLS coefficients of interest are estimated elasticities—there is still room for computing beta coefficients. Although elasticities are free of units of measurement, a change in a particular explanatory variable by, say, 10% may represent a larger or smaller change over a variable’s range than changing another explanatory variable by 10%. For example, in a state with wide income variation but relatively little variation in spending per student, it might not make much sense to compare performance elas- ticities with respect to the income and spending. Comparing beta coefficient magni- tudes can be helpful. To obtain the beta coefficients, we can always standardize y, x1, ..., xk and then run the OLS regression of the z-score of y on the z-scores of x1, ..., xk—where it is not neces- sary to include an intercept, as it will be zero. This can be tedious with many independent variables. Some regression packages provide beta coefficients via a simple command. The following example illustrates the use of beta coefficients. EXAMPLE 6.1 EFFECTS OF POLLUTION ON HOUSING PRICES We use the data from Example 4.5 (in the file HPRICE2.RAW) to illustrate the use of beta coefficients. Recall that the key independent variable is nox, a measure of the nitrogen oxide in the air over each community. One way to understand the size of the pollution effect—without getting into the science underlying nitrogen oxide’s effect on air quality—is to compute beta coefficients. (An alternative approach is contained in Example 4.5: we obtained a price elasticity with respect to nox by using price and nox in logarithmic form.) The population equation is the level-level model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1nox 􏱕 􏱬2crime 􏱕 􏱬3rooms 􏱕 􏱬4dist 􏱕 􏱬5stratio 􏱕 u, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 191 where all the variables except crime were defined in Example 4.5; crime is the number of reported crimes per capita. The beta coefficients are reported in the following equation (so each variable has been converted to its z-score): 􏱾zprice 􏱪 􏱦.340 znox 􏱦 .143 zcrime 􏱕 .514 zrooms 􏱦 .235 zdist 􏱦 .270 zstratio. This equation shows that a one standard deviation increase in nox decreases price by .34 stan- dard deviation; a one standard deviation increase in crime reduces price by .14 standard devi- ation. Thus, the same relative movement of pollution in the population has a larger effect on housing prices than crime does. Size of the house, as measured by number of rooms (rooms), has the largest standardized effect. If we want to know the effects of each independent vari- able on the dollar value of median house price, we should use the unstandardized variables. Whether we use standardized or unstandardized variables does not affect statistical significance: the t statistics are the same in both cases. 6.2 More on Functional Form In several previous examples, we have encountered the most popular device in econometrics for allowing nonlinear relationships between the explained and explanatory variables: using logarithms for the dependent or independent variables. We have also seen models containing quadratics in some explanatory variables, but we have yet to provide a systematic treatment of them. In this section, we cover some variations and extensions on functional forms that often arise in applied work. More on Using Logarithmic Functional Forms We begin by reviewing how to interpret the parameters in the model log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(nox) 􏱕 􏱬2rooms 􏱕 u, [6.6] where these variables are taken from Example 4.5. Recall that throughout the text log(x) is the natural log of x. The coefficient 􏱬1 is the elasticity of price with respect to nox (pollution). The coefficient 􏱬2 is the change in log( price), when ∆rooms 􏱪 1; as we have seen many times, when multiplied by 100, this is the approximate percentage change in price. Recall that 100􏱳􏱬2 is sometimes called the semi-elasticity of price with respect to rooms. When estimated using the data in HPRICE2.RAW, we obtain 􏱾log(price) 􏱪 9.23 􏱦 .718 log(nox) 􏱕 .306 rooms (0.19) (.066) (.019) [6.7] n 􏱪 506, R2 􏱪 .514. Thus, when nox increases by 1%, price falls by .718%, holding only rooms fixed. When rooms increases by one, price increases by approximately 100(.306) 􏱪 30.6%. The estimate that one more room increases price by about 30.6% turns out to be somewhat inaccurate for this application. The approximation error occurs because, as the change in log(y) becomes larger and larger, the approximation %∆y 􏱴 100􏱳∆log(y) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 192 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data becomes more and more inaccurate. Fortunately, a simple calculation is available to com- pute the exact percentage change. To describe the procedure, we consider the general estimated model 􏱾log(y) 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1log(x1) 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x2. (Adding additional independent variables does not change the procedure.) Now, fixing x1, we have ∆􏱾log(y) 􏱪 􏱬ˆ2∆x2. Using simple algebraic properties of the exponential and loga- rithmic functions gives the exact percentage change in the predicted y as %∆yˆ 􏱪 100·[exp(􏱬ˆ2∆x2) 􏱦 1], [6.8] where the multiplication by 100 turns the proportionate change into a percentage change. When ∆x2 􏱪 1, %∆yˆ 􏱪 100·[exp(􏱬ˆ2) 􏱦 1]. [6.9] Applied to the housing price example with x2 􏱪 rooms and ˆ􏱬 2 􏱪 .306, %∆􏱾price 􏱪 100[exp(.306) 􏱦 1] 􏱪 35.8%, which is notably larger than the approximate percent- age change, 30.6%, obtained directly from (6.7). {Incidentally, this is not an unbiased estimator because exp(􏱳) is a nonlinear function; it is, however, a consistent estimator of 100[exp(􏱬2) 􏱦 1]. This is because the probability limit passes through continuous func- tions, while the expected value operator does not. See Appendix C.} The adjustment in equation (6.8) is not as crucial for small percentage changes. For example, when we include the student-teacher ratio in equation (6.7), its estimated coefficient is 􏱦.052, which means that if stratio increases by one, price decreases by approximately 5.2%. The exact proportionate change is exp(􏱦.052) 􏱦 1 􏱴 􏱦.051, or 􏱦5.1%. On the other hand, if we increase stratio by five, then the approximate percentage change in price is 􏱦26%, while the exact change obtained from equation (6.8) is 100[exp(􏱦.26) 􏱦 1] 􏱴 􏱦22.9%. The logarithmic approximation to percentage changes has an advantage that justifies its reporting even when the percentage change is large. To describe this advantage, consider again the effect on price of changing the number of rooms by one. The logarithmic approximation is just the coefficient on rooms in equation (6.7) multiplied by 100, namely, 30.6%. We also computed an estimate of the exact percentage change for increasing the number of rooms by one as 35.8%. But what if we want to estimate the percentage change for decreasing the num- ber of rooms by one? In equation (6.8) we take ∆ x2 􏱪 􏱦1 and 􏱬ˆ 2 􏱪 .306, and so %∆􏱾price 􏱪 100[exp(􏱦.306) − 1] 􏱪 􏱦26.4, or a drop of 26.4%. Notice that the approximation based on using the coefficient on rooms is between 26.4 and 35.8—an outcome that always occurs. In other words, simply using the coefficient (multiplied by 100) gives us an estimate that is always between the absolute value of the estimates for an increase and a decrease. If we are specifically interested in an increase or a decrease, we can use the calculation based on equation (6.8). The point just made about computing percentage changes is essentially the one made in introductory economics when it comes to computing, say, price elasticities of demand based on large price changes: the result depends on whether we use the beginning or ending price and quantity in computing the percentage changes. Using the logarithmic approxi- mation is similar in spirit to calculating an arc elasticity of demand, where the average of prices and quantities is used in the denominators in computing the percentage changes. We have seen that using natural logs leads to coefficients with appealing interpreta- tions, and we can be ignorant about the units of measurement of variables appearing in logarithmic form because the slope coefficients are invariant to rescalings. There are several Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 193 other reasons logs are used so much in applied work. First, when y 􏱰 0, models using log(y) as the dependent variable often satisfy the CLM assumptions more closely than models using the level of y. Strictly positive variables often have conditional distributions that are heteroskedastic or skewed; taking the log can mitigate, if not eliminate, both problems. Another potential benefit of using logs is that taking the log of a variable often narrows its range. This is particularly true of variables that can be large monetary values, such as firms’ annual sales or baseball players’ salaries. Population variables also tend to vary widely. Narrow- ing the range of the dependent and independent variables can make OLS estimates less sensitive to outlying (or extreme values); we take up the issue of outlying observations in Chapter 9. However, one must not indiscriminantly use the logarithmic transformation because in some cases it can actually create extreme values. An example is when a variable y is between zero and one (such as a proportion) and takes on values close to zero. In this case, log(y) (which is necessarily negative) can be very large in magnitude whereas the original variable, y, is bounded between zero and one. There are some standard rules of thumb for taking logs, although none is written in stone. When a variable is a positive dollar amount, the log is often taken. We have seen this for variables such as wages, salaries, firm sales, and firm market value. Variables such as population, total number of employees, and school enrollment often appear in logarithmic form; these have the common feature of being large integer values. Variables that are measured in years—such as education, experience, tenure, age, and so on—usually appear in their original form. A variable that is a proportion or a percent—such as the unemployment rate, the participation rate in a pension plan, the percentage of students pass- ing a standardized exam, and the arrest rate on reported crimes—can appear in either original or logarithmic form, although there is a tendency to use them in level forms. This is because any regression coefficients involving the original variable—whether it is the dependent or independent variable—will have a percentage point change interpretation. (See Appendix A for a review of the distinction between a percentage change and a percentage point change.) If we use, say, log(unem) in a regression, where unem is the percentage of unemployed individu- als, we must be very careful to distinguish between a percentage point change and a percent- age change. Remember, if unem goes from 8 to 9, this is an increase of one percentage point, but a 12.5% increase from the initial unemployment level. Using the log means that we are looking at the percentage change in the unemployment rate: log(9) 􏱦 log(8) 􏱴 .118 or 11.8%, which is the logarithmic approximation to the actual 12.5% increase. One limitation of the log is that it cannot be used if a variable takes on zero or negative values. In cases where a vari- able y is nonnegative but can take on the value 0, log(1􏱕y) is sometimes used. The percentage change interpretations are of- ten closely preserved, except for changes beginning at y 􏱪 0 (where the percentage change is not even defined). Generally, using log(1􏱕y) and then interpreting the estimates as if the variable were log(y) is acceptable when the data on y contain relatively few zeros. An example might be where y is hours of training per employee for the population of manufacturing firms, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 6.2 Suppose that the annual number of drunk driving arrests is determined by log(arrests) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(pop) 􏱕 􏱬2age16_25 􏱕 other factors, where age16_25 is the proportion of the population between 16 and 25 years of age. Show that 􏱬2 has the following (ceteris paribus) interpretation: it is the percentage change in arrests when the percentage of the people aged 16 to 25 increases by one percentage point. 194 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data if a large fraction of firms provides training to at least one worker. Technically, however, log (1 􏱕 y) cannot be normally distributed (although it might be less heteroskedastic than y). Useful, albeit more advanced, alternatives are the Tobit and Poisson models in Chapter 17. One drawback to using a dependent variable in logarithmic form is that it is more difficult to predict the original variable. The original model allows us to predict log(y), not y. Nevertheless, it is fairly easy to turn a prediction for log(y) into a prediction for y (see Section 6.4). A related point is that it is not legitimate to compare R-squareds from models where y is the dependent variable in one case and log(y) is the dependent variable in the other. These measures explain variations in different variables. We discuss how to compute comparable goodness-of-fit measures in Section 6.4. Models with Quadratics Quadratic functions are also used quite often in applied economics to capture decreasing or increasing marginal effects. You may want to review properties of quadratic functions in Appendix A. In the simplest case, y depends on a single observed factor x, but it does so in a quadratic fashion: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕u. For example, take y 􏱪 wage and x 􏱪 exper. As we discussed in Chapter 3, this model falls outside of simple regression analysis but is easily handled with multiple regression. It is important to remember that 􏱬1 does not measure the change in y with respect to x; it makes no sense to hold x2 fixed while changing x. If we write the estimated equation as yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x2, [6.10] ∆yˆ 􏱴 (􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 2􏱬ˆ2x)∆x, so ∆yˆ/∆x 􏱴 􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 2􏱬ˆ2x. [6.11] This says that the slope of the relationship between x and y depends on the value of x; the estimated slope is 􏱬ˆ1 􏱕 2􏱬ˆ2x. If we plug in x 􏱪 0, we see that 􏱬ˆ1 can be interpreted as the approximate slope in going from x 􏱪 0 to x 􏱪 1. After that, the second term, 2􏱬ˆ2x, must be accounted for. then we have the approximation If we are only interested in computing the predicted change in y given a starting value for x and a change in x, we could use (6.10) directly: there is no reason to use the calculus approximation at all. However, we are usually more interested in quickly summarizing the effect of x on y, and the interpretation of 􏱬ˆ 1 and 􏱬ˆ 2 in equation (6.11) provides that summary. Typically, we might plug in the average value of x in the sample, or some other interesting values, such as the median or the lower and upper quartile values. In many applications, 􏱬ˆ1 is positive and 􏱬ˆ2 is negative. For example, using the wage data in WAGE1.RAW, we obtain w􏱾age 􏱪 3.73 􏱕 .298 exper 􏱦 .0061 exper 2 (.35) (.041) (.0009) [6.12] n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .093. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 195 This estimated equation implies that exper has a diminishing effect on wage. The first year of experience is worth roughly 30¢ per hour ($.298). The second year of experience is worth less [about .298 􏱦 2(.0061)(1) 􏱴 .286, or 28.6¢, according to the approximation in (6.11) with x 􏱪 1]. In going from 10 to 11 years of experience, wage is predicted to increase by about .298 􏱦 2(.0061)(10) 􏱪 .176, or 17.6¢. And so on. When the coefficient on x is positive and the coefficient on x2 is negative, the qua- dratic has a parabolic shape. There is always a positive value of x where the effect of x on y is zero; before this point, x has a positive effect on y; after this point, x has a negative effect on y. In practice, it can be important to know where this turning point is. In the estimated equation (6.10) with 􏱬ˆ1 􏱰 0 and 􏱬ˆ2 􏱷 0, the turning point (or maxi- mum of the function) is always achieved at the coefficient on x over twice the absolute value of the coefficient on x2: x* 􏱪 􏰫􏱬ˆ1/(2􏱬ˆ2)􏰫. [6.13] In the wage example, x* 􏱪 exper* is .298/[2(.0061)] 􏱴 24.4. (Note how we just drop the minus sign on 􏱦.0061 in doing this calculation.) This quadratic relationship is illustrated in Figure 6.1. In the wage equation (6.12), the return to experience becomes zero at about 24.4 years. What should we make of this? There are at least three possible explanations. First, it may be that few people in the sample have more than 24 years of experience, and so the part of the curve to the right of 24 can be ignored. The cost of using a quadratic to capture diminishing effects is that the quadratic must eventually turn around. If this point is beyond all but a small percentage of the people in the sample, then this is not of much concern. F I G U R E 6 . 1 Quadratic relationship between 􏱾wage and exper. wage 7.37 3.73 24.4 exper Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 196 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data But in the data set WAGE1.RAW, about 28% of the people in the sample have more than 24 years of experience; this is too high a percentage to ignore. It is possible that the return to exper really becomes negative at some point, but it is hard to believe that this happens at 24 years of experience. A more likely possibility is that the estimated effect of exper on wage is biased because we have controlled for no other factors, or because the functional relationship between wage and exper in equation (6.12) is not entirely correct. Computer Exercise C2 asks you to explore this possibility by controlling for education, in addition to using log(wage) as the dependent variable. When a model has a dependent variable in logarthmic form and an explanatory variable entering as a quadratic, some care is needed in reporting the partial effects. The following example also shows that the quadratic can have a U-shape, rather than a parabolic shape. A U-shape arises in equation (6.10) when 􏱬ˆ1 is negative and 􏱬ˆ2 is positive; this captures an increasing effect of x on y. EXAMPLE 6.2 EFFECTS OF POLLUTION ON HOUSING PRICES We modify the housing price model from Example 4.5 to include a quadratic term in rooms: log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(nox) 􏱕 􏱬2log(dist) 􏱕 􏱬3rooms 􏱕 􏱬4rooms2 􏱕 􏱬5stratio 􏱕 u. The model estimated using the data in HPRICE2.RAW is 􏱾log( price) 􏱪 13.39 􏱦 .902 log(nox) 􏱦 .087 log(dist) (.57) (.115) (.043) 􏱦 .545 rooms 􏱕 .062 rooms2 􏱦 .048 stratio (.165) (.013) (.006) n 􏱪 506, R2 􏱪 .603. [6.14] The quadratic term rooms2 has a t statistic of about 4.77, and so it is very statistically significant. But what about interpreting the effect of rooms on log(price)? Initially, the effect appears to be strange. Because the coefficient on rooms is negative and the coefficient on rooms2 is positive, this equation literally implies that, at low values of rooms, an additional room has a negative effect on log(price). At some point, the effect becomes positive, and the quadratic shape means that the semi-elasticity of price with respect to rooms is increasing as rooms increases. This situation is shown in Figure 6.2. ˆ We obtain the turnaround value of rooms using equation (6.13) (even though 􏱬1 is negative and 􏱬ˆ2 is positive). The absolute value of the coefficient on rooms, .545, divided by twice the coefficient on rooms2, .062, gives rooms* 􏱪 .545/[2(.062)] 􏱴 4.4; this point is labeled in Figure 6.2. Do we really believe that starting at three rooms and increasing to four rooms actually re- duces a house’s expected value? Probably not. It turns out that only five of the 506 communities in the sample have houses averaging 4.4 rooms or less, about 1% of the sample. This is so small that the quadratic to the left of 4.4 can, for practical purposes, be ignored. To the right of 4.4, we see that adding another room has an increasing effect on the percentage change in price: ∆􏱾log(price) 􏱴 {[􏱦.545 􏱕 2(.062)]rooms}∆rooms Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. and so CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 197 F I G U R E 6 . 2 􏱾log(price) as a quadratic function of rooms. log(price) 4.4 rooms %∆􏱾price 􏱴 100{[􏱦.545 􏱕 2(.062)]rooms}∆rooms 􏱪 (􏱦54.5 􏱕 12.4 rooms)∆rooms. Thus, an increase in rooms from, say, five to six increases price by about 􏱦54.5 􏱕 12.4(5) 􏱪 7.5%; the increase from six to seven increases price by roughly 􏱦54.5 􏱕 12.4(6) 􏱪 19.9%. This is a very strong increasing effect. The strong increasing effect of rooms on log(price) in this example illustrates an im- portant lesson: one cannot simply look at the coefficient on the quadratic term—in this case, .062—and declare that it is too small to bother with based only on its magnitude. In many applications with quadratics the coefficient on the squared variable has one or more zeros after the decimal point: after all, this coefficient measures how the slope is chang- ing as x (rooms) changes. A seemingly small coefficient can have practically important consequences, as we just saw. As a general rule, one must compute the partial effect and see how it varies with x to determine if the quadratic term is practically important. In doing so, it is useful to compare the changing slope implied by the quadratic model with the constant slope obtained from the model with only a linear term. If we drop rooms2 from the equation, the coefficient on rooms becomes about .255, which implies that each additional room— starting from any number of rooms—increases median price by about 25.5%. This is very different from the quadratic model, where the effect becomes 25.5% at rooms 􏱪 6.45 but changes rapidly as rooms gets smaller or larger. For example, at rooms 􏱪 7, the return to the next room is about 32.3%. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 198 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data What happens generally if the coefficients on the level and squared terms have the same sign (either both positive or both negative) and the explanatory variable is necessarily nonnegative (as in the case of rooms or exper)? In either case, there is no turning point for values x 􏱰 0. For example, if 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 are both positive, the smallest expected value of y is at x 􏱪 0, and increases in x always have a positive and increasing effect on y. (This isalsotrueif􏱬1 􏱪0and􏱬2 􏱰0,whichmeansthatthepartialeffectiszeroatx􏱪0and increasing as x increases.) Similarly, if 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 are both negative, the largest expected value of y is at x 􏱪 0, and increases in x have a negative effect on y, with the magnitude of the effect increasing as x gets larger. ˆ ˆ The general formula for the turning point of any quadratic is x* 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1/(2􏱬2), which leads to a positive value if 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 have opposite signs and a negative value when 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 have the same sign. Knowing this simple formula is useful in cases where x may take on both positive and negative values; one can compute the turning point and see if it makes sense, taking into account the range of x in the sample. There are many other possibilities for using quadratics along with logarithms. For example, an extension of (6.14) that allows a nonconstant elasticity between price and nox is log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(nox) 􏱕 􏱬2[log(nox)]2 􏱕 􏱬3crime 􏱕 􏱬4rooms 􏱕 􏱬5rooms2 􏱕 􏱬6stratio 􏱕 u. [6.15] If 􏱬2 􏱪 0, then 􏱬1 is the elasticity of price with respect to nox. Otherwise, this elasticity depends on the level of nox. To see this, we can combine the arguments for the partial effects in the quadratic and logarithmic models to show that %∆price 􏱴 [􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2log(nox)]%∆nox; [6.16] therefore, the elasticity of price with respect to nox is 􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2log(nox), so that it depends on log(nox). Finally, other polynomial terms can be included in regression models. Certainly, the quadratic is seen most often, but a cubic and even a quartic term appear now and then. An often reasonable functional form for a total cost function is cost 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1quantity 􏱕 􏱬2quantity2 􏱕 􏱬3quantity3 􏱕 u. Estimating such a model causes no complications. Interpreting the parameters is more involved (though straightforward using calculus); we do not study these models further. Models with Interaction Terms Sometimes, it is natural for the partial effect, elasticity, or semi-elasticity of the dependent variable with respect to an explanatory variable to depend on the magnitude of yet another explanatory variable. For example, in the model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sqrft 􏱕 􏱬2bdrms 􏱕 􏱬3sqrft􏱳bdrms 􏱕 􏱬4bthrms 􏱕 u, the partial effect of bdrms on price (holding all other variables fixed) is ∆price _______ 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 􏱬3sqrft. ∆bdrms [6.17] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 199 If 􏱬3 􏱰 0, then (6.17) implies that an additional bedroom yields a higher increase in hous- ing price for larger houses. In other words, there is an interaction effect between square footage and number of bedrooms. In summarizing the effect of bdrms on price, we must evaluate (6.17) at interesting values of sqrft, such as the mean value, or the lower and upper quartiles in the sample. Whether or not 􏱬3 is zero is something we can easily test. The parameters on the original variables can be tricky to interpret when we include an interaction term. For example, in the previous housing price equation, equation (6.17) shows that 􏱬2 is the effect of bdrms on price for a home with zero square feet! This effect is clearly not of much interest. Instead, we must be careful to put interesting values of sqrft, such as the mean or median values in the sample, into the estimated version of equation (6.17). Often, it is useful to reparameterize a model so that the coefficients on the original variables have an interesting meaning. Consider a model with two explanatory variables and an interaction: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x1x2 􏱕u. As just mentioned, 􏱬2 is the partial effect of x2 on y when x1 􏱪 0. Often, this is not of interest. Instead, we can reparameterize the model as y􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛1x1 􏱕􏱛2x2 􏱕􏱬3(x1 􏱦μ1)(x2 􏱦μ2)􏱕u, where μ1 is the population mean of x1 and μ2 is the population mean of x2. We can easily see that now the coefficient on x2, 􏱛2, is the partial effect of x2 on y at the mean value of x1. (By multiplying out the interaction in the second equation and comparing the coefficients, we can easily show that 􏱛2 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 􏱬3 μ1. The parameter 􏱛1 has a similar interpretation.) Therefore, if we subtract the means of the variables—in practice, these would typically be the sample means—before creating the interaction term, the coefficients on the original variables have a useful interpretation. Plus, we immediately obtain standard errors for the partial effects at the mean values. Nothing prevents us from replacing μ1 or μ2 with other values of the explanatory variables that may be of interest. The following example illus- trates how we can use interaction terms. EXAMPLE 6.3 EFFECTS OF ATTENDANCE ON FINAL EXAM PERFORMANCE A model to explain the standardized outcome on a final exam (stndfnl) in terms of percent- age of classes attended, prior college grade point average, and ACT score is stndfnl 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1atndrte 􏱕 􏱬2 priGPA 􏱕 􏱬3 ACT 􏱕 􏱬4 priGPA2 􏱕 􏱬5 ACT 2 􏱕 􏱬6 priGPA􏱳atndrte 􏱕 u. [6.18] (We use the standardized exam score for the reasons discussed in Section 6.1: it is easier to interpret a student’s performance relative to the rest of the class.) In addition to quadratics in priGPA and ACT, this model includes an interaction between priGPA and the attendance rate. The idea is that class attendance might have a different effect for students who have performed differently in the past, as measured by priGPA. We are interested in the effects of attendance on final exam score: ∆stndfnl/∆atndrte 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬6 priGPA. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 200 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Using the 680 observations in ATTEND.RAW, for students in a course on microeco- nomic principles, the estimated equation is 􏱾stndfnl 􏱪 2.05 􏱦 .0067 atndrte 􏱦 1.63 priGPA 􏱦 .128 ACT (1.36) (.0102) (.48) (.098) We must interpret this equation with extreme care. If we simply look at the coefficient on atndrte, we will incorrectly conclude that attendance has a negative effect on final exam score. But this coefficient supposedly measures the effect when priGPA 􏱪 0, which is not interesting (in this sample, the smallest prior GPA is about .86). We must also take care not to look separately at the estimates of 􏱬1 and 􏱬6 and conclude that, because each t statistic is insignificant, we cannot reject H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0, 􏱬6 􏱪 0. In fact, the p-value for the F test of this joint hypothesis is .014, so we certainly reject H0 at the 5% level. This is a good example of where looking at separate t statistics when testing a joint hypothesis can lead one far astray. How should we estimate the partial effect of atndrte on stndfnl? We must plug in interesting values of priGPA to obtain the partial effect. The mean value of priGPA in the sample is 2.59, so at the mean priGPA, the effect of atndrte on stndfnl is 􏱦.0067 􏱕 .0056(2.59) 􏱴 .0078. What does this mean? Because atndrte is measured as a percentage, it means that a 10 percentage point increase in atndrte increases 􏱾stndfnl by .078 standard deviations from the mean final exam score. How can we tell whether the estimate .0078 is statistically different from zero? We need to rerun the regression, where we replace priGPA􏱳atndrte with (priGPA 􏱦 2.59)􏱳atndrte. This gives, as the new co- efficient on atndrte, the estimated effect at priGPA 􏱪 2.59, along with its standard error; nothing else in the regression changes. (We described this device in Section 4.4.) Running this new regression gives the standard error of 􏱬ˆ 1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ 6(2.59) 􏱪 .0078 as .0026, which yields t 􏱪 .0078/.0026 􏱪 3. Therefore, at the average priGPA, we conclude that attendance has a statistically significant positive effect on final exam score. Things are even more complicated for finding the effect of priGPA on stndfnl because of the quadratic term priGPA2. To find the effect at the mean value of priGPA and the mean attendance rate, 82, we would replace priGPA2 with (priGPA 􏱦 2.59)2 and priGPA􏱳atndrte with priGPA􏱳(atndrte 􏱦 82). The coefficient on priGPA becomes the partial effect at the mean values, and we would have its standard error. (See Computer Exercise C7.) 6.3 More on Goodness-of-Fit and Selection of Regressors Until now, we have not focused much on the size of R2 in evaluating our regression mod- els, because beginning students tend to put too much weight on R-squared. As we will see shortly, choosing a set of explanatory variables based on the size of the R-squared can lead to nonsensical models. In Chapter 10, we will discover that R-squareds obtained from time series regressions can be artificially high and can result in misleading conclusions. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱕 .296 priGPA2 􏱕 .0045 ACT 2 􏱕 .0056 priGPA􏱳atndrte (.101) (.0022) (.0043) [6.19] n 􏱪 680, R2 􏱪 .229,R-2 􏱪 .222. EXPLORING FURTHER 6.3 If we add the term 􏱬7 ACT􏱳atndrte to equation (6.18), what is the partial effect of atndrte on stndfnl? CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 201 Nothing about the classical linear model assumptions requires that R2 be above any particular value; R2 is simply an estimate of how much variation in y is explained by x1, x2, ..., xk in the population. We have seen several regressions that have had pretty small R-squareds. Although this means that we have not accounted for several factors that affect y, this does not mean that the factors in u are correlated with the independent variables. The zero conditional mean assumption MLR.4 is what determines whether we get unbi- ased estimators of the ceteris paribus effects of the independent variables, and the size of the R-squared has no direct bearing on this. A small R-squared does imply that the error variance is large relative to the variance of y, which means we may have a hard time precisely estimating the 􏱬j. But remember, we saw in Section 3.4 that a large error variance can be offset by a large sample size: if we have enough data, we may be able to precisely estimate the partial effects even though we have not controlled for many unobserved factors. Whether or not we can get precise enough estimates depends on the application. For example, suppose that some incoming students at a large university are randomly given grants to buy computer equip- ment. If the amount of the grant is truly randomly determined, we can estimate the ceteris paribus effect of the grant amount on subsequent college grade point average by using simple regression analysis. (Because of random assignment, all of the other factors that affect GPA would be uncorrelated with the amount of the grant.) It seems likely that the grant amount would explain little of the variation in GPA, so the R-squared from such a regression would probably be very small. But, if we have a large sample size, we still might get a reasonably precise estimate of the effect of the grant. Another good illustration of where poor explanatory power has nothing to do with unbiased estimation of the 􏱬j is given by analyzing the data set APPLE.RAW. Unlike the other data sets we have used, the key explanatory variables in APPLE.RAW were set exper- imentally—that is, without regard to other factors that might affect the dependent variable. The variable we would like to explain, ecolbs, is the (hypothetical) pounds of “ecologi- cally friendly” (“ecolabeled”) apples a family would demand. Each family (actually, family head) was presented with a description of ecolabeled apples, along with prices of regular apples (regprc) and prices of the hypothetical ecolabeled apples (ecoprc). Because the price pairs were randomly assigned to each family, they are unrelated to other observed factors (such as family income) and unobserved factors (such as desire for a clean environ- ment). Therefore, the regression of ecolbs on ecoprc, regprc (across all samples generated in this way) produces unbiased estimators of the price effects. Nevertheless, the R-squared from the regression is only .0364: the price variables explain only about 3.6% of the total variation in ecolbs. So, here is a case where we explain very little of the variation in y, yet we are in the rare situation of knowing that the data have been generated so that unbiased estimation of the 􏱬j is possible. (Incidentally, adding observed family characteristics has a very small effect on explanatory power. See Computer Exercise C11.) Remember, though, that the relative change in the R-squared when variables are added to an equation is very useful: the F statistic in (4.41) for testing the joint signif- icance crucially depends on the difference in R-squareds between the unrestricted and restricted models. As we will see in Section 6.4, an important consequence of a low R-squared is that prediction is difficult. Because most of the variation in y is explained by unobserved fac- tors (or at least factors we do not include in our model), we will generally have a hard time using the OLS equation to predict future outcomes on y given a set of values for the explanatory variables. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 202 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Adjusted R-Squared Most regression packages will report, along with the R-squared, a statistic called the adjusted R-squared. Because the adjusted R-squared is reported in much applied work, and because it has some useful features, we cover it in this subsection. To see how the usual R-squared might be adjusted, it is usefully written as R2 􏱪 1 􏱦 (SSR /n)/(SST/n), [6.20] where SSR is the sum of squared residuals and SST is the total sum of squares; compared with equation (3.28), all we have done is divide both SSR and SST by n. This expression reveals what R2 is actually estimating. Define 􏱧2y as the population variance of y and let 􏱧u2 denote the population variance of the error term, u. (Until now, we have used 􏱧2 to denote 􏱧2u, but it is helpful to be more specific here.) The population R-squared is defined as 􏰴2 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱧2u/􏱧2y; this is the proportion of the variation in y in the population explained by the independent variables. This is what R2 is supposed to be estimating. R2 estimates 􏱧2u by SSR/n, which we know to be biased. So why not replace SSR/n with SSR/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)? Also, we can use SST/(n 􏱦 1) in place of SST/n, as the former is the unbiased estimator of 􏱧2y. Using these estimators, we arrive at the adjusted R-squared: R-2 􏱪 1 􏱦 [SSR/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)]/[SST/(n 􏱦 1)] 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱧ˆ 2/[SST/(n 􏱦 1)], [6.21] because ˆ􏱧 2 􏱪 SSR/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1). Because of the notation used to denote the adjusted R-squared, it is sometimes called R-bar squared. The adjusted R-squared is sometimes called the corrected R-squared, but this is not a good name because it implies that R- 2 is somehow better than R2 as an estimator of the population R-squared. Unfortunately, R- 2 is not generally known to be a better estimator. It is tempting to think that R- 2 corrects the bias in R2 for estimating the population R-squared, 􏰴2, but it does not: the ratio of two unbiased estimators is not an unbiased estimator. The primary attractiveness of R- 2 is that it imposes a penalty for adding additional independent variables to a model. We know that R2 can never fall when a new indepen- dent variable is added to a regression equation: this is because SSR never goes up (and usually falls) as more independent variables are added. But the formula for R- 2 shows that it depends explicitly on k, the number of independent variables. If an independent vari- able is added to a regression, SSR falls, but so does the df in the regression, n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1. SSR/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) can go up or down when a new independent variable is added to a regression. An interesting algebraic fact is the following: If we add a new independent variable to a regression equation, R- 2 increases if, and only if, the t statistic on the new variable is greater than one in absolute value. (An extension of this is that R- 2 increases when a group of variables is added to a regression if, and only if, the F statistic for joint significance of the new variables is greater than unity.) Thus, we see immediately that using R- 2 to decide whether a certain independent variable (or set of variables) belongs in a model gives us a different answer than standard t or F testing (because a t or F statistic of unity is not statis- tically significant at traditional significance levels). It is sometimes useful to have a formula for R- 2 in terms of R2. Simple algebra gives R-2 􏱪1􏱦(1􏱦R2)(n􏱦1)/(n􏱦k􏱦1). [6.22] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 203 F o r e x a m p l e , i f R 2 􏱪 . 3 0 , n 􏱪 5 1 , a n d k 􏱪 1 0 , t h e n R- 2 􏱪 1 􏱦 . 7 0 ( 5 0 ) / 4 0 􏱪 . 1 2 5 . T h u s , f o r small n and large k, R- 2 can be substantially below R2. In fact, if the usual R-squared is small, and n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 is small, R- 2 can actually be negative! For example, you can plug in R2 􏱪 .10, n 􏱪 51, and k 􏱪 10 to verify that R- 2 􏱪 􏱦.125. A negative R- 2 indicates a very poor model fit relative to the number of degrees of freedom. The adjusted R-squared is sometimes reported along with the usual R-squared in regressions, and sometimes R- 2 is reported in place of R2. It is important to remember that it is R2,notR-2,thatappearsintheFstatisticin(4.41).ThesameformulawithR-2andR-2 isnotvalid. r ur Using Adjusted R-Squared to Choose between Nonnested Models In Section 4.5, we learned how to compute an F statistic for testing the joint significance of a group of variables; this allows us to decide, at a particular significance level, whether at least one variable in the group affects the dependent variable. This test does not allow us to decide which of the variables has an effect. In some cases, we want to choose a model without redundant independent variables, and the adjusted R-squared can help with this. In the major league baseball salary example in Section 4.5, we saw that neither hrunsyr nor rbisyr was individually significant. These two variables are highly correlated, so we might want to choose between the models log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1years 􏱕 􏱬2gamesyr 􏱕 􏱬3bavg 􏱕 􏱬4hrunsyr 􏱕 u and log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1years 􏱕 􏱬2gamesyr 􏱕 􏱬3bavg 􏱕 􏱬4rbisyr 􏱕 u. These two equations are nonnested models because neither equation is a special case of the other. The F statistics we studied in Chapter 4 only allow us to test nested models: one model (the restricted model) is a special case of the other model (the unrestricted model). See equations (4.32) and (4.28) for examples of restricted and unrestricted models. One possibil- ity is to create a composite model that contains all explanatory variables from the original models and then to test each model against the general model using the F test. The problem with this process is that either both models might be rejected or neither model might be rejected (as happens with the major league baseball salary example in Section 4.5). Thus, it does not always provide a way to distinguish between models with nonnested regressors. In the baseball player salary regression, R- 2 for the regression containing hrunsyr is .6211, and R- 2 for the regression containing rbisyr is .6226. Thus, based on the adjusted R-squared, there is a very slight preference for the model with rbisyr. But the difference is practically very small, and we might obtain a different answer by controlling for some of the variables in Computer Exercise C5 in Chapter 4. (Because both nonnested models contain five parameters, the usual R-squared can be used to draw the same conclusion.) Comparing R- 2 to choose among different nonnested sets of independent variables can be valuable when these variables represent different functional forms. Consider two models relating R&D intensity to firm sales: rdintens 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 u. [6.23] rdintens 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sales 􏱕 􏱬2sales2 􏱕 u. [6.24] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 204 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The first model captures a diminishing return by including sales in logarithmic form; the second model does this by using a quadratic. Thus, the second model contains one more parameter than the first. When equation (6.23) is estimated using the 32 observations on chemical firms in RDCHEM.RAW, R2 is .061, and R2 for equation (6.24) is .148. Therefore, it appears that the quadratic fits much better. But a comparison of the usual R-squareds is unfair to the first model because it contains one fewer parameter than (6.24). That is, (6.23) is a more parsimonious model than (6.24). Everything else being equal, simpler models are better. Since the usual R-squared does not penalize more complicated models, it is better to use R- 2. R- 2 for (6.23) is .030, while -R2 for (6.24) is .090. Thus, even after adjusting for the difference in degrees of freedom, the quadratic model wins out. The quadratic model is also preferred when profit margin is added to each regression. - 2 ThereisanimportantlimitationinusingR tochoosebetweennonnestedmodels:we cannot use it to choose between different functional forms for the dependent variable. This is unfortunate, because we often want to decide on whether y or log(y) (or maybe some other transformation) should be used as the dependent variable based on goodness-of-fit. But neither R2 nor R- 2 can be used for this purpose. The reason is simple: these R-squareds measure the explained proportion of the total variation in whatever dependent variable we are using in the regression, and different functions of the dependent variable will have different amounts of variation to explain. For example, the total variations in y and log(y) are not the same, and are often very different. Comparing the adjusted R-squareds from regressions with these different forms of the dependent variables does not tell us anything about which model fits better; they are fitting two separate dependent variables. EXPLORING FURTHER 6.4 Explain why choosing a model by maximiz- ing R- 2 or minimizing 􏱧ˆ (the standard error of the regression) is the same thing. EXAMPLE 6.4 CEO COMPENSATION AND FIRM PERFORMANCE Consider two estimated models relating CEO compensation to firm performance: and 􏱾salary 􏱪 830.63 􏱕 .0163 sales 􏱕 19.63 roe (223.90) (.0089) (11.08) [6.25] [6.26] n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 .029,R-2 􏱪 .020 􏱾lsalary 􏱪 4.36 􏱕 .275 lsales 􏱕 .0179 roe (0.29) (.033) - (.0040) n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 .282,R2 􏱪 .275, where roe is the return on equity discussed in Chapter 2. For simplicity, lsalary and lsales denote the natural logs of salary and sales. We already know how to interpret these differ- ent estimated equations. But can we say that one model fits better than the other? The R-squared for equation (6.25) shows that sales and roe explain only about 2.9% of the variation in CEO salary in the sample. Both sales and roe have marginal statistical significance. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 205 Equation (6.26) shows that log(sales) and roe explain about 28.2% of the variation in log(salary). In terms of goodness-of-fit, this much higher R-squared would seem to imply that model (6.26) is much better, but this is not necessarily the case. The total sum of squares for salary in the sample is 391,732,982, while the total sum of squares for log(salary) is only 66.72. Thus, there is much less variation in log(salary) that needs to be explained. At this point, we can use features other than R2 or R- 2 to decide between these models. For example, log(sales) and roe are much more statistically significant in (6.26) than are sales and roe in (6.25), and the coefficients in (6.26) are probably of more interest. To be sure, however, we will need to make a valid goodness-of-fit comparison. In Section 6.4, we will offer a goodness-of-fit measure that does allow us to compare models where y appears in both level and log form. Controlling for Too Many Factors in Regression Analysis In many of the examples we have covered, and certainly in our discussion of omitted vari- ables bias in Chapter 3, we have worried about omitting important factors from a model that might be correlated with the independent variables. It is also possible to control for too many variables in a regression analysis. If we overemphasize goodness-of-fit, we open ourselves to controlling for factors in a regression model that should not be controlled for. To avoid this mistake, we need to remember the ceteris paribus interpretation of multiple regression models. To illustrate this issue, suppose we are doing a study to assess the impact of state beer taxes on traffic fatalities. The idea is that a higher tax on beer will reduce alcohol con- sumption, and likewise drunk driving, resulting in fewer traffic fatalities. To measure the ceteris paribus effect of taxes on fatalities, we can model fatalities as a function of several factors, including the beer tax: fatalities 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1tax 􏱕 􏱬2miles 􏱕 􏱬3 percmale 􏱕 􏱬4 perc16_21 􏱕 ..., where miles 􏱪 total miles driven. percmale 􏱪 percentage of the state population that is male. perc16_21 􏱪 percentage of the population between ages 16 and 21, and so on. Notice how we have not included a variable measuring per capita beer consumption. Are we committing an omitted variables error? The answer is no. If we control for beer consumption in this equation, then how would beer taxes affect traffic fatalities? In the equation fatalities 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1tax 􏱕 􏱬2beercons 􏱕 ..., 􏱬1 measures the difference in fatalities due to a one percentage point increase in tax, hold- ing beercons fixed. It is difficult to understand why this would be interesting. We should not be controlling for differences in beercons across states, unless we want to test for some sort of indirect effect of beer taxes. Other factors, such as gender and age distribution, should be controlled for. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 206 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data As a second example, suppose that, for a developing country, we want to estimate the effects of pesticide usage among farmers on family health expenditures. In addition to pesticide usage amounts, should we include the number of doctor visits as an explanatory variable? No. Health expenditures include doctor visits, and we would like to pick up all effects of pesticide use on health expenditures. If we include the number of doctor visits as an explanatory variable, then we are only measuring the effects of pesticide use on health expenditures other than doctor visits. It makes more sense to use number of doctor visits as a dependent variable in a separate regression on pesticide amounts. The previous examples are what can be called over controlling for factors in multiple regression. Often this results from nervousness about potential biases that might arise by leaving out an important explanatory variable. But it is important to remember the ceteris paribus nature of multiple regression. In some cases, it makes no sense to hold some fac- tors fixed precisely because they should be allowed to change when a policy variable changes. Unfortunately, the issue of whether or not to control for certain factors is not always clear-cut. For example, Betts (1995) studies the effect of high school quality on subse- quent earnings. He points out that, if better school quality results in more education, then controlling for education in the regression along with measures of quality will underesti- mate the return to quality. Betts does the analysis with and without years of education in the equation to get a range of estimated effects for quality of schooling. To see explicitly how pursuing high R-squareds can lead to trouble, consider the housing price example from Section 4.5 that illustrates the testing of multiple hypotheses. In that case, we wanted to test the rationality of housing price assessments. We regressed log(price) on log(assess), log(lotsize), log(sqrft), and bdrms and tested whether the latter three variables had zero population coefficients while log(assess) had a coefficient of unity. But what if we change the purpose of the analysis and estimate a hedonic price model, which allows us to obtain the marginal values of various housing attributes? Should we include log(assess) in the equation? The adjusted R-squared from the regression with log(assess) is .762, while the adjusted R-squared without it is .630. Based on goodness-of- fit only, we should include log(assess). But this is incorrect if our goal is to determine the effects of lot size, square footage, and number of bedrooms on housing values. Including log(assess) in the equation amounts to holding one measure of value fixed and then asking how much an additional bedroom would change another measure of value. This makes no sense for valuing housing attributes. If we remember that different models serve different purposes, and we focus on the ceteris paribus interpretation of regression, then we will not include the wrong factors in a regression model. Adding Regressors to Reduce the Error Variance We have just seen some examples of where certain independent variables should not be included in a regression model, even though they are correlated with the dependent variable. From Chapter 3, we know that adding a new independent variable to a regression can exacerbate the multicollinearity problem. On the other hand, since we are taking something out of the error term, adding a variable generally reduces the error variance. Generally, we cannot know which effect will dominate. However, there is one case that is clear: we should always include independent variables that affect y and are uncorrelated with all of the independent variables of interest. Why? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 207 Because adding such a variable does not induce multicollinearity in the population (and therefore multicollinearity in the sample should be negligible), but it will reduce the error variance. In large sample sizes, the standard errors of all OLS estimators will be reduced. As an example, consider estimating the individual demand for beer as a function of the average county beer price. It may be reasonable to assume that individual characteristics are uncorrelated with county-level prices, and so a simple regression of beer consumption on county price would suffice for estimating the effect of price on individual demand. But it is possible to get a more precise estimate of the price elasticity of beer demand by includ- ing individual characteristics, such as age and amount of education. If these factors affect demand and are uncorrelated with price, then the standard error of the price coefficient will be smaller, at least in large samples. As a second example, consider the grants for computer equipment given at the begin- ning of Section 6.3. If, in addition to the grant variable, we control for other factors that can explain college GPA, we can probably get a more precise estimate of the effect of the grant. Measures of high school grade point average and rank, SAT and ACT scores, and family background variables are good candidates. Because the grant amounts are randomly assigned, all additional control variables are uncorrelated with the grant amount; in the sample, multicollinearity between the grant amount and other independent vari- ables should be minimal. But adding the extra controls might significantly reduce the error variance, leading to a more precise estimate of the grant effect. Remember, the issue is not unbiasedness here: we obtain an unbiased and consistent estimator whether or not we add the high school performance and family background variables. The issue is getting an estimator with a smaller sampling variance. Unfortunately, cases where we have information on additional explanatory variables that are uncorrelated with the explanatory variables of interest are somewhat rare in the social sciences. But it is worth remembering that when these variables are available, they can be included in a model to reduce the error variance without inducing multicollinearity. 6.4 Prediction and Residual Analysis In Chapter 3, we defined the OLS predicted or fitted values and the OLS residuals. Pre- dictions are certainly useful, but they are subject to sampling variation, because they are obtained using the OLS estimators. Thus, in this section, we show how to obtain confidence intervals for a prediction from the OLS regression line. From Chapters 3 and 4, we know that the residuals are used to obtain the sum of squared residuals and the R-squared, so they are important for goodness-of-fit and testing. Sometimes, economists study the residuals for particular observations to learn about indi- viduals (or firms, houses, etc.) in the sample. Confidence Intervals for Predictions Suppose we have estimated the equation yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk. [6.27] When we plug in particular values of the independent variables, we obtain a prediction for y, which is an estimate of the expected value of y given the particular values for the explanatory variables. For emphasis, let c1, c2, ..., ck denote particular values for each of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 208 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data the k independent variables; these may or may not correspond to an actual data point in our sample. The parameter we would like to estimate is 􏰩0 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1c1 􏱕􏱬2c2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kck [6.28] [6.29] The estimator of 􏰩0 is 􏱪E(y􏰫x1 􏱪c1,x2 􏱪c2,...,xk 􏱪ck). 􏰩ˆ0 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1c1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2c2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkck. In practice, this is easy to compute. But what if we want some measure of the uncertainty in this predicted value? It is natural to construct a confidence interval for 􏰩0, which is centered at 􏰩ˆ0. ˆ To obtain a confidence interval for 􏰩0, we need a standard error for 􏰩0. Then, with a large df, we can construct a 95% confidence interval using the rule of thumb 􏰩ˆ0 􏲁 2􏱳se(􏰩ˆ0). (As always, we can use the exact percentiles in a t distribution.) How do we obtain the standard error of 􏰩ˆ0? This is the same problem we encountered in Section 4.4: we need to obtain a standard error for a linear combination of the OLS estimators. Here, the problem is even more complicated, because all of the OLS estimators generally appear in 􏰩ˆ0 (unless some cj are zero). Nevertheless, the same trick that we used in Section 4.4 will work here. Write 􏱬0 􏱪 􏰩0 􏱦 􏱬1c1 􏱦 ... 􏱦 􏱬kck and plug this into the equation to obtain y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u y􏱪􏰩0 􏱕􏱬1(x1 􏱦c1)􏱕􏱬2(x2 􏱦c2)􏱕...􏱕􏱬k(xk 􏱦ck)􏱕u. [6.30] In other words, we subtract the value cj from each observation on xj, and then we run the regression of yi on (xi1 􏱦 c1), ..., (xik 􏱦 ck), i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. [6.31] The predicted value in (6.29) and, more importantly, its standard error, are obtained from the intercept (or constant) in regression (6.31). As an example, we obtain a confidence interval for a prediction from a college GPA regression, where we use high school information. EXAMPLE 6.5 CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR PREDICTED COLLEGE GPA Using the data in GPA2.RAW, we obtain the following equation for predicting college GPA: 􏱾colgpa 􏱪 1.493 􏱕 .00149 sat 􏱦 .01386 hsperc (0.075) (.00007) (.00056) 􏱦 .06088 hsize 􏱕 .00546 hsize2 [6.32] (.01650) (.00227) n􏱪4,137,R2 􏱪.278,R-2 􏱪.277,􏱧ˆ􏱪.560, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 209 where we have reported estimates to several digits to reduce round-off error. What is pre- dicted college GPA, when sat 􏱪 1,200, hsperc 􏱪 30, and hsize 􏱪 5 (which means 500)? This is easy to get by plugging these values into equation (6.32): 􏱾colgpa 􏱪 2.70 (rounded to two digits). Unfortunately, we cannot use equation (6.32) directly to get a confidence interval for the expected colgpa at the given values of the independent variables. One simple way to obtain a confidence interval is to define a new set of independent variables: sat0 􏱪 sat 􏱦 1,200, hsperc0 􏱪 hsperc 􏱦 30, hsize0 􏱪 hsize 􏱦 5, and hsizesq0 􏱪 hsize2 􏱦 25. When we regress colgpa on these new independent variables, we get 􏱾colgpa 􏱪 2.700 􏱕 .00149 sat0 􏱦 .01386 hsperc0 (0.020) (.00007) (.00056) 􏱦 .06088 hsize0 􏱕 .00546 hsizesq0 (.01650) (.00227) n􏱪4,137,R2 􏱪.278,R-2 􏱪.277,􏱧ˆ􏱪.560. The only difference between this regression and that in (6.32) is the intercept, which is the prediction we want, along with its standard error, .020. It is not an accident that the slope coefficents, their standard errors, R-squared, and so on are the same as before; this pro- vides a way to check that the proper transformations were done. We can easily construct a 95% confidence interval for the expected college GPA: 2.70 􏲁 1.96(.020) or about 2.66 to 2.74. This confidence interval is rather narrow due to the very large sample size. Because the variance of the intercept estimator is smallest when each explanatory variable has zero sample mean (see Question 2.5 for the simple regression case), it follows from the regression in (6.31) that the variance of the prediction is smallest at the mean values of the xj. (That is, cj 􏱪 x-j for all j.) This result is not too surprising, since we have the most faith in our regression line near the middle of the data. As the values of the cj get farther away from the x-j, Var(yˆ) gets larger and larger. The previous method allows us to put a confidence interval around the OLS estimate of E( y􏰫x1, ..., xk) for any values of the explanatory variables. In other words, we obtain a confidence interval for the average value of y for the subpopulation with a given set of covariates. But a confidence interval for the average person in the subpopulation is not the same as a confidence interval for a particular unit (individual, family, firm, and so on) from the population. In forming a confidence interval for an unknown outcome on y, we must account for another very important source of variation: the variance in the unobserved error, which measures our ignorance of the unobserved factors that affect y. Let y0 denote the value for which we would like to construct a confidence interval, which we sometimes call a prediction interval. For example, y0 could represent a person or firm not in our original sample. Let x01, ..., x0k be the new values of the independent variables, which we assume we observe, and let u0 be the unobserved error. Therefore, we have y0 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x01 􏱕􏱬2x02 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kx0k 􏱕u0. [6.33] As before, our best prediction of y0 is the expected value of y0 given the explanatory vari- ˆables, which we estimate from the OLS regression line: yˆ0 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x01 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x02 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kx0k. The prediction error in using yˆ0 to predict y0 is eˆ0 􏱪y0 􏱦yˆ0 􏱪(􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x01 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kx0k)􏱕u0 􏱦yˆ0. [6.34] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 210 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Now, E(yˆ0) 􏱪 E(􏱬ˆ0) 􏱕 E(􏱬ˆ1)x01 􏱕 E(􏱬ˆ2)x02 􏱕 ... 􏱕 E(􏱬ˆk)x0k 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x01 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kx0k, because the 􏱬ˆj are unbiased. (As before, these expectations are all conditional on the sam- ple values of the independent variables.) Because u0 has zero mean, E(eˆ0) 􏱪 0. We have shown that the expected prediction error is zero. ˆ In finding the variance of eˆ0, note that u0 is uncorrelated with each 􏱬j, because u0 is uncorrelated with the errors in the sample used to obtain the 􏱬ˆ j. By basic properties of covariance (see Appendix B), u0 and yˆ0 are uncorrelated. Therefore, the variance of the prediction error (conditional on all in-sample values of the independent variables) is the sum of the variances: Var(eˆ0) 􏱪 Var(yˆ0) 􏱕 Var(u0) 􏱪 Var(yˆ0) 􏱕 􏱧2, [6.35] where 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(u0) is the error variance. There are two sources of variation in eˆ0. The first is the sampling error in yˆ0, which arises because we have estimated the 􏱬j. Because each 􏱬ˆj has a variance proportional to 1/n, where n is the sample size, Var(yˆ0) is proportional to 1/n. This means that, for large samples, Var(yˆ0) can be very small. By contrast, 􏱧2 is the variance of the error in the population; it does not change with the sample size. In many examples, 􏱧2 will be the dominant term in (6.35). ˆ 0 Under the classical linear model assumptions, the 􏱬j and u are normally distributed, and so eˆ0 is also normally distributed (conditional on all sample values of the explanatory variables). Earlier, we described how to obtain an unbiased estimator of Var(yˆ0), and we obtained our unbiased estimator of 􏱧2 in Chapter 3. By using these estimators, we can define the standard error of eˆ0 as se(eˆ0) 􏱪 {[se(yˆ0)]2 􏱕 􏱧ˆ2}1/2. [6.36] U s i n g t h e s a m e r e a s o n i n g f o r t h e t s t a t i s t i c s o f t h e 􏱬ˆ j , eˆ 0 / s e ( eˆ 0 ) h a s a t d i s t r i b u t i o n w i t h n 􏱦 (k 􏱕 1) degrees of freedom. Therefore, P[􏱦t.025 􏰯 eˆ0/se(eˆ0) 􏰯 t.025] 􏱪 .95, where t.025 is the 97.5th percentile in the tn􏱦k􏱦1 distribution. For large n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1, remember that t.025 􏱴 1.96. Plugging in eˆ0 􏱪 y0 􏱦 yˆ0 and rearranging gives a 95% prediction interval for y0: yˆ0 􏲁 t.025􏱳se(eˆ0); [6.37] as usual, except for small df, a good rule of thumb is yˆ0 􏲁 2se(eˆ0). This is wider than the confidence interval for yˆ0 itself because of 􏱧ˆ2 in (6.36); it often is much wider to reflect the factors in u0 that we have not accounted for. EXAMPLE 6.6 CONFIDENCE INTERVAL FOR FUTURE COLLEGE GPA Suppose we want a 95% CI for the future college GPA of a high school student with sat 􏱪 1,200, hsperc 􏱪 30, and hsize 􏱪 5. In Example 6.5, we obtained a 95% confidence interval for the average college GPA among all students with the particular characteris- tics sat 􏱪 1,200, hsperc 􏱪 30, and hsize 􏱪 5. Now, we want a 95% confidence interval for any particular student with these characteristics. The 95% prediction interval must account for the variation in the individual, unobserved characteristics that affect college performance. We have everything we need to obtain a CI for colgpa. se(yˆ0) 􏱪 .020 and Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 211 􏱧ˆ 􏱪 .560 and so, from (6.36), se(eˆ0) 􏱪 [(.020)2 􏱕 (.560)2]1/2 􏱴 .560. Notice how small se(yˆ0) is relative to 􏱧ˆ: virtually all of the variation in eˆ0 comes from the variation in u0. The 95% CI is 2.70 􏲁 1.96(.560) or about 1.60 to 3.80. This is a wide confidence interval and shows that, based on the factors we included in the regression, we cannot accurately pin down an individual’s future college grade point average. (In one sense, this is good news, as it means that high school rank and performance on the SAT do not preordain one’s per- formance in college.) Evidently, the unobserved characteristics that affect college GPA vary widely among individuals with the same observed SAT score and high school rank. Residual Analysis Sometimes, it is useful to examine individual observations to see whether the actual value of the dependent variable is above or below the predicted value; that is, to examine the residuals for the individual observations. This process is called residual analysis. Economists have been known to examine the residuals from a regression in order to aid in the purchase of a home. The following housing price example illustrates residual analysis. Housing price is related to various observable characteristics of the house. We can list all of the charac- teristics that we find important, such as size, number of bedrooms, number of bathrooms, and so on. We can use a sample of houses to estimate a relationship between price and attributes, where we end up with a predicted value and an actual value for each house. Then, we can construct the residuals, uˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 yˆi. The house with the most negative residual is, at least based on the factors we have controlled for, the most underpriced one relative to its observed characteristics. Of course, a selling price substantially below its predicted price could indicate some undesirable feature of the house that we have failed to account for, and which is therefore contained in the unobserved error. In addition to obtaining the prediction and residual, it also makes sense to compute a confidence interval for what the future selling price of the home could be, using the method described in equation (6.37). Using the data in HPRICE1.RAW, we run a regression of price on lotsize, sqrft, and bdrms. In the sample of 88 homes, the most negative residual is 􏱦120.206, for the 81st house. Therefore, the asking price for this house is $120,206 below its predicted price. There are many other uses of residual analysis. One way to rank law schools is to regress median starting salary on a variety of student characteristics (such as median LSAT scores of entering class, median college GPA of entering class, and so on) and to obtain a predicted value and residual for each law school. The law school with the largest residual has the highest predicted value added. (Of course, there is still much uncertainty about how an individual’s starting salary would compare with the median for a law school overall.) These residuals can be used along with the costs of attending each law school to determine the best value; this would require an appropriate discounting of future earnings. Residual analysis also plays a role in legal decisions. A New York Times article entitled “Judge Says Pupil’s Poverty, Not Segregation, Hurts Scores” (6/28/95) describes an important legal case. The issue was whether the poor performance on standardized tests in the Hartford School District, relative to performance in surrounding suburbs, was due to poor school quality at the highly segregated schools. The judge concluded that “the disparity in test scores does not indicate that Hartford is doing an inadequate or poor job in educating its students or that its schools are failing, because the predicted scores based upon the relevant socioeconomic factors are about at the levels that one would ex- pect.” This conclusion is based on a regression analysis of average or median scores on Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 212 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data socioeconomic characteristics of vari- ous school districts in Connecticut. The judge’s conclusion suggests that, given the poverty levels of students at Hart- ford schools, the actual test scores were similar to those predicted from a regres- sion analysis: the residual for Hartford was not sufficiently negative to conclude that the schools themselves were the cause of low test scores. Predicting y When log(y) Is the Dependent Variable Because the natural log transformation is used so often for the dependent variable in empirical economics, we devote this subsection to the issue of predicting y when log(y) is the dependent variable. As a byproduct, we will obtain a goodness-of-fit measure for the log model that can be compared with the R-squared from the level model. To obtain a prediction, it is useful to define logy 􏱪 log(y); this emphasizes that it is the log of y that is predicted in the model logy􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u. [6.38] In this equation, the xj might be transformations of other variables; for example, we could have x1 􏱪 log(sales), x2 􏱪 log(mktval), x3 􏱪 ceoten in the CEO salary example. Given the OLS estimators, we know how to predict logy for any value of the indepen- dent variables: 􏱾logy 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk. [6.39] Now, since the exponential undoes the log, our first guess for predicting y is to simply expo- nentiate the predicted value for log(y): yˆ 􏱪 exp(􏱾logy). This does not work; in fact, it will sys- tematically underestimate the expected value of y. In fact, if model (6.38) follows the CLM assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6, it can be shown that E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 exp(􏱧2/2)􏱳exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 􏱬2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk), where x denotes the independent variables and 􏱧2 is the variance of u. [If u ~ Normal(0,􏱧2), then the expected value of exp(u) is exp(􏱧2/2).] This equation shows that a simple adjust- ment is needed to predict y: yˆ 􏱪 exp(􏱧ˆ2/2)exp(􏱾logy), [6.40] where 􏱧ˆ 2 is simply the unbiased estimator of 􏱧2. Because 􏱧ˆ , the standard error of the regression, is always reported, obtaining predicted values for y is easy. Because 􏱧ˆ 2 􏱰 0, exp(􏱧ˆ2/2) 􏱰 1. For large 􏱧ˆ2, this adjustment factor can be substantially larger than unity. The prediction in (6.40) is not unbiased, but it is consistent. There are no unbiased pre- dictions of y, and in many cases, (6.40) works well. However, it does rely on the normality of the error term, u. In Chapter 5, we showed that OLS has desirable properties, even when u is not normally distributed. Therefore, it is useful to have a prediction that does not rely on normality. If we just assume that u is independent of the explanatory variables, then we have E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱮0exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 􏱬2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk), [6.41] where 􏱮0 is the expected value of exp(u), which must be greater than unity. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 6.5 How would you use residual analysis to deter- mine which professional athletes are overpaid or underpaid relative to their performance? CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 213 Given an estimate 􏱮ˆ0, we can predict y as yˆ 􏱪 􏱮ˆ0exp(􏱾logy), [6.42] which again simply requires exponentiating the predicted value from the log model and multiplying the result by 􏱮ˆ0. Two approaches suggest themselves for estimating 􏱮0 without the normality as- sumption. The first is based on 􏱮0 􏱪 E[exp(u)]. To estimate 􏱮0 we replace the population expectation with a sample average and then we replace the unobserved errors, ui, with the OLS residuals, uˆi 􏱪 log(yi) − 􏱬ˆ0 − 􏱬ˆ1xi1 − ... − 􏱬ˆkxik. This leads to the method of moments estimator (see Appendix C) ∑n 􏱮ˆ0 􏱪n􏱦1 exp(uˆ). [6.43] Not surprisingly, 􏱮ˆ0 is a consistent estimator of 􏱮0, but it is not unbiased because we have replaced ui with uˆi inside a nonlinear function. This version of 􏱮ˆ0 is a special case of what Duan (1983) called a smearing estimate. Because the OLS residuals have a zero sample average, it can be shown that, for any data set, 􏱮ˆ0 􏱰 1. (Technically, 􏱮ˆ0 would equal one if all the OLS residuals were zero, but this never happens in any interesting application.) That 􏱮ˆ 0 is necessarily greater than one is convenient because it must be that 􏱮0 􏱰 1. A different estimate of 􏱮0 is based on a simple regression through the origin. To see how it works, define mi 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxik), so that, from equation (6.41), E(yi|mi) 􏱪 􏱮0mi. If we could observe the mi, we could obtain an unbiased estimator of 􏱮0 from the regression yi on mi without an intercept. Instead, we replace the 􏱬j with their OLS estimates and obtain mˆ i 􏱪 exp(􏱾logyi), where, of course, the 􏱾logyi are the fitted values from the regression logyi on xi1, ..., xik (with an intercept). Then 􏱮ˇ0 [to distinguish it from ˆ􏱮0 in equation (6.43)] is the OLS slope estimate from the simple regression yi on ˆmi (no intercept): ∑n 􏱦1∑n 􏱮ˇ0 􏱪􏱵 mˆ2i 􏱷 􏱵 mˆiyi􏱷. [6.44] i􏱪1 i􏱪1 We will call 􏱮ˇ 0 the regression estimate of 􏱮0. Like 􏱮ˆ 0, 􏱮ˇ 0 is consistent but not unbiased. Interestingly, 􏱮ˇ0 is not guaranteed to be greater than one, although it will be in most appli- cations. If 􏱮ˇ0 is less than one, and especially if it is much less than one, it is likely that the assumption of independence between u and the xj is violated. If 􏱮ˇ0 􏱷 1, one possibility is to just use the estimate in (6.43), although this may simply be masking a problem with the linear model for log(y). We summarize the steps: Predicting y When the Dependent Variable Is log(y): 1. Obtain the fitted values, 􏱾logyi, and residuals, uˆi, from the regression logy on x1, ..., xk. 2. Obtain 􏱮ˆ0 as in equation (6.43) or 􏱮ˇ0 in equation (6.44). 3. For given values of x1, ..., xk, obtain 􏱾logy from (6.42). 4. Obtain the prediction yˆ from (6.42) (with 􏱮ˆ0 or 􏱮ˇ0). We now show how to predict CEO salaries using this procedure. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i i􏱪1 214 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 6.7 PREDICTING CEO SALARIES The model of interest is log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2log(mktval) 􏱕 􏱬3ceoten 􏱕 u, so that 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 are elasticities and 100􏱳􏱬3 is a semi-elasticity. The estimated equation using CEOSAL2.RAW is 􏱾lsalary 􏱪 4.504 􏱕 .163 lsales 􏱕 .109 lmktval 􏱕 .0117 ceoten (.257) (.039) (.050) (.0053) [6.45] n 􏱪 177, R2 􏱪 .318, where, for clarity, we let lsalary denote the log of salary, and similarly for lsales and lmktval. 􏱾 Next, we obtain mˆ i 􏱪 exp(lsalaryi) for each observation in the sample. The Duan smearing estimate from (6.43) is about 􏱮ˆ0 􏱪 1.136, and the regression esti- mate from (6.44) is 􏱮ˇ0 􏱪 1.117. We can use either estimate to predict salary for any values of sales, mktval, and ceoten. Let us find the prediction for sales 􏱪 5,000 (which means $5 billion because sales is in millions), mktval 􏱪 10,000 (or $10 billion), and ceoten 􏱪 10. From (6.45), the prediction for lsalary is 4.504 􏱕 .163 􏱳 log(5,000) 􏱕 .109 􏱳 log(10,000) 􏱕 .0117(10) 􏱴 7.013, and exp(7.013) 􏱴1,110.983. Using the estimate of 􏱮0 from (6.43), the predicted salary is about 1,262.077, or $1,262,077. Using the estimate from (6.44) gives an estimated salary of about $1,240,968. These differ from each other by much less than each differs from the naive prediction of $1,110,983. We can use the previous method of obtaining predictions to determine how well the model with log(y) as the dependent variable explains y. We already have measures for models when y is the dependent variable: the R-squared and the adjusted R-squared. The goal is to find a goodness-of-fit measure in the log(y) model that can be compared with an R-squared from a model where y is the dependent variable. There are different ways to define a goodness-of-fit measure after retransforming a model for log(y) to predict y. Here we present an approach that is easy to implement and that gives the same value whether we estimate 􏱮0 as in (6.40), (6.43), or (6.44). To motivate the measure, recall that in the linear regression equation estimated by OLS, yˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk, [6.46] the usual R-squared is simply the square of the correlation between yi and yˆi (see Section 3.2). Now, if instead we compute fitted values from (6.42)—that is, yˆi 􏱪 􏱮ˆ0mi for all observa- tions i—then it makes sense to use the square of the correlation between yi and these fitted values as an R-squared. Because correlation is unaffected if we multiply by a constant, it does not matter which estimate of 􏱮0 we use. In fact, this R-squared measure for y [not log(y)] is just the squared correlation between yi and mˆ i. We can compare this directly with the R-squared from equation (6.46). [Because the R-squared calculation does not depend on the estimate of 􏱮0, it does not allow us to choose among (6.40), (6.43), and (6.44). But we know that (6.44) minimizes the sum of squared residuals between yi and mˆi, without a constant. In other words, given the mˆi, 􏱮ˇ0 is chosen to produce the best fit based on sum of squared residuals. We are interested here in choosing between the linear model for y and log(y), and so an R-squared measure that does not depend on how we estimate 􏱮0 is suitable.] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 215 EXAMPLE 6.8 PREDICTING CEO SALARIES After we obtain the mˆ i, we just obtain the correlation between salaryi and mˆ i; it is .493. The square of it is about .243, and this is a measure of how well the log model explains the variation in salary, not log(salary). [The R2 from (6.45), .318, tells us that the log model explains about 31.8% of the variation in log(salary).] As a competing linear model, suppose we estimate a model with all variables in levels: salary 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sales 􏱕 􏱬2mktval 􏱕 􏱬3ceoten 􏱕 u. [6.47] The key is that the dependent variable is salary. We could use logs of sales or mktval on the right-hand side, but it makes more sense to have all dollar values in levels if one (salary) appears as a level. The R-squared from estimating this equation using the same 177 observations is .201. Thus, the log model explains more of the variation in salary, and so we prefer it to (6.47) on goodness-of-fit grounds. The log model is also preferred because it seems more realistic and its parameters are easier to interpret. If we maintain the full set of classical linear model assumptions in the model (6.38), we can easily obtain prediction intervals for y0 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x01 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kx0k 􏱕 u0) when we have estimated a linear model for log(y). Recall that x01, x02, ..., x0k are known values and u0 is the unobserved error that partly determines y0. From equation (6.37), a 95% predic- tion interval for logy0 􏱪 log(y0) is simply 􏱾logy0 􏲁 t.025 􏱳 se(eˆ0), where se(eˆ0) is obtained from the regression of log(y) on x1, ..., xk using the original n observations. Let cl 􏱪 􏱦t.025 􏱳 se(eˆ0) and cu 􏱪 t.025 􏱳 se(eˆ0) be the lower and upper bounds of the prediction interval for logy0. That is, P(cl 􏰯 logy0 􏰯 cu) 􏱪 .95. Because the exponential function is strictly increas- ing, it is also true that P[exp(cl) 􏰯 exp(logy0) 􏰯 exp(cu)] 􏱪 .95,that is, P[exp(cl) 􏰯 y0 􏰯 exp(cu)] 􏱪 .95. Therefore, we can take exp(cl) and exp(cu) as the lower and upper bounds, 0ˆ predictioˆn interval forˆy0 is exp[−1.96 􏱳 se(ˆe0)] exp(􏱬ˆ 0 􏱕 x0 􏱮) to exp[−1.96 􏱳 se(ˆe )] exp respectively, for a 95% prediction interval for y . For large n, t.025 􏱪 1.96, and so a 95% 0 000 0 (􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x0􏱮), where x 􏱮 is shorthand for 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk. Remember, the 􏱬ˆj and se(ˆe ) are obtained from the regression with log(y) as the dependent variable. Because we assume normality of u in (6.38), we probably would use (6.40) to obtain a point prediction for y0. Un- like in equation (6.37), this point prediction will not lie halfway between the upper and lower bounds exp(cl) and exp(cu). One can obtain different 95% prediction intervalues by choosing different quantiles in the tn−k−1 distribution. If q􏱮1 and q􏱮2 are quantiles with 􏱮2 􏱦 􏱮1 􏱪 .95, then we can choose cl 􏱪 q􏱮1se(ê0) and cu 􏲁 q􏱮2se(ê0). As an example, consider the CEO salary regression, where we make the prediction at the same values of sales, mktval, and ceoten as in Example 6.7. The standard error of the regression for (6.43) is about .505, and the standard error of 􏱾logy0 is about .075. Therefore, using equation (6.36), se(ˆe0) 􏱴 .511; as in the GPA example, the error variance swamps the estimation error in the parameters, even though here the sample size is only 177. A 95% prediction interval for salary0 is exp[−1.96 􏱳 (.511)] exp(7.013) to exp[1.96 􏱳 (.511)] exp(7.013), or about 408.071 to 3,024.678, that is, $408,071 to $3,024,678. This very wide 95% prediction interval for CEO salary at the given sales, market value, and tenure values shows that there is much else that we have not included in the regression that determines salary. Incidentally, the point prediction for salary, using (6.40), is about $1,262,075—higher than the predictions using the other estimates of 􏱮0 and closer to the lower bound than the upper bound of the 95% prediction interval. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 216 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Summary In this chapter, we have covered some important multiple regression analysis topics. Section 6.1 showed that a change in the units of measurement of an independent variable changes the OLS coefficient in the expected manner: if xj is multiplied by c, its coefficient is divided by c. If the dependent variable is multiplied by c, all OLS coefficients are multiplied by c. Neither t nor F statistics are affected by changing the units of measurement of any variables. We discussed beta coefficients, which measure the effects of the independent variables on the dependent variable in standard deviation units. The beta coefficients are obtained from a standard OLS regression after the dependent and independent variables have been transformed into z-scores. We provided a detailed discussion of functional form, including the logarithmic transfor- mation, quadratics, and interaction terms. It is helpful to summarize some of our conclusions. CONSIDERATIONS WHEN USING LOGARITHIMS 1. Thecoefficientshavepercentagechangeinterpretations.Wecanbeignorantoftheunitsof measurement of any variable that appears in logarithmic form, and changing units from, say, dollars to thousands of dollars has no effect on a variable’s coefficient when that vari- able appears in logarithmic form. 2. Logs are often used for dollar amounts that are always positive, as well as for variables such as population, especially when there is a lot of variation. They are used less often for variables measured in years, such as schooling, age, and experience. Logs are used infre- quently for variables that are already percents or proportions, such as an unemployment rate or a pass rate on a test. 3. Modelswithlog(y)asthedependentvariableoftenmorecloselysatisfytheclassicallinear model assumptions. For example, the model has a better chance of being linear, homoske- dasticity is more likely to hold, and normality is often more plausible. 4. In many cases, taking the log greatly reduces the variation of a variable, making OLS esti- mates less prone to outlier influence. However, in cases where y is a fraction and close to zero for many observations, log(yi) can have much more variability than yi. For values yi very close to zero, log(yi) is a negative number very large in magnitude. 5. If y 􏱩 0 but y 􏱪 0 is possible, we cannot use log(y). Sometimes log(1 􏱕 y) is used, but interpretation of the coefficients is difficult. 6. For large changes in an explanatory variable, we can compute a more accurate estimate of the percentage change effect. 7. It is harder (but possible) to predict y when we have estimated a model for log(y). CONSIDERATIONS WHEN USING QUADRATICS 1. A quadratic function in an explanatory variable allows for an increasing or decreasing effect. 2. The turning point of a quadratic is easily calculated, and it should be calculated to see if it makes sense. 3. Quadraticfunctionswherethecoefficientshavetheoppositesignhaveastrictlypositiveturning point; if the signs of the coefficients are the same, the turning point is at a negative value of x. 4. Aseeminglysmallcoefficientonthesquareofavariablecanbepracticallyimportantinwhat it implies about a changing slope. One can use a t test to see if the quadratic is statistically significant, and compute the slope at various values of x to see if it is practically important. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 217 5. Foramodelquadraticinavariablex,thecoefficientonxmeasuresthepartialeffectstarting from x 􏱪 0, as can be seen in equation (6.11). If zero is not a possible or interesting value of x, one can center x about a more interesting value, such as the average in the sample, before computing the square. Computing Exercise 6.12 provides an example. CONSIDERATIONS WHEN USING INTERACTIONS 1. Interaction terms allow the partial effect of an explanatory variable, say x1, to depend on the level of another variable, say x2 —and vice versa. 2. Interpreting models with interactions can be tricky. The coefficient on x1, say 􏱬1, measures the partial effect of x1 on y when x2 􏱪 0, which may be impossible or uninteresting. Centering x1 and x2 around interesting values before constructing the interaction term typically leads to an equation that is visually more appealing. 3. A standard t test can be used to determine if an interaction term is statistically significant. Computing the partial effects at different values of the explanatory variables can be used to determine the practical importance of interactions. We introduced the adjusted R-squared, R- 2, as an alternative to the usual R-squared for measuring goodness-of-fit. Whereas R2 can never fall when another variable is added to a regression, R- 2 penalizes the number of regressors and can drop when an independent variable is added. This makes R- 2 preferable for choosing between nonnested models with different numbers of explanatory variables. Neither R2 nor R- 2 can be used to compare mod- els with different dependent variables. Nevertheless, it is fairly easy to obtain goodness- of-fit measures for choosing between y and log(y) as the dependent variable, as shown in Section 6.4. - In Section 6.3, we discussed the somewhat subtle problem of relying too much on R2 or R2 in arriving at a final model: it is possible to control for too many factors in a regression model. For this reason, it is important to think ahead about model specification, particularly the ceteris paribus nature of the multiple regression equation. Explanatory variables that affect y and are uncorrelated with all the other explanatory variables can be used to reduce the error variance without inducing multicollinearity. In Section 6.4, we demonstrated how to obtain a confidence interval for a prediction made from an OLS regression line. We also showed how a confidence interval can be constructed for a future, unknown value of y. Occasionally, we want to predict y when log(y) is used as the dependent variable in a regression model. Section 6.4 explains this simple method. Finally, we are sometimes interested in knowing about the sign and magnitude of the residuals for particular observations. Residual analysis can be used to determine whether particular members of the sample have predicted values that are well above or well below the actual outcomes. Key Terms Adjusted R-Squared Beta Coefficients Bootstrap Bootstrap Standard Error Interaction Effect Nonnested Models Over Controlling Population R-Squared Prediction Error Prediction Interval Predictions Quadratic Functions Resampling Method Residual Analysis Smearing Estimate Standardized Coefficients Variance of the Prediction Error Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 218 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Problems 1 The following equation was estimated using the data in CEOSAL1.RAW: 􏱾log(salary) 􏱪 4.322 􏱕 .276 log(sales) 􏱕 .0215 roe 􏱦 .00008 roe2 (.324) (.033) (.0129) (.00026) n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 .282. This equation allows roe to have a diminishing effect on log(salary). Is this generality nec- essary? Explain why or why not. 2 Let􏱬ˆ0,􏱬ˆ1,...,􏱬ˆkbetheOLSestimatesfromtheregressionofyionxi1,...,xik,i􏱪1,2,...,n. For nonzero constants c1, ..., ck, argue that the OLS intercept and slopes from the regression of c0yi on c1xi1, ..., ckxik, i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, are given by 􏱬 ̃0 􏱪 c0􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 (c0/c1)􏱬ˆ1, ..., 􏱬 ̃k 􏱪 (c0/ck)􏱬ˆ k. [Hint: Use the fact that the 􏱬ˆ j solve the first order conditions in (3.13), and the 􏱬 ̃j must solve the first order conditions involving the rescaled dependent and independent variables.] 3 Using the data in RDCHEM.RAW, the following equation was obtained by OLS: 􏱾rdintens 􏱪 2.613 􏱕 .00030 sales 􏱦 .0000000070 sales2 (.429) (.00014) (.0000000037) n 􏱪 32, R2 􏱪 .1484. (i) At what point does the marginal effect of sales on rdintens become negative? (ii) Would you keep the quadratic term in the model? Explain. (iii) Define salesbil as sales measured in billions of dollars: salesbil 􏱪 sales/1,000. Rewrite the estimated equation with salesbil and salesbil2 as the independent variables. Be sure to report standard errors and the R-squared. [Hint: Note that salesbil2 􏱪 sales2/(1,000)2.] (iv) For the purpose of reporting the results, which equation do you prefer? 4 The following model allows the return to education to depend upon the total amount of both parents’ education, called pareduc: log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2educ􏱳pareduc 􏱕 􏱬3exper 􏱕 􏱬4tenure 􏱕 u. (i) Show that, in decimal form, the return to another year of education in this model is ∆log(wage)/∆educ 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2pareduc. What sign do you expect for 􏱬2? Why? (ii) Using the data in WAGE2.RAW, the estimated equation is 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 5.65 􏱕 .047 educ 􏱕 .00078 educ􏱳pareduc 􏱕 (.13) (.010) (.00021) .019 exper 􏱕 .010 tenure (.004) (.003) n 􏱪 722, R2 􏱪 .169. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 219 (Only 722 observations contain full information on parents’ education.) Interpret the coefficient on the interaction term. It might help to choose two specific values for pareduc—for example, pareduc 􏱪 32 if both parents have a college education, or pareduc 􏱪 24 if both parents have a high school education—and to compare the estimated return to educ. (iii) When pareduc is added as a separate variable to the equation, we get: 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 4.94 􏱕 .097 educ 􏱕 .033 pareduc 􏱦 .0016 educ􏱳pareduc (.38) (.027) (.017) (.0012) 􏱕 .020 exper 􏱕 .010 tenure (.004) (.003) n 􏱪 722, R2 􏱪 .174. Does the estimated return to education now depend positively on parent education? Test the null hypothesis that the return to education does not depend on parent education. 5 InExample4.2,wherethepercentageofstudentsreceivingapassingscoreonatenth-grade math exam (math10) is the dependent variable, does it make sense to include sci11—the per- centage of eleventh graders passing a science exam—as an additional explanatory variable? 6 Whenatndrte2andACT􏱳atndrteareaddedtotheequationestimatedin(6.19),theR-squared becomes .232. Are these additional terms jointly significant at the 10% level? Would you include them in the model? 7 Thefollowingthreeequationswereestimatedusingthe1,534observationsin401K.RAW: 􏱾prate 􏱪 80.29 􏱕 5.44 mrate 􏱕 .269 age 􏱦 .00013 totemp (.78) (.52) (.045) (.00004) R2 􏱪.100,R-2 􏱪.098. 􏱾prate 􏱪 97.32 􏱕 5.02 mrate 􏱕 .314 age 􏱦 2.66 log(totemp) (1.95) (0.51) (.044) (.28) R2 􏱪.144,R-2 􏱪.142. 􏱾prate 􏱪 80.62 􏱕 5.34 mrate 􏱕 .290 age 􏱦 .00043 totemp (.78) (.52) (.045) (.00009) 􏱕 .0000000039 totemp2 (.0000000010) R2 􏱪.108,R-2 􏱪.106. Which of these three models do you prefer? Why? 8 Supposewewanttoestimatetheeffectsofalcoholconsumption(alcohol)oncollegegrade point average (colGPA). In addition to collecting information on grade point averages and alcohol usage, we also obtain attendance information (say, percentage of lectures attended, called attend). A standardized test score (say, SAT) and high school GPA (hsGPA) are also available. (i) Should we include attend along with alcohol as explanatory variables in a multiple regression model? (Think about how you would interpret 􏱬alcohol.) (ii) Should SAT and hsGPA be included as explanatory variables? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 220 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 9 If we start with (6.38) under the CLM assumptions, assume large n, and ignore the estimation error in the 􏱬ˆj, a 95% prediction interval for y0 is [exp(􏱦1.96􏱧ˆ) exp(􏱾logy0), exp (1.96􏱧ˆ) exp(􏱾logy0)]. The point prediction for y0 isyˆ0 􏱪 exp(􏱧ˆ2/2) exp(􏱾logy0). (i) For what values of 􏱧ˆ will the point prediction be in the 95% prediction interval? Does this condition seem likely to hold in most applications? (ii) Verify that the condition from part (i) is satisfied in the CEO salary example. Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in KIELMC.RAW, only for the year 1981, to answer the following ques- tions. The data are for houses that sold during 1981 in North Andover, Massachusetts; 1981 was the year construction began on a local garbage incinerator. (i) To study the effects of the incinerator location on housing price, consider the simple regression model log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(dist) 􏱕 u, where price is housing price in dollars and dist is distance from the house to the incinerator measured in feet. Interpreting this equation causally, what sign do you expect for 􏱬1 if the presence of the incinerator depresses housing prices? Estimate this equation and interpret the results. (ii) To the simple regression model in part (i), add the variables log(intst), log(area), log(land), rooms, baths, and age, where intst is distance from the home to the inter- state, area is square footage of the house, land is the lot size in square feet, rooms is total number of rooms, baths is number of bathrooms, and age is age of the house in years. Now, what do you conclude about the effects of the incinerator? Explain why (i) and (ii) give conflicting results. (iii) Add [log(intst)]2 to the model from part (ii). Now what happens? What do you conclude about the importance of functional form? (iv) Is the square of log(dist) significant when you add it to the model from part (iii)? C2 Use the data in WAGE1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Use OLS to estimate the equation log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 u and report the results using the usual format. (ii) Is exper2 statistically significant at the 1% level? (iii) Using the approximation %∆w􏱾age 􏱴 100(􏱬ˆ2 􏱕 2􏱬ˆ3exper)∆exper, find the approximate return to the fifth year of experience. What is the approxi- mate return to the twentieth year of experience? (iv) At what value of exper does additional experience actually lower predicted log(wage)? How many people have more experience in this sample? C3 Consider a model where the return to education depends upon the amount of work expe- rience (and vice versa): log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3educ􏱳exper 􏱕 u. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. C4 Use (i) Estimate the model CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 221 (i) Show that the return to another year of education (in decimal form), holding exper fixed, is 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬3exper. (ii) State the null hypothesis that the return to education does not depend on the level of exper. What do you think is the appropriate alternative? (iii) Use the data in WAGE2.RAW to test the null hypothesis in (ii) against your stated alternative. (iv) Let􏰩1denotethereturntoeducation(indecimalform),whenexper􏱪10:􏰩1􏱪􏱬1􏱕 10􏱬3. Obtain 􏰩ˆ1 and a 95% confidence interval for 􏰩1. (Hint: Write 􏱬1 􏱪 􏰩1 􏱦 10􏱬3 and plug this into the equation; then rearrange. This gives the regression for ob- taining the confidence interval for 􏰩1.) the data in GPA2.RAW for this exercise. sat 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1hsize 􏱕 􏱬2hsize2 􏱕 u, where hsize is the size of the graduating class (in hundreds), and write the results in the usual form. Is the quadratic term statistically significant? (ii) Using the estimated equation from part (i), what is the “optimal” high school size? Justify your answer. (iii) Is this analysis representative of the academic performance of all high school seniors? Explain. (iv) Find the estimated optimal high school size, using log(sat) as the dependent variable. Is it much different from what you obtained in part (ii)? C5 Use (i) Estimate the model the housing price data in HPRICE1.RAW for this exercise. log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(lotsize) 􏱕 􏱬2log(sqrft) 􏱕 􏱬3bdrms 􏱕 u and report the results in the usual OLS format. (ii) Find the predicted value of log(price), when lotsize 􏱪 20,000, sqrft 􏱪 2,500, and bdrms 􏱪 4. Using the methods in Section 6.4, find the predicted value of price at the same values of the explanatory variables. (iii) For explaining variation in price, decide whether you prefer the model from part (i) or the model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lotsize 􏱕 􏱬2sqrft 􏱕 􏱬3bdrms 􏱕 u. the data in VOTE1.RAW for this exercise. C6 Use (i) Consider a model with an interaction between expenditures: voteA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1prtystrA 􏱕 􏱬2expendA 􏱕 􏱬3expendB 􏱕 􏱬4expendA􏱳expendB 􏱕 u. What is the partial effect of expendB on voteA, holding prtystrA and expendA fixed? What is the partial effect of expendA on voteA? Is the expected sign for 􏱬4 obvious? (ii) Estimate the equation in part (i) and report the results in the usual form. Is the interaction term statistically significant? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 222 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (iii) Find the average of expendA in the sample. Fix expendA at 300 (for $300,000). What is the estimated effect of another $100,000 spent by Candidate B on voteA? Is this a large effect? (iv) Now fix expendB at 100. What is the estimated effect of ∆expendA 􏱪 100 on voteA? Does this make sense? (v) Now, estimate a model that replaces the interaction with shareA, Candidate A’s percentage share of total campaign expenditures. Does it make sense to hold both expendA and expendB fixed, while changing shareA? (vi) (Requires calculus) In the model from part (v), find the partial effect of expendB on voteA, holding prtystrA and expendA fixed. Evaluate this at expendA 􏱪 300 and expendB 􏱪 0 and comment on the results. C7 Use the data in ATTEND.RAW for this exercise. (i) In the model of Example 6.3, argue that ∆stndfnl/∆priGPA 􏱴 􏱬2 􏱕 2􏱬4 priGPA 􏱕 􏱬6atndrte. Use equation (6.19) to estimate the partial effect when priGPA 􏱪 2.59 and atndrte 􏱪 82. Interpret your estimate. (ii) Show that the equation can be written as stndfnl 􏱪 􏰩0 􏱕 􏱬1atndrte 􏱕 􏰩2 priGPA 􏱕 􏱬3 ACT 􏱕 􏱬4(priGPA 􏱦 2.59)2 􏱕 􏱬5 ACT 2 􏱕 􏱬6 priGPA(atndrte 􏱦 82) 􏱕 u, where 􏰩2 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 2􏱬4(2.59) 􏱕 􏱬6(82). (Note that the intercept has changed, but this is unimportant.) Use this to obtain the standard error of 􏰩ˆ2 from part (i). (iii) Suppose that, in place of priGPA(atndrte 􏱦 82), you put (priGPA 􏱦 2.59)􏱳 (atndrte 􏱦 82). Now how do you interpret the coefficients on atndrte and priGPA? C8 Use the data in HPRICE1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate the model price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lotsize 􏱕 􏱬2sqrft 􏱕 􏱬3bdrms 􏱕 u and report the results in the usual form, including the standard error of the regression. Obtain predicted price, when we plug in lotsize 􏱪 10,000, sqrft 􏱪 2,300, and bdrms 􏱪 4; round this price to the nearest dollar. (ii) Run a regression that allows you to put a 95% confidence interval around the predicted value in part (i). Note that your prediction will differ somewhat due to rounding error. (iii) Let price0 be the unknown future selling price of the house with the characteristics used in parts (i) and (ii). Find a 95% CI for price0 and comment on the width of this confidence interval. C9 The data set NBASAL.RAW contains salary information and career statistics for 269 players in the National Basketball Association (NBA). (i) Estimate a model relating points-per-game (points) to years in the league (exper), age, and years played in college (coll). Include a quadratic in exper; the other variables should appear in level form. Report the results in the usual way. (ii) Holding college years and age fixed, at what value of experience does the next year of experience actually reduce points-per-game? Does this make sense? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. C10 Use (i) Estimate the equation CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 223 (iii) Why do you think coll has a negative and statistically significant coefficient? (Hint: NBA players can be drafted before finishing their college careers and even directly out of high school.) (iv) Add a quadratic in age to the equation. Is it needed? What does this appear to imply about the effects of age, once experience and education are controlled for? (v) Now regress log(wage) on points, exper, exper2, age, and coll. Report the results in the usual format. (vi) Test whether age and coll are jointly significant in the regression from part (v). What does this imply about whether age and education have separate effects on wage, once productivity and seniority are accounted for? the data in BWGHT2.RAW for this exercise. log(bwght) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1npvis 􏱕 􏱬2npvis2 􏱕 u by OLS, and report the results in the usual way. Is the quadratic term significant? (ii) Show that, based on the equation from part (i), the number of prenatal visits that maximizes log(bwght) is estimated to be about 22. How many women had at least 22 prenatal visits in the sample? (iii) Does it make sense that birth weight is actually predicted to decline after 22 prenatal visits? Explain. (iv) Add mother’s age to the equation, using a quadratic functional form. Holding npvis fixed, at what mother’s age is the birth weight of the child maximized? What fraction of women in the sample are older than the “optimal” age? (v) Would you say that mother’s age and number of prenatal visits explain a lot of the variation in log(bwght)? (vi) Using quadratics for both npvis and age, decide whether using the natural log or the level of bwght is better for predicting bwght. C11 Use (i) Run the regression ecolbs on ecoprc, regprc and report the results in the usual APPLE.RAW to verify some of the claims made in Section 6.3. form, including the R-squared and adjusted R-squared. Interpret the coefficients on the price variables and comment on their signs and magnitudes. (ii) Are the price variables statistically significant? Report the p-values for the individual t tests. (iii) What is the range of fitted values for ecolbs? What fraction of the sample reports ecolbs 􏱪 0? Comment. (iv) Do you think the price variables together do a good job of explaining variation in ecolbs? Explain. (v) Add the variables faminc, hhsize (household size), educ, and age to the regression from part (i). Find the p-value for their joint significance. What do you conclude? (vi) Run separate simple regressions of ecolbs on ecoprc and then ecolbs on regprc. How do the simple regression coefficients compare with the multiple regression from part (i)? Find the correlation coefficient between ecoprc and regprc to help explain your findings. C12 Use person households; see also Computer Exercise C8 in Chapter 4. (i) What is the youngest age of people in this sample? How many people are at that age? the subset of 401KSUBS.RAW with fsize 􏱪 1; this restricts the analysis to single- Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 224 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (ii) In the model nettfa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2age 􏱕 􏱬3age2 􏱕 u, what is the literal interpretation of 􏱬2? By itself, is it of much interest? (iii) Estimate the model from part (ii) and report the results in standard form. Are you concerned that the coefficient on age is negative? Explain. (iv) Because the youngest people in the sample are 25, it makes sense to think that, for a given level of income, the lowest average amount of net total financial assets is at age 25. Recall that the partial effect of age on nettfa is 􏱬2 􏱕 2􏱬3age, so the partial effect at age 25 is 􏱬2 􏱕 2􏱬3(25) 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 50􏱬3; call this 􏰩2. Find 􏰩ˆ2 and ˆ obtain the two-sided p-value for testing H0: 􏰩2 􏱪 0. You should conclude that 􏰩2 is small and very statistically insignificant. [Hint: One way to do this is to estimate the model nettfa 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏰩2age 􏱕 􏱬3(age 􏱦 25)2 􏱕 u, where the intercept, 􏱮0, is different from 􏱬0. There are other ways, too.] (v) Because the evidence against H0: 􏰩2 􏱪 0 is very weak, set it to zero and estimate the model nettfa 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬3(age 􏱦 25)2 􏱕 u. In terms of goodness-of-fit, does this model fit better than that in part (ii)? (vi) For the estimated equation in part (v), set inc 􏱪 30 (roughly, the average value) and graph the relationship between nettfa and age, but only for age 􏱸 25. Describe what you see. (vii) Check to see whether including a quadratic in inc is necessary. C13 Use the data in MEAP00.RAW to answer this question. (i) Estimate the model math4 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬2lexppp 􏱕 􏱬2lenroll 􏱕 􏱬3lunch 􏱕 u by OLS, and report the results in the usual form. Is each explanatory variable statistically significant at the 5% level? (ii) Obtain the fitted values from the regression in part (i). What is the range of fitted values? How does it compare with the range of the actual data on math4? (iii) Obtaintheresidualsfromtheregressioninpart(i).Whatisthebuildingcodeofthe school that has the largest (positive) residual? Provide an interpretation of this residual. (iv) Add quadratics of all explanatory variables to the equation, and test them for joint significance. Would you leave them in the model? (v) Returning to the model in part (i), divide the dependent variable and each explanatory variable by its sample standard deviation, and rerun the regression. (Include an inter- cept unless you also first subtract the mean from each variable.) In terms of standard deviation units, which explanatory variable has the largest effect on the math pass rate? C14 Use the data in BENEFITS.RAW to answer this question. It is a school-level data set at the K–5 level on average teacher salary and benefits. See Example 4.10 for background. (i) Regress lavgsal on bs and report the results in the usual form. Can you reject H0: 􏱬bs 􏱪 0 against a two-sided alternative? Can you reject H0: 􏱬bs 􏱪 −1 against H1: 􏱬bs 􏱰 −1? Report the p-values for both tests. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 6 Multiple Regression Analysis: Further Issues 225 (ii) Define lbs 􏱪 log(bs). Find the range of values for lbs and find its standard deviation. How do these compare to the range and standard deviation for bs? (iii) Regress lavgsal on lbs. Does this fit better than the regression from part (i)? (iv) Estimate the equation lavgsal 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1bs 􏱕 􏱬2 lenroll 􏱕 􏱬3lstaff 􏱕 􏱬4lunch 􏱕 u and report the results in the usual form. What happens to the coefficient on bs? Is it now statistically different from zero? (v) Interpret the coefficient on lstaff. Why do you think it is negative? (vi) Addlunch2totheequationfrompart(iv).Isitstatisticallysignificant?Computethe turning point (minimum value) in the quadratic, and show that it is within the range of the observed data on lunch. How many values of lunch are higher than the calculated turning point? (vii) Based on the findings from part (vi), describe how teacher salaries relate to school poverty rates. In terms of teacher salary, and holding other factors fixed, is it bet- ter to teach at a school with lunch 􏱪 0 (no poverty), lunch 􏱪 50, or lunch 􏱪 100 (all kids eligible for the free lunch program)? APPENDIX 6A 6A. A Brief Introduction to Bootstrapping In many cases where formulas for standard errors are hard to obtain mathematically, or where they are thought not to be very good approximations to the true sampling variation of an estimator, we can rely on a resampling method. The general idea is to treat the observed data as a population that we can draw samples from. The most common resam- pling method is the bootstrap. (There are actually several versions of the bootstrap, but the most general, and most easily applied, is called the nonparametric bootstrap, and that is what we describe here.) ˆ Suppose we have an estimate, 􏰩, of a population parameter, 􏰩. We obtained this estimate, which could be a function of OLS estimates (or estimates that we cover in later chapters), from a random sample of size n. We would like to obtain a standard error for 􏰩ˆ that can be used for constructing t statistics or confidence intervals. Remarkably, we can obtain a valid standard error by computing the estimate from different random samples drawn from the original data. Implementation is easy. If we list our observations from 1 through n, we draw n numbers randomly, with replacement, from this list. This produces a new data set (of size n) that consists of the original data, but with many observations appearing multiple times (except in the rather unusual case that we resample the original data). Each time we randomly sample from the original data, we can estimate 􏰩 using the same procedure that we used on the original data. Let 􏰩ˆ(b) denote the estimate from bootstrap sample b. Now, if we repeat the resampling and estimation m times, we have m new estimates, {􏰩ˆ(b): b 􏱪 1, 2, ..., m}. The bootstrap standard error of 􏰩ˆ is just the sample standard deviation of the 􏰩ˆ(b), namely, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 226 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data m - 1/2 bse(􏰩ˆ) 􏱪 􏰻(m 􏱦 1)􏱦1 ∑ (􏰩ˆ(b) 􏱦 􏰩ˆ)2 􏰿 , [6.48] b􏱪1 where 􏰩ˆ- is the average of the bootstrap estimates. If obtaining an estimate of 􏰩 on a sample of size n requires little computational time, as in the case of OLS and all the other estimators we encounter in this text, we can afford to choose m—the number of bootstrap replications—to be large. A typical value is m 􏱪 1,000, but even m 􏱪 500 or a somewhat smaller value can produce a reliable standard error. Note that the size of m—the number of times we resample the original data—has nothing to do with the sample size, n. (For certain estimation problems beyond the scope of this text, a large n can force one to do fewer bootstrap replications.) Many statistics and econometrics packages have built-in bootstrap commands, and this makes the cal- culation of bootstrap standard errors simple, especially compared with the work often required to obtain an analytical formula for an asymptotic standard error. One can actually do better in most cases by using the bootstrap sample to compute p-values for t statistics (and F statistics), or for obtaining confidence intervals, rather than obtaining a bootstrap standard error to be used in the construction of t statistics or confi- dence intervals. See Horowitz (2001) for a comprehensive treatment. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information: Binary (or Dummy) Variables In previous chapters, the dependent and independent variables in our multiple regres- sion models have had quantitative meaning. Just a few examples include hourly wage rate, years of education, college grade point average, amount of air pollution, level of firm sales, and number of arrests. In each case, the magnitude of the variable conveys useful information. In empirical work, we must also incorporate qualitative factors into regression models. The gender or race of an individual, the industry of a firm (manufactur- ing, retail, and so on), and the region in the United States where a city is located (South, North, West, and so on) are all considered to be qualitative factors. Most of this chapter is dedicated to qualitative independent variables. After we discuss the appropriate ways to describe qualitative information in Section 7.1, we show how qualitative explanatory variables can be easily incorporated into multiple regression models in Sections 7.2, 7.3, and 7.4. These sections cover almost all of the popular ways that qualitative independent variables are used in cross-sectional regression analysis. In Section 7.5, we discuss a binary dependent variable, which is a particular kind of qualitative dependent variable. The multiple regression model has an interesting interpre- tation in this case and is called the linear probability model. While much maligned by some econometricians, the simplicity of the linear probability model makes it useful in many empirical contexts. We will describe its drawbacks in Section 7.5, but they are often secondary in empirical work. 7.1 Describing Qualitative Information Qualitative factors often come in the form of binary information: a person is female or male; a person does or does not own a personal computer; a firm offers a certain kind of employee pension plan or it does not; a state administers capital punishment or it does not. In all of these examples, the relevant information can be captured by defining a binary variable or a zero-one variable. In econometrics, binary variables are most commonly called dummy variables, although this name is not especially descriptive. 227 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 228 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data TABLE 7.1 A Partial Listing of the Data in WAGE1.RAW person wage educ exper female married 1 3.10 11 2 1 0 2 3.24 12 22 1 1 3 3.00 11 2 0 0 4 6.00 8 44 0 1 5 5.30 12 7 0 1 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 525 11.56 16 5 0 1 526 3.50 14 5 1 0 In defining a dummy variable, we must decide which event is assigned the value one and which is assigned the value zero. For example, in a study of individual wage determi- nation, we might define female to be a binary variable taking on the value one for females and the value zero for males. The name in this case indicates the event with the value one. The same information is captured by defining male to be one if the person is male and zero if the person is female. Either of these is better than using gender because this name does not make it clear when the dummy variable is one: does gender 􏱪 1 correspond to male or female? What we call our variables is unimportant for get- ting regression results, but it always helps to choose names that clarify equations and expositions. Suppose in the wage example that we have chosen the name female to indicate gender. Further, we define a binary variable married to equal one if a person is married and zero if otherwise. Table 7.1 gives a partial listing of a wage data set that might result. We see that Person 1 is female and not married, Person 2 is female and married, Person 3 is male and not married, and so on. Why do we use the values zero and one to describe qualitative information? In a sense, these values are arbitrary: any two different values would do. The real benefit of capturing qualitative information using zero-one variables is that it leads to regression models where the parameters have very natural interpretations, as we will see now. 7.2 A Single Dummy Independent Variable How do we incorporate binary information into regression models? In the simplest case, with only a single dummy explanatory variable, we just add it as an independent variable in the equation. For example, consider the following simple model of hourly wage determination: wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 female 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u. [7.1] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 7.1 Suppose that, in a study comparing elec- tion outcomes between Democratic and Republican candidates, you wish to indi- cate the party of each candidate. Is a name such as party a wise choice for a binary variable in this case? What would be a better name? © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 229 We use 􏱛0 as the parameter on female in order to highlight the interpretation of the parameters multiplying dummy variables; later, we will use whatever notation is most convenient. In model (7.1), only two observed factors affect wage: gender and education. Because female 􏱪 1 when the person is female, and female 􏱪 0 when the person is male, the parameter 􏱛0 has the following interpretation: 􏱛0 is the difference in hourly wage between females and males, given the same amount of education (and the same error term u). Thus, the coefficient 􏱛0 determines whether there is discrimination against women: if 􏱛0 􏱷 0, then, for the same level of other factors, women earn less than men on average. In terms of expectations, if we assume the zero conditional mean assumption E(u􏰫 female,educ) 􏱪 0, then 􏱛0 􏱪 E(wage􏰫 female 􏱪 1,educ) 􏱦 E(wage􏰫 female 􏱪 0,educ). Because female 􏱪 1 corresponds to females and female 􏱪 0 corresponds to males, we can write this more simply as 􏱛0 􏱪 E(wage􏰫 female,educ) 􏱦 E(wage􏰫male,educ). [7.2] The key here is that the level of education is the same in both expectations; the difference, 􏱛0, is due to gender only. The situation can be depicted graphically as an intercept shift between males and females. In Figure 7.1, the case 􏱛0 􏱷 0 is shown, so that men earn a fixed amount more per F I G U R E 7 . 1 Graph of wage 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰬0 female 􏱕 􏱮1 educ for 􏰬0 􏱼 0. wage men: wage = 0 1 1educ slope = 1 women: wage = ( 0 1 0) + 1 educ 0 010 0 educ Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 230 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data hour than women. The difference does not depend on the amount of education, and this explains why the wage-education profiles for women and men are parallel. At this point, you may wonder why we do not also include in (7.1) a dummy vari- able, say male, which is one for males and zero for females. This would be redundant. In (7.1), the intercept for males is 􏱬0, and the intercept for females is 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0. Because there are just two groups, we only need two different intercepts. This means that, in addition to 􏱬0, we need to use only one dummy variable; we have chosen to include the dummy vari- able for females. Using two dummy variables would introduce perfect collinearity because female 􏱕 male 􏱪 1, which means that male is a perfect linear function of female. Includ- ing dummy variables for both genders is the simplest example of the so-called dummy variable trap, which arises when too many dummy variables describe a given number of groups. We will discuss this problem later. In (7.1), we have chosen males to be the base group or benchmark group, that is, the group against which comparisons are made. This is why 􏱬0 is the intercept for males, and 􏱛0 is the difference in intercepts between females and males. We could choose females as the base group by writing the model as wage􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰸0male􏱕􏱬1educ􏱕u, where the intercept for females is 􏱮0 and the intercept for males is 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸0; this implies that 􏱮0 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 and 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸0 􏱪 􏱬0. In any application, it does not matter how we choose the base group, but it is important to keep track of which group is the base group. Some researchers prefer to drop the overall intercept in the model and to include dummy variables for each group. The equation would then be wage 􏱪 􏱬0male 􏱕 􏱮0 female 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u, where the intercept for men is 􏱬0 and the intercept for women is 􏱮0. There is no dummy variable trap in this case because we do not have an overall intercept. However, this formulation has little to offer, since testing for a difference in the intercepts is more difficult, and there is no generally agreed upon way to compute R-squared in regressions without an intercept. Therefore, we will always include an over- all intercept for the base group. Nothing much changes when more explanatory variables are involved. Taking males as the base group, a model that controls for experience and tenure in addition to education is wage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 female 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 u. [7.3] If educ, exper, and tenure are all relevant productivity characteristics, the null hypothesis of no difference between men and women is H0: 􏱛0 􏱪 0. The alternative that there is dis- crimination against women is H1: 􏱛0 􏱷 0. How can we actually test for wage discrimination? The answer is simple: just estimate the model by OLS, exactly as before, and use the usual t statistic. Nothing changes about the mechanics of OLS or the statistical theory when some of the independent variables are defined as dummy variables. The only difference with what we have done up until now is in the interpretation of the coefficient on the dummy variable. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 231 EXAMPLE 7.1 HOURLY WAGE EQUATION Using the data in WAGE1.RAW, we estimate model (7.3). For now, we use wage, rather than log(wage), as the dependent variable: 􏱵wage 􏱪 􏱦1.57 􏱦 1.81 female 􏱕 .572 educ (.72) (.26) (.049) 􏱕 .025 exper 􏱕 .141 tenure (.012) (.021) n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .364. [7.4] The negative intercept—the intercept for men, in this case—is not very meaningful because no one has zero values for all of educ, exper, and tenure in the sample. The coefficient on female is interesting because it measures the average difference in hourly wage between a man and a woman who have the same levels of educ, exper, and tenure. If we take a woman and a man with the same levels of education, experience, and tenure, the woman earns, on average, $1.81 less per hour than the man. (Recall that these are 1976 wages.) It is important to remember that, because we have performed multiple regression and controlled for educ, exper, and tenure, the $1.81 wage differential cannot be explained by different average levels of education, experience, or tenure between men and women. We can conclude that the differential of $1.81 is due to gender or factors associated with gen- der that we have not controlled for in the regression. [In 2003 dollars, the wage differential is about 3.23(1.81) 􏱴 5.85.] It is informative to compare the coefficient on female in equation (7.4) to the estimate we get when all other explanatory variables are dropped from the equation: 􏱵wage 􏱪 7.10 􏱦 2.51 female (.21) (.30) [7.5] n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .116. The coefficients in (7.5) have a simple interpretation. The intercept is the average wage for men in the sample (let female 􏱪 0), so men earn $7.10 per hour on average. The coef- ficient on female is the difference in the average wage between women and men. Thus, the average wage for women in the sample is 7.10 􏱦 2.51 􏱪 4.59, or $4.59 per hour. (Inciden- tally, there are 274 men and 252 women in the sample.) Equation (7.5) provides a simple way to carry out a comparison-of-means test between the two groups, which in this case are men and women. The estimated difference, 􏱦2.51, has a t statistic of 􏱦8.37, which is very statistically significant (and, of course, $2.51 is economically large as well). Generally, simple regression on a constant and a dummy variable is a straightforward way to compare the means of two groups. For the usual t test to be valid, we must assume that the homoskedasticity assumption holds, which means that the population variance in wages for men is the same as that for women. The estimated wage differential between men and women is larger in (7.5) than in (7.4) because (7.5) does not control for differences in education, experience, and tenure, and these are lower, on average, for women than for men in this sample. Equation (7.4) gives a more reliable estimate of the ceteris paribus gender wage gap; it still indicates a very large differential. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 232 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data In many cases, dummy independent variables reflect choices of individuals or other economic units (as opposed to something predetermined, such as gender). In such situations, the matter of causality is again a central issue. In the following example, we would like to know whether personal computer ownership causes a higher college grade point average. EXAMPLE 7.2 EFFECTS OF COMPUTER OWNERSHIP ON COLLEGE GPA In order to determine the effects of computer ownership on college grade point average, we estimate the model colGPA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0PC 􏱕 􏱬1hsGPA 􏱕 􏱬2ACT 􏱕 u, where the dummy variable PC equals one if a student owns a personal computer and zero oth- erwise. There are various reasons PC ownership might have an effect on colGPA. A student’s work might be of higher quality if it is done on a computer, and time can be saved by not hav- ing to wait at a computer lab. Of course, a student might be more inclined to play computer games or surf the Internet if he or she owns a PC, so it is not obvious that 􏱛0 is positive. The variables hsGPA (high school GPA) and ACT (achievement test score) are used as controls: it could be that stronger students, as measured by high school GPA and ACT scores, are more likely to own computers. We control for these factors because we would like to know the av- erage effect on colGPA if a student is picked at random and given a personal computer. Using the data in GPA1.RAW, we obtain 􏱵colGPA 􏱪 1.26 􏱕 .157 PC 􏱕 .447 hsGPA 􏱕 .0087 ACT (.33) (.057) (.094) (.0105) [7.6] n 􏱪 141, R2 􏱪 .219. This equation implies that a student who owns a PC has a predicted GPA about .16 points higher than a comparable student without a PC (remember, both colGPA and hsGPA are on a four-point scale). The effect is also very statistically significant, with tPC 􏱪 .157/.057 􏱴 2.75. What happens if we drop hsGPA and ACT from the equation? Clearly, dropping the latter variable should have very little effect, as its coefficient and t statistic are very small. But hsGPA is very significant, and so dropping it could affect the estimate of 􏱬PC. Regressing colGPA on PC gives an estimate on PC equal to about .170, with a standard error of .063; in this case, 􏱬ˆPC and its t statistic do not change by much. In the exercises at the end of the chapter, you will be asked to control for other factors in the equation to see if the computer ownership effect disappears, or if it at least gets notably smaller. Each of the previous examples can be viewed as having relevance for policy analysis. In the first example, we were interested in gender discrimination in the workforce. In the second example, we were concerned with the effect of computer ownership on college performance. A special case of policy analysis is program evaluation, where we would like to know the effect of economic or social programs on individuals, firms, neighborhoods, cities, and so on. In the simplest case, there are two groups of subjects. The control group does not participate in the program. The experimental group or treatment group does take part in the program. These names come from literature in the experimental sciences, and they should not be taken literally. Except in rare cases, the choice of the control and treatment Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 233 groups is not random. However, in some cases, multiple regression analysis can be used to control for enough other factors in order to estimate the causal effect of the program. EXAMPLE 7.3 EFFECTS OF TRAINING GRANTS ON HOURS OF TRAINING Using the 1988 data for Michigan manufacturing firms in JTRAIN.RAW, we obtain the following estimated equation: 􏱵hrsemp 􏱪 46.67 􏱕 26.25 grant 􏱦 .98 log(sales) (43.41) (5.59) (3.54) 􏱦 6.07 log(employ) (3.88) n 􏱪 105, R2 􏱪 .237. [7.7] The dependent variable is hours of training per employee, at the firm level. The variable grant is a dummy variable equal to one if the firm received a job training grant for 1988 and zero otherwise. The variables sales and employ represent annual sales and number of employees, respectively. We cannot enter hrsemp in logarithmic form because hrsemp is zero for 29 of the 105 firms used in the regression. The variable grant is very statistically significant, with tgrant 􏱪 4.70. Controlling for sales and employment, firms that received a grant trained each worker, on average, 26.25 hours more. Because the average number of hours of per worker training in the sample is about 17, with a maximum value of 164, grant has a large effect on training, as is expected. The coefficient on log(sales) is small and very insignificant. The coefficient on log(employ) means that, if a firm is 10% larger, it trains its workers about .61 hour less. Its t statistic is 􏱦1.56, which is only marginally statistically significant. As with any other independent variable, we should ask whether the measured effect of a qualitative variable is causal. In equation (7.7), is the difference in training between firms that receive grants and those that do not due to the grant, or is grant receipt simply an indicator of something else? It might be that the firms receiving grants would have, on average, trained their workers more even in the absence of a grant. Nothing in this analysis tells us whether we have estimated a causal effect; we must know how the firms receiving grants were determined. We can only hope we have controlled for as many factors as pos- sible that might be related to whether a firm received a grant and to its levels of training. We will return to policy analysis with dummy variables in Section 7.6, as well as in later chapters. Interpreting Coefficients on Dummy Explanatory Variables When the Dependent Variable Is log(y) A common specification in applied work has the dependent variable appearing in logarith- mic form, with one or more dummy variables appearing as independent variables. How do we interpret the dummy variable coefficients in this case? Not surprisingly, the coef- ficients have a percentage interpretation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 234 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 7.4 HOUSING PRICE REGRESSION Using the data in HPRICE1.RAW, we obtain the equation 􏱵log(price) 􏱪 􏱦1.35 􏱕 .168 log(lotsize) 􏱕 .707 log(sqrft) (.65) (.038) (.093) 􏱕 .027 bdrms 􏱕 .054 colonial (.029) (.045) [7.8] n􏱪88,R2 􏱪.649. All the variables are self-explanatory except colonial, which is a binary variable equal to one if the house is of the colonial style. What does the coefficient on colonial mean? For 􏱵 given levels of lotsize, sqrft, and bdrms, the difference in log(price) between a house of colonial style and that of another style is .054. This means that a colonial-style house is predicted to sell for about 5.4% more, holding other factors fixed. This example shows that, when log(y) is the dependent variable in a model, the co- efficient on a dummy variable, when multiplied by 100, is interpreted as the percentage difference in y, holding all other factors fixed. When the coefficient on a dummy variable suggests a large proportionate change in y, the exact percentage difference can be obtained exactly as with the semi-elasticity calculation in Section 6.2. EXAMPLE 7.5 LOG HOURLY WAGE EQUATION Let us reestimate the wage equation from Example 7.1, using log(wage) as the dependent [7.9] variable and adding quadratics in exper and tenure: 􏱵log(wage) 􏱪 .417 􏱦 .297 female 􏱕 .080 educ 􏱕 .029 exper (.099) (.036) (.007) (.005) 􏱦 .00058 exper2 􏱕 .032 tenure 􏱦 .00059 tenure2 (.00010) (.007) (.00023) n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .441. Using the same approximation as in Example 7.4, the coefficient on female implies that, for the same levels of educ, exper, and tenure, women earn about 100(.297) 􏱪 29.7% less than men. We can do better than this by computing the exact percentage difference in predicted wages. What we want is the proportionate difference in wages between females and males, holding other factors 􏱵􏱵􏱵 fixed: (wageF 􏱦 wageM)/wageM. What we have from (7.9) is 􏱵log(wageF) 􏱦 􏱵log(wageM) 􏱪 􏱶.297. Exponentiating and subtracting one gives (􏱵wageF 􏱦 􏱵wageM )/􏱵wageM 􏱪 exp(􏱦.297) 􏱦 1 􏱴 􏱦.257. This more accurate estimate implies that a woman’s wage is, on average, 25.7% below a comparable man’s wage. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 235 If we had made the same correction in Example 7.4, we would have obtained exp(.054) 􏱦 1 􏱴 .0555, or about 5.6%. The correction has a smaller effect in Example 7.4 than in the wage example because the magnitude of the coefficient on the dummy variable is much smaller in (7.8) than in (7.9). Generally, if 􏱬ˆ1 is the coefficient on a dummy variable, say x1, when log(y) is the dependent variable, the exact percentage difference in the predicted y when x1 􏱪 1 versus when x1 􏱪 0 is 100 􏱳 [exp(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱦 1]. [7.10] The estimate 􏱬ˆ 1 can be positive or negative, and it is important to preserve its sign in computing (7.10). The logarithmic approximation has the advantage of providing an estimate between the magnitudes obtained by using each group as the base group. In particular, although equa- tion (7.10) gives us a better estimate than 100 􏱳 􏱬ˆ1 of the percentage by which y for x1 􏱪 1 is greater than y for x1 􏱪 0, (7.10) is not a good estimate if we switch the base group. In Example 7.5, we can estimate the percentage by which a man’s wage exceeds a compa- rable woman’s wage, and this estimate is 100 􏱳 [exp(􏱦􏱬ˆ1) 􏱦1] 􏱪 100 􏱳 [exp(.297) 􏱦1] 􏱴 34.6. The approximation, based on 100 􏱳 􏱬ˆ1, 29.7, is between 25.7 and 34.6 (and close to the middle). Therefore, it makes sense to report that “the difference in predicted wages between men and women is about 29.7%,” without having to take a stand on which is the base group. 7.3 Using Dummy Variables for Multiple Categories We can use several dummy independent variables in the same equation. For example, we could add the dummy variable married to equation (7.9). The coefficient on married gives the (approximate) proportional differential in wages between those who are and are not married, holding gender, educ, exper, and tenure fixed. When we estimate this model, the coefficient on married (with standard error in parentheses) is .053 (.041), and the coef- ficient on female becomes 􏱦.290 (.036). Thus, the “marriage premium” is estimated to be about 5.3%, but it is not statistically different from zero (t 􏱪 1.29). An important limita- tion of this model is that the marriage premium is assumed to be the same for men and women; this is relaxed in the following example. EXAMPLE 7.6 LOG HOURLY WAGE EQUATION Let us estimate a model that allows for wage differences among four groups: married men, married women, single men, and single women. To do this, we must select a base group; we choose single men. Then, we must define dummy variables for each of the remain- ing groups. Call these marrmale, marrfem, and singfem. Putting these three variables into (7.9)􏱵(and, of course, dropping female, since it is now redundant) gives log(wage) 􏱪 .321 􏱕 .213 marrmale 􏱦 .198 marrfem (.100) (.055) (.058) 􏱦 .110 singfem 􏱕 .079 educ 􏱕 .027 exper 􏱦 .00054 exper2 (.056) (.007) (.005) (.00011) [7.11] 􏱕 .029 tenure 􏱦 .00053 tenure2 (.007) (.00023) n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .461. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 236 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data All of the coefficients, with the exception of singfem, have t statistics well above two in absolute value. The t statistic for singfem is about 􏱦1.96, which is just significant at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative. To interpret the coefficients on the dummy variables, we must remember that the base group is single males. Thus, the estimates on the three dummy variables measure the proportionate difference in wage relative to single males. For example, married men are estimated to earn about 21.3% more than single men, holding levels of education, experience, and tenure fixed. [The more precise estimate from (7.10) is about 23.7%.] A married woman, on the other hand, earns a predicted 19.8% less than a single man with the same levels of the other variables. Because the base group is represented by the intercept in (7.11), we have included dummy variables for only three of the four groups. If we were to add a dummy variable for single males to (7.11), we would fall into the dummy variable trap by introducing perfect collinearity. Some regression packages will automatically correct this mistake for you, while others will just tell you there is perfect collinearity. It is best to carefully specify the dummy variables because then we are forced to properly interpret the final model. Even though single men is the base group in (7.11), we can use this equation to obtain the estimated difference between any two groups. Because the overall intercept is com- mon to all groups, we can ignore that in finding differences. Thus, the estimated propor- tionate difference between single and married women is 􏱦.110 􏱦 (􏱦.198) 􏱪 .088, which means that single women earn about 8.8% more than married women. Unfortunately, we cannot use equation (7.11) for testing whether the estimated difference between single and married women is statistically significant. Knowing the standard errors on marrfem and singfem is not enough to carry out the test (see Section 4.4). The easiest thing to do is to choose one of these groups to be the base group and to reestimate the equation. Nothing substantive changes, but we get the needed estimate and its standard error directly. When we use married women as the base group, we obtain 􏱵log(wage) 􏱪 .123 􏱕 .411 marrmale 􏱕 .198 singmale 􏱕 .088 singfem 􏱕 ..., (.106) (.056) (.058) (.052) where, of course, none of the unreported coefficients or standard errors have changed. The estimate on singfem is, as expected, .088. Now, we have a standard error to go along with this estimate. The t statistic for the null that there is no difference in the population between married and single women is tsingfem 􏱪 .088/.052 􏱴 1.69. This is marginal evidence against the null hypothesis. We also see that the estimated difference between married men and married women is very statistically significant (tmarrmale 􏱪 7.34). The previous example illustrates a general principle for including dummy variables to indicate different groups: if the regression model is to have different intercepts for, say, g groups or categories, we need to include g 􏱦 1 dummy variables in the model along with an intercept. The intercept for the base group is the overall intercept in the model, and the dummy variable coefficient for a particular group represents the estimated difference in intercepts between that group and the base group. Including g dummy variables along with an intercept will result in the dummy variable trap. An alternative is to include g dummy vari- ables and to exclude an overall intercept. Including g dummies without an overall intercept is sometimes useful, but it has two practical drawbacks. First, it makes it more cumbersome Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 237 to test for differences relative to a base group. Second, regression packages usually change the way R-squared is computed when an overall intercept is not included. In particular, in the formula R2 􏱪 1 􏱦 SSR/SST, the total sum of squares, SST, is replaced with a EXPLORING FURTHER 7.2 In the baseball salary data found in MLB1. RAW, players are given one of six positions: frstbase, scndbase, thrdbase, shrtstop, out- field, or catcher. To allow for salary differen- tials across position, with outfielders as the base group, which dummy variables would you include as independent variables? The resulting R-squared, say R20 􏱪 1 􏱦 SSR/ SST0, is sometimes called the uncen- tered R-squared. Unfortunately, R20 is rarely suitable as a goodness of fit mea- sure. It is always true that SST0 􏱸 SST with equality only if y- 􏱪 0. Often, SST0 is much larger that SST, which means that R20 is much larger than R2. For example, if in the previous example we regress log(wage) on marrmale, singmale, marrfem, singfem, and the other explanatory variables—without an intercept—the reported R-squared from Stata, which is R20, is .948. This high R-squared is an artifact of not centering the total sum of squares in the calculation. The correct R-squared is given in equation (7.11) as .461. Some regression packages, including Stata, have an option to force calculation of the centered R-squared even though an overall intercept has not been included, and using this option is generally a good idea. In the vast majority of cases, any R-squared based on comparing an SSR and SST should have SST computed by centering the yi about y-. We can think of this SST as the sum of squared residuals obtained if we just use the sample average, y-, to predict each yi. Surely we are set- ting the bar pretty low for any model if all we measure is its fit relative to using a constant predictor. For a model without an intercept that fits poorly, it is possible that SSR 􏱰 SST, which means R2 would be negative. The uncentered R-squared will always be between zero and one, which likely explains why it is usually the default when an intercept is not estimated in regression models. Incorporating Ordinal Information by Using Dummy Variables Suppose that we would like to estimate the effect of city credit ratings on the municipal bond interest rate (MBR). Several financial companies, such as Moody’s Investors Service and Standard and Poor’s, rate the quality of debt for local governments, where the ratings depend on things like probability of default. (Local governments prefer lower interest rates in order to reduce their costs of borrowing.) For simplicity, suppose that rankings range from zero to four, with zero being the worst credit rating and four being the best. This is an example of an ordinal variable. Call this variable CR for concreteness. The question we need to address is: How do we incorporate the variable CR into a model to explain MBR? One possibility is to just include CR as we would include any other explanatory variable: MBR 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1CR 􏱕 other factors, where we do not explicitly show what other factors are in the model. Then 􏱬1 is the percentage point change in MBR when CR increases by one unit, holding other factors fixed. Unfortunately, it is rather hard to interpret a one-unit increase in CR. We know the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. total sum of squares that does n∑ot center yi about its mean, say, SST0 􏱪 n y2. i􏱪1 i 238 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data quantitative meaning of another year of education, or another dollar spent per student, but things like credit ratings typically have only ordinal meaning. We know that a CR of four is better than a CR of three, but is the difference between four and three the same as the difference between one and zero? If not, then it might not make sense to assume that a one-unit increase in CR has a constant effect on MBR. A better approach, which we can implement because CR takes on relatively few values, is to define dummy variables for each value of CR. Thus, let CR1 􏱪 1 if CR 􏱪 1, and CR1 􏱪 0 otherwise; CR2 􏱪 1 if CR 􏱪 2, and CR2 􏱪 0 otherwise; and so on. Effectively, we take the single credit rating and turn it into five categories. Then, we can estimate the model MBR 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1CR1 􏱕 􏱛2CR2 􏱕 􏱛3CR3 􏱕 􏱛4CR4 􏱕 other factors. [7.12] Following our rule for including dummy variables in a model, we include four dummy vari- ables because we have five categories. The omitted category here is a credit rating of zero, and so it is the base group. (This is why we do not need to define a dummy variable for this category.) The coefficients are easy to in- terpret: 􏱛1 is the difference in MBR (other factors fixed) between a municipality with a credit rating of one and a municipality with a credit rating of zero; 􏱛2 is the differ- ence in MBR between a municipality with a credit rating of two and a municipality with a credit rating of zero; and so on. The movement between each credit rating is allowed to have a different effect, so using (7.12) is much more flexible than simply putting CR in as a single variable. Once the dummy variables are defined, estimating (7.12) is straightforward. Equation (7.12) contains the model with a constant partial effect as a special case. One way to write the three restrictions that imply a constant partial effect is 􏱛2 􏱪 2􏱛1, 􏱛3 􏱪 3􏱛1, and 􏱛4 􏱪 4􏱛1. When we plug these into equation (7.12) and rearrange, we get MBR 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1(CR1 􏱕 2CR2 􏱕 3CR3 􏱕 4CR4) 􏱕 other factors. Now, the term multiply- ing 􏱛1 is simply the original credit rating variable, CR. To obtain the F statistic for testing the constant partial effect restrictions, we obtain the unrestricted R-squared from (7.12) and the restricted R-squared from the regression of MBR on CR and the other factors we have controlled for. The F statistic is obtained as in equation (4.41) with q 􏱪 3. EXAMPLE 7.7 EFFECTS OF PHYSICAL ATTRACTIVENESS ON WAGE Hamermesh and Biddle (1994) used measures of physical attractiveness in a wage equa- tion. (The file BEAUTY.RAW contains fewer variables but more observations than used by Hamermesh and Biddle. See Computer Exercise C12.) Each person in the sample was ranked by an interviewer for physical attractiveness, using five categories (homely, quite plain, average, good looking, and strikingly beautiful or handsome). Because there are so few people at the two extremes, the authors put people into one of three groups for the regression analysis: average, below average, and above average, where the base group is average. Using data from the 1977 Quality of Employment Survey, after controlling for the usual producti􏱵vity characteristics, Hamermesh and Biddle estimated an equation for men: log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 .164 belavg 􏱕 .016 abvavg 􏱕 other factors (.046) (.033) EXPLORING FURTHER 7.3 In model (7.12), how would you test the null hypothesis that credit rating has no effect on MBR? n􏱪700,R-2 􏱪.403 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 239 and an equation for women: 􏱵log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 .124 belavg 􏱕 .035 abvavg 􏱕 other factors (.066) (.049) n􏱪409,R-2 􏱪.330. The other factors controlled for in the regressions include education, experience, tenure, marital status, and race; see Table 3 in Hamermesh and Biddle’s paper for a more com- plete list. In order to save space, the coefficients on the other variables are not reported in the paper and neither is the intercept. For men, those with below average looks are estimated to earn about 16.4% less than an average-looking man who is the same in other respects (including education, experi- ence, tenure, marital status, and race). The effect is statistically different from zero, with t 􏱪 􏱦3.57. Similarly, men with above average looks earn an estimated 1.6% more, although the effect is not statistically significant (t 􏱷 .5). A woman with below average looks earns about 12.4% less than an otherwise compa- rable average-looking woman, with t 􏱪 􏱦1.88. As was the case for men, the estimate on abvavg is not statistically different from zero. In related work, Biddle and Hamermesh (1998) revisit the effects of looks on earn- ings using a more homogeneous group: graduates of a particular law school. The authors continue to find that physical appearance has an effect on annual earnings, something that is perhaps not too surprising among people practicing law. In some cases, the ordinal variable takes on too many values so that a dummy vari- able cannot be included for each value. For example, the file LAWSCH85.RAW con- tains data on median starting salaries for law school graduates. One of the key explanatory variables is the rank of the law school. Because each law school has a different rank, we clearly cannot include a dummy variable for each rank. If we do not wish to put the rank directly in the equation, we can break it down into categories. The following example shows how this is done. EXAMPLE 7.8 EFFECTS OF LAW SCHOOL RANKINGS ON STARTING SALARIES Define the dummy variables top10, r11_25, r26_40, r41_60, r61_100 to take on the value unity when the variable rank falls into the appropriate range. We let schools ranked below 100 be the ba􏱵se group. The estimated equation is log(salary) 􏱪 9.17 􏱕 .700 top10 􏱕 .594 r11_25 􏱕 .375 r26_40 (.41) (.053) (.039) (.034) 􏱕 .263 r41_60 􏱕 .132 r61_100 􏱕 .0057 LSAT (.028) (.021) (.0031) [7.13] 􏱕 .014 GPA 􏱕 .036 log(libvol) 􏱕 .0008 log(cost) (.074) (.026) (.0251) n 􏱪 136, R2 􏱪 .911,R-2 􏱪 .905. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 240 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data We see immediately that all of the dummy variables defining the different ranks are very statistically significant. The estimate on r61_100 means that, holding LSAT, GPA, libvol, and cost fixed, the median salary at a law school ranked between 61 and 100 is about 13.2% higher than that at a law school ranked below 100. The difference between a top 10 school and a below 100 school is quite large. Using the exact calculation given in equation (7.10) gives exp(.700) 􏱦 1 􏱴 1.014, and so the predicted median salary is more than 100% higher at a top 10 school than it is at a below 100 school. As an indication of whether breaking the rank into different groups is an improve- ment, we can compare the adjusted R-squared in (7.13) with the adjusted R-squared from including rank as a single variable: the former is .905 and the latter is .836, so the addi- tional flexibility of (7.13) is warranted. Interestingly, once the rank is put into the (admittedly somewhat arbitrary) given categories, all of the other variables become insignificant. In fact, a test for joint signifi- cance of LSAT, GPA, log(libvol), and log(cost) gives a p-value of .055, which is borderline significant. When rank is included in its original form, the p-value for joint significance is zero to four decimal places. One final comment about this example: In deriving the properties of ordinary least squares, we assumed that we had a random sample. The current application violates that assumption because of the way rank is defined: a school’s rank necessarily depends on the rank of the other schools in the sample, and so the data cannot represent independent draws from the population of all law schools. This does not cause any serious problems provided the error term is uncorrelated with the explanatory variables. 7.4 Interactions Involving Dummy Variables Interactions among Dummy Variables Just as variables with quantitative meaning can be interacted in regression models, so can dummy variables. We have effectively seen an example of this in Example 7.6, where we defined four categories based on marital status and gender. In fact, we can recast that model by adding an interaction term between female and married to the model where female and married appear separately. This allows the marriage premium to depend on gender, just as it did in equation (7.11). For purposes of comparison, the estimated model with the female-married interaction term is 􏱵log(wage) 􏱪 .321 􏱦 .110 female 􏱕 .213 married (.100) (.056) (.055) 􏱦 .301 female􏱳married 􏱕 ..., (.072) [7.14] where the rest of the regression is necessarily identical to (7.11). Equation (7.14) shows explicitly that there is a statistically significant interaction between gender and marital status. This model also allows us to obtain the estimated wage differential among all four groups, but here we must be careful to plug in the correct combination of zeros and ones. Setting female 􏱪 0 and married 􏱪 0 corresponds to the group single men, which is the base group, since this eliminates female, married, and female􏱳married. We can find Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 241 the intercept for married men by setting female 􏱪 0 and married 􏱪 1 in (7.14); this gives an intercept of .321 􏱕 .213 􏱪 .534, and so on. Equation (7.14) is just a different way of finding wage differentials across all gender􏱦marital status combinations. It allows us to easily test the null hypothesis that the gender differential does not depend on marital status (equivalently, that the marriage differential does not depend on gender). Equation (7.11) is more convenient for testing for wage differentials between any group and the base group of single men. EXAMPLE 7.9 EFFECTS OF COMPUTER USAGE ON WAGES Krueger (1993) estimates the effects of computer usage on wages. He defines a dummy variable, which we call compwork, equal to one if an individual uses a computer at work. Another dummy variable, comphome, equals one if the person uses a computer at home. Using 13,379 people from the 1989 Current Population Survey, Krueger (1993, Table 4) obtains 􏱵log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 .177 compwork 􏱕 .070 comphome (.009) (.019) 􏱕 .017 compwork􏱳comphome 􏱕 other factors. (.023) [7.15] (The other factors are the standard ones for wage regressions, including education, experi- ence, gender, and marital status; see Krueger’s paper for the exact list.) Krueger does not report the intercept because it is not of any importance; all we need to know is that the base group consists of people who do not use a computer at home or at work. It is worth noticing that the estimated return to using a computer at work (but not at home) is about 17.7%. (The more precise estimate is 19.4%.) Similarly, people who use computers at home but not at work have about a 7% wage premium over those who do not use a com- puter at all. The differential between those who use a computer at both places, relative to those who use a computer in neither place, is about 26.4% (obtained by adding all three coefficients and multiplying by 100), or the more precise estimate 30.2% obtained from equation (7.10). The interaction term in (7.15) is not statistically significant, nor is it very big eco- nomically. But it is causing little harm by being in the equation. Allowing for Different Slopes We have now seen several examples of how to allow different intercepts for any number of groups in a multiple regression model. There are also occasions for interacting dummy variables with explanatory variables that are not dummy variables to allow for a differ- ence in slopes. Continuing with the wage example, suppose that we wish to test whether the return to education is the same for men and women, allowing for a constant wage differential between men and women (a differential for which we have already found evidence). For simplicity, we include only education and gender in the model. What kind of model allows for different returns to education? Consider the model log(wage) 􏱪 (􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 female) 􏱕 (􏱬1 􏱕 􏱛1 female)educ 􏱕 u. [7.16] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 242 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data FIGURE 7.2 Graphs of equation (7.16): (a) 􏰬0 􏱼 0, 􏰬1 􏱼 0; (b) 􏰬0 􏱼 0, 􏰬1 􏱆 0. wage wage men women men (a) women educ (b) educ If we plug female 􏱪 0 into (7.16), then we find that the intercept for males is 􏱬0, and the slope on education for males is 􏱬1. For females, we plug in female 􏱪 1; thus, the intercept for females is 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0, and the slope is 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱛1. Therefore, 􏱛0 measures the difference in intercepts between women and men, and 􏱛1 measures the difference in the return to education between women and men. Two of the four cases for the signs of 􏱛0 and 􏱛1 are presented in Figure 7.2. Graph (a) shows the case where the intercept for women is below that for men, and the slope of the line is smaller for women than for men. This means that women earn less than men at all levels of education, and the gap increases as educ gets larger. In graph (b), the intercept for women is below that for men, but the slope on education is larger for women. This means that women earn less than men at low levels of educa- tion, but the gap narrows as education increases. At some point, a woman earns more than a man, given the same levels of education (and this point is easily found given the estimated equation). How can we estimate model (7.16)? To apply OLS, we must write the model with an interaction between female and educ: log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 female 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱛1 female􏱳educ 􏱕 u. [7.17] The parameters can now be estimated from the regression of log(wage) on female, educ, and female􏱳educ. Obtaining the interaction term is easy in any regression package. Do not be daunted by the odd nature of female􏱳educ, which is zero for any man in the sample and equal to the level of education for any woman in the sample. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 243 An important hypothesis is that the return to education is the same for women and men. In terms of model (7.17), this is stated as H0: 􏱛1 􏱪 0, which means that the slope of log(wage) with respect to educ is the same for men and women. Note that this hypothesis puts no restrictions on the difference in intercepts, 􏱛0. A wage differential between men and women is allowed under this null, but it must be the same at all levels of education. This situation is described by Figure 7.1. We are also interested in the hypothesis that average wages are identical for men and women who have the same levels of education. This means that 􏱛0 and 􏱛1 must both be zero under the null hypothesis. In equation (7.17), we must use an F test to test H0: 􏱛0􏱪 0, 􏱛1 􏱪 0. In the model with just an intercept difference, we reject this hypothesis because H0: 􏱛0 􏱪 0 is soundly rejected against H1: 􏱛0 􏱷 0. EXAMPLE 7.10 LOG HOURLY WAGE EQUATION We add q􏱵uadratics in experience and tenure to (7.17): log(wage) 􏱪 .389 􏱦 .227 female 􏱕 .082 educ (.119) (.168) (.008) 􏱦 .0056 female􏱳educ 􏱕 .029 exper 􏱦 .00058 exper2 (.0131) (.005) (.00011) [7.18] 􏱕 .032 tenure 􏱦 .00059 tenure2 (.007) (.00024) n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .441. The estimated return to education for men in this equation is .082, or 8.2%. For women, it is .082 􏱦 .0056 􏱪 .0764, or about 7.6%. The difference, 􏱦.56%, or just over one-half a percentage point less for women, is not economically large nor statistically significant: the t statistic is 􏱦.0056/.0131 􏱴 􏱦.43. Thus, we conclude that there is no evidence against the hypothesis that the return to education is the same for men and women. The coefficient on female, while remaining economically large, is no longer sig- nificant at conventional levels (t 􏱪 􏱦1.35). Its coefficient and t statistic in the equa- tion without the interaction were 􏱦.297 and 􏱦8.25, respectively [see equation (7.9)]. Should we now conclude that there is no statistically significant evidence of lower pay for women at the same levels of educ, exper, and tenure? This would be a serious error. Because we have added the interaction female􏱳educ to the equation, the coefficient on female is now estimated much less precisely than it was in equation (7.9): the standard error has increased by almost fivefold (.168/.036 􏱴 4.67). This occurs because female and female􏱳educ are highly correlated in the sample. In this example, there is a useful way to think about the multicollinearity: in equation (7.17) and the more general equa- tion estimated in (7.18), 􏱛0 measures the wage differential between women and men when educ 􏱪 0. Very few people in the sample have very low levels of education, so it is not surprising that we have a difficult time estimating the differential at educ 􏱪 0 (nor is the differential at zero years of education very informative). More interesting would be to estimate the gender differential at, say, the average education level in the sample (about 12.5). To do this, we would replace female􏱳educ with female􏱳(educ 􏱦 12.5) and rerun the regression; this only changes the coefficient on female and its standard error. (See Computer Exercise C7.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 244 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data IfwecomputetheFstatisticforH0:􏱛0 􏱪0,􏱛1 􏱪0,weobtainF􏱪34.33,whichisa huge value for an F random variable with numerator df 􏱪 2 and denominator df 􏱪 518: the p-value is zero to four decimal places. In the end, we prefer model (7.9), which allows for a constant wage differential between women and men. As a more complicated example involving interactions, we now look at the effects of race and city racial composition on major league baseball player salaries. EXAMPLE 7.11 EFFECTS OF RACE ON BASEBALL PLAYER SALARIES Using MLB1.RAW, the following equation is estimated for the 330 major league baseball players for which city racial composition statistics are available. The variables black and hispan are binary indicators for the individual players. (The base group is white players.) The variable percblck is the percentage of the team’s city that is black, and perchisp is the percentage of Hispanics. The other variables measure aspects of player productivity and longevity. Here, we are interested in race effects after controlling for these other factors. EXPLORING FURTHER 7.4 How would you augment the model esti- mated in (7.18) to allow the return to tenure to differ by gender? In addition to including black and hispan in the equation, we add the interactions black􏱳percblck and hispan􏱳perchisp. The estimated equation is 􏱵log(salary) 􏱪 10.34 􏱕 .0673 years 􏱕 .0089 gamesyr (2.18) (.0129) (.0034) 􏱕 .00095 bavg 􏱕 .0146 hrunsyr 􏱕 .0045 rbisyr (.00151) (.0164) (.0076) 􏱕 .0072 runsyr 􏱕 .0011 fldperc 􏱕 .0075 allstar (.0046) (.0021) (.0029) [7.19] 􏱦 .198 black 􏱦 .190 hispan 􏱕 .0125 black􏱳percblck (.125) (.153) (.0050) 􏱕 .0201 hispan􏱳perchisp (.0098) n 􏱪 330, R2 􏱪 .638. First, we should test whether the four race variables, black, hispan, black􏱳percblck, and hispan􏱳perchisp, are jointly significant. Using the same 330 players, the R-squared when the four race variables are dropped is .626. Since there are four restrictions and df 􏱪 330 􏱦 13 in the unrestricted model, the F statistic is about 2.63, which yields a p-value of .034. Thus, these variables are jointly significant at the 5% level (though not at the 1% level). How do we interpret the coefficients on the race variables? In the following discus- sion, all productivity factors are held fixed. First, consider what happens for black players, holding perchisp fixed. The coefficient 􏱦.198 on black literally means that, if a black player is in a city with no blacks (percblck 􏱪 0), then the black player earns about 19.8% Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 245 less than a comparable white player. As percblck increases—which means the white popu- lation decreases, since perchisp is held fixed—the salary of blacks increases relative to that for whites. In a city with 10% blacks, log(salary) for blacks compared to that for whites is 􏱦.198 􏱕 .0125(10) 􏱪 􏱦.073, so salary is about 7.3% less for blacks than for whites in such a city. When percblck 􏱪 20, blacks earn about 5.2% more than whites. The largest percentage of blacks in a city is about 74% (Detroit). Similarly, Hispanics earn less than whites in cities with a low percentage of Hispanics. But we can easily find the value of perchisp that makes the differential between whites and Hispanics equal zero: it must make 􏱦.190 􏱕 .0201 perchisp 􏱪 0, which gives perchisp 􏱴 9.45. For cities in which the percentage of Hispanics is less than 9.45%, Hispanics are predicted to earn less than whites (for a given black population), and the opposite is true if the percentage of Hispanics is above 9.45%. Twelve of the 22 cities represented in the sample have Hispanic populations that are less than 9.45% of the total population. The largest percentage of Hispanics is about 31%. How do we interpret these findings? We cannot simply claim discrimination exists against blacks and Hispanics, because the estimates imply that whites earn less than blacks and Hispanics in cities heavily populated by minorities. The importance of city composi- tion on salaries might be due to player preferences: perhaps the best black players live dis- proportionately in cities with more blacks and the best Hispanic players tend to be in cities with more Hispanics. The estimates in (7.19) allow us to determine that some relationship is present, but we cannot distinguish between these two hypotheses. Testing for Differences in Regression Functions across Groups The previous examples illustrate that interacting dummy variables with other indepen- dent variables can be a powerful tool. Sometimes, we wish to test the null hypothesis that two populations or groups follow the same regression function, against the alternative that one or more of the slopes differ across the groups. We will also see examples of this in Chapter 13, when we discuss pooling different cross sections over time. Suppose we want to test whether the same regression model describes college grade point averages for male and female college athletes. The equation is cumgpa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sat 􏱕 􏱬2hsperc 􏱕 􏱬3tothrs 􏱕 u, where sat is SAT score, hsperc is high school rank percentile, and tothrs is total hours of college courses. We know that, to allow for an intercept difference, we can include a dummy variable for either males or females. If we want any of the slopes to depend on gender, we simply interact the appropriate variable with, say, female, and include it in the equation. If we are interested in testing whether there is any difference between men and women, then we must allow a model where the intercept and all slopes can be different across the two groups: cumgpa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 female 􏱕 􏱬1sat 􏱕 􏱛1 female􏱳sat 􏱕 􏱬2hsperc 􏱕 􏱛2 female􏱳hsperc 􏱕 􏱬3tothrs 􏱕 􏱛3 female􏱳tothrs 􏱕 u. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. [7.20] 246 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The parameter 􏱛0 is the difference in the intercept between women and men, 􏱛1 is the slope difference with respect to sat between women and men, and so on. The null hypothesis that cumgpa follows the same model for males and females is stated as H0:􏱛0 􏱪0,􏱛1 􏱪0,􏱛2 􏱪0,􏱛3 􏱪0. [7.21] If one of the 􏱛j is different from zero, then the model is different for men and women. Using the spring semester data from the file GPA3.RAW, the full model is estimated as 􏱵cumgpa 􏱪 1.48 􏱦 .353 female 􏱕 .0011 sat 􏱕 .00075 female􏱳sat (0.21) (.411) (.0002) (.00039) 􏱦.0085 hsperc 􏱦 .00055 female􏱳hsperc 􏱕 .0023 tothrs (.0014) (.00316) (.0009) [7.22] 􏱦.00012 female􏱳tothrs (.00163) - n 􏱪 366, R2 􏱪 .406,R2 􏱪 .394. None of the four terms involving the female dummy variable is very statistically significant; only the female􏱳sat interaction has a t statistic close to two. But we know better than to rely on the individual t statistics for testing a joint hypothesis such as (7.21). To compute the F statistic, we must estimate the restricted model, which results from dropping female and all of the interactions; this gives an R2 (the restricted R2) of about .352, so the F statistic is about 8.14; the p-value is zero to five decimal places, which causes us to soundly reject (7.21). Thus, men and women athletes do follow different GPA models, even though each term in (7.22) that allows women and men to be different is individually insignificant at the 5% level. The large standard errors on female and the interaction terms make it difficult to tell exactly how men and women differ. We must be very careful in interpreting equation (7.22) because, in obtaining differences between women and men, the interaction terms must be taken into account. If we look only at the female variable, we would wrongly con- clude that cumgpa is about .353 less for women than for men, holding other factors fixed. This is the estimated difference only when sat, hsperc, and tothrs are all set to zero, which is not close to being a possible scenario. At sat 􏱪 1,100, hsperc 􏱪 10, and tothrs 􏱪 50, the predicted difference between a woman and a man is 􏱦.353 􏱕 .00075(1,100) 􏱦 .00055(10) 􏱦.00012(50) 􏱴 .461. That is, the female athlete is predicted to have a GPA that is almost one-half a point higher than the comparable male athlete. In a model with three variables, sat, hsperc, and tothrs, it is pretty simple to add all of the interactions to test for group differences. In some cases, many more explanatory vari- ables are involved, and then it is convenient to have a different way to compute the statis- tic. It turns out that the sum of squared residuals form of the F statistic can be computed easily even when many independent variables are involved. In the general model with k explanatory variables and an intercept, suppose we have two groups; call them g 􏱪 1 and g 􏱪 2. We would like to test whether the intercept and all slopes are the same across the two groups. Write the model as y􏱪􏱬g,0 􏱕􏱬g,1x1 􏱕􏱬g,2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬g,kxk 􏱕u, [7.23] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 247 for g 􏱪 1 and g 􏱪 2. The hypothesis that each beta in (7.23) is the same across the two groups involves k 􏱕 1 restrictions (in the GPA example, k 􏱕 1 􏱪 4). The unrestricted model, which we can think of as having a group dummy variable and k interaction terms in addition to the intercept and variables themselves, has n 􏱦 2(k 􏱕 1) degrees of freedom. [In the GPA example, n 􏱦 2(k 􏱕 1) 􏱪 366 􏱦 2(4) 􏱪 358.] So far, there is nothing new. The key insight is that the sum of squared residuals from the unrestricted model can be ob- tained from two separate regressions, one for each group. Let SSR1 be the sum of squared residuals obtained estimating (7.23) for the first group; this involves n1 observations. Let SSR2 be the sum of squared residuals obtained from estimating the model using the sec- ond group (n2 observations). In the previous example, if group 1 is females, then n1 􏱪 90 and n2 􏱪 276. Now, the sum of squared residuals for the unrestricted model is simply SSRur 􏱪 SSR1 􏱕 SSR2. The restricted sum of squared residuals is just the SSR from pooling the groups and estimating a single equation, say SSRP. Once we have these, we compute the F statistic as usual: [SSR 􏱦(SSR 􏱕SSR )] [n􏱦2(k􏱕1)] F 􏱪 ______P________1_______2__ 􏱫 _____________, [7.24] SSR1 􏱕SSR2 k􏱕1 where n is the total number of observations. This particular F statistic is usually called the Chow statistic in econometrics. Because the Chow test is just an F test, it is only valid under homoskedasticity. In particular, under the null hypothesis, the error variances for the two groups must be equal. As usual, normality is not needed for asymptotic analysis. To apply the Chow statistic to the GPA example, we need the SSR from the regres- sion that pooled the groups together: this is SSRP 􏱪 85.515. The SSR for the 90 women in the sample is SSR1 􏱪 19.603, and the SSR for the men is SSR2 􏱪 58.752. Thus, SSRur 􏱪 19.603 􏱕 58.752 􏱪 78.355. The F statistic is [(85.515 􏱦 78.355)/78.355](358/4) 􏱴 8.18]; of course, subject to rounding error, this is what we get using the R-squared form of the test in the models with and without the interaction terms. (A word of caution: there is no simple R-squared form of the test if separate regressions have been estimated for each group; the R-squared form of the test can be used only if interactions have been included to create the unrestricted model.) One important limitation of the traditional Chow test, regardless of the method used to implement it, is that the null hypothesis allows for no differences at all between the groups. In many cases, it is more interesting to allow for an intercept difference between the groups and then to test for slope differences; we saw one example of this in the wage equation in Example 7.10. There are two ways to allow the intercepts to differ under the null hypothesis. One is to include the group dummy and all interaction terms, as in equation (7.22), but then test joint significance of the interaction terms only. The second approach, which produces an identical statistic, is to form a sum-of-squared-residuals F statistic, as in equation (7.24), but where the restricted SSR, called “SSRP” in equation (7.24), is obtained using a regression that contains only an intercept shift. Because we are testing k restrictions, rather than k 􏱕 1, the F statistic becomes [SSR 􏱦(SSR 􏱕SSR )] [n􏱦2(k􏱕1)] F􏱪_____P________1______2__􏱫_____________. SSR1 􏱕 SSR2 k Using this approach in the GPA example, SSRP is obtained from the regression cumgpa on female, sat, hsperc, and tothrs using the data for both male and female student-athletes. Because there are relatively few explanatory variables in the GPA example, it is easy to estimate (7.20) and test H0 : 􏱛1 􏱪 0, 􏱛2 􏱪 0, 􏱛3 􏱪 0 (with 􏱛0 unrestricted under the null). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 248 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The F statistic for the three exclusion restrictions gives a p-value equal to .205, and so we do not reject the null hypothesis at even the 20% significance level. Failure to reject the hypothesis that the parameters multiplying the interaction terms are all zero suggests that the best model allows for an intercept difference only: 􏱵cumgpa 􏱪 1.39 􏱕 .310 female 􏱕 .0012 sat 􏱦 .0084 hsperc (.18) (.059) 􏱕 .0025 tothrs (.0002) (.0012) (.0007) n 􏱪 366, R2 􏱪 .398,R2 􏱪 .392. The slope coefficients in (7.25) are close to those for the base group (males) in (7.22); dropping the interactions changes very little. However, female in (7.25) is highly signifi- cant: its t statistic is over 5, and the estimate implies that, at given levels of sat, hsperc, and tothrs, a female athlete has a predicted GPA that is .31 point higher than that of a male athlete. This is a practically important difference. 7.5 A Binary Dependent Variable: The Linear Probability Model By now, we have learned much about the properties and applicability of the multiple linear regression model. In the last several sections, we studied how, through the use of binary independent variables, we can incorporate qualitative information as explanatory variables in a multiple regression model. In all of the models up until now, the dependent variable y has had quantitative meaning (for example, y is a dollar amount, a test score, a percent- age, or the logs of these). What happens if we want to use multiple regression to explain a qualitative event? In the simplest case, and one that often arises in practice, the event we would like to explain is a binary outcome. In other words, our dependent variable, y, takes on only two values: zero and one. For example, y can be defined to indicate whether an adult has a high school educa- tion; y can indicate whether a college student used illegal drugs during a given school year; or y can indicate whether a firm was taken over by another firm during a given year. In each of these examples, we can let y 􏱪 1 denote one of the outcomes and y 􏱪 0 the other outcome. What does it mean to write down a multiple regression model, such as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, [7.26] when y is a binary variable? Because y can take on only two values, 􏱬j cannot be inter- preted as the change in y given a one-unit increase in xj, holding all other factors fixed: y either changes from zero to one or from one to zero (or does not change). Neverthe- less, the 􏱬j still have useful interpretations. If we assume that the zero conditional mean assumption MLR.4 holds, that is, E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 0, then we have, as always, E(y􏰫x)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk, where x is shorthand for all of the explanatory variables. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. - [7.25] CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 249 The key point is that when y is a binary variable taking on the values zero and one, it is always true that P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱪 E(y􏰫x): the probability of “success”—that is, the prob- ability that y 􏱪 1—is the same as the expected value of y. Thus, we have the important equation P(y􏱪1􏰫x)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk, [7.27] which says that the probability of success, say, p(x) 􏱪 P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x), is a linear function of the xj. Equation (7.27) is an example of a binary response model, and P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) is also called the response probability. (We will cover other binary response models in Chapter 17.) Because probabilities must sum to one, P( y 􏱪 0􏰫x) 􏱪 1 􏱦 P( y 􏱪 1􏰫x) is also a linear function of the xj. The multiple linear regression model with a binary dependent variable is called the linear probability model (LPM) because the response probability is linear in the param- eters 􏱬j. In the LPM, 􏱬j measures the change in the probability of success when xj changes, holding other factors fixed: 􏰧P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱬j 􏰧 xj. [7.28] With this in mind, the multiple regression model can allow us to estimate the effect of various explanatory variables on qualitative events. The mechanics of OLS are the same as before. If we write the estimated equation as yˆ􏱪􏱬ˆ0 􏱕􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬ˆkxk, we must now remember that yˆ is the predicted probability of success. Therefore, 􏱬ˆ0 is the predicted probability of success when each xj is set to zero, which may or may not be interesting. The slope coefficient 􏱬ˆ1 measures the predicted change in the probability of success when x1 increases by one unit. To correctly interpret a linear probability model, we must know what constitutes a “success.” Thus, it is a good idea to give the dependent variable a name that describes the event y 􏱪 1. As an example, let inlf (“in the labor force”) be a binary variable indicating labor force participation by a married woman during 1975: inlf 􏱪 1 if the woman reports working for a wage outside the home at some point during the year, and zero otherwise. We assume that labor force participation depends on other sources of income, including husband’s earnings (nwifeinc, measured in thousands of dollars), years of education (educ), past years of labor market experience (exper), age, number of children less than six years old (kidslt6), and number of kids between 6 and 18 years of age (kidsge6). Using the data in MROZ.RAW from Mroz (1987), we estimate the following linear probability model, where 428 of the 753 women in the sample report being in the labor force at some point during 1975: 􏱾inlf 􏱪 .586 􏱦 .0034 nwifeinc 􏱕 .038 educ 􏱕 .039 exper (.154) (.0014) (.007) (.006) 􏱦.00060 exper2 􏱦 .016 age 􏱦 .262 kidslt6 􏱕 .013 kidsge6 (.00018) (.002) (.034) (.013) n 􏱪 753, R2 􏱪 .264. [7.29] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 250 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Using the usual t statistics, all variables in (7.29) except kidsge6 are statistically signifi- cant, and all of the significant variables have the effects we would expect based on eco- nomic theory (or common sense). To interpret the estimates, we must remember that a change in the independent vari- able changes the probability that inlf 􏱪 1. For example, the coefficient on educ means that, everything else in (7.29) held fixed, another year of education increases the probabil- ity of labor force participation by .038. If we take this equation literally, 10 more years of education increases the probability of being in the labor force by .038(10) 􏱪 .38, which is a pretty large increase in a probability. The relationship between the probability of labor force participation and educ is plotted in Figure 7.3. The other independent variables are fixed at the values nwifeinc 􏱪 50, exper 􏱪 5, age 􏱪 30, kidslt6 􏱪 1, and kidsge6 􏱪 0 for il- lustration purposes. The predicted probability is negative until education equals 3.84 years. This should not cause too much concern because, in this sample, no woman has less than five years of education. The largest reported education is 17 years, and this leads to a pre- dicted probability of .5. If we set the other independent variables at different values, the range of predicted probabilities would change. But the marginal effect of another year of education on the probability of labor force participation is always .038. The coefficient on nwifeinc implies that, if 􏰧nwifeinc 􏱪 10 (which means an increase of $10,000), the probability that a woman is in the labor force falls by .034. This is not an especially large effect given that an increase in income of $10,000 is substantial in terms of 1975 dollars. Experience has been entered as a quadratic to allow the effect of past experience to have a diminishing effect on the labor force participation probability. Holding other factors fixed, the estimated change in the probability is approximated as .039 􏱦 2(.0006)exper 􏱪 .039 􏱦 .0012 exper. The point at which past experience has no F I G U R E 7 . 3 Estimated relationship between the probability of being in the labor force and years of education, with other explanatory variables fixed. probability of labor force participation .5 0 –.146 slope = .038 3.84 educ Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 251 effect on the probability of labor force participation is .039/.0012 􏱪 32.5, which is a high level of experience: only 13 of the 753 women in the sample have more than 32 years of experience. Unlike the number of older children, the number of young children has a huge impact on labor force participation. Having one additional child less than six years old reduces the probability of participation by 􏱦.262, at given levels of the other variables. In the sample, just under 20% of the women have at least one young child. This example illustrates how easy linear probability models are to estimate and inter- pret, but it also highlights some shortcomings of the LPM. First, it is easy to see that, if we plug certain combinations of values for the independent variables into (7.29), we can get predictions either less than zero or greater than one. Since these are predicted probabili- ties, and probabilities must be between zero and one, this can be a little embarassing. For example, what would it mean to predict that a woman is in the labor force with a probabil- ity of 􏱦.10? In fact, of the 753 women in the sample, 16 of the fitted values from (7.29) are less than zero, and 17 of the fitted values are greater than one. A related problem is that a probability cannot be linearly related to the independent variables for all their possible values. For example, (7.29) predicts that the effect of going from zero children to one young child reduces the probability of working by .262. This is also the predicted drop if the woman goes from having one young child to two. It seems more realistic that the first small child would reduce the probability by a large amount, but subsequent children would have a smaller marginal effect. In fact, when taken to the extreme, (7.29) implies that going from zero to four young children reduces the probability of working by 􏰧􏱾inlf 􏱪 .262(􏰧kidslt6) 􏱪 .262(4) 􏱪 1.048, which is impossible. Even with these problems, the linear probability model is useful and often applied in economics. It usually works well for values of the independent variables that are near the averages in the sample. In the labor force participation example, no women in the sample have four young children; in fact, only three women have three young children. Over 96% of the women have either no young children or one small child, and so we should probably restrict attention to this case when interpreting the estimated equation. Predicted probabilities outside the unit interval are a little troubling when we want to make predictions. Still, there are ways to use the estimated probabilities (even if some are negative or greater than one) to predict a zero-one outcome. As before, let yˆi denote the fitted values—which may not be bounded between zero and one. Define a predicted value asy ̃i 􏱪1ifyˆi 􏱸.5andy ̃i 􏱪0ifyˆi 􏱷.5.Nowwehaveasetofpredictedvalues,y ̃i,i􏱪 1, ..., n, that, like the yi, are either zero or one. We can use the data on yI and y ̃i to obtain the frequencies with which we correctly predict yi 􏱪 1 and yi 􏱪 0, as well as the propor- tion of overall correct predictions. The latter measure, when turned into a percentage, is a widely used goodness-of-fit measure for binary dependent variables: the percent cor- rectly predicted. An example is given in Computer Exercise C9(v), and further discus- sion, in the context of more advanced models, can be found in Section 17.1. Due to the binary nature of y, the linear probability model does violate one of the Gauss-Markov assumptions. When y is a binary variable, its variance, conditional on x, is Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 p(x)[1 􏱦 p(x)], [7.30] where p(x) is shorthand for the probability of success: p(x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk. This means that, except in the case where the probability does not depend on any of the inde- pendent variables, there must be heteroskedasticity in a linear probability model. We know Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 252 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data from Chapter 3 that this does not cause bias in the OLS estimators of the 􏱬j. But we also know from Chapters 4 and 5 that homoskedasticity is crucial for justifying the usual t and F statistics, even in large samples. Because the standard errors in (7.29) are not generally valid, we should use them with caution. We will show how to correct the standard errors for heteroskedasticity in Chapter 8. It turns out that, in many applications, the usual OLS statistics are not far off, and it is still acceptable in applied work to present a standard OLS analysis of a linear probability model. EXAMPLE 7.12 A LINEAR PROBABILITY MODEL OF ARRESTS Let arr86 be a binary variable equal to unity if a man was arrested during 1986, and zero otherwise. The population is a group of young men in California born in 1960 or 1961 who have at least one arrest prior to 1986. A linear probability model for describing arr86 is arr86 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1pcnv 􏱕 􏱬2avgsen 􏱕 􏱬3tottime 􏱕 􏱬4ptime86 􏱕 􏱬5qemp86 􏱕 u, where pcnv 􏱪 the proportion of prior arrests that led to a conviction. avgsen 􏱪 the average sentence served from prior convictions (in months). tottime 􏱪 months spent in prison since age 18 prior to 1986. ptime86 􏱪 months spent in prison in 1986. qemp86 􏱪 the number of quarters (0 to 4) that the man was legally employed in 1986. The data we use are in CRIME1.RAW, the same data set used for Example 3.5. Here, we use a binary dependent variable because only 7.2% of the men in the sample were ar- rested more than once. About 27.7% of the men were arrested at least once during 1986. The estimated equation is 􏱾arr86 􏱪 .441 􏱦 .162 pcnv 􏱕 .0061 avgsen 􏱦 .0023 tottime (.017) (.021) (.0065) (.0050) 􏱦 .022 ptime86 􏱦 .043 qemp86 (.005) (.005) n 􏱪 2,725, R2 􏱪 .0474. [7.31] The intercept, .441, is the predicted probability of arrest for someone who has not been convicted (and so pcnv and avgsen are both zero), has spent no time in prison since age 18, spent no time in prison in 1986, and was unemployed during the entire year. The vari- ables avgsen and tottime are insignificant both individually and jointly (the F test gives p-value 􏱪 .347), and avgsen has a counterintuitive sign if longer sentences are sup- posed to deter crime. Grogger (1991), using a superset of these data and different econometric methods, found that tottime has a statistically significant positive effect on arrests and concluded that tottime is a measure of human capital built up in criminal activity. Increasing the probability of conviction does lower the probability of arrest, but we must be careful when interpreting the magnitude of the coefficient. The variable pcnv is a proportion between zero and one; thus, changing pcnv from zero to one essentially means a change from no chance of being convicted to being convicted with certainty. Even this Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 253 large change reduces the probability of arrest only by .162; increasing pcnv by .5 decreases the probability of arrest by .081. The incarcerative effect is given by the coefficient on ptime86. If a man is in prison, he cannot be arrested. Since ptime86 is measured in months, six more months in prison reduces the probability of arrest by .022(6) 􏱪 .132. Equation (7.31) gives another example of where the linear probability model cannot be true over all ranges of the independent variables. If a man is in prison all 12 months of 1986, he cannot be arrested in 1986. Set- ting all other variables equal to zero, the predicted probability of arrest when ptime86 􏱪 12 is .441 􏱦 .022(12) 􏱪 .177, which is not zero. Nevertheless, if we start from the uncondi- tional probability of arrest, .277, 12 months in prison reduces the probability to essentially zero: .277 􏱦 .022(12) 􏱪 .013. Finally, employment reduces the probability of arrest in a significant way. All other factors fixed, a man employed in all four quarters is .172 less likely to be arrested than a man who is not employed at all. We can also include dummy independent variables in models with dummy depen- dent variables. The coefficient measures the predicted difference in probability relative to the base group. For example, if we add two race dummies, black and hispan, to the arrest equation, we obtain 􏱾arr86 􏱪 .380 􏱦 .152 pcnv 􏱕 .0046 avgsen 􏱦 .0026 tottime (.019) (.021) (.0064) (.0049) 􏱦 .024 ptime86 􏱦 .038 qemp86 􏱕 .170 black 􏱕 .096 hispan [7.32] (.005) (.005) n 􏱪 2,725, R2 􏱪 .0682. (.024) (.021) The coefficient on black means that, all other factors being equal, a black man has a .17 higher chance of being arrested than a white man (the base group). Another way to say this is that the probability of arrest is 17 percentage points higher for blacks than for whites. The difference is statistically significant as well. Similarly, Hispanic men have a .096 higher chance of being arrested than white men. EXPLORING FURTHER 7.5 What is the predicted probability of arrest for a black man with no prior convictions— so that pcnv, avgsen, tottime, and ptime86 are all zero—who was employed all four quarters in 1986? Does this seem reasonable? 7.6 More on Policy Analysis and Program Evaluation We have seen some examples of models containing dummy variables that can be useful for evaluating policy. Example 7.3 gave an example of program evaluation, where some firms received job training grants and others did not. As we mentioned earlier, we must be careful when evaluating programs because in most examples in the social sciences the control and treatment groups are not randomly assigned. Consider again the Holzer et al. (1993) study, where we are now interested in Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 254 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data the effect of the job training grants on worker productivity (as opposed to amount of job training). The equation of interest is log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1grant 􏱕 􏱬2log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬3log(employ) 􏱕 u, where scrap is the firm’s scrap rate, and the latter two variables are included as controls. The binary variable grant indicates whether the firm received a grant in 1988 for job training. Before we look at the estimates, we might be worried that the unobserved factors affecting worker productivity—such as average levels of education, ability, experience, and tenure—might be correlated with whether the firm receives a grant. Holzer et al. point out that grants were given on a first-come, first-served basis. But this is not the same as giving out grants randomly. It might be that firms with less productive workers saw an opportunity to improve productivity and therefore were more diligent in applying for the grants. Using the data in JTRAIN.RAW for 1988—when firms actually were eligible to receive the grants—we obtain 􏱾log(scrap)􏱪4.99 􏱦 .052 grant 􏱦 .455 log(sales) (4.66) (.431) (.373) 􏱕 .639 log(employ) (.365) n􏱪50,R2 􏱪.072. [7.33] (Seventeen out of the 50 firms received a training grant, and the average scrap rate is 3.47 across all firms.) The point estimate of 􏱦.052 on grant means that, for given sales and employ, firms receiving a grant have scrap rates about 5.2% lower than firms without grants. This is the direction of the expected effect if the training grants are effective, but the t statistic is very small. Thus, from this cross-sectional analysis, we must conclude that the grants had no effect on firm productivity. We will return to this example in Chapter 9 and show how adding information from a prior year leads to a much different conclusion. Even in cases where the policy analysis does not involve assigning units to a control group and a treatment group, we must be careful to include factors that might be system- atically related to the binary independent variable of interest. A good example of this is testing for racial discrimination. Race is something that is not determined by an individual or by government administrators. In fact, race would appear to be the perfect example of an exogenous explanatory variable, given that it is determined at birth. However, for historical reasons, race is often related to other relevant factors: there are systematic dif- ferences in backgrounds across race, and these differences can be important in testing for current discrimination. As an example, consider testing for discrimination in loan approvals. If we can collect data on, say, individual mortgage applications, then we can define the dummy dependent vari- able approved as equal to one if a mortgage application was approved, and zero otherwise. A systematic difference in approval rates across races is an indication of discrimination. How- ever, since approval depends on many other factors, including income, wealth, credit ratings, and a general ability to pay back the loan, we must control for them if there are systematic differences in these factors across race. A linear probability model to test for discrimination might look like the following: approved 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1nonwhite 􏱕 􏱬2income 􏱕 􏱬3wealth 􏱕 􏱬4credrate 􏱕 other factors. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 255 Discrimination against minorities is indicated by a rejection of H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 in favor of H0: 􏱬1 􏱷 0, because 􏱬1 is the amount by which the probability of a nonwhite getting an approval differs from the probability of a white getting an approval, given the same levels of other variables in the equation. If income, wealth, and so on are systematically different across races, then it is important to control for these factors in a multiple regression analysis. Another problem that often arises in policy and program evaluation is that individu- als (or firms or cities) choose whether or not to participate in certain behaviors or pro- grams. For example, individuals choose to use illegal drugs or drink alcohol. If we want to examine the effects of such behaviors on unemployment status, earnings, or criminal behavior, we should be concerned that drug usage might be correlated with other factors that can affect employment and criminal outcomes. Children eligible for programs such as Head Start participate based on parental decisions. Since family background plays a role in Head Start decisions and affects student outcomes, we should control for these factors when examining the effects of Head Start [see, for example, Currie and Thomas (1995)]. Individuals selected by employers or government agencies to participate in job training programs can participate or not, and this decision is unlikely to be random [see, for example, Lynch (1992)]. Cities and states choose whether to implement certain gun con- trol laws, and it is likely that this decision is systematically related to other factors that affect violent crime [see, for example, Kleck and Patterson (1993)]. The previous paragraph gives examples of what are generally known as self-selection problems in economics. Literally, the term comes from the fact that individuals self-select into certain behaviors or programs: participation is not randomly determined. The term is used generally when a binary indicator of participation might be systematically related to unobserved factors. Thus, if we write the simple model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1partic 􏱕 u, [7.34] where y is an outcome variable and partic is a binary variable equal to unity if the individ- ual, firm, or city participates in a behavior or a program or has a certain kind of law, then we are worried that the average value of u depends on participation: E(u􏰫partic 􏱪 1) 􏱻 E(u􏰫partic 􏱪 0). As we know, this causes the simple regression estimator of 􏱬1 to be biased, and so we will not uncover the true effect of participation. Thus, the self-selection prob- lem is another way that an explanatory variable (partic in this case) can be endogenous. By now, we know that multiple regression analysis can, to some degree, alleviate the self-selection problem. Factors in the error term in (7.34) that are correlated with partic can be included in a multiple regression equation, assuming, of course, that we can collect data on these factors. Unfortunately, in many cases, we are worried that unobserved factors are related to participation, in which case multiple regression produces biased estimators. With standard multiple regression analysis using cross-sectional data, we must be aware of finding spurious effects of programs on outcome variables due to the self- selection problem. A good example of this is contained in Currie and Cole (1993). These authors examine the effect of AFDC (Aid to Families with Dependent Children) participa- tion on the birth weight of a child. Even after controlling for a variety of family and back- ground characteristics, the authors obtain OLS estimates that imply participation in AFDC lowers birth weight. As the authors point out, it is hard to believe that AFDC participa- tion itself causes lower birth weight. [See Currie (1995) for additional examples.] Using a different econometric method that we will discuss in Chapter 15, Currie and Cole find evidence for either no effect or a positive effect of AFDC participation on birth weight. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 256 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data When the self-selection problem causes standard multiple regression analysis to be biased due to a lack of sufficient control variables, the more advanced methods covered in Chapters 13, 14, and 15 can be used instead. 7.7 Interpreting Regression Results with Discrete Dependent Variables A binary response is the most extreme form of a discrete random variable: it takes on only two values, zero and one. As we discussed in Section 7.5, the parameters in a linear prob- ability model can be interpreted as measuring the change in the probability that y 􏱪 1 due to a one-unit increase in an explanatory variable. We also discussed that, because y is a zero-one outcome, P(y 􏱪 1) 􏱪 E(y), and this equality continues to hold when we condition on explanatory variables. Other discrete dependent variables arise in practice, and we have already seen some ex- amples, such as the number of times someone is arrested in a given year (Example 3.5). Studies on factors affecting fertility often use the number of living children as the dependent variable in a regression analysis. As with number of arrests, the number of living children takes on a small set of integer values, and zero is a common value. The data in FERTIL2.RAW, which contains information on a large sample of women in Botswana is one such example. Often demographers are interested in the effects of education on fertility, with special attention to trying to determine whether education has a causal effect on fertility. Such examples raise a question about how one interprets regression coefficients: after all, one cannot have a fraction of a child. To illustrate the issues, the regression below uses the data in FERTIL2.RAW: 􏱾children 􏱪 􏱦1.997 􏱕 .175 age 􏱦 .090 educ [7.35] (.094) (.003) (.006) n 􏱪 4,361, R2 􏱪 .560. At this time, we ignore the issue of whether this regression adequately controls for all fac- tors that affect fertility. Instead we focus on interpreting the regression coefficients. Consider the main coefficient of interest, 􏱬ˆeduc 􏱪 􏱦.090. If we take this estimate liter- ally, it says that each additional year of education reduces the estimated number of children by .090—something obviously impossible for any particular woman. A similar problem arises when trying to interpret 􏱬ˆage 􏱪 .175. How can we make sense of these coefficients? To interpret regression results generally, even in cases where y is discrete and takes on a small number of values, it is useful to remember the interpretation of OLS as estimat- ing the effects of the xj on the expected (or average) value of y. Generally, under Assump- tions MLR.1 and MLR.4, E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk. [7.36] Therefore, 􏱬j is the effect of a ceteris paribus increase of xj on the expected value of y. As we discussed in Section 6.4, for a given set of xj values we interpret the predicted value, 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk, as an estimate of E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk ). Therefore, 􏱬ˆj is our estimate of how the average of y changes when ∆xj 􏱪 1 (keeping other factors fixed). Seen in this light, we can now provide meaning to regression results as in equation (7.35). The coefficient 􏱬ˆeduc 􏱪 −.090 means that we estimate that average fertility falls by .09 children given one more year of education. A nice way to summarize this Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 257 interpretation is that if each woman in a group of 100 obtains another year of education, we estimate there will be nine fewer children among them. Adding dummy variables to regressions when y is itself discrete causes no prob- lems when we intepret the estimated effect in terms of average values. Using the data in FERTIL2.RAW we get 􏱾children 􏱪 􏱦2.071 􏱕 .177 age 􏱦 .079 educ 􏱦 .362 electric [7.37] (.095) (.003) (.006) (.068) n 􏱪 4,358, R2 􏱪 .562, where electric is a dummy variable equal to one if the woman lives in a home with elec- tricity. Of course it cannot be true that a particular woman who has electricity has .362 less children than an otherwise comparable woman who does not. But we can say that when comparing 100 women with electricity to 100 women without—at the same age and level of education—we estimate the former group to have about 36 fewer children. Incidentally, when y is discrete the linear model does not always provide the best estimates of partial effects on E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk ). Chapter 17 contains more advanced models and estimation methods that tend to fit the data better when the range of y is limited in some substantive way. Nevertheless, a linear model estimated by OLS often provides a good approximation to the true partial effects, at least on average. Summary In this chapter, we have learned how to use qualitative information in regression analysis. In the simplest case, a dummy variable is defined to distinguish between two groups, and the coefficient estimate on the dummy variable estimates the ceteris paribus difference between the two groups. Allowing for more than two groups is accomplished by defining a set of dummy variables: if there are g groups, then g 􏱦 1 dummy variables are included in the model. All estimates on the dummy variables are interpreted relative to the base or benchmark group (the group for which no dummy variable is included in the model). Dummy variables are also useful for incorporating ordinal information, such as a credit or a beauty rating, in regression models. We simply define a set of dummy variables representing different outcomes of the ordinal variable, allowing one of the categories to be the base group. Dummy variables can be interacted with quantitative variables to allow slope differences across different groups. In the extreme case, we can allow each group to have its own slope on every variable, as well as its own intercept. The Chow test can be used to detect whether there are any differences across groups. In many cases, it is more interesting to test whether, after allowing for an intercept difference, the slopes for two different groups are the same. A standard F test can be used for this purpose in an unrestricted model that includes interactions between the group dummy and all variables. The linear probability model, which is simply estimated by OLS, allows us to explain a binary response using regression analysis. The OLS estimates are now interpreted as changes in the probability of “success” (y 􏱪 1), given a one-unit increase in the corresponding explana- tory variable. The LPM does have some drawbacks: it can produce predicted probabilities that are less than zero or greater than one, it implies a constant marginal effect of each explana- tory variable that appears in its original form, and it contains heteroskedasticity. The first two problems are often not serious when we are obtaining estimates of the partial effects of the explanatory variables for the middle ranges of the data. Heteroskedasticity does invalidate the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 258 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data usual OLS standard errors and test statistics, but, as we will see in the next chapter, this is easily fixed in large enough samples. Section 7.6 provides a discussion of how binary variables are used to evaluate policies and programs. As in all regression analysis, we must remember that program participation, or some other binary regressor with policy implications, might be correlated with unobserved factors that affect the dependent variable, resulting in the usual omitted variables bias. We ended this chapter with a general discussion of how to interpret regression equations when the dependent variable is discrete. The key is to remember that the coefficients can be interpreted as the effects on the expected value of the dependent variable. Key Terms Base Group Benchmark Group Binary Variable Chow Statistic Control Group Difference in Slopes Dummy Variable Trap Problems Dummy Variables Experimental Group Interaction Term Intercept Shift Linear Probability Model (LPM) Ordinal Variable Percent Correctly Predicted Policy Analysis Program Evaluation Response Probability Self-Selection Treatment Group Uncentered R-Squared Zero-One Variable 1 UsingthedatainSLEEP75.RAW(seealsoProblem3inChapter3),weobtaintheestimated equation 􏱾sleep􏱪3,840.83 􏱦 .163 totwrk 􏱦 11.71 educ 􏱦 8.70 age (235.11) (.018) (5.86) (11.21) 􏱕 .128 age2 􏱕 87.75 male (.134) (34.33) n 􏱪 706, R2 􏱪 .123,R-2 􏱪 .117. The variable sleep is total minutes per week spent sleeping at night, totwrk is total weekly minutes spent working, educ and age are measured in years, and male is a gender dummy. (i) All other factors being equal, is there evidence that men sleep more than women? How strong is the evidence? (ii) Is there a statistically significant tradeoff between working and sleeping? What is the estimated tradeoff? (iii) What other regression do you need to run to test the null hypothesis that, holding other factors fixed, age has no effect on sleeping? 2 The following equations were estimated using the data in BWGHT.RAW: 􏱾log(bwght)􏱪4.66 􏱦 .0044 cigs 􏱕 .0093 log( faminc) 􏱕 .016 parity (.22) (.0009) (.0059) (.006) 􏱕 .027 male 􏱕 .055 white (.010) (.013) n 􏱪 1,388, R2 􏱪 .0472 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 259 and 􏱾log(bwght)􏱪4.65 􏱦 .0052 cigs 􏱕 .0110 log( faminc) 􏱕 .017 parity (.38) (.0010) (.0085) (.006) 􏱕 .034 male 􏱕 .045 white 􏱦 .0030 motheduc 􏱕 .0032 fatheduc (.011) (.015) (.0030) (.0026) n 􏱪 1,191, R2 􏱪 .0493. The variables are defined as in Example 4.9, but we have added a dummy variable for whether the child is male and a dummy variable indicating whether the child is classified as white. (i) In the first equation, interpret the coefficient on the variable cigs. In particular, what is the effect on birth weight from smoking 10 more cigarettes per day? (ii) Howmuchmoreisawhitechildpredictedtoweighthananonwhitechild,holding the other factors in the first equation fixed? Is the difference statistically significant? (iii) Comment on the estimated effect and statistical significance of motheduc. (iv) From the given information, why are you unable to compute the F statistic for joint significance of motheduc and fatheduc? What would you have to do to compute the F statistic? 3 Using the data in GPA2.RAW, the following equation was estimated: s􏱾at􏱪1,028.10 􏱕 19.30 hsize 􏱦 2.19 hsize2 􏱦 45.09 female (6.29) (3.83) (.53) (4.29) 􏱦 169.81 black 􏱕 62.31 female􏱳black (12.71) (18.15) n 􏱪 4,137, R2 􏱪 .0858. The variable sat is the combined SAT score, hsize is size of the student’s high school grad- uating class, in hundreds, female is a gender dummy variable, and black is a race dummy variable equal to one for blacks and zero otherwise. (i) Is there strong evidence that hsize2 should be included in the model? From this equa- tion, what is the optimal high school size? (ii) Holdinghsizefixed,whatistheestimateddifferenceinSATscorebetweennonblack females and nonblack males? How statistically significant is this estimated difference? (iii) What is the estimated difference in SAT score between nonblack males and black males? Test the null hypothesis that there is no difference between their scores, against the alternative that there is a difference. (iv) What is the estimated difference in SAT score between black females and nonblack females? What would you need to do to test whether the difference is statistically significant? 4 An equation explaining chief executive officer salary is 􏱾log(salary)􏱪 4.59 􏱕 .257 log(sales) 􏱕 .011 roe 􏱕 .158 finance (.30) (.032) (.004) (.089) 􏱕 .181 consprod 􏱦 .283 utility (.085) (.099) n 􏱪 209, R2 􏱪 .357. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 260 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The data used are in CEOSAL1.RAW, where finance, consprod, and utility are binary variables indicating the financial, consumer products, and utilities industries. The omitted industry is transportation. (i) Compute the approximate percentage difference in estimated salary between the util- ity and transportation industries, holding sales and roe fixed. Is the difference statisti- cally significant at the 1% level? (ii) Use equation (7.10) to obtain the exact percentage difference in estimated salary between the utility and transportation industries and compare this with the answer obtained in part (i). (iii) What is the approximate percentage difference in estimated salary between the consumer products and finance industries? Write an equation that would allow you to test whether the difference is statistically significant. 5 InExample7.2,letnoPCbeadummyvariableequaltooneifthestudentdoesnotowna PC, and zero otherwise. (i) If noPC is used in place of PC in equation (7.6), what happens to the intercept in the estimated equation? What will be the coefficient on noPC? (Hint: Write PC 􏱪 1 􏱦 noPC and plug this into the equation 􏱾colGPA􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱛ˆ0PC 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1hsGPA 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2ACT.) (ii) What will happen to the R-squared if noPC is used in place of PC? (iii) Should PC and noPC both be included as independent variables in the model? Explain. 6 Totesttheeffectivenessofajobtrainingprogramonthesubsequentwagesofworkers,we specify the model log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1train 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 􏱬3exper 􏱕 u, where train is a binary variable equal to unity if a worker participated in the program. Think of the error term u as containing unobserved worker ability. If less able workers have a greater chance of being selected for the program, and you use an OLS analysis, what can you say about the likely bias in the OLS estimator of 􏱬1? (Hint: Refer back to Chapter 3.) 7 Intheexampleinequation(7.29),supposethatwedefineoutlftobeoneifthewomanis out of the labor force, and zero otherwise. (i) If we regress outlf on all of the independent variables in equation (7.29), what will happen to the intercept and slope estimates? (Hint: inlf 􏱪 1 􏱦 outlf. Plug this into the population equation inlf 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1nwifeinc 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 ... and rearrange.) (ii) What will happen to the standard errors on the intercept and slope estimates? (iii) What will happen to the R-squared? 8 Suppose you collect data from a survey on wages, education, experience, and gender. In addition, you ask for information about marijuana usage. The original question is: “On how many separate occasions last month did you smoke marijuana?” (i) Write an equation that would allow you to estimate the effects of marijuana usage on wage, while controlling for other factors. You should be able to make statements such as, “Smoking marijuana five more times per month is estimated to change wage by x%.” (ii) Write a model that would allow you to test whether drug usage has different effects on wages for men and women. How would you test that there are no differences in the effects of drug usage for men and women? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 261 (iii) Suppose you think it is better to measure marijuana usage by putting people into one of four categories: nonuser, light user (1 to 5 times per month), moderate user (6 to 10 times per month), and heavy user (more than 10 times per month). Now, write a model that allows you to estimate the effects of marijuana usage on wage. (iv) Using the model in part (iii), explain in detail how to test the null hypothesis that marijuana usage has no effect on wage. Be very specific and include a careful listing of degrees of freedom. (v) What are some potential problems with drawing causal inference using the survey data that you collected? 9 Let d be a dummy (binary) variable and let z be a quantitative variable. Consider the model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱛0d􏱕􏱬1z􏱕􏱛1d􏱳z􏱕u; this is a general version of a model with an interaction between a dummy variable and a quantitative variable. [An example is in equation (7.17).] (i) Since it changes nothing important, set the error to zero, u 􏱪 0. Then, when d 􏱪 0 we can write the relationship between y and z as the function f0(z) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1z. Write the same relationship when d 􏱪 1, where you should use f1(z) on the left-hand side to denote the linear function of z. (ii) Assuming that 􏱛1􏱻 0 (which means the two lines are not parallel), show that the value of z* such that f0(z*) 􏱪 f1(z*) is z* 􏱪 􏱦􏱛0/􏱛1. This is the point at which the two lines intersect [as in Figure 7.2(b)]. Argue that z* is positive if and only if 􏱛0 and 􏱛1 have opposite signs. (iii) Using the data in TWOYEAR.RAW, the following equation can be estimated: 􏱾log(wage)􏱪2.289 􏱦 .357 female 􏱕 .50 totcoll 􏱕 .030 female 􏱫 totcoll (0.011) (.015) (.003) (.005) n 􏱪 6,763, R2 􏱪 .202, where all coefficients and standard errors have been rounded to three decimal places. Using this equation, find the value of totcoll such that the predicted values of log(wage) are the same for men and women. (iv) Based on the equation in part (iii), can women realistically get enough years of college so that their earnings catch up to those of men? Explain. 10 Forachildilivinginaparticularschooldistrict,letvoucheribeadummyvariableequalto one if a child is selected to participate in a school voucher program, and let scorei be that child’s score on a subsequent standardized exam. Suppose that the participation variable, voucheri, is completely randomized in the sense that it is independent of both observed and unobserved factors that can affect the test score. (i) If you run a simple regression scorei on voucheri using a random sample of size n, does the OLS estimator provide an unbiased estimator of the effect of the voucher program? (ii) Suppose you can collect additional background information, such as family income, family structure (e.g., whether the child lives with both parents), and parents’ educa- tion levels. Do you need to control for these factors to obtain an unbiased estimator of the effects of the voucher program? Explain. (iii) Why should you include the family background variables in the regression? Is there a situation in which you would not include the background variables? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 262 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in GPA1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Add the variables mothcoll and fathcoll to the equation estimated in (7.6) and report the results in the usual form. What happens to the estimated effect of PC ownership? Is PC still statistically significant? (ii) Test for joint significance of mothcoll and fathcoll in the equation from part (i) and be sure to report the p-value. (iii) Add hsGPA2 to the model from part (i) and decide whether this generalization is needed. C2 Use the data in WAGE2.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate the model log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 􏱬4married 􏱕 􏱬5black 􏱕 􏱬6south 􏱕 􏱬7urban 􏱕 u and report the results in the usual form. Holding other factors fixed, what is the approximate difference in monthly salary between blacks and nonblacks? Is this difference statistically significant? (ii) Add the variables exper2 and tenure2 to the equation and show that they are jointly insignificant at even the 20% level. (iii) Extend the original model to allow the return to education to depend on race and test whether the return to education does depend on race. (iv) Again, start with the original model, but now allow wages to differ across four groups of people: married and black, married and nonblack, single and black, and single and nonblack. What is the estimated wage differential between married blacks and married nonblacks? C3 A model that allows major league baseball player salary to differ by position is log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1years 􏱕 􏱬2gamesyr 􏱕 􏱬3bavg 􏱕 􏱬4hrunsyr 􏱕 􏱬5rbisyr 􏱕 􏱬6runsyr 􏱕 􏱬7 fldperc 􏱕 􏱬8allstar 􏱕 􏱬9 frstbase 􏱕 􏱬10scndbase 􏱕 􏱬11thrdbase 􏱕 􏱬12shrtstop 􏱕 􏱬13catcher 􏱕 u, where outfield is the base group. (i) State the null hypothesis that, controlling for other factors, catchers and outfielders earn, on average, the same amount. Test this hypothesis using the data in MLB1.RAW and comment on the size of the estimated salary differential. (ii) State and test the null hypothesis that there is no difference in average salary across positions, once other factors have been controlled for. (iii) Are the results from parts (i) and (ii) consistent? If not, explain what is happening. C4 Use the data in GPA2.RAW for this exercise. (i) Consider the equation colgpa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1hsize 􏱕 􏱬2hsize2 􏱕 􏱬3hsperc 􏱕 􏱬4sat 􏱕 􏱬5 female 􏱕 􏱬6athlete 􏱕 u, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 263 where colgpa is cumulative college grade point average, hsize is size of high school graduating class, in hundreds, hsperc is academic percentile in graduating class, sat is combined SAT score, female is a binary gender variable, and athlete is a binary variable, which is one for student-athletes. What are your expectations for the coefficients in this equation? Which ones are you unsure about? (ii) Estimate the equation in part (i) and report the results in the usual form. What is the estimated GPA differential between athletes and nonathletes? Is it statistically significant? (iii) Drop sat from the model and reestimate the equation. Now, what is the estimated effect of being an athlete? Discuss why the estimate is different than that obtained in part (ii). (iv) In the model from part (i), allow the effect of being an athlete to differ by gender and test the null hypothesis that there is no ceteris paribus difference between women athletes and women nonathletes. (v) Does the effect of sat on colgpa differ by gender? Justify your answer. C5 In Problem 2 in Chapter 4, we added the return on the firm’s stock, ros, to a model explaining CEO salary; ros turned out to be insignificant. Now, define a dummy variable, rosneg, which is equal to one if ros 􏱷 0 and equal to zero if ros 􏱸 0. Use CEOSAL1.RAW to estimate the model log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2roe 􏱕 􏱬3rosneg 􏱕 u. Discuss the interpretation and statistical significance of 􏱬ˆ3. C6 Use the data in SLEEP75.RAW for this exercise. The equation of interest is sleep 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1totwrk 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 􏱬4age2 􏱕 􏱬5yngkid 􏱕 u. (i) Estimate this equation separately for men and women and report the results in the usual form. Are there notable differences in the two estimated equations? (ii) Compute the Chow test for equality of the parameters in the sleep equation for men and women. Use the form of the test that adds male and the interaction terms male􏱳totwrk, ..., male􏱳yngkid and uses the full set of observations. What are the relevant df for the test? Should you reject the null at the 5% level? (iii) Now, allow for a different intercept for males and females and determine whether the interaction terms involving male are jointly significant. (iv) Given the results from parts (ii) and (iii), what would be your final model? C7 Use (i) Use equation (7.18) to estimate the gender differential when educ 􏱪 12.5. Compare this with the estimated differential when educ 􏱪 0. (ii) Run the regression used to obtain (7.18), but with female􏱳(educ 􏱦 12.5) replacing female􏱳educ. How do you interpret the coefficient on female now? (iii) Is the coefficient on female in part (ii) statistically significant? Compare this with (7.18) and comment. the data in WAGE1.RAW for this exercise. C8 Use is approve, which is equal to one if a mortgage loan to an individual was approved. The key explanatory variable is white, a dummy variable equal to one if the applicant was white. The other applicants in the data set are black and Hispanic. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in LOANAPP.RAW for this exercise. The binary variable to be explained 264 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data To test for discrimination in the mortgage loan market, a linear probability model can be used: approve 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1white 􏱕 other factors. (i) If there is discrimination against minorities, and the appropriate factors have been controlled for, what is the sign of 􏱬1? (ii) Regress approve on white and report the results in the usual form. Interpret the coefficient on white. Is it statistically significant? Is it practically large? (iii) As controls, add the variables hrat, obrat, loanprc, unem, male, married, dep, sch, cosign, chist, pubrec, mortlat1, mortlat2, and vr. What happens to the coefficient on white? Is there still evidence of discrimination against nonwhites? (iv) Now, allow the effect of race to interact with the variable measuring other obliga- tions as a percentage of income (obrat). Is the interaction term significant? (v) Using the model from part (iv), what is the effect of being white on the probability of approval when obrat 􏱪 32, which is roughly the mean value in the sample? Obtain a 95% confidence interval for this effect. C9 There has been much interest in whether the presence of 401(k) pension plans, available to many U.S. workers, increases net savings. The data set 401KSUBS.RAW contains information on net financial assets (nettfa), family income (inc), a binary variable for eligibility in a 401(k) plan (e401k), and several other variables. (i) What fraction of the families in the sample are eligible for participation in a 401(k) plan? (ii) Estimate a linear probability model explaining 401(k) eligibility in terms of income, age, and gender. Include income and age in quadratic form, and report the results in the usual form. (iii) Would you say that 401(k) eligibility is independent of income and age? What about gender? Explain. (iv) Obtain the fitted values from the linear probability m􏱷odel estimated in part (ii). re any fitted values negative or greater than one? A􏱷 (v) Using the fitted values 􏱾e401ki from part (iv), define e401ki 􏱪 1 if 􏱾e401k 􏱸 .5 and 401k 􏱪 0 if 􏱾e401k 􏱷 .5. Out of 9,275 families, how many are predicted to be eligible for a 401(k) plan? (vi) For the 5,638 families not eligible for a 401(k), 􏱷what percentage of these are pre- dicted not to have a 401(k), using the predictor e401ki? For the 3,637 families eligible for a 401(k) plan, what percentage are predicted to have one? (It is helpful if your econometrics package has a “tabulate” command.) (vii) The overall percent correctly predicted is about 64.9%. Do you think this is a com- plete description of how well the model does, given your answers in part (vi)? (viii) Add the variable pira as an explanatory variable to the linear probability model. Other things equal, if a family has someone with an individual retirement account, how much higher is the estimated probability that the family is eligible for a 401(k) plan? Is it statistically different from zero at the 10% level? C10 Use the data in NBASAL.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate a linear regression model relating points per game to experience in the league and position (guard, forward, or center). Include experience in quadratic form and use centers as the base group. Report the results in the usual form. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 265 (ii) Why do you not include all three position dummy variables in part (i)? (iii) Holding experience fixed, does a guard score more than a center? How much more? Is the difference statistically significant? (iv) Now, add marital status to the equation. Holding position and experience fixed, are married players more productive (based on points per game)? (v) Add interactions of marital status with both experience variables. In this expanded model, is there strong evidence that marital status affects points per game? (vi) Estimate the model from part (iv) but use assists per game as the dependent variable. Are there any notable differences from part (iv)? Discuss. C11 Use (i) Compute the average, standard deviation, minimum, and maximum values of nettfa in the sample. (ii) Test the hypothesis that average nettfa does not differ by 401(k) eligibility status; use a two-sided alternative. What is the dollar amount of the estimated difference? (iii) From part (ii) of Computer Exercise C9, it is clear that e401k is not exogenous in a simple regression model; at a minimum, it changes by income and age. Estimate a multiple linear regression model for nettfa that includes income, age, and e401k as explanatory variables. The income and age variables should appear as quadratics. Now, what is the estimated dollar effect of 401(k) eligibility? (iv) To the model estimated in part (iii), add the interactions e401k 􏱳 (age 􏱦 41) and e401k · (age 􏱦 41)2. Note that the average age in the sample is about 41, so that in the new model, the coefficient on e401k is the estimated effect of 401(k) eligibility at the average age. Which interaction term is significant? (v) Comparing the estimates from parts (iii) and (iv), do the estimated effects of 401(k) eligibility at age 41 differ much? Explain. (vi) Now, drop the interaction terms from the model, but define five family size dummy variables: fsize1, fsize2, fsize3, fsize4, and fsize5. The variable fsize5 is unity for families with five or more members. Include the family size dummies in the model estimated from part (iii); be sure to choose a base group. Are the family dummies significant at the 1% level? (vii) Now, do a Chow test for the model nettfa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2inc2 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 􏱬4age2 􏱕 􏱬5e401k 􏱕 u across the five family size categories, allowing for intercept differences. The restricted sum of squared residuals, SSRr, is obtained from part (vi) because that regression assumes all slopes are the same. The unrestricted sum of squared residuals is SSRur 􏱪 SSR1 􏱕 SSR2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 SSR5, where SSRf is the sum of squared residuals for the equation estimated using only family size f. You should convince yourself that there are 30 parameters in the unrestricted model (5 inter- cepts plus 25 slopes) and 10 parameters in the restricted model (5 intercepts plus 5 slopes). Therefore, the number of restrictions being tested is q 􏱪 20, and the df for the unrestricted model is 9,275 􏱦 30 􏱪 9,245. C12 Use the data set in BEAUTY.RAW, which contains a subset of the variables (but more usable observations than in the regressions) reported by Hamermesh and Biddle (1994). (i) Find the separate fractions of men and women that are classified as having above average looks. Are more people rated as having above average or below average looks? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in 401KSUBS.RAW for this exercise. 266 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (ii) Test the null hypothesis that the population fractions of above-average-looking women and men are the same. Report the one-sided p-value that the fraction is higher for women. (Hint: Estimating a simple linear probability model is easiest.) (iii) Now estimate the model log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1belavg 􏱕 􏱬2abvavg 􏱕 u separately for men and women, and report the results in the usual form. In both cases, interpret the coefficient on belavg. Explain in words what the hypothesis H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱷 0 means, and find the p-values for men and women. (iv) Is there convincing evidence that women with above average looks earn more than women with average looks? Explain. (v) For both men and women, add the explanatory variables educ, exper, exper2, union, goodhlth, black, married, south, bigcity, smllcity, and service. Do the effects of the “looks” variables change in important ways? (vi) Use the SSR form of the Chow F statistic to test whether the slopes of the regres- sion functions in part (v) differ across men and women. Be sure to allow for an intercept shift under the null. C13 Use (i) Define a binary variable as ecobuy 􏱪 1 if ecolbs 􏱰 0 and ecobuy 􏱪 0 if ecolbs 􏱪 0. In other words, ecobuy indicates whether, at the prices given, a family would buy any ecologically friendly apples. What fraction of families claim they would buy ecolabeled apples? (ii) Estimate the linear probability model ecobuy 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1ecoprc 􏱕 􏱬2 regprc 􏱕 􏱬3 faminc 􏱕 􏱬4hhsize 􏱕 􏱬5educ 􏱕 􏱬6age 􏱕 u, and report the results in the usual form. Carefully interpret the coefficients on the price variables. (iii) Are the nonprice variables jointly significant in the LPM? (Use the usual F statis- tic, even though it is not valid when there is heteroskedasticity.) Which explana- tory variable other than the price variables seems to have the most important effect on the decision to buy ecolabeled apples? Does this make sense to you? (iv) In the model from part (ii), replace faminc with log(faminc). Which model fits the data better, using faminc or log( faminc)? Interpret the coefficient on log( faminc). (v) In the estimation in part (iv), how many estimated probabilities are negative? How many are bigger than one? Should you be concerned? (vi) For the estimation in part (iv), compute the percent correctly predicted for each outcome, ecobuy 􏱪 0 and ecobuy 􏱪 1. Which outcome is best predicted by the model? the data in APPLE.RAW to answer this question. C14 Use dummy variable equal to one if a person responded with a contribution on the most recent mailing sent by a charitable organization. The variable resplast is a dummy vari- able equal to one if the person responded to the previous mailing, avggift is the average of past gifts (in Dutch guilders), and propresp is the proportion of times the person has responded to past mailings. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in CHARITY.RAW to answer this question. The variable respond is a CHAPTER 7 Multiple Regression Analysis with Qualitative Information 267 (i) Estimate a linear probability model relating respond to resplast and avggift. Report the results in the usual form, and interpret the coefficient on resplast. (ii) Does the average value of past gifts seem to affect the probability of responding? (iii) Add the variable propresp to the model, and interpret its coefficient. (Be careful here: an increase of one in propresp is the largest possible change.) (iv) What happened to the coefficient on resplast when propresp was added to the regression? Does this make sense? (v) Add mailsyear, the number of mailings per year, to the model. How big is its esti- mated effect? Why might this not be a good estimate of the causal effect of mailings on responding? C15 Use (i) Find the smallest and largest values of children in the sample. What is the average the data in FERTIL2.RAW to answer this question. of children? Does any woman have exactly the average number of children? (ii) What percentage of women have electricity in the home? (iii) Compute the average of children for those without electricity and do the same for those with electricity. Comment on what you find. Test whether the population means are the same using a simple regression. (iv) From part (iii), can you infer that having electricity “causes” women to have fewer children? Explain. (v) Estimate a multiple regression model of the kind reported in equation (7.37), but add age2, urban, and the three religious affiliation dummies. How does the esti- mated effect of having electricity compare with that in part (iii)? Is it still statisti- cally significant? (vi) To the equation in part (v), add an interaction between electric and educ. Is its co- efficient statistically significant? What happens to the coefficient on electric? (vii) The median and mode value for educ is 7. In the equation from part (vi), use the centered interaction term electric 􏱫 (educ – 7) in place of electric 􏱫 educ. What happens to the coefficient on electric compared with part (vi)? Why? How does the coefficient on electric compare with that in part (v)? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u. [8.1] In Chapter 3, we proved unbiasedness of the OLS estimators 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, 􏱬ˆ2, ..., 􏱬ˆk under the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions, MLR.1 through MLR.4. In Chapter 5, we showed that the same four assumptions imply consistency of OLS. The homoskedasticity assump- tion MLR.5, stated in terms of the error variance as Var(u􏱊x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱧2, played no role in showing whether OLS was unbiased or consistent. It is important to remember that heteroskedasticity does not cause bias or inconsistency in the OLS estimators of the 􏱬j, whereas something like omitting an important variable would have this effect. The interpretation of our goodness-of-fit measures, R2 and R- 2, is also unaffected by the presence of heteroskedasticity. Why? Recall from Section 6.3 that the usual R-squared and the adjusted R-squared are different ways of estimating the population R-squared, which is simply 1 􏱦 􏱧u2/􏱧y2, where 􏱧u2 is the population error variance and 􏱧y2 is the CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity The homoskedasticity assumption, introduced in Chapter 3 for multiple regression, states that the variance of the unobserved error, u, conditional on the explanatory variables, is constant. Homoskedasticity fails whenever the variance of the unob- served factors changes across different segments of the population, where the segments are determined by the different values of the explanatory variables. For example, in a savings equation, heteroskedasticity is present if the variance of the unobserved factors affecting savings increases with income. In Chapters 4 and 5, we saw that homoskedasticity is needed to justify the usual t tests, F tests, and confidence intervals for OLS estimation of the linear regression model, even with large sample sizes. In this chapter, we discuss the available remedies when hetero- skedasticity occurs, and we also show how to test for its presence. We begin by briefly reviewing the consequences of heteroskedasticity for ordinary least squares estimation. 8.1 Consequences of Heteroskedasticity for OLS Consider again the multiple linear regression model: 268 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. population variance of y. The key point is that because both variances in the population R-squared are unconditional variances, the population R-squared is unaffected by the presence of heteroskedasticity in Var(u􏰫x1, ..., xk). Further, SSR/n consistently estimates 􏱧2, and SST/n consistently estimates 􏱧2, whether or not Var(u􏰫x , ..., x ) is constant. The uy1k2-2 same is true when we use the degrees of freedom adjustments. Therefore, R and R are both consistent estimators of the population R-squared whether or not the homoskedasticity assumption holds. If heteroskedasticity does not cause bias or inconsistency in the OLS estimators, why did we introduce it as one of the Gauss-Markov assumptions? Recall from Chapter 3 that the estimators of the variances, Var(􏱬ˆj), are biased without the homoskedasticity assump- tion. Since the OLS standard errors are based directly on these variances, they are no lon- ger valid for constructing confidence intervals and t statistics. The usual OLS t statistics do not have t distributions in the presence of heteroskedasticity, and the problem is not resolved by using large sample sizes. We will see this explicitly for the simple regression case in the next section, where we derive the variance of the OLS slope estimator un- der heteroskedasticity and propose a valid estimator in the presence of heteroskedasticity. Similarly, F statistics are no longer F distributed, and the LM statistic no longer has an asymptotic chi-square distribution. In summary, the statistics we used to test hypotheses under the Gauss-Markov assumptions are not valid in the presence of heteroskedasticity. We also know that the Gauss-Markov Theorem, which says that OLS is best linear unbiased, relies crucially on the homoskedasticity assumption. If Var(u􏰫x) is not constant, OLS is no longer BLUE. In addition, OLS is no longer asymptotically efficient in the class of estimators described in Theorem 5.3. As we will see in Section 8.4, it is possible to find estimators that are more efficient than OLS in the presence of heteroskedasticity (although it requires knowing the form of the heteroskedasticity). With relatively large sample sizes, it might not be so important to obtain an efficient estimator. In the next section, we show how the usual OLS test statistics can be modified so that they are valid, at least asymptotically. 8.2 Heteroskedasticity-Robust Inference after OLS Estimation Because testing hypotheses is such an important component of any econometric analysis and the usual OLS inference is generally faulty in the presence of heteroskedasticity, we must decide if we should entirely abandon OLS. Fortunately, OLS is still useful. In the last two decades, econometricians have learned how to adjust standard errors and t, F, and LM statistics so that they are valid in the presence of heteroskedasticity of unknown form. This is very convenient because it means we can report new statistics that work regardless of the kind of heteroskedasticity present in the population. The methods in this section are known as heteroskedasticity-robust procedures because they are valid—at least in large samples—whether or not the errors have constant variance, and we do not need to know which is the case. ˆ We begin by sketching how the variances, Var(􏱬j), can be estimated in the presence of heteroskedasticity. A careful derivation of the theory is well beyond the scope of this text, but the application of heteroskedasticity-robust methods is very easy now because many statistics and econometrics packages compute these statistics as an option. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 269 270 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data First, consider the model with a single independent variable, where we include an i subscript for emphasis: yi 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xi 􏱕ui. We assume throughout that the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions hold. If the errors contain heteroskedasticity, then Var(ui􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱧i2, where we put an i subscript on 􏱧2 to indicate that the variance of the error depends upon the particular value of xi. Write the OLS estimator as ∑n - 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 ∑ 11n-2 (x 􏱶x) i i􏲁1 Under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4 (that is, without the homoskedasticity assumption), and conditioning on the values xi in the sample, we can use the same arguments from Chapter 2 to show that ∑n -22 ˆ (xi 􏱶x) 􏱧i Var(􏱬1) 􏱪 _i_􏲁_1________________, [8.2] SST2x (xi 􏱦 x-)2 is the total sum of squares of the xi. When 􏱧2i 􏱪 􏱧2 for all i, 2 where SSTx 􏱪 ∑ n i􏱪1 this formula reduces to the usual form, 􏱧 /SSTx. Equation (8.2) explicitly shows that, for the simple regression case, the variance formula derived under homoskedasticity is no longer valid when heteroskedasticity is present. Since the standard error of 􏱬ˆ1 is based directly on estimating Var(􏱬ˆ1), we need a way to estimate equation (8.2) when heteroskedasticity is present. White (1980) showed how this can be done. Let uˆi denote the OLS residuals from the initial regression of y on x. Then, a valid estimator of Var(􏱬ˆ1), for heteroskedasticity of any form (including homo- skedasticity), is ∑n -22 ( x i 􏱶 x ) uˆ i _i􏲁_1__________, SST2x [8.3] which is easily computed from the data after the OLˆS regression. In what sense is (8.3) a valid estimator of Var(􏱬1)? This is pretty subtle. Briefly, it can be shown that when equation (8.3) is multiplied by the sample size n, it converges in prob- ability to E[(xi 􏱦 􏱙x)2u2i ]/(􏱧2x)2, which is the probability limit of n times (8.2). Ultimately, this is what is necessary for justifying the use of standard errors to construct confidence intervals and t statistics. The law of large numbers and the central limit theorem play Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. (xi 􏱶 x)ui _i_􏲁_1______________ . where rˆij denotes the ith residual from regressing xj on all other independent variables, and SSRj is the sum of squared residuals from this regression (see Section 3.2 for the partial- ling out representation of the OLS estimates). The square root of the quantity in (8.4) is called the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error for 􏱬ˆj. In econometrics, these robust standard errors are usually attributed to White (1980). Earlier works in statistics, notably those by Eicker (1967) and Huber (1967), pointed to the possibility of obtaining such ro- bust standard errors. In applied work, these are sometimes called White, Huber, or Eicker standard errors (or some hyphenated combination of these names). We will just refer to them as heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors, or even just robust standard errors when the context is clear. Sometimes, as a degrees of freedom correction, (8.4) is multiplied by n/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) before taking the square root. The reasoning for this adjustment is that, if the squared OLS residualsuˆ2i werethesameforallobservationsi—thestrongestpossibleformofhomoske- dasticity in a sample—we would get the usual OLS standard errors. Other modifications of (8.4) are studied in MacKinnon and White (1985). Since all forms have only asymptotic justification and they are asymptotically equivalent, no form is uniformly preferred above all others. Typically, we use whatever form is computed by the regression package at hand. Once heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are obtained, it is simple to construct a heteroskedasticity-robust t statistic. Recall that the general form of the t statistic is estimate 􏱶 hypothesized value t 􏱪 _________________________ . [8.5] standard error Because we are still using the OLS estimates and we have chosen the hypothesized value ahead of time, the only difference between the usual OLS t statistic and the heteroskedas- ticity-robust t statistic is in how the standard error in the denominator is computed. The term SSRj in equation (8.4) can be replaced with SSTj(1 – R2j ), where SSTj is the total sum of squares of xj and R2j is the usual R-squared from regressing xj on all other explanatory variables. [We implicitly used this equivalance in deriving equation (3.51).] Consequently, little sample variation in xj, or a strong linear relationship between xj and the other explanatory variables—that is, multicollinearity—can cause the heteroskedas- ticity-robust standard errrors to be large. We discussed these issues with the usual OLS standard errors in Section 3.4. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾Var (􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 rˆ2uˆ2 i􏲁1 , CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 271 key roles in establishing these convergences. You can refer to White’s original paper for details, but that paper is quite technical. See also Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 4). A similar formula works in the general multiple regression model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u. It can be shown that a valid estimator of Var(􏱬ˆ j), under Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4, is [8.4] ∑n ij i SSR2j 272 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 8.1 LOG WAGE EQUATION WITH HETEROSKEDASTICITY- ROBUST STANDARD ERRORS We estimate the model in Example 7.6, but we report the heteroskedasticity-robust stan- dard errors along with the usual OLS standard errors. Some of the estimates are reported to more digits so that we can compare the usual standard errors with the heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors: 􏱾log(wage)􏱪 .321 􏱕 .213 marrmale 􏱦 .198 marrfem 􏱦 .110 singfem (.100) (.055) (.058) (.056) [.109] [.057] [.058] [.057] 􏱕 .0789 educ 􏱕 .0268 exper 􏱦 .00054 exper2 (.0067) (.0055) (.00011) [.0074] [.0051] [.00011] 􏱕 .0291 tenure 􏱦 .00053 tenure2 (.0068) (.00023) [.0069] [.00024] n 􏱪 526, R2 􏱪 .461. [8.6] The usual OLS standard errors are in parentheses, ( ), below the corresponding OLS esti- mate, and the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are in brackets, [ ]. The numbers in brackets are the only new things, since the equation is still estimated by OLS. Several things are apparent from equation (8.6). First, in this particular application, any variable that was statistically significant using the usual t statistic is still statistically significant using the heteroskedasticity-robust t statistic. This occurs because the two sets of standard errors are not very different. (The associated p-values will differ slightly because the robust t statistics are not identical to the usual, nonrobust t statistics.) The largest relative change in standard errors is for the coefficient on educ: the usual standard error is .0067, and the robust standard error is .0074. Still, the robust standard error implies a robust t statistic above 10. Equation (8.6) also shows that the robust standard errors can be either larger or smaller than the usual standard errors. For example, the robust standard error on exper is .0051, whereas the usual standard error is .0055. We do not know which will be larger ahead of time. As an empirical matter, the robust standard errors are often found to be larger than the usual standard errors. Before leaving this example, we must emphasize that we do not know, at this point, whether heteroskedasticity is even present in the population model underlying equation (8.6). All we have done is report, along with the usual standard errors, those that are valid (asymptoti- cally) whether or not heteroskedasticity is present. We can see that no important conclusions are overturned by using the robust standard errors in this example. This often happens in applied work, but in other cases, the differences between the usual and robust standard errors are much larger. As an example of where the differences are substantial, see Computer Exercise C2. At this point, you may be asking the following question: If the heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors are valid more often than the usual OLS standard errors, why do we bother with the usual standard errors at all? This is a sensible question. One reason the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. usual standard errors are still used in cross-sectional work is that, if the homoskedasticity assumption holds and the errors are normally distributed, then the usual t statistics have exact t distributions, regardless of the sample size (see Chapter 4). The robust standard errors and robust t statistics are justified only as the sample size becomes large, even if the CLM assumptions are true. With small sample sizes, the robust t statistics can have distri- butions that are not very close to the t distribution, and that could throw off our inference. In large sample sizes, we can make a case for always reporting only the heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors in cross-sectional applications, and this practice is being followed more and more in applied work. It is also common to report both standard errors, as in equation (8.6), so that a reader can determine whether any conclusions are sensitive to the standard error in use. It is also possible to obtain F and LM statistics that are robust to heteroskedasticity of an unknown, arbitrary form. The heteroskedasticity-robust F statistic (or a simple transformation of it) is also called a heteroskedasticity-robust Wald statistic. A general treatment of the Wald statistic requires matrix algebra and is sketched in Appendix E; see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 4) for a more detailed treatment. Nevertheless, using heteroskedasticity-robust statistics for multiple exclusion restrictions is straightforward because many econometrics packages now compute such statistics routinely. EXAMPLE 8.2 HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST F STATISTIC Using the data for the spring semester in GPA3.RAW, we estimate the following equation: [8.7] Again, the differences between the usual standard errors and the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are not very big, and use of the robust t statistics does not change the statis- tical significance of any independent variable. Joint significance tests are not much affected either. Suppose we wish to test the null hypothesis that, after the other factors are controlled for, there are no differences in cumgpa by race. This is stated as H0: 􏱬black 􏱪 0, 􏱬white 􏱪 0. The usual F statistic is easily obtained, once we have the R-squared from the restricted model; this turns out to be .3983. The F statistic is then [(.4006 􏱦 .3983)/(1􏱦.4006)](359/2) 􏱴 .69. If heteroskedasticity is present, this version of the test is invalid. The heteroskedasticity- robust version has no simple form, but it can be computed using certain statistical packages. The value of the heteroskedasticity-robust F statistic turns out to be .75, which differs only slightly from the nonrobust version. The p-value for the robust test is .474, which is not close to standard significance levels. We fail to reject the null hypothesis using either test. Because the usual sum-of-squared residuals form of the F statistic is not valid under heteroskedasticity, it can be important when computing a Chow test to use the form that includes a full set of interactions between the group dummy variable and the other Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 273 c􏱾umgpa 􏱪 1.47 􏱕 .00114 sat 􏱦 .00857 hsperc 􏱕 .00250 tothrs (.23) (.00018) (.00124) (.00073) [.22] [.00019] [.00140] [.00073] 􏱕 .303 female 􏱦 .128 black 􏱦 .059 white (.059) (.147) (.141) [.059] [.118] [.110] n 􏱪 366, R2 􏱪 .4006, R-2 􏱪 .3905. 274 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data explanatory variables. This can be tedious but is necessary for obtaining heteroskedasticity- robust F statistics using popular regression packages. See Computer Exercise C14 for an example. Computing Heteroskedasticity-Robust LM Tests Not all regression packages compute F statistics that are robust to heteroskedas- ticity. Therefore, it is sometimes conve- nient to have a way of obtaining a test of multiple exclusion restrictions that is robust to heteroskedasticity and does not require a particular kind of econometric software. It turns out that a heteroskedasticity-robust LM statistic is easily obtained using virtually any regression package. To illustrate computation of the robust LM statistic, consider the model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕􏱬4x4 􏱕􏱬5x5 􏱕u, and suppose we would like to test H0: 􏱬4 􏱪 0, 􏱬5 􏱪 0. To obtain the usual LM statistic, we would first estimate the restricted model (that is, the model without x4 and x5) to obtain the EXPLORING FURTHER 8.1 Evaluate the following statement: The heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are always bigger than the usual standard errors. residuals, u ̃. Then, we would regress u ̃ on all of the independent variables and the LM 􏱪 22 n􏱳Ru~ where Ru~ is the usual R-squared from this regression. Obtaining a version that is robust to heteroskedasticity requires more work. One way to compute the statistic requires only OLS regressions. We need the residuals, say, r ̃1, from the regression of x4 on x1, x2, x3. Also, we need the residuals, say, r ̃2, from the regression of x5 on x1, x2, x3. Thus, we regress each of the independent variables excluded under the null on all of the included independent variables. We keep the residuals each time. The final step appears odd, but it is, after all, just a computational device. Run the regression of 1 on r ̃1u ̃, r ̃2u ̃, [8.8] without an intercept. Yes, we actually define a dependent variable equal to the value one for all observations. We regress this onto the products r ̃1u ̃ and r ̃2u ̃. The robust LM statistic turns out to be n 􏱦 SSR1, where SSR1 is just the usual sum of squared residuals from regression (8.8). The reason this works is somewhat technical. Basically, this is doing for the LM test what the robust standard errors do for the t test. [See Wooldridge (1991b) or Davidson and MacKinnon (1993) for a more detailed discussion.] We now summarize the computation of the heteroskedasticity-robust LM statistic in the general case. A Heteroskedasticity-Robust LM Statistic: 1. Obtain the residuals u ̃ from the restricted model. 2. Regress each of the independent variables excluded under the null on all of the in- cluded independent variables; if there are q excluded variables, this leads to q sets of residuals (r ̃1, r ̃2, ..., r ̃q). 3. Find the products between each r ̃j and u ̃ (for all observations). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 4. Runtheregressionof1onr ̃1u ̃,r ̃2u ̃,...,r ̃qu ̃,withoutanintercept.Theheteroskedasticity- robust LM statistic is n 􏱦 SSR1, where SSR1 is just the usual sum of squared residuals from this final regression. Under H0, LM is distributed approximately as 􏱚q2. Once the robust LM statistic is obtained, the rejection rule and computation of p-values are the same as for the usual LM statistic in Section 5.2. EXAMPLE 8.3 HETEROSKEDASTICITY-ROBUST LM STATISTIC We use the data in CRIME1.RAW to test whether the average sentence length served for past convictions affects the number of arrests in the current year (1986). The estimated model is CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 275 􏱾narr86 􏱪 .567 􏱦 .136 pcnv 􏱕 .0178 avgsen 􏱦 .00052 avgsen2 (.036) (.040) (.0097) (.00030) [.040] [.034] [.0101] [.00021] 􏱦 .0394 ptime86 􏱦 .0505 qemp86 􏱦 .00148 inc86 (.0087) (.0144) [.0062] [.0142] 􏱕 .325 black 􏱕 .193 hispan (.045) (.040) [.058] [.040] n 􏱪 2,725, R2 􏱪 .0728. (.00034) [.00023] [8.9] In this example, there are more substantial differences between some of the usual standard errors and the robust standard errors. For example, the usual t statistic on avgsen2 is about 􏱦1.73, while the robust t statistic is about 􏱦2.48. Thus, avgsen2 is more significant using the robust standard error. The effect of avgsen on narr86 is somewhat difficult to reconcile. Because the relation- ship is quadratic, we can figure out where avgsen has a positive effect on narr86 and where the effect becomes negative. The turning point is .0178/[2(.00052)] 􏱴 17.12; recall that this is measured in months. Literally, this means that narr86 is positively related to avgsen when avgsen is less than 17 months; then avgsen has the expected deterrent effect after 17 months. To see whether average sentence length has a statistically significant effect on narr86, we must test the joint hypothesis H0: 􏱬avgsen 􏱪 0, 􏱬avgsen2 􏱪 0. Using the usual LM statistic (see Section 5.2), we obtain LM 􏱪 3.54; in a chi-square distribution with two df, this yields a p-value 􏱪 .170. Thus, we do not reject H0 at even the 15% level. The heteroskedasticity- robust LM statistic is LM 􏱪 4.00 (rounded to two decimal places), with a p-value 􏱪 .135. This is still not very strong evidence against H0; avgsen does not appear to have a strong effect on narr86. [Incidentally, when avgsen appears alone in (8.9), that is, without the qua- dratic term, its usual t statistic is .658, and its robust t statistic is .592.] 8.3 Testing for Heteroskedasticity The heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors provide a simple method for computing t statistics that are asymptotically t distributed whether or not heteroskedasticity is pres- ent. We have also seen that heteroskedasticity-robust F and LM statistics are available. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 276 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Implementing these tests does not require knowing whether or not heteroskedasticity is pres- ent. Nevertheless, there are still some good reasons for having simple tests that can detect its presence. First, as we mentioned in the previous section, the usual t statistics have exact t distributions under the classical linear model assumptions. For this reason, many econo- mists still prefer to see the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics reported, unless there is evidence of heteroskedasticity. Second, if heteroskedasticity is present, the OLS estimator is no longer the best linear unbiased estimator. As we will see in Section 8.4, it is possible to obtain a better estimator than OLS when the form of heteroskedasticity is known. Many tests for heteroskedasticity have been suggested over the years. Some of them, while having the ability to detect heteroskedasticity, do not directly test the assumption that the variance of the error does not depend upon the independent variables. We will restrict our- selves to more modern tests, which detect the kind of heteroskedasticity that invalidates the usual OLS statistics. This also has the benefit of putting all tests in the same framework. As usual, we start with the linear model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, [8.10] where Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4 are maintained in this section. In particular, we assume that E(u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 0, so that OLS is unbiased and consistent. We take the null hypothesis to be that Assumption MLR.5 is true: H0: Var(u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱧2. [8.11] That is, we assume that the ideal assumption of homoskedasticity holds, and we require the data to tell us otherwise. If we cannot reject (8.11) at a sufficiently small significance level, we usually conclude that heteroskedasticity is not a problem. However, remember that we never accept H0; we simply fail to reject it. Because we are assuming that u has a zero conditional expectation, Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 E(u2􏰫x), and so the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity is equivalent to H0: E(u2􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 E(u2) 􏱪 􏱧2. This shows that, in order to test for violation of the homoskedasticity assumption, we want to test whether u2 is related (in expected value) to one or more of the explanatory variables. If H0 is false, the expected value of u2, given the independent variables, can be virtually any function of the xj. A simple approach is to assume a linear function: u2 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1x1 􏱕􏱛2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱛kxk 􏱕v, [8.12] where v is an error term with mean zero given the xj. Pay close attention to the dependent vari- able in this equation: it is the square of the error in the original regression equation, (8.10). The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity is H0:􏱛1 􏱪􏱛2 􏱪...􏱪􏱛k 􏱪0. [8.13] Under the null hypothesis, it is often reasonable to assume that the error in (8.12), v, is in- dependent of x1, x2, ..., xk. Then, we know from Section 5.2 that either the F or LM statis- tics for the overall significance of the independent variables in explaining u2 can be used to test (8.13). Both statistics would have asymptotic justification, even though u2 cannot Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 277 be normally distributed. (For example, if u is normally distributed, then u2/􏱧2 is distributed as 􏱚21.) If we could observe the u2 in the sample, then we could easily compute this statistic by running the OLS regression of u2 on x1, x2, ..., xk, using all n observations. As we have emphasized before, we never know the actual errors in the population model, but we do have estimates of them: the OLS residual, uˆi, is an estimate of the error ui for observation i. Thus, we can estimate the equation uˆ2 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1x1 􏱕􏱛2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱛kxk 􏱕error [8.14] and compute the F or LM statistics for the joint significance of x1, ..., xk. It turns out that using the OLS residuals in place of the errors does not affect the large sample distribution of the F or LM statistics, although showing this is pretty complicated. The F and LM statistics both depend on the R-squared from regression (8.14); call this R22 to distinguish it from the R-squared in estimating equation (8.10). Then, the F statistic is R22/k F 􏱪 _________uˆ_________, [8.15] (1 􏱦 R22)/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) uˆ uˆ where k is the number of regressors in (8.14); this is the same number of independent variables in (8.10). Computing (8.15) by hand is rarely necessary, because most regression packages automatically compute the F statistic for overall significance of a regression. This F statistic has (approximately) an Fk,n􏱦k􏱦1 distribution under the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity. The LM statistic for heteroskedasticity is just the sample size times the R-squared from (8.14): LM 􏱪 n􏱳R22. [8.16] uˆ Under the null hypothesis, LM is distributed asymptotically as 􏱚2k. This is also very easy to obtain after running regression (8.14). The LM version of the test is typically called the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroske- dasticity (BP test). Breusch and Pagan (1979) suggested a different form of the test that assumes the errors are normally distributed. Koenker (1981) suggested the form of the LM statistic in (8.16), and it is generally preferred due to its greater applicability. We summarize the steps for testing for heteroskedasticity using the BP test: The Breusch-Pagan Test for Heteroskedasticity: 1. Estimate the model (8.10) by OLS, as usual. Obtain the squared OLS residuals, uˆ2 (one for each observation). 2. Run the regression in (8.14). Keep the R-squared from this regression, R22. uˆ 3. Form either the F statistic or the LM statistic and compute the p-value (using the Fk,n􏱦k􏱦1 distribution in the former case and the 􏱚k2 distribution in the latter case). If the p-value is sufficiently small, that is, below the chosen significance level, then we reject the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity. If the BP test results in a small enough p-value, some corrective measure should be taken. One possibility is to just use the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors and test statistics discussed in the previous section. Another possibility is discussed in Section 8.4. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 278 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 8.4 HETEROSKEDASTICITY IN HOUSING PRICE EQUATIONS We use the data in HPRICE1.RAW to test for heteroskedasticity in a simple housing price equation. The estimated equation using the levels of all variables is 􏱾price 􏱪 􏱦21.77 􏱕 .00207 lotsize 􏱕 .123 sqrft 􏱕 13.85 bdrms (29.48) (.00064) (.013) (9.01) [8.17] n 􏱪 88, R2 􏱪 .672. This equation tells us nothing about whether the error in the population model is het- eroskedastic. We need to regress the squared OLS residuals on the independent variables. The R-squared from the regression of uˆ2 on lotsize, sqrft, and bdrms is Rû2 2 􏱪 .1601. With n 􏱪 88 and k 􏱪 3, this produces an F statistic for significance of the independent variables of F 􏱪 [.1601/(1 􏱦 .1601)](84/3) 􏱴 5.34. The associated p-value is .002, which is strong evidence against the null. The LM statistic is 88(.1601) 􏱴 14.09; this gives a p-value 􏱴 .0028 (using the 􏱚23. distribution), giving essentially the same conclusion as the F statistic. This means that the usual standard errors reported in (8.17) are not reliable. In Chapter 6, we mentioned that one benefit of using the logarithmic functional form for the dependent variable is that heteroskedasticity is often reduced. In the current applica- tion, let us put price, lotsize, and sqrft in logarithmic form, so that the elasticities of price, with respect to lotsize and sqrft, are constant. The estimated equation is 􏱾log(price) 􏱪 􏱦1.30 􏱕 .168 log(lotsize) 􏱕 .700 log(sqrft) 􏱕 .037 bdrms (.65) (.038) (.093) (.028) [8.18] n 􏱪 88, R2 􏱪 .643. Regressing the squared OLS residuals from this regression on log(lotsize), log(sqrft), and bdrms gives Rû2 2 􏱪 .0480. Thus, F 􏱪 1.41 ( p-value 􏱪 .245), and LM 􏱪 4.22 ( p-value 􏱪 .239). Therefore, we fail to reject the null hypothesis of homoskedasticity in the model with the logarithmic functional forms. The occurrence of less heteroskedasticity with the dependent variable in logarithmic form has been noticed in many empirical applications. If we suspect that heteroskedasticity depends only upon certain independent variables, we can easily modify the Breusch-Pagan test: we simply regress uˆ2 on whatever independent variables we choose and carry out the appropriate F or LM test. Remember that the appropri- ate degrees of freedom depends upon the number of independent variables in the re- gression with uˆ2 as the dependent variable; the number of independent variables show- ing up in equation (8.10) is irrelevant. If the squared residuals are regressed on only a single independent variable, the test for heteroskedasticity is just the usual t statistic on the variable. A signifi- cant t statistic suggests that heteroske- dasticity is a problem. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 8.2 Consider wage equation (7.11), where you think that the conditional variance of log(wage) does not depend on educ, exper, or tenure. However, you are worried that the variance of log(wage) differs across the four demographic groups of married males, married females, single males, and single females. What regression would you run to test for heteroskedasticity? What are the de- grees of freedom in the F test? CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 279 The White Test for Heteroskedasticity In Chapter 5, we showed that the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics are asymp- totically valid, provided all of the Gauss-Markov assumptions hold. It turns out that the homoskedasticity assumption, Var(u1􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 􏱧2, can be replaced with the weaker as- sumption that the squared error, u2, is uncorrelated with all the independent variables (xj), the squares of the independent variables (x2j ), and all the cross products (xj xh for j 􏱻 h). This observation motivated White (1980) to propose a test for heteroskedasticity that adds the squares and cross products of all the independent variables to equation (8.14). The test is explicitly intended to test for forms of heteroskedasticity that invalidate the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics. When the model contains k 􏱪 3 independent variables, the White test is based on an estimation of uˆ2􏱪􏱛0􏱕􏱛1x1􏱕􏱛2x2􏱕􏱛3x3􏱕􏱛4x21 􏱕􏱛5x2 􏱕􏱛6x23 􏱕 􏱛7 x1x2 􏱕 􏱛8x1x3 􏱕 􏱛9x2x3 􏱕 error. [8.19] Compared with the Breusch-Pagan test, this equation has six more regressors. The White test for heteroskedasticity is the LM statistic for testing that all of the 􏱛j in equation (8.19) are zero, except for the intercept. Thus, nine restrictions are being tested in this case. We can also use an F test of this hypothesis; both tests have asymptotic justification. With only three independent variables in the original model, equation (8.19) has nine independent variables. With six independent variables in the original model, the White regression would generally involve 27 regressors (unless some are redundant). This abun- dance of regressors is a weakness in the pure form of the White test: it uses many degrees of freedom for models with just a moderate number of independent variables. It is possible to obtain a test that is easier to implement than the White test and more conserving on degrees of freedom. To create the test, recall that the difference between the White and Breusch-Pagan tests is that the former includes the squares and cross products of the independent variables. We can preserve the spirit of the White test while conserv- ing on degrees of freedom by using the OLS fitted values in a test for heteroskedasticity. Remember that the fitted values are defined, for each observation i, by yˆi 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2xi2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxik. These are just linear functions of the independent variables. If we square the fitted values, we get a particular function of all the squares and cross products of the independent vari- ables. This suggests testing for heteroskedasticity by estimating the equation uˆ2 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1yˆ 􏱕 􏱛2yˆ2 􏱕 error, [8.20] where yˆ stands for the fitted values. It is important not to confuse yˆ and y in this equation. We use the fitted values because they are functions of the independent variables (and the es- timated parameters); using y in (8.20) does not produce a valid test for heteroskedasticity. We can use the F or LM statistic for the null hypothesis H0: 􏱛1 􏱪 0, 􏱛2 􏱪 0 in equation (8.20). This results in two restrictions in testing the null of homoskedasticity, regardless of the number of independent variables in the original model. Conserving on degrees of free- dom in this way is often a good idea, and it also makes the test easy to implement. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 280 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 1. 2. 3. EXAMPLE 8.5 Estimate the model (8.10) by OLS, as usual. Obtain the OLS residuals uˆ and the fitted values yˆ. Compute the squared OLS residuals uˆ2 and the squared fitted values yˆ2. Runtheregressioninequation(8.20).KeeptheR-squaredfromthisregression,Rû22. Form either the F or LM statistic and compute the p-value (using the F2,n􏱦3 distribu- tion in the former case and the 􏰨2 distribution in the latter case). SPECIAL FORM OF THE WHITE TEST IN THE LOG HOUSING PRICE EQUATION Since yˆ is an estimate of the expected value of y, given the xj, using (8.20) to test for heteroskedasticity is useful in cases where the variance is thought to change with the level of the expected value, E(y􏰫x). The test from (8.20) can be viewed as a special case of the White test, since equation (8.20) can be shown to impose restrictions on the parameters in equation (8.19). A Special Case of the White Test for Heteroskedasticity: We apply the special case of the White test to equation (8.18), where we use the LM form of the statistic. The important thing to remember is that the chi-square distribution always has two df. The regression of uˆ2 on 􏱾lprice, (􏱾lprice)2, where 􏱾lprice denotes the fitted values from (8.18), produces Rû2 2 􏱪 .0392; thus, LM 􏱪 88(.0392) 􏱴 3.45, and the p-value 􏱪 .178. This is stronger evidence of heteroskedasticity than is provided by the Breusch-Pagan test, but we still fail to reject homoskedasticity at even the 15% level. Before leaving this section, we should discuss one important caveat. We have inter- preted a rejection using one of the heteroskedasticity tests as evidence of heteroskedastic- ity. This is appropriate provided we maintain Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.4. But, if MLR.4 is violated—in particular, if the functional form of E(y􏰫x) is misspecified—then a test for heteroskedasticity can reject H0, even if Var(y􏰫x) is constant. For example, if we omit one or more quadratic terms in a regression model or use the level model when we should use the log, a test for heteroskedasticity can be significant. This has led some economists to view tests for heteroskedasticity as general misspecification tests. However, there are better, more direct tests for functional form misspecification, and we will cover some of them in Section 9.1. It is better to use explicit tests for functional form first, since functional form misspecification is more important than heteroskedasticity. Then, once we are satisfied with the functional form, we can test for heteroskedasticity. 8.4 Weighted Least Squares Estimation If heteroskedasticity is detected using one of the tests in Section 8.3, we know from Section 8.2 that one possible response is to use heteroskedasticity-robust statistics after estimation by OLS. Before the development of heteroskedasticity-robust statistics, the response to a finding of heteroskedasticity was to specify its form and use a weighted least squares method, which we develop in this section. As we will argue, if we have correctly specified the form of the variance (as a function of explanatory variables), then weighted least squares (WLS) is more efficient than OLS, and WLS leads to new t and F statistics Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 281 that have t and F distributions. We will also discuss the implications of using the wrong form of the variance in the WLS procedure. The Heteroskedasticity Is Known up to a Multiplicative Constant Let x denote all the explanatory variables in equation (8.10) and assume that Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2h(x), [8.21] where h(x) is some function of the explanatory variables that determines the heteroskedas- ticity. Since variances must be positive, h(x) 􏱰 0 for all possible values of the independent variables. For now, we assume that the function h(x) is known. The population parameter 􏱧2 is unknown, but we will be able to estimate it from a data sample. For a random drawing from the population, we can write 􏱧 2i 􏱪 Var(ui􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱧2h(xi) 􏱪 􏱧2hi, where we again use the notation xi to denote all independent variables for observa- tion i, and hi changes with each observation because the independent variables change across observations. For example, consider the simple savings function savi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inci 􏱕 ui [8.22] Var(ui􏰫inci) 􏱪 􏱧2inci. [8.23] Here, h(x) 􏱪 h(inc) 􏱪 inc: the variance of the error is proportional to the level of income. This means that, as income increases, the variability in savings increases. (If 􏱬1 􏱰 0, the expected value of savings also increases with income.) Because inc is always positive, the variance in equation (8.23) is always guaranteed to be positive. The standard deviation of ___ ui, conditional on inci, is 􏱧􏱯 inci. How can we use the information in equation (8.21) to estimate the 􏱬j? Essentially, we take the original equation, yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 􏱬2xi2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxik 􏱕 ui , [8.24] which contains heteroskedastic errors, and transform it into an equation that has homoske- dastic errors (and satisfies the other Gauss-Markov assumptions). Since h is just a func- __ i tion of x , u /􏱯 h has a zero expected value conditional on x . Further, since Var(u 􏰫x ) 􏱪 iii __ i ii E(u2i 􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱧2hi, the variance of ui /􏱯 h i (conditional on xi) is 􏱧2: __ E 􏱵 (ui /􏱯 hi )2 􏱷 􏱪 E(u2i ) / hi 􏱪 (􏱧2hi) / hi 􏱪 􏱧2, where we have suppressed the conditioning on x for simplicity. We can divide equation (8.24) __ i by 􏱯 hi to get __ __ __ __ yi/􏱯hi 􏱪 􏱬0/􏱯hi 􏱕 􏱬1(xi1/􏱯hi ) 􏱕 􏱬2(xi2/􏱯hi ) 􏱕 ... __ __ [8.25] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱕 􏱬k(xik /􏱯 hi ) 􏱕 (ui /􏱯 hi ) 282 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data or y*i 􏱪􏱬0x*i0􏱕􏱬1x*i1􏱕...􏱕􏱬kx*ik􏱕u*i, [8.26] where x* 􏱪 1/􏱯 h and the other starred variables denote the corresponding original __ i0 i__ variables divided by 􏱯 hi . Equation (8.26) looks a little peculiar, but the important thing to remember is that we derived it so we could obtain estimators of the 􏱬j that have better efficiency properties than OLS. The intercept 􏱬 in the original equation (8.24) is now multiplying the variable x* 􏱪 __0 i0 1/􏱯 hi . Each slope parameter in 􏱬j multiplies a new variable that rarely has a useful inter- pretation. This should not cause problems if we recall that, for interpreting the parameters and the model, we always want to return to the original equation (8.24). In the preceding savings example, the transformed equation looks like ____ ____ ____ savi/􏱯inci 􏱪 􏱬0(1/􏱯inci ) 􏱕 􏱬1􏱯inci 􏱕 u*i , ____ ____ whereweusethefactthatinci/􏱯inci 􏱪􏱯inci.Nevertheless,􏱬1isthemarginalpropensity to save out of income, an interpretation we obtain from equation (8.22). Equation (8.26) is linear in its parameters (so it satisfies MLR.1), and the random sampling assumption has not changed. Further, u*i has a zero mean and a constant vari- ance (􏱧2), conditional on x*i . This means that if the original equation satisfies the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions, then the transformed equation (8.26) satisfies all five Gauss-Markov assumptions. Also, if ui has a normal distribution, then u*i has a normal distribution with variance 􏱧2. Therefore, the transformed equation satisfies the classical linear model assumptions (MLR.1 through MLR.6) if the original model does so except for the homoskedasticity assumption. Since we know that OLS has appealing properties (is BLUE, for example) under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the discussion in the previous paragraph suggests estimat- ing the parameters in equation (8.26) by ordinary least squares. These estimators, 􏱬*0, 􏱬*1,...,􏱬*k,willbedifferentfromtheOLSestimatorsintheoriginalequation.The􏱬*j are examples of generalized least squares (GLS) estimators. In this case, the GLS estima- tors are used to account for heteroskedasticity in the errors. We will encounter other GLS estimators in Chapter 12. Because equation (8.26) satisfies all of the ideal assumptions, standard errors, t statis- tics, and F statistics can all be obtained from regressions using the transformed variables. The sum of squared residuals from (8.26) divided by the degrees of freedom is an unbiased estimator of 􏱧2. Further, the GLS estimators, because they are the best linear unbiased estimators of the 􏱬j, are necessarily more efficient than the OLS estimators 􏱬ˆj obtained from the untransformed equation. Essentially, after we have transformed the variables, we simply use standard OLS analysis. But we must remember to interpret the estimates in light of the original equation. The R-squared that is obtained from estimating (8.26), while useful for computing F statistics, is not especially informative as a goodness-of-fit measure: it tells us how much variation in y* is explained by the x*j , and this is seldom very meaningful. The GLS estimators for correcting heteroskedasticity are called weighted least squares (WLS) estimators. This name comes from the fact that the 􏱬*j minimize the weighted sum of squared residuals, where each squared residual is weighted by 1/hi. The Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 283 idea is that less weight is given to observations with a higher error variance; OLS gives each observation the same weight because it is best when the error variance is identical for all partitions of the population. Mathematically, the WLS estimators are the values of the bj that make ∑n i 0 1i1 2i2 kik i (y􏱦b 􏱦bx 􏱦bx 􏱦...􏱦bx )2/h [8.27] i􏱪1 as small as possible. Bringing the square root of 1/hi inside the squared residual shows that the weighted sum of squared residuals is identical to the sum of squared residuals in the transformed variables: ∑n i 0 i0 1 i1 2 i2 k ik (y*􏱦bx* 􏱦bx* 􏱦bx* 􏱦...􏱦bx*)2. i􏱪1 Since OLS minimizes the sum of squared residuals (regardless of the definitions of the dependent variable and independent variable), it follows that the WLS estimators that min- imize (8.27) are simply the OLS estimators from (8.26). Note carefully that the squared residuals in (8.27) are weighted by 1/h , whereas the transformed variables in (8.26) are __ i weighted by 1/􏱯 hi . A weighted least squares estimator can be defined for any set of positive weights. OLS is the special case that gives equal weight to all observations. The efficient procedure, GLS, weights each squared residual by the inverse of the conditional variance of ui given xi. Obtaining the transformed variables in equation (8.25) in order to manually perform weighted least squares can be tedious, and the chance of making mistakes is nontrivial. Fortunately, most modern regression packages have a feature for computing weighted least squares. Typically, along with the dependent and independent variables in the origi- nal model, we just specify the weighting function, 1/hi, appearing in (8.27). That is, we specify weights proportional to the inverse of the variance. In addition to making mis- takes less likely, this forces us to interpret weighted least squares estimates in the original model. In fact, we can write out the estimated equation in the usual way. The estimates and standard errors will be different from OLS, but the way we interpret those estimates, standard errors, and test statistics is the same. EXAMPLE 8.6 FINANCIAL WEALTH EQUATION We now estimate equations that explain net total financial wealth (nettfa, measured in $1,000s) in terms of income (inc, also measured in $1,000s) and some other variables, including age, gender, and an indicator for whether the person is eligible for a 401(k) pen- sion plan. We use the data on single people ( fsize 􏱪 1) in 401KSUBS.RAW. In Computer Exercise C12 in Chapter 6, it was found that a specific quadratic function in age, namely (age 􏱦 25)2, fit the data just as well as an unrestricted quadratic. Plus, the restricted form gives a simplified intepretation because the minimum age in the sample is 25: nettfa is an increasing function of age after age 􏱪 25. The results are reported in Table 8.1. Because we suspect heteroskedasticity, we report the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for OLS. The weighted least squares estimates, and their standard errors, are obtained under the assumption Var(u􏱍inc) 􏱪 􏱧2inc. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 284 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data T A B L E 8 . 1 Dependent Variable: nettfa Independent (1) (2) (3) (4) Variables OLS WLS OLS WLS inc .821 (.104) .787 (.063) .771 (.100) .740 (.064) (age 􏱦 25)2 — — .0251 (.0043) .0175 (.0019) male — — 2.48 (2.06) 1.84 (1.56) e401k — — 6.89 (2.29) 5.19 (1.70) intercept 􏱦10.57 (2.53) −9.58 (1.65) 􏱦20.98 (3.50) 􏱦16.70 (1.96) Observations 2,017 2,017 2,017 2,017 R-squared .0827 .0709 .1279 .1115 Without controlling for other factors, another dollar of income is estimated to in- crease nettfa by about 82¢ when OLS is used; the WLS estimate is smaller, about 79¢. The difference is not large; we certainly do not expect them to be identical. The WLS coefficient does have a smaller standard error than OLS, almost 40% smaller, provided we assume the model Var(nettfa􏰫inc) 􏱪 􏱧2inc is correct. Adding the other controls reduced the inc coefficient somewhat, with the OLS esti- mate still larger than the WLS estimate. Again, the WLS estimate of 􏱬inc is more precise. Age has an increasing effect starting at age 􏱪 25, with the OLS estimate showing a larger effect. The WLS estimate of 􏱬age is more precise in this case. Gender does not have a statistically significant effect on nettfa, but being eligible for a 401(k) plan does: the OLS estimate is that those eligible, holding fixed income, age, and gender, have net total finan- cial assets about $6,890 higher. The WLS estimate is substantially below the OLS estimate and suggests a misspecification of the functional form in the mean equa- tion. (One possibility is to interact e401k and inc; see Computer Exercise C11.) Using WLS, the F statistic for joint significance of (age 􏱦 25)2, male, and e401k is about 30.8 if we use the R-squareds reported in Table 8.1. With 2 and 2,012 degrees of freedom, the p-value is zero to more than 15 decimal places; of course, this is not surprising given the very large t statistics for the age and 401(k) variables. Assuming that the error variance in the financial wealth equation has a variance propor- tional to income is essentially arbitrary. In fact, in most cases, our choice of weights in WLS has a degree of arbitrariness. However, there is one case where the weights needed for WLS arise naturally from an underlying econometric model. This happens when, instead of using Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 8.3 Using the OLS residuals obtained from the OLS regression reported in column (1) of Table 8.1, the regression of ˆu2 on inc yields a t statistic of 2.96. Does it appear we should worry about heteroskedasticity in the financial wealth equation? © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 285 individual-level data, we only have averages of data across some group or geographic region. For example, suppose we are interested in determining the relationship between the amount a worker contributes to his or her 401(k) pension plan as a function of the plan generosity. Let i denote a particular firm and let e denote an employee within the firm. A simple model is contribi, e 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1earnsi, e 􏱕 􏱬2agei, e 􏱕 􏱬3mratei 􏱕 ui, e, [8.28] where contribi, e is the annual contribution by employee e who works for firm i, earnsi, e is annual earnings for this person, and agei, e is the person’s age. The variable mratei is the amount the firm puts into an employee’s account for every dollar the employee contributes. If (8.28) satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, then we could estimate it, given a sample on individuals across various employers. Suppose, however, that we only have average values of contributions, earnings, and age by employer. In other words, individual- level data are not available. Thus, let 􏰲contribi denote average contribution for people at 􏰲􏰲 firm i, and similarly for earnsi and agei. Let mi denote the number of employees at firm i; we assume that this is a known quantity. Then, if we average equation (8.28) across all employees at firm i, we obtain the firm-level equation 􏰲􏰲􏰲- contribi 􏱪􏱬0􏱕􏱬1earnsi􏱕􏱬2agei􏱕􏱬3mratei􏱕ui, [8.29] where u- i 􏱪 mi􏱦1∑ mi ui, e is the average error across all employees in firm i. If we have e􏱪1 n firms in our sample, then (8.29) is just a standard multiple linear regression model that can be estimated by OLS. The estimators are unbiased if the original model (8.28) satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions and the individual errors ui, e are independent of the firm’s size, mi [because then the expected value of u- i, given the explanatory variables in (8.29), is zero]. If the individual-level equation (8.28) satisfies the homoskedasticity assumption, and the errors within firm i are uncorrelated across employees, then we can show that the firm- level equation (8.29) has a particular kind of heteroskedasticity. Specifically, if Var(ui,e) 􏱪 􏱧2 for all i and e, and Cov(ui,e,ui,g) 􏱪 0 for every pair of employees e 􏱻 g within firm i, then Var(u-i) 􏱪 􏱧2/mi; this is just the usual formula for the variance of an average of uncorrelated random variables with common variance. In other words, the variance of the error term u-i decreases with firm size. In this case, hi 􏱪 1/mi, and so the most efficient procedure is weighted least squares, with weights equal to the number of employees at the firm (1/hi 􏱪 mi). This ensures that larger firms receive more weight. This gives us an efficient way of estimating the parameters in the individual-level model when we only have averages at the firm level. A similar weighting arises when we are using per capita data at the city, county, state, or country level. If the individual-level equation satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, then the error in the per capita equation has a variance proportional to one over the size of the population. Therefore, weighted least squares with weights equal to the population is appropriate. For example, suppose we have city-level data on per capita beer consumption (in ounces), the percentage of people in the population over 21 years old, average adult edu- cation levels, average income levels, and the city price of beer. Then, the city-level model beerpc 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1perc21 􏱕 􏱬2avgeduc 􏱕 􏱬3incpc 􏱕 􏱬4 price 􏱕 u can be estimated by weighted least squares, with the weights being the city population. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 286 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The advantage of weighting by firm size, city population, and so on relies on the underlying individual equation being homoskedastic. If heteroskedasticity exists at the individual level, then the proper weighting depends on the form of heteroskedasticity. Further, if there is correlation across errors within a group (say, firm), then Var(u-i) 􏱻 􏱧2/mi; see Problem 7. Uncertainty about the form of Var(u-i) in equations such as (8.29) is why more and more researchers simply use OLS and compute robust standard errors and test statistics when estimating models using per capita data. An alternative is to weight by group size but to report the heteroskedasticity-robust statistics in the WLS estimation. This ensures that, while the estimation is efficient if the individual-level model satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, heteroskedasticity at the individual level or within-group correlation are accounted for through robust inference. The Heteroskedasticity Function Must Be Estimated: Feasible GLS In the previous subsection, we saw some examples of where the heteroskedasticity is known up to a multiplicative form. In most cases, the exact form of heteroskedasticity is not obvious. In other words, it is difficult to find the function h(xi) of the previous section. Nevertheless, in many cases we can model the function h and use the data to estimate the unknown parameters in this model. This results in an estimate of each hi, denoted as hˆi. Using hˆi instead of hi in the GLS transformation yields an estimator called the feasible GLS (FGLS) estimator. Feasible GLS is sometimes called estimated GLS, or EGLS. There are many ways to model heteroskedasticity, but we will study one particular, fairly flexible approach. Assume that Var(u􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2exp(􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1x1 􏱕 􏱛2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛kxk), [8.30] where x1, x2, ..., xk are the independent variables appearing in the regression model [see equation (8.1)], and the 􏱛j are unknown parameters. Other functions of the xj can appear, but we will focus primarily on (8.30). In the notation of the previous subsection, h(x) 􏱪 exp(􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1x1 􏱕 􏱛2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛kxk). You may wonder why we have used the exponential function in (8.30). After all, when testing for heteroskedasticity using the Breusch-Pagan test, we assumed that het- eroskedasticity was a linear function of the xj. Linear alternatives such as (8.12) are fine when testing for heteroskedasticity, but they can be problematic when correcting for het- eroskedasticity using weighted least squares. We have encountered the reason for this problem before: linear models do not ensure that predicted values are positive, and our estimated variances must be positive in order to perform WLS. If the parameters 􏱛j were known, then we would just apply WLS, as in the previous subsection. This is not very realistic. It is better to use the data to estimate these param- eters, and then to use these estimates to construct weights. How can we estimate the 􏱛j? Essentially, we will transform this equation into a linear form that, with slight modifica- tion, can be estimated by OLS. Under assumption (8.30), we can write u2 􏱪 􏱧2exp(􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1x1 􏱕 􏱛2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛kxk)v, where v has a mean equal to unity, conditional on x 􏱪 (x1, x2, ..., xk). If we assume that v is actually independent of x, we can write Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 287 log(u2)􏱪a0 􏱕􏱛1x1􏱕􏱛2x2􏱕...􏱕􏱛kxk􏱕e, [8.31] where e has a zero mean and is independent of x; the intercept in this equation is different from 􏱛0, but this is not important in implementing WLS. The dependent variable is the log of the squared error. Since (8.31) satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, we can get unbiased estimators of the 􏱛j by using OLS. As usual, we must replace the unobserved u with the OLS residuals. Therefore, we run the regression of log(uˆ2) on x1, x2, ..., xk. [8.32] Actually, what we need from this regression are the fitted values; call these gˆi. Then, the the steps. estimates of hi are simply We now use WLS with weights 1/hˆi in place of 1/hi in equation (8.27). We summarize hˆi 􏱪 exp(gˆi). [8.33] A Feasible GLS Procedure to Correct for Heteroskedasticity: 1. Run the regression of y on x1, x2, ..., xk and obtain the residuals, uˆ. 2. Create log(uˆ2) by first squaring the OLS residuals and then taking the natural log. 3. Run the regression in equation (8.32) and obtain the fitted values, gˆ. 4. Exponentiate the fitted values from (8.32): hˆ 􏱪 exp(gˆ). 5. Estimate the equation y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk 􏱕 u by WLS, using weights 1/hˆ. In other words, we replace hi with hˆi in equation (8.27). Remember, the squared residual for observation i gets weighted by 1/hˆ . If instead i __ we first transform all variables and run OLS, each variable gets multiplied by 1/􏱯hˆi, including the intercept. If we could use hi rather than hˆi in the WLS procedure, we know that our estimators would be unbiased; in fact, they would be the best linear unbiased estimators, assum- ing that we have properly modeled the heteroskedasticity. Having to estimate hi using the same data means that the FGLS estimator is no longer unbiased (so it cannot be BLUE, either). Nevertheless, the FGLS estimator is consistent and asymptotically more efficient than OLS. This is difficult to show because of estimation of the variance parameters. But if we ignore this—as it turns out we may—the proof is similar to showing that OLS is efficient in the class of estimators in Theorem 5.3. At any rate, for large sample sizes, FGLS is an attractive alternative to OLS when there is evidence of heteroskedasticity that inflates the standard errors of the OLS estimates. We must remember that the FGLS estimators are estimators of the parameters in the usual population model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk 􏱕 u. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 288 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Just as the OLS estimates measure the marginal impact of each xj on y, so do the FGLS estimates. We use the FGLS estimates in place of the OLS estimates because the FGLS estimators are more efficient and have associated test statistics with the usual t and F dis- tributions, at least in large samples. If we have some doubt about the variance specified in equation (8.30), we can use heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors and test statistics in the transformed equation. Another useful alternative for estimating hi is to replace the independent variables in regression (8.32) with the OLS fitted values and their squares. In other words, obtain the gˆi as the fitted values from the regression of log(uˆ2) on yˆ, yˆ2 [8.34] and then obtain the hˆi exactly as in equation (8.33). This changes only step (3) in the previ- ous procedure. If we use regression (8.32) to estimate the variance function, you may be wondering if we can simply test for heteroskedasticity using this same regression (an F or LM test can be used). In fact, Park (1966) suggested this. Unfortunately, when compared with the tests discussed in Section 8.3, the Park test has some problems. First, the null hypothesis must be something stronger than homoskedasticity: effectively, u and x must be independent. This is not required in the Breusch-Pagan or White tests. Second, using the OLS residuals uˆ in place of u in (8.32) can cause the F statistic to deviate from the F distribution, even in large sample sizes. This is not an issue in the other tests we have covered. For these reasons, the Park test is not recommended when testing for heteroskedasticity. Regression (8.32) works well for weighted least squares because we only need consistent estimators of the 􏱛j, and regression (8.32) certainly delivers those. EXAMPLE 8.7 DEMAND FOR CIGARETTES We use the data in SMOKE.RAW to estimate a demand function for daily cigarette con- sumption. Since most people do not smoke, the dependent variable, cigs, is zero for most observations. A linear model is not ideal because it can result in negative predicted values. Nevertheless, we can still learn something about the determinants of cigarette smoking by using a linear model. The equation estimated by ordinary least squares, with the usual OLS standard errors in parentheses, is where 􏱾cigs 􏱪 􏱦3.64 􏱕 .880 log(income) 􏱦 .751 log(cigpric) (24.08) (.728) (5.773) 􏱦 .501 educ 􏱕 .771 age 􏱦 .0090 age2 􏱦 2.83 restaurn (.167) (.160) (.0017) (1.11) n 􏱪 807, R2 􏱪 .0526, [8.35] cigs 􏱪 number of cigarettes smoked per day. income 􏱪 annual income. cigpric 􏱪 the per-pack price of cigarettes (in cents). educ 􏱪 years of schooling. age 􏱪 measured in years. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 289 restaurn 􏱪 a binary indicator equal to unity if the person resides in a state with restaurant smoking restrictions. Since we are also going to do weighted least squares, we do not report the heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors for OLS. (Incidentally, 13 out of the 807 fitted values are less than zero; this is less than 2% of the sample and is not a major cause for concern.) Neither income nor cigarette price is statistically significant in (8.35), and their ef- fects are not practically large. For example, if income increases by 10%, cigs is predicted to increase by (.880/100)(10) 􏱪 .088, or less than one-tenth of a cigarette per day. The magnitude of the price effect is similar. Each year of education reduces the average cigarettes smoked per day by one-half of a cigarette, and the effect is statistically significant. Cigarette smoking is also related to age, in a quadratic fashion. Smoking increases with age up until age 􏱪 .771/[2(.009)] 􏱴 42.83, and then smoking decreases with age. Both terms in the quadratic are statistically significant. The presence of a restriction on smoking in restaurants decreases cigarette smoking by almost three cigarettes per day, on average. Do the errors underlying equation (8.35) contain heteroskedasticity? The Breusch- Pagan regression of the squared OLS residuals on the independent variables in (8.35) [see equation (8.14)] produces Rû2 2 􏱪 .040. This small R-squared may seem to indicate no heteroskedasticity, but we must remember to compute either the F or LM statistic. If the sample size is large, a seemingly small Rû2 2 can result in a very strong rejection of ho- moskedasticity. The LM statistic is LM 􏱪 807(.040) 􏱪 32.28, and this is the outcome of a 􏱚26 random variable. The p-value is less than .000015, which is very strong evidence of heteroskedasticity. Therefore, we estimate the equation using the feasible GLS procedure based on equation (8.32). The weighted least squares estimates are 􏱾cigs􏱪 5.64 􏱕 1.30 log(income) 􏱦 2.94 log(cigpric) (17.80) (.44) (4.46) 􏱦 .463 educ 􏱕 .482 age 􏱦 .0056 age2 􏱦 3.46 restaurn (.120) (.097) (.0009) (.80) n 􏱪 807, R2 􏱪 .1134. [8.36] The income effect is now statistically significant and larger in magnitude. The price effect is also notably bigger, but it is still statistically insignificant. [One reason for this is that cigpric varies only across states in the sample, and so there is much less variation in log(cigpric) than in log(income), educ, and age.] The estimates on the other variables have, naturally, changed somewhat, but the basic story is still the same. Cigarette smoking is negatively related to schooling, has a quadratic relationship with age, and is negatively affected by restaurant smoking restrictions. We must be a little careful in computing F statistics for testing multiple hypotheses after estimation by WLS. (This is true whether the sum of squared residuals or R-squared form of the F statistic is used.) It is important that the same weights be used to estimate the unrestricted and restricted models. We should first estimate the unrestricted model by OLS. Once we have obtained the weights, we can use them to estimate the restricted Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 290 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data model as well. The F statistic can be computed as usual. Fortunately, many regression packages have a simple command for testing joint restrictions after WLS estimation, so we need not perform the restricted regression ourselves. Example 8.7 hints at an issue that sometimes arises in applications of weighted least squares: the OLS and WLS estimates can be substantially different. This is not such a big problem in the demand for cigarettes equation because all the coefficients maintain the same signs, and the biggest changes are on variables that were statistically insig- nificant when the equation was estimated by OLS. The OLS and WLS estimates will always differ due to sampling error. The issue is whether their difference is enough to change important conclusions. If OLS and WLS produce statistically significant estimates that differ in sign—for example, the OLS price elasticity is posi- tive and significant, while the WLS price elasticity is negative and significant—or the difference in magnitudes of the esti- mates is practically large, we should be sus- picious. Typically, this indicates that one of the other Gauss-Markov assumptions is false, particularly the zero conditional mean assumption on the error (MLR.4). If E(y􏰫x)􏲅􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk,thenOLS and WLS have different expected values and probability limits. For WLS to be con- sistent for the 􏱬j, it is not enough for u to be uncorrelated with each xj; we need the stronger as- sumption MLR.4 in the linear model MLR.1. Therefore, a significant difference between OLS and WLS can indicate a functional form misspecification in E(y􏰫x). The Hausman test [Haus- man (1978)] can be used to formally compare the OLS and WLS estimates to see if they differ by more than sampling error suggests they should, but this test is beyond the scope of this text. In many cases, an informal “eyeballing” of the estimates is sufficient to detect a problem. What If the Assumed Heteroskedasticity Function Is Wrong? We just noted that if OLS and WLS produce very different estimates, it is likely that the con- ditional mean E(y􏰫x) is misspecified. What are the properties of WLS if the variance func- tion we use is misspecified in the sense that Var(y􏰫x) 􏱻 􏱧2h(x) for our chosen function h(x)? The most important issue is whether misspecification of h(x) causes bias or inconsistency in the WLS estimator. Fortunately, the answer is no, at least under MLR.4. Recall that, if is uncorrelated with the weighted regressors, xj/􏱯h(x), for any function h(x) that is always positive. This is why, as we just discussed, we can take large differences between the OLS and WLS estimators as indicative of functional form misspecification. If we estimate pa- rameters in the function, say h(x, 􏱛ˆ), then we can no longer claim that WLS is unbiased, but it will generally be consistent (whether or not the variance function is correctly specified). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 8.4 Let ˆui be the WLS residuals from (8.36), which are not weighted, and let 􏱾cigsi be the fitted values. (These are obtained using the same formulas as OLS; they differ because of different estimates of the 􏱬j.) One way to determine whether heteroskedasticity has been eliminated is to use the uˆi2/hi 􏱪 (uˆi /􏱯hi ) in a test for heteroskedasticity. [If hi 􏱪 Var(ui􏰫xi), then the transformed residuals should have little evidence of heteroske- dasticity.] There are many possibilities, but one—based on White’s test in the trans- ˆ􏱾 fo_r_med equation—is to regress uˆ2i /hi on cigsi/ 􏱯 hˆ i and 􏱾cigsi2/hˆ i (including an intercept). The joint F statistic when we use SMOKE. RAW is 11.15. Does it appear that our cor- rection for heteroskedasticity has actually eliminated the heteroskedasticity? __ ˆˆ2 E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0, then any function of x is uncorrelated with u, and so the weighted error, u/􏱯h(x), ____ ____ CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 291 If WLS is at least consistent under MLR.1 to MLR.4, what are the consequences of using WLS with a misspecified variance function? There are two. The first, which is very important, is that the usual WLS standard errors and test statistics, computed under the assumption that Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2h(x), are no longer valid, even in large samples. For example, the WLS estimates and standard errors in column (4) of Table 8.1 assume that Var(nettfa􏰫inc, age, male, e401k) 􏱪 Var(nettfa􏰫inc) 􏱪 􏱧2inc; so we are assuming not only that the variance depends just on income, but also that it is a linear function of income. If this assumption is false, the standard errors (and any statistics we obtain using those stan- dard errors) are not valid. Fortunately, there is an easy fix: just as we can obtain standard errors for the OLS estimates that are robust to arbitrary heteroskedasticity, we can obtain standard errors for WLS that allow the variance function to be arbitrarily misspecified. It is easy to see why this works. Write the transformed equation as __ __ __ __ __ yi/􏱯hi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱹1/􏱯hi 􏱺 􏱕 􏱬1􏱹xi1/􏱯hi 􏱺 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k􏱹xik/􏱯hi 􏱺 􏱕 ui/􏱯hi . 2 __ Now, if Var(ui􏰫xi) 􏱻 􏱧 hi, then the weighted error ui/􏱯hi is heteroskedastic. So we can just apply the usual heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors after estimating this equation by OLS—which, remember, is identical to WLS. To see how robust inference with WLS works in practice, column (1) of Table 8.2 reproduces the last column of Table 8.1, and column (2) contains standard errors robust to Var(ui􏰫xi) 􏱻 􏱧2inci. The standard errors in column (2) allow the variance function to be misspecified. We see that, for the income and age variables, the robust standard errors are somewhat above the usual WLS standard errors—certainly by enough to stretch the confidence intervals. On the other hand, the robust standard errors for male and e401k are actually smaller than those that assume a correct variance function. We saw this could happen with the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for OLS, too. Even if we use flexible forms of variance functions, such as that in (8.30), there is no guarantee that we have the correct model. While exponential heteroskedasticity is T A B L E 8 . 2 WLS Estimation of the nettfa Equation Independent With Nonrobust With Robust Variables Standard Errors Standard Errors inc .740 (.064) .740 (.075) (age 􏱦 25)2 .0175 (.0019) .0175 (.0026) male 1.84 (1.56) 1.84 (1.31) e401k 5.19 (1.70) 5.19 (1.57) intercept 􏱦16.70 (1.96) 􏱦16.70 (2.24) Observations 2,017 2,017 R-squared .1115 .1115 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 292 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data appealing and reasonably flexible, it is, after all, just a model. Therefore, it is always a good idea to compute fully robust standard errors and test statistics after WLS estimation. A modern criticism of WLS is that if the variance function is misspecified, it is not guaranteed to be more efficient than OLS. In fact, that is the case: if Var(y􏰫x) is neither con- stant nor equal to 􏱧2h(x), where h(x) is the proposed model of heteroskedasticity, then we cannot rank OLS and WLS in terms of variances (or asymptotic variances when the vari- ance parameters must be estimated). However, this theoretically correct criticism misses an important practical point. Namely, in cases of strong heteroskedasticity, it is often better to use a wrong form of heteroskedasticity and apply WLS than to ignore heteroskedasticity altogether in estimation and use OLS. Models such as (8.30) can well approximate a vari- ety of heteroskedasticity functions and may produce estimators with smaller (asymptotic) variances. Even in Example 8.6, where the form of heteroskedasticity was assumed to have the simple form Var(nettfa􏰫x) 􏲁 􏱧2inc, the fully robust standard errors for WLS are well below the fully robust standard errors for OLS. (Comparing robust standard errors for the two estimators puts them on equal footing: we assume neither homoskedasticity nor that the variance has the form 􏱧2inc.) For example, the robust standard error for the WLS estimator of 􏱬inc is about .075, which is 25% lower than the robust standard error for OLS (about .100). For the coefficient on (age – 25)2, the robust standard error of WLS is about .0026, almost 40% below the robust standard error for OLS (about .0043). Prediction and Prediction Intervals with Heteroskedasticity If we start with the standard linear model under MLR.1 to MLR.4, but allow for heteroskedasticity of the form Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2h(x) [see equation (8.21)], the presence of heteroskedasticity affects the point prediction of y only insofar as it affects estimation of the 􏱬j. Of course, it is natural to use WLS on a sample of size n to obtain the 􏱬ˆj. Our prediction of an unobserved outcome, y0, given known values of the explanatory variables x0, has the same form as in Section 6.4: yˆ0 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x0􏱮ˆ. This makes sense: once we know E(y|x), we base our prediction on it; the structure of Var(y|x) plays no direct role. On the other hand, prediction intervals do depend directly on the nature of Var(y􏰫x). Recall in Section 6.4 that we constructed a prediction interval under the classical linear model assumptions. Suppose now that all the CLM assumptions hold except that (8.21) replaces the homoskedasticity assumption, MLR.5. We know that the WLS estimators are BLUE and, because of normality, have (conditional) normal distributions. We can obtain se(yˆ0) using the same method in Section 6.4, except that now we use WLS. [A simple ap- p r o a c h i s t o w r i t e y i 􏱪 􏰩 0 􏱕 􏱬 1 ( x i 1 − x 10 ) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬 k ( x i k 􏱦 x k0 ) 􏱕 u i , w h e r e t h e x j 0 a r e t h e values of the explanatory variables for which we want a predicted value of y. We can estimate this equation by WLS and then obtain yˆ0 􏱪 􏰩ˆ0 and se(yˆ0) 􏱪 se(􏰩ˆ0).] We also need to estimate the standard deviation of u0, the unobserved part of y0. But Var(u0􏰫x 􏱪 x0) 􏱪 _____ 􏱧2h(x0), and so se(u0) 􏱪 􏱧ˆ􏱯h(x0), where 􏱧ˆ is the standard error of the regression from the WLS estimation. Therefore, a 95% prediction interval is yˆ0 􏲁 t.025 􏱳 se(eˆ0) [8.37] where se(eˆ0) 􏲁 {[se(yˆ0)]2 􏱕 􏱧ˆ2h(x0)}1/2. This interval is exact only if we do not have to estimate the variance function. If we estimate parameters, as in model (8.30), then we cannot obtain an exact interval. In fact, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 293 accounting for the estimation error in the 􏱬ˆj and the 􏱛ˆj (the variance parameters) becomes very difficult. We saw two examples in Section 6.4 where the estimation error in the pa- rameters was swamped by the variation in the unobservables, u0. Therefore, we might still use equation (8.37) with h(x0) simply replaced by hˆ(x0). In fact, if we are to ignore the parameter estimation error entirely, we can drop se(yˆ0) from se(eˆ0). [Remember, se(yˆ0) __ converges to zero at the rate 1/􏱯 n, while se(uˆ0) is roughly constant.] We can also obtain a prediction for y in the model log(y)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk􏱕u, [8.38] where u is heteroskedastic. We assume that u has a conditional normal distribution with a specific form of heteroskedasticity. We assume the exponential form in equation (8.30), but add the normality assumption: u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk 􏱷 Normal[0, exp(􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛kxk)]. [8.39] As a notational shorthand, write the variance function as exp(􏱛0 􏱕 x􏱛). Then, because log(y) given x has a normal distribution with mean 􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱮 and variance exp(􏱛0 􏱕 x􏰬), it follows that E(y|x) 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱮 􏱕 􏱧2 exp(􏱛0 􏱕 x􏰬)/2). [8.40] Now we estimate the 􏱬j and dj using WLS estimation of (8.38). That is, after OLS to obtain the residuals, run the regression in (8.32) to obtain fitted values, gˆi 􏱪 􏱮ˆ0 􏱕 􏱛ˆ1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛ˆkxik, [8.41] and then the hˆi as in (8.33). Using these hˆi, obtain the WLS estimates, 􏱬ˆj and also 􏱧ˆ2. Then, for each i, we can obtain a fitted value yˆ 􏱪 exp(􏱾logy 􏱕 􏱧ˆ hˆ / 2). [8.42] We can use these fitted values to obtain an R-squared measure, as described in Section 6.4: use the squared correlation coefficient between yi and yˆi. iii For any values of the explanatory variables x0, we can estimate E(y􏰫x 􏱪 x0) as Eˆ(y􏰫x 􏱪 x0) 􏱪 exp(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x0􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏱧ˆ2 exp(􏱮ˆ0 􏱕 x0􏰬ˆ)/2), where 􏱬ˆj 􏱪 the WLS estimates. 􏱮ˆ0 􏱪 the intercept in (8.41). 􏱛ˆj 􏱪 the slopes from the same regression. [8.43] Obtaining a proper standard error for the prediction in (8.42) is very complicated ana- lytically, but, as in Section 6.4, it would be fairly easy to obtain a standard error using a resampling method such as the bootstrap described in Appendix 6A. Obtaining a prediction interval is more of a challenge when we estimate a model for heteroskedasticity, and a full treatment is complicated. Nevertheless, we saw in Section 6.4 two examples where the error variance swamps the estimation error, and we would make only a small mistake by ignoring the estimation error in all parameters. Using arguments similar to those in Section 6.4, an approximate 95% prediction interval (for large sample Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 2 294 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data _____ _____ s i z e s ) i s e x p [ 􏱶 1 . 9 6 􏱳 􏱧ˆ 􏱯 hˆ ( x 0 ) ] e x p ( 􏱬ˆ 0 􏱕 x 0 􏱮ˆ ) t o e x p [ 1 . 9 6 􏱳 􏱧ˆ 􏱯 hˆ ( x 0 ) ] e x p ( 􏱬ˆ 0 􏱕 x 0 􏱮ˆ ) , w h e r e hˆ(x0) is the estimated variance function evaluated at x0, hˆ(x0) 􏱪 exp(􏱮ˆ0 􏱕 􏱛ˆ1x10 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛ˆkxk0). As in Section 6.4, we obtain this approximate interval by simply exponentiating the endpoints. 8.5 The Linear Probability Model Revisited As we saw in Section 7.5, when the dependent variable y is a binary variable, the model must contain heteroskedasticity, unless all of the slope parameters are zero. We are now in a position to deal with this problem. The simplest way to deal with heteroskedasticity in the linear probability model is to continue to use OLS estimation, but to also compute robust standard errors in test sta- tistics. This ignores the fact that we actually know the form of heteroskedasticity for the LPM. Nevertheless, OLS estimation of the LPM is simple and often produces satisfactory results. EXAMPLE 8.8 LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION OF MARRIED WOMEN In the labor force participation example in Section 7.5 [see equation (7.29)], we reported the usual OLS standard errors. Now, we compute the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors as well. These are reported in brackets below the usual standard errors: 􏱾inlf 􏱪 .586 􏱦 .0034 nwifeinc 􏱕 .038 educ 􏱕 .039 exper (.154) (.0014) (.007) (.006) [.151] [.0015] [.007] [.006] 􏱶 .00060 exper2 􏱦 .016 age 􏱦 .262 kidslt6 􏱕 .0130 kidsge6 (.00018) (.002) (.034) (.0132) [.00019] [.002] [.032] [.0135] n 􏱪 753, R2 􏱪 .264. [8.44] Several of the robust and OLS standard errors are the same to the reported degree of preci- sion; in all cases, the differences are practically very small. Therefore, while heteroskedas- ticity is a problem in theory, it is not in practice, at least not for this example. It often turns out that the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics are similar to their heteroskedas- ticity-robust counterparts. Furthermore, it requires a minimal effort to compute both. Generally, the OLS estimators are inefficient in the LPM. Recall that the conditional variance of y in the LPM is where Var( y􏰫x) 􏱪 p(x)[1 􏱦 p(x)], [8.45] p(x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk [8.46] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 1. 2. 3. 4. EXAMPLE 8.9 Estimate the model by OLS and obtain the fitted values, yˆ. Determine whether all of the fitted values are inside the unit interval. If so, proceed to step (3). If not, some adjustment is needed to bring all fitted values into the unit interval. Construct the estimated variances in equation (8.47). Estimate the equation y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk 􏱕 u by WLS, using weights 1/hˆ. DETERMINANTS OF PERSONAL COMPUTER OWNERSHIP CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 295 is the response probability (probability of success, y 􏱪 1). It seems natural to use weighted least squares, but there are a couple of hitches. The probability p(x) clearly depends on the unknown population parameters, 􏱬j. Nevertheless, we do have unbiased estimators of these parameters, namely the OLS estimators. When the OLS estimators are plugged into equation (8.46), we obtain the OLS fitted values. Thus, for each observation i, Var(yi􏰫xi) is estimated by hˆi 􏱪 yˆi(1 􏱦 yˆi), [8.47] where yˆi is the OLS fitted value for observation i. Now, we apply feasible GLS, just as in Section 8.4. Unfortunately, being able to estimate hi for each i does not mean that we can proceed directly with WLS estimation. The problem is one that we briefly discussed in Section 7.5: the fitted values yˆi need not fall in the unit interval. If either yˆi 􏱷 0 or yˆi 􏱰 1, equation (8.47) shows that hˆ will be negative. Since WLS proceeds by multiplying observation i by __ i 1/􏱯hˆi, the method will fail if hˆi is negative (or zero) for any observation. In other words, all of the weights for WLS must be positive. In some cases, 0 􏱷 yˆi 􏱷 1 for all i, in which case WLS can be used to estimate the LPM. In cases with many observations and small probabilities of success or failure, it is very common to find some fitted values outside the unit interval. If this happens, as it does in the labor force participation example in equation (8.44), it is easiest to abandon WLS and to report the heteroskedasticity-robust statistics. An alternative is to adjust those fitted values that are less than zero or greater than unity, and then to apply WLS. One suggestion is to set yˆi 􏱪 .01 if yˆi 􏱷 0 and yˆi 􏱪 .99 if yˆi 􏱰 1. Unfortunately, this requires an arbitrary choice on the part of the researcher—for example, why not use .001 and .999 as the ad- justed values? If many fitted values are outside the unit interval, the adjustment to the fit- ted values can affect the results; in this situation, it is probably best to just use OLS. Estimating the Linear Probability Model by Weighted Least Squares: We use the data in GPA1.RAW to estimate the probability of owning a computer. Let PC denote a binary indicator equal to unity if the student owns a computer, and zero other- wise. The variable hsGPA is high school GPA, ACT is achievement test score, and parcoll is a binary indicator equal to unity if at least one parent attended college. (Separate college indicators for the mother and the father do not yield individually significant results, as these are pretty highly correlated.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 296 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The equation estimated by OLS is PC 􏱪 􏱦.0004 􏱕 .065 hsGPA 􏱕 .0006 ACT 􏱕 .221 parcoll (.4905) (.137) (.0155) (.093) [.4888] [.139] [.0158] [.087] n 􏱪 141, R2 􏱪 .0415. 􏱾 Just as with Example 8.8, there are no striking differences between the usual and robust standard errors. Nevertheless, we also estimate the model by WLS. Because all of the OLS fitted values are inside the unit interval, no adjustments are needed: 􏱾PC 􏱪 .026 􏱕 .033 hsGPA 􏱕 .0043 ACT 􏱕 .215 parcoll (.477) (.130) (.0155) (.086) [8.49] n 􏱪 141, R2 􏱪 .0464. There are no important differences in the OLS and WLS estimates. The only significant explanatory variable is parcoll, and in both cases we estimate that the probability of PC ownership is about .22 higher if at least one parent attended college. Summary We began by reviewing the properties of ordinary least squares in the presence of heteroske- dasticity. Heteroskedasticity does not cause bias or inconsistency in the OLS estimators, but the usual standard errors and test statistics are no longer valid. We showed how to compute heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors and t statistics, something that is routinely done by many regression packages. Most regression packages also compute a heteroskedasticity- robust F-type statistic. We discussed two common ways to test for heteroskedasticity: the Breusch-Pagan test and a special case of the White test. Both of these statistics involve regressing the squared OLS residuals on either the independent variables (BP) or the fitted and squared fitted values (White). A simple F test is asymptotically valid; there are also Lagrange multiplier versions of the tests. OLS is no longer the best linear unbiased estimator in the presence of heteroskedasticity. When the form of heteroskedasticity is known, generalized least squares (GLS) estimation can be used. This leads to weighted least squares as a means of obtaining the BLUE estimator. The test statistics from the WLS estimation are either exactly valid when the error term is normally distributed or asymptotically valid under nonnormality. This assumes, of course, that we have the proper model of heteroskedasticity. More commonly, we must estimate a model for the heteroskedasticity before applying WLS. The resulting feasible GLS estimator is no longer unbiased, but it is consistent and as- ymptotically efficient. The usual statistics from the WLS regression are asymptotically valid. We discussed a method to ensure that the estimated variances are strictly positive for all obser- vations, something needed to apply WLS. As we discussed in Chapter 7, the linear probability model for a binary dependent vari- able necessarily has a heteroskedastic error term. A simple way to deal with this problem is to compute heteroskedasticity-robust statistics. Alternatively, if all the fitted values (that is, the estimated probabilities) are strictly between zero and one, weighted least squares can be used to obtain asymptotically efficient estimators. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. [8.48] Key Terms Breusch-Pagan Test for Heteroskedasticity (BP Test) Feasible GLS (FGLS) Estimator Generalized Least Squares (GLS) Estimators Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Heteroskedasticity-Robust F Statistic Heteroskedasticity-Robust LM Statistic Heteroskedasticity-Robust Standard Error Heteroskedasticity-Robust t Statistic Weighted Least Squares (WLS) Estimators White Test for Heteroskedasticity CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 297 Problems 1 Which of the following are consequences of heteroskedasticity? (i) The OLS estimators, 􏱬ˆj, are inconsistent. (ii) The usual F statistic no longer has an F distribution. (iii) The OLS estimators are no longer BLUE. 2 Consider a linear model to explain monthly beer consumption: beer 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2 price 􏱕 􏱬3educ 􏱕 􏱬4 female 􏱕 u E(u􏰫inc, price, educ, female) 􏱪 0 Var(u􏰫inc, price, educ, female) 􏱪 􏱧2inc2. Write the transformed equation that has a homoskedastic error term. 3 True or False: WLS is preferred to OLS when an important variable has been omitted from the model. 4 Using the data in GPA3.RAW, the following equation was estimated for the fall and second semester students: 􏱾trmgpa􏱪 􏱦2.12 􏱕 .900 crsgpa 􏱕 .193 cumgpa 􏱕 .0014 tothrs (.55) (.175) (.064) (.0012) [.55] [.166] [.074] [.0012] 􏱕 .0018 sat 􏱦 .0039 hsperc 􏱕 .351 female 􏱦 .157 season (.0002) (.0018) (.085) (.098) [.0002] [.0019] [.079] [.080] n 􏱪 269, R2 􏱪 .465. Here, trmgpa is term GPA, crsgpa is a weighted average of overall GPA in courses taken, cumgpa is GPA prior to the current semester, tothrs is total credit hours prior to the semester, sat is SAT score, hsperc is graduating percentile in high school class, female is a gender dummy, and season is a dummy variable equal to unity if the student’s sport is in season during the fall. The usual and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are reported in parentheses and brackets, respectively. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 298 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (i) Do the variables crsgpa, cumgpa, and tothrs have the expected estimated effects? Which of these variables are statistically significant at the 5% level? Does it matter which standard errors are used? (ii) Why does the hypothesis H0: 􏱬crsgpa 􏱪 1 make sense? Test this hypothesis against the two-sided alternative at the 5% level, using both standard errors. Describe your conclusions. (iii) Test whether there is an in-season effect on term GPA, using both standard errors. Does the significance level at which the null can be rejected depend on the standard error used? 5 The variable smokes is a binary variable equal to one if a person smokes, and zero oth- erwise. Using the data in SMOKE.RAW, we estimate a linear probability model for smokes: 􏱾smokes􏱪 .656 􏱦 .069 log(cigpric) 􏱕 .012 log(income) 􏱦 .029 educ (.855) (.204) (.026) (.006) [.856] [.207] [.026] [.006] 􏱕 .020 age 􏱦 .00026 age2 􏱦 .101 restaurn 􏱦 .026 white (.006) (.00006) (.039) (.052) [.005] [.00006] [.038] [.050] n 􏱪 807, R2 􏱪 .062. The variable white equals one if the respondent is white, and zero otherwise; the other in- dependent variables are defined in Example 8.7. Both the usual and heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors are reported. (i) Are there any important differences between the two sets of standard errors? (ii) Holding other factors fixed, if education increases by four years, what happens to the estimated probability of smoking? (iii) At what point does another year of age reduce the probability of smoking? (iv) Interpret the coefficient on the binary variable restaurn (a dummy variable equal to one if the person lives in a state with restaurant smoking restrictions). (v) Person number 206 in the data set has the following characteristics: cigpric 􏱪 67.44, income 􏱪 6,500, educ 􏱪 16, age 􏱪 77, restaurn 􏱪 0, white 􏱪 0, and smokes 􏱪 0. Compute the predicted probability of smoking for this person and comment on the result. 6 There are different ways to combine features of the Breusch-Pagan and White tests for heteroskedasticity. One possibility not covered in the text is to run the regression uˆi2 on xi1, xi2, ..., xik, yˆi2, i 􏱪 1, ..., n, where the uˆi are the OLS residuals and the yˆi are the OLS fitted values. Then, we would test joint significance of xi1, xi2, ..., xik and yˆi2. (Of course, we always include an intercept in this regression.) (i) What are the df associated with the proposed F test for heteroskedasticity? (ii) Explain why the R-squared from the regression above will always be at least as large as the R-squareds for the BP regression and the special case of the White test. (iii) Does part (ii) imply that the new test always delivers a smaller p-value than either the BP or special case of the White statistic? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 299 (iv) Suppose someone suggests also adding yˆi to the newly proposed test. What do you think of this idea? 7 Consider a model at the employee level, yi,e 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi,e,1 􏱕 􏱬2xi,e,2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxi,e,k 􏱕 fi 􏱕 vi,e, where the unobserved variable fi is a “firm effect” to each employee at a given firm i. The error term vi,e is specific to employee e at firm i. The composite error is ui,e 􏱪 fi 􏱕 vi,e, such as in equation (8.28). (i) Assume that Var(fi) 􏱪 􏱧f2, Var(vi,e) 􏱪 􏱧v2, and fi and vi,e are uncorrelated. Show that Var(ui,e) 􏱪 􏱧f2 􏱕 􏱧v2; call this 􏱧2. (ii) Nowsuppose∑thatfore􏱻g,vi,eandvi,gareuncorrelated.ShowthatCov(ui,e,ui,g)􏱪􏱧f2 (iii) Let u-i 􏱪 mi􏱦1 mi u be the average of the composite errors within a firm. -eˆ􏱪1 i,e2 2 Show that Var(ui) 􏱪 􏱧f 􏱕 􏱧v /mi. (iv) Discuss the relevance of part (iii) for WLS estimation using data averaged at the firm level, where the weight used for observation i is the usual firm size. Computer Exercises C1 Consider the following model to explain sleeping behavior: sleep 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1totwrk 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 􏱬4age2 􏱕 􏱬5 yngkid 􏱕 􏱬6male 􏱕 u. (i) Write down a model that allows the variance of u to differ between men and women. The variance should not depend on other factors. (ii) Use the data in SLEEP75.RAW to estimate the parameters of the model for heteroskedasticity. (You have to estimate the sleep equation by OLS, first, to obtain the OLS residuals.) Is the estimated variance of u higher for men or for women? (iii) Is the variance of u statistically different for men and for women? C2 (i) Use the data in HPRICE1.RAW to obtain the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for equation (8.17). Discuss any important differences with the usual stan- dard errors. (ii) Repeat part (i) for equation (8.18). (iii) What does this example suggest about heteroskedasticity and the transformation used for the dependent variable? C3 Apply the full White test for heteroskedasticity [see equation (8.19)] to equation (8.18). Using the chi-square form of the statistic, obtain the p-value. What do you conclude? C4 Use VOTE1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate a model with voteA as the dependent variable and prtystrA, democA, log(expendA), and log(expendB) as independent variables. Obtain the OLS re- siduals, uˆi, and regress these on all of the independent variables. Explain why you obtain R2 􏱪 0. (ii) Now, compute the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity. Use the F statistic version and report the p-value. (iii) Compute the special case of the White test for heteroskedasticity, again using the F statistic form. How strong is the evidence for heteroskedasticity now? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 300 PART 1 C5 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Use the data in PNTSPRD.RAW for this exercise. (i) The variable sprdcvr is a binary variable equal to one if the Las Vegas point spread for a college basketball game was covered. The expected value of sprdcvr, say 􏱙, is the probability that the spread is covered in a randomly selected game. Test H0: 􏱙 􏱪 .5 against H1: 􏱙 􏱻 .5 at the 10% significance level and discuss your findings. (Hint: This is easily done using a t test by regressing sprdcvr on an intercept only.) (ii) How many games in the sample of 553 were played on a neutral court? (iii) Estimate the linear probability model sprdcvr 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 favhome 􏱕 􏱬2neutral 􏱕 􏱬3 fav25 􏱕 􏱬4und25 􏱕 u and report the results in the usual form. (Report the usual OLS standard errors and the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors.) Which variable is most sig- nificant, both practically and statistically? (iv) Explain why, under the null hypothesis H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱪 􏱬3 􏱪 􏱬4 􏱪 0, there is no heteroskedasticity in the model. (v) Use the usual F statistic to test the hypothesis in part (iv). What do you conclude? (vi) Given the previous analysis, would you say that it is possible to systematically predict whether the Las Vegas spread will be covered using information avail- able prior to the game? In Example 7.12, we estimated a linear probability model for whether a young man was arrested during 1986: arr86 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1pcnv 􏱕 􏱬2avgsen 􏱕 􏱬3tottime 􏱕 􏱬4 ptime86 􏱕 􏱬5qemp86 􏱕 u. (i) Using the data in CRIME1.RAW, estimate this model by OLS and verify that all fitted values are strictly between zero and one. What are the smallest and largest fitted values? (ii) Estimate the equation by weighted least squares, as discussed in Section 8.5. (iii) Use the WLS estimates to determine whether avgsen and tottime are jointly significant at the 5% level. Use the data in LOANAPP.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate the equation in part (iii) of Computer Exercise C8 in Chapter 7, computing the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. Compare the 95% confidence interval on 􏱬white with the nonrobust confidence interval. (ii) Obtain the fitted values from the regression in part (i). Are any of them less than zero? Are any of them greater than one? What does this mean about applying weighted least squares? Use the data set GPA1.RAW for this exercise. (i) Use OLS to estimate a model relating colGPA to hsGPA, ACT, skipped, and PC. C6 C7 C8 Obtain the OLS residuals. (ii) Compute the special case of the White test for heteroskedasticity. In the regres- 􏱾􏱾 2ˆ sion of û2i on colGPAi , colGPAi , obtain the fitted values, say hi. (iii) Verify that the fitted values from part (ii) are all strictly positive. Then, obtain the weighted least squares estimates using weights 1/hˆi. Compare the weighted least squares estimates for the effect of skipping lectures and the effect of PC ownership with the corresponding OLS estimates. What about their statistical significance? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 8 Heteroskedasticity 301 (iv) In the WLS estimation from part (iii), obtain heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. In other words, allow for the fact that the variance function estimated in part (ii) might be misspecified. (See Question 8.4.) Do the standard errors change much from part (iii)? C9 In Example 8.7, we computed the OLS and a set of WLS estimates in a cigarette de- mand equation. (i) Obtain the OLS estimates in equation (8.35). (ii) Obtain the hˆi used in the WLS estimation of equation (8.36) and reproduce equa- tion (8.36). From this equation, obtain the unweighted residuals and fitted values; call these uˆi and yˆi, respectively. (For example, in Stata, the unweighted residuals and fitted values _a_re given by de_fa_ult.) (iii) Let u ̆i 􏱪 uˆi /􏱯hˆi and y ̆i 􏱪 yˆi /􏱯hˆi be the weighted quantities. Carry out the special case of the White test for heteroskedasticity by regressing u ̆2i on y ̆i, y ̆2i , being sure to include an intercept, as always. Do you find heteroskedasticity in the weighted residuals? (iv) What does the finding from part (iii) imply about the proposed form of heteroskedasticity used in obtaining (8.36)? (v) Obtain valid standard errors for the WLS estimates that allow the variance function to be misspecified. C10 Use the data set 401KSUBS.RAW for this exercise. (i) Using OLS, estimate a linear probability model for e401k, using as explana- tory variables inc, inc2, age, age2, and male. Obtain both the usual OLS stan- dard errors and the heteroskedasticity-robust versions. Are there any important differences? (ii) In the special case of the White test for heteroskedasticity, where we regress the squared OLS residuals on a quadratic in the OLS fitted values, uˆ2i on yˆi,yˆ2i , i 􏱪 1, ..., n, argue that the probability limit of the coefficient on yˆi should be one, the probability limit of the coefficient on yˆ2i should be 􏱦1, and the probability limit of the intercept should be zero. {Hint: Remember that Var(y􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 p(x) [1 􏱦 p(x)], where p(x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk.} (iii) For the model estimated from part (i), obtain the White test and see if the co- efficient estimates roughly correspond to the theoretical values described in part (ii). (iv) After verifying that the fitted values from part (i) are all between zero and one, obtain the weighted least squares estimates of the linear probability model. Do they differ in important ways from the OLS estimates? C11 Use the data in 401KSUBS.RAW for this question, restricting the sample to fsize 􏱪 1. (i) To the model estimated in Table 8.1, add the interaction term, e401k 􏱳 inc. Esti- mate the equation by OLS and obtain the usual and robust standard errors. What do you conclude about the statistical significance of the interaction term? (ii) NowestimatethemoregeneralmodelbyWLSusingthesameweights,1/inci, as in Table 8.1. Compute the usual and robust standard error for the WLS esti- mator. Is the interaction term statistically significant using the robust standard error? (iii) Discuss the WLS coefficient on e401k in the more general model. Is it of much interest by itself? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 302 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data C12 (iv) Reestimate the model by WLS but use the interaction term e401k 􏱳 (inc 􏱦 30); the average income in the sample is about 29.44. Now interpret the coefficient on e401k. Use the data in MEAP00.RAW to answer this question. (i) Estimate the model math4 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lunch 􏱕 􏱬2log(enroll) 􏱕 􏱬3log(exppp) 􏱕 u by OLS and obtain the usual standard errors and the fully robust standard errors. How do they generally compare? (ii) Apply the special case of the White test for heteroskedasticity. What is the value of the F test? What do you conclude? (iii) Obtain gˆi as the fitted values from the regression log(uˆ2i ) on 􏱾math4i, 􏱾math42i , where 􏱾math4i are the OLS fitted values and the uˆi are the OLS residuals. Let hˆi 􏱪 exp(gˆi). Use the hˆi to obtain WLS estimates. Are there big differences with the OLS coefficients? (iv) Obtain the standard errors for WLS that allow misspecification of the variance function. Do these differ much from the usual WLS standard errors? (v) For estimating the effect of spending on math4, does OLS or WLS appear to be more precise? Use the data in FERTIL2.RAW to answer this question. (i) Estimate the model children 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1age 􏱕 􏱬2age2 􏱕 􏱬3educ 􏱕 􏱬4electric 􏱕 􏱬5urban 􏱕 u and report the usual and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. Are the robust standard errors always bigger than the nonrobust ones? (ii) Add the three religious dummy variables and test whether they are jointly significant. What are the p-values for the nonrobust and robust tests? (iii) From the regresion in part (ii), obtain the fitted values yˆ and the residuals, uˆ. Regress uˆ2 on yˆ, yˆ2 and test the joint significance of the two regressors. Conclude that heteroskedasticity is present in the equation for children. (iv) Would you say the heteroskedasticity you found in part (iii) is practically important? Use the data in BEAUTY.RAW for this question. (i) Using the data pooled for men and women, estimate the equation C13 C14 lwage 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1belavg 􏱕 􏱬2abvavg 􏱕 􏱬3 female 􏱕 􏱬4educ 􏱕 􏱬5exper 􏱕 􏱬5exper2 􏱕 u, and report the results using heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors below coefficients. Are any of the coefficients surprising in either their signs or magni- tudes? Is the coefficient on female practically large and statistically significant? (ii) Add interactions of female with all other explanatory variables in the equation from part (i) (five interactions in all). Compute the usual F test of joint signifi- cance of the five interactions and a heteroskedasticity-robust version. Does using the heteroskedasticity-robust version change the outcome in any important way? (iii) In the full model with interactions, determine whether those involving the looks variables—female 􏱫 belavg and female 􏱫 abvavg—are jointly significant. Are their coefficients practically small? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues In Chapter 8, we dealt with one failure of the Gauss-Markov assumptions. While heteroskedasticity in the errors can be viewed as a problem with a model, it is a relatively minor one. The presence of heteroskedasticity does not cause bias or incon- sistency in the OLS estimators. Also, it is fairly easy to adjust confidence intervals and t and F statistics to obtain valid inference after OLS estimation, or even to get more efficient estimators by using weighted least squares. In this chapter, we return to the much more serious problem of correlation between the error, u, and one or more of the explanatory variables. Remember from Chapter 3 that if u is, for whatever reason, correlated with the explanatory variable xj, then we say that xj is an endogenous explanatory variable. We also provide a more detailed discussion on three reasons why an explanatory variable can be endogenous; in some cases, we discuss possible remedies. We have already seen in Chapters 3 and 5 that omitting a key variable can cause correlation between the error and some of the explanatory variables, which generally leads to bias and inconsistency in all of the OLS estimators. In the special case that the omit- ted variable is a function of an explanatory variable in the model, the model suffers from functional form misspecification. We begin in the first section by discussing the consequences of functional form mis- specification and how to test for it. In Section 9.2, we show how the use of proxy variables can solve, or at least mitigate, omitted variables bias. In Section 9.3, we derive and explain the bias in OLS that can arise under certain forms of measurement error. Additional data problems are discussed in Section 9.4. All of the procedures in this chapter are based on OLS estimation. As we will see, certain problems that cause correlation between the error and some explanatory variables cannot be solved by using OLS on a single cross section. We postpone a treatment of alternative estimation methods until Part 3. 303 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 304 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 9.1 Functional Form Misspecification A multiple regression model suffers from functional form misspecification when it does not properly account for the relationship between the dependent and the observed explanatory variables. For example, if hourly wage is determined by log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 u, but we omit the squared experience term, exper2, then we are committing a functional form misspecification. We already know from Chapter 3 that this generally leads to biased estimators of 􏱬0, 􏱬1, and 􏱬2. (We do not estimate 􏱬3 because exper2 is excluded from the model.) Thus, misspecifying how exper affects log(wage) generally results in a biased estimator of the return to education, 􏱬1. The amount of this bias depends on the size of 􏱬3 and the correlation among educ, exper, and exper2. Things are worse for estimating the return to experience: even if we could get an un- biased estimator of 􏱬2, we would not be able to estimate the return to experience because it equals 􏱬2 􏱕 2􏱬3exper (in decimal form). Just using the biased estimator of 􏱬2 can be misleading, especially at extreme values of exper. As another example, suppose the log(wage) equation is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 􏱬4 female 􏱕 􏱬5 female·educ 􏱕 u, [9.1] where female is a binary variable. If we omit the interaction term, female􏱳educ, then we are misspecifying the functional form. In general, we will not get unbiased estimators of any of the other parameters, and since the return to education depends on gender, it is not clear what return we would be estimating by omitting the interaction term. Omitting functions of independent variables is not the only way that a model can suffer from misspecified functional form. For example, if (9.1) is the true model satisfying the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions, but we use wage rather than log(wage) as the dependent variable, then we will not obtain unbiased or consistent estimators of the partial effects. The tests that follow have some ability to detect this kind of functional form problem, but there are better tests that we will mention in the subsection on testing against nonnested alternatives. Misspecifying the functional form of a model can certainly have serious consequences. Nevertheless, in one important respect, the problem is minor: by definition, we have data on all the necessary variables for obtaining a functional relationship that fits the data well. This can be contrasted with the problem addressed in the next section, where a key variable is omitted on which we cannot collect data. We already have a very powerful tool for detecting misspecified functional form: the F test for joint exclusion restrictions. It often makes sense to add quadratic terms of any significant variables to a model and to perform a joint test of significance. If the additional quadratics are significant, they can be added to the model (at the cost of complicating the interpretation of the model). However, significant quadratic terms can be symptomatic of other functional form problems, such as using the level of a variable when the logarithm is more appropriate, or vice versa. It can be difficult to pinpoint the precise reason that a functional form is misspecified. Fortunately, in many cases, using logarithms of certain variables and adding quadratics are sufficient for detecting many important nonlinear relationships in economics. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 305 EXAMPLE 9.1 ECONOMIC MODEL OF CRIME Table 9.1 contains OLS estimates of the economic model of crime (see Example 8.3). We first estimate the model without any quadratic terms; those results are in column (1). In column (2), the squares of pcnv, ptime86, and inc86 are added; we chose to include the squares of these variables because each level term is significant in column (1). The variable qemp86 is a discrete variable taking on only five values, so we do not include its square in column (2). Each of the squared terms is significant, and together they are jointly very significant (F 􏱪 31.37, with df 􏱪 3 and 2,713; the p-value is essentially zero). Thus, it appears that the initial model overlooked some potentially important nonlinearities. The presence of the quadratics makes interpreting the model somewhat difficult. For example, pcnv no longer has a strict deterrent effect: the relation- ship between narr86 and pcnv is positive EXPLORING FURTHER 9.1 Why do we not include the squares of black and hispan in column (2) of Table 9.1? T A B L E 9 . 1 Dependent Variable: narr86 Independent Variables (1) (2) pcnv –.133 (.040) .533 (.154) pcnv2 — –.730 (.156) avgsen –.011 (.012) –.017 (.012) tottime .012 (.009) .012 (.009) ptime86 –.041 (.009) .287 (.004) ptime862 — –.0296 (.0039) qemp86 –.051 (.014) –.014 (.017) inc86 –.0015 (.0003) –.0034 (.0008) inc862 — –.000007 (.000003) black .327 (.045) .292 (.045) hispan .194 (.040) .164 (.039) intercept .596 (.036) .505 (.037) Observations R-squared 2,725 .0723 2,725 .1035 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 306 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data up until pcnv 􏱪 .365, and then the relationship is negative. We might conclude that there is little or no deterrent effect at lower values of pcnv; the effect only kicks in at higher prior conviction rates. We would have to use more sophisticated functional forms than the qua- dratic to verify this conclusion. It may be that pcnv is not entirely exogenous. For example, men who have not been convicted in the past (so that pcnv 􏱪 0) are perhaps casual criminals, and so they are less likely to be arrested in 1986. This could be biasing the estimates. Similarly, the relationship between narr86 and ptime86 is positive up until ptime86 􏱪 4.85 (almost five months in prison), and then the relationship is negative. The vast major- ity of men in the sample spent no time in prison in 1986, so again we must be careful in interpreting the results. Legal income has a negative effect on narr86 until inc86 􏱪 242.85; since income is measured in hundreds of dollars, this means an annual income of $24,285. Only 46 of the men in the sample have incomes above this level. Thus, we can conclude that narr86 and inc86 are negatively related with a diminishing effect. Example 9.1 is a tricky functional form problem due to the nature of the dependent variable. Other models are theoretically better suited for handling dependent variables tak- ing on a small number of integer values. We will briefly cover these models in Chapter 17. RESET as a General Test for Functional Form Misspecification Some tests have been proposed to detect general functional form misspecification. Ramsey’s (1969) regression specification error test (RESET) has proven to be useful in this regard. The idea behind RESET is fairly simple. If the original model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u [9.2] satisfies MLR.4, then no nonlinear functions of the independent variables should be sig- nificant when added to equation (9.2). In Example 9.1, we added quadratics in the signifi- cant explanatory variables. Although this often detects functional form problems, it has the drawback of using up many degrees of freedom if there are many explanatory variables in the original model (much as the straight form of the White test for heteroskedasticity con- sumes degrees of freedom). Further, certain kinds of neglected nonlinearities will not be picked up by adding quadratic terms. RESET adds polynomials in the OLS fitted values to equation (9.2) to detect general kinds of functional form misspecification. To implement RESET, we must decide how many functions of the fitted values to in- clude in an expanded regression. There is no right answer to this question, but the squared and cubed terms have proven to be useful in most applications. Let yˆ denote the OLS fitted values from estimating (9.2). Consider the expanded equation y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕􏱛1yˆ2 􏱕􏱛2yˆ3 􏱕error. [9.3] This equation seems a little odd, because functions of the fitted values from the initial estimation now appear as explanatory variables. In fact, we will not be interested in the estimated parameters from (9.3); we only use this equation to test whether (9.2) has Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 307 missed important nonlinearities. The thing to remember is that yˆ2 and yˆ3 are just nonlinear functions of the xj. The null hypothesis is that (9.2) is correctly specified. Thus, RESET is the F statistic for testing H0: 􏱛1 􏱪 0, 􏱛2 􏱪 0 in the expanded model (9.3). A significant F statistic suggests some sort of functional form problem. The distribution of the F statistic is approximately F2,n􏱦k􏱦3 in large samples under the null hypothesis (and the Gauss-Markov assumptions). The df in the expanded equation (9.3) is n􏱦k􏱦1􏱦2􏱪n􏱦k􏱦3. An LM version is also available (and the chi-square distribution will have two df ). Further, the test can be made robust to heteroskedasticity using the methods discussed in Section 8.2. EXAMPLE 9.2 HOUSING PRICE EQUATION We estimate two models for housing prices. The first one has all variables in level form: price 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lotsize 􏱕 􏱬2 sqrft 􏱕 􏱬3 bdrms 􏱕 u. [9.4] The second one uses the logarithms of all variables except bdrms: lprice 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1llotsize 􏱕 􏱬2 lsqrft 􏱕 􏱬3 bdrms 􏱕 u. [9.5] Using n 􏱪 88 houses in HPRICE1.RAW, the RESET statistic for equation (9.4) turns out to be 4.67; this is the value of an F2,82 random variable (n 􏱪 88, k 􏱪 3), and the associated p-value is .012. This is evidence of functional form misspecification in (9.4). The RESET statistic in (9.5) is 2.56, with p-value 􏱪 .084. Thus, we do not reject (9.5) at the 5% significance level (although we would at the 10% level). On the basis of RESET, the log-log model in (9.5) is preferred. In the previous example, we tried two models for explaining housing prices. One was rejected by RESET, while the other was not (at least at the 5% level). Often, things are not so simple. A drawback with RESET is that it provides no real direction on how to proceed if the model is rejected. Rejecting (9.4) by using RESET does not immediately suggest that (9.5) is the next step. Equation (9.5) was estimated because constant elasticity models are easy to interpret and can have nice statistical properties. In this example, it so happens that it passes the functional form test as well. Some have argued that RESET is a very general test for model misspecification, including unobserved omitted variables and heteroskedasticity. Unfortunately, such use of RESET is largely misguided. It can be shown that RESET has no power for detecting omitted variables whenever they have expectations that are linear in the included inde- pendent variables in the model [see Wooldridge (1995) for a precise statement]. Further, if the functional form is properly specified, RESET has no power for detecting heteroske- dasticity. The bottom line is that RESET is a functional form test, and nothing more. Tests against Nonnested Alternatives Obtaining tests for other kinds of functional form misspecification—for example, trying to decide whether an independent variable should appear in level or logarithmic form—takes us outside the realm of classical hypothesis testing. It is possible to test the model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕u [9.6] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 308 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data against the model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(x1) 􏱕 􏱬2log(x2) 􏱕 u, [9.7] and vice versa. However, these are nonnested models (see Chapter 6), and so we cannot simply use a standard F test. Two different approaches have been suggested. The first is to construct a comprehensive model that contains each model as a special case and then to test the restrictions that led to each of the models. In the current example, the comprehensive model is y 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1x1 􏱕 􏰸2x2 􏱕 􏰸3log(x1) 􏱕 􏰸4log(x2) 􏱕 u. [9.8] WecanfirsttestH0:􏰸3 􏱪0,􏰸4 􏱪0asatestof(9.6).WecanalsotestH0:􏰸1 􏱪0,􏰸2 􏱪0 as a test of (9.7). This approach was suggested by Mizon and Richard (1986). Another approach has been suggested by Davidson and MacKinnon (1981). They point out that if (9.6) is true, then the fitted values from the other model, (9.7), should be insignificant in (9.6). Thus, to test (9.6), we first estimate model (9.7) by OLS to obtain the fitted values. Call these yˆ. Then, the Davidson-MacKinnon test is based on the t sta- tistic on yˆ in the equation y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏰩1yˆ􏱕error. A significant t statistic (against a two-sided alternative) is a rejection of (9.6). Similarly, if yˆ denotes the fitted values from estimating (9.6), the test of (9.7) is the t statistic on yˆ in the model y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(x1) 􏱕 􏱬2log(x2) 􏱕 􏰩1yˆ 􏱕 error; a significant t statistic is evidence against (9.7). The same two tests can be used for testing any two nonnested models with the same dependent variable. There are a few problems with nonnested testing. First, a clear winner need not emerge. Both models could be rejected or neither model could be rejected. In the lat- ter case, we can use the adjusted R-squared to choose between them. If both models are rejected, more work needs to be done. However, it is important to know the practical con- sequences from using one form or the other: if the effects of key independent variables on y are not very different, then it does not really matter which model is used. A second problem is that rejecting (9.6) using, say, the Davidson-MacKinnon test does not mean that (9.7) is the correct model. Model (9.6) can be rejected for a variety of functional form misspecifications. An even more difficult problem is obtaining nonnested tests when the competing models have different dependent variables. The leading case is y versus log(y). We saw in Chapter 6 that just obtaining goodness-of-fit measures that can be compared requires some care. Tests have been proposed to solve this problem, but they are beyond the scope of this text. [See Wooldridge (1994a) for a test that has a simple interpretation and is easy to implement.] 9.2 Using Proxy Variables for Unobserved Explanatory Variables A more difficult problem arises when a model excludes a key variable, usually because of data unavailability. Consider a wage equation that explicitly recognizes that ability (abil) affects log(wage): log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3abil 􏱕 u. [9.9] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 309 This model shows explicitly that we want to hold ability fixed when measuring the return to educ and exper. If, say, educ is correlated with abil, then putting abil in the error term causes the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 (and 􏱬2) to be biased, a theme that has appeared repeatedly. Our primary interest in equation (9.9) is in the slope parameters 􏱬1 and 􏱬2. We do not really care whether we get an unbiased or consistent estimator of the intercept 􏱬0; as we will see shortly, this is not usually possible. Also, we can never hope to estimate 􏱬3 because abil is not observed; in fact, we would not know how to interpret 􏱬3 anyway, since ability is at best a vague concept. How can we solve, or at least mitigate, the omitted variables bias in an equation like (9.9)? One possibility is to obtain a proxy variable for the omitted variable. Loosely speaking, a proxy variable is something that is related to the unobserved variable that we would like to control for in our analysis. In the wage equation, one possibility is to use the intelligence quotient, or IQ, as a proxy for ability. This does not require IQ to be the same thing as ability; what we need is for IQ to be correlated with ability, something we clarify in the following discussion. All of the key ideas can be illustrated in a model with three independent variables, two of which are observed: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x*3􏱕u. [9.10] We assume that data are available on y, x1, and x2—in the wage example, these are log(wage), educ, and exper, respectively. The explanatory variable x*3 is unobserved, but we have a proxy variable for x*3. Call the proxy variable x3. What do we require of x3? At a minimum, it should have some relationship to x*3. This is captured by the simple regression equation x*3 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛3x3 􏱕 v3, [9.11] where v3 is an error due to the fact that x*3 and x3 are not exactly related. The parameter 􏱛3 measures the relationship between x*3 and x3; typically, we think of x*3 and x3 as being posi- tively related, so that 􏱛3 􏱰 0. If 􏱛3 􏱪 0, then x3 is not a suitable proxy for x*3. The intercept 􏱛0 in (9.11), which can be positive or negative, simply allows x*3 and x3 to be measured on different scales. (For example, unobserved ability is certainly not required to have the same average value as IQ in the U.S. population.) How can we use x3 to get unbiased (or at least consistent) estimators of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2? The proposal is to pretend that x3 and x*3 are the same, so that we run the regression of y on x1, x2, x3. [9.12] We call this the plug-in solution to the omitted variables problem because x3 is just plugged in for x*3 before we run OLS. If x3 is truly related to x*3, this seems like a sensible thing. However, since x3 and x*3 are not the same, we should determine when this proce- dure does in fact give consistent estimators of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2. The assumptions needed for the plug-in solution to provide consistent estimators of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 can be broken down into assumptions about u and v3: (1) The error u is uncorrelated with x1, x2, and x*3, which is just the standard assump- tion in model (9.10). In addition, u is uncorrelated with x3. This latter assumption just means that x3 is irrelevant in the population model, once x1, x2, and x*3 have been included. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 310 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data This is essentially true by definition, since x3 is a proxy variable for x*3: it is x*3 that directly affects y, not x3. Thus, the assumption that u is uncorrelated with x1, x2, x*3, and x3 is not very controversial. (Another way to state this assumption is that the expected value of u, given all these variables, is zero.) (2) The error v3 is uncorrelated with x1, x2, and x3. Assuming that v3 is uncorrelated with x1 and x2 requires x3 to be a “good” proxy for x*3. This is easiest to see by writing the analog of these assumptions in terms of conditional expectations: E(x*3􏰫x1, x2, x3) 􏱪 E(x*3􏰫x3) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛3x3. [9.13] The first equality, which is the most important one, says that, once x3 is controlled for, the expected value of x*3 does not depend on x1 or x2. Alternatively, x*3 has zero correlation with x1 and x2 once x3 is partialled out. In the wage equation (9.9), where IQ is the proxy for ability, condition (9.13) becomes E(abil􏰫educ,exper,IQ) 􏱪 E(abil􏰫IQ) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛3IQ. Thus, the average level of ability only changes with IQ, not with educ and exper. Is this reasonable? Maybe it is not exactly true, but it may be close to being true. It is certainly worth including IQ in the wage equation to see what happens to the estimated return to education. We can easily see why the previous assumptions are enough for the plug-in solution to work. If we plug equation (9.11) into equation (9.10) and do simple algebra, we get y􏱪(􏱬0 􏱕􏱬3􏱛0)􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3􏱛3x3 􏱕u􏱕􏱬3v3. Call the composite error in this equation e 􏱪 u 􏱕 􏱬3v3; it depends on the error in the model of interest, (9.10), and the error in the proxy variable equation, v3. Since u and v3 both have zero mean and each is uncorrelated with x1, x2, and x3, e also has zero mean and is uncorrelated with x1, x2, and x3. Write this equation as y􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱮3x3 􏱕e, where 􏱮0 􏱪 (􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬3􏱛0) is the new intercept and 􏱮3 􏱪 􏱬3􏱛3 is the slope parameter on the proxy variable x3. As we alluded to earlier, when we run the regression in (9.12), we will not get unbiased estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬3; instead, we will get unbiased (or at least consis- tent) estimators of 􏱮0, 􏱬1, 􏱬2, and 􏱮3. The important thing is that we get good estimates of the parameters 􏱬1 and 􏱬2. In most cases, the estimate of 􏱮3 is actually more interesting than an estimate of 􏱬3 anyway. For example, in the wage equation, 􏱮3 measures the return to wage given one more point on IQ score. EXAMPLE 9.3 IQ AS A PROXY FOR ABILITY The file WAGE2.RAW, from Blackburn and Neumark (1992), contains information on monthly earnings, education, several demographic variables, and IQ scores for 935 men in 1980. As a method to account for omitted ability bias, we add IQ to a standard log wage equation. The results are shown in Table 9.2. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 311 T A B L E 9 . 2 Dependent Variable: log(wage) Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) educ .065 (.006) .054 (.007) .018 (.041) exper .014 (.003) .014 (.003) .014 (.003) tenure .012 (.002) .011 (.002) .011 (.002) married .199 (.039) .200 (.039) .201 (.039) south 􏱦.091 (.026) 􏱦.080 (.026) 􏱦.080 (.026) urban .184 (.027) .182 (.027) .184 (.027) black 􏱦.188 (.038) 􏱦.143 (.039) 􏱦.147 (.040) IQ — .0036 (.0010) 􏱦.0009 (.0052) educ􏱳IQ — — .00034 (.00038) intercept 5.395 (.113) 5.176 (.128) 5.648 (.546) Observations R-squared 935 .253 935 .263 935 .263 Our primary interest is in what happens to the estimated return to education. Column (1) contains the estimates without using IQ as a proxy variable. The estimated return to educa- tion is 6.5%. If we think omitted ability is positively correlated with educ, then we assume that this estimate is too high. (More precisely, the average estimate across all random sam- ples would be too high.) When IQ is added to the equation, the return to education falls to 5.4%, which corresponds with our prior beliefs about omitted ability bias. The effect of IQ on socioeconomic outcomes has been documented in the controver- sial book The Bell Curve, by Herrnstein and Murray (1994). Column (2) shows that IQ does have a statistically significant, positive effect on earnings, after controlling for sev- eral other factors. Everything else being equal, an increase of 10 IQ points is predicted to raise monthly earnings by 3.6%. The standard deviation of IQ in the U.S. population is 15, so a one standard deviation increase in IQ is associated with higher earnings of 5.4%. This is identical to the predicted increase in wage due to another year of education. It is clear from column (2) that education still has an important role in increasing earnings, even though the effect is not as large as originally estimated. Some other interesting observations emerge from columns (1) and (2). Adding IQ to the equation only increases the R-squared from .253 to .263. Most of the variation in log(wage) is not explained by the factors in column (2). Also, adding IQ to the equa- tion does not eliminate the estimated earnings difference between black and white men: a Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 312 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data black man with the same IQ, education, experience, and so on, as a white man is predicted to earn about 14.3% less, and the difference is very statistically significant. Column (3) in Table 9.2 includes the interaction term educ􏱳IQ. This allows for the possibility that educ and abil inter- act in determining log(wage). We might think that the return to education is higher for people with more ability, but this turns out not to be the case: the interaction term is not significant, and its addition makes educ and IQ individually insignificant while complicating the model. Therefore, the esti- mates in column (2) are preferred. There is no reason to stop at a single proxy variable for ability in this example. The data set WAGE2.RAW also contains a score for each man on the Knowledge of the World of Work (KWW) test. This provides a different measure of ability, which can be used in place of IQ or along with IQ, to estimate the return to education (see Computer Exercise C2). It is easy to see how using a proxy variable can still lead to bias if the proxy variable does not satisfy the preceding assumptions. Suppose that, instead of (9.11), the unobserved variable, x*3, is related to all of the observed variables by x*3 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1x1 􏱕􏱛2x2 􏱕􏱛3x3 􏱕v3, [9.14] where v3 has a zero mean and is uncorrelated with x1, x2, and x3. Equation (9.11) assumes EXPLORING FURTHER 9.2 What do you make of the small and sta- tistically insignificant coefficient on educ in column (3) of Table 9.2? (Hint: When educ􏱳IQ is in the equation, what is the inter- pretation of the coefficient on educ?) that 􏱛1 and 􏱛2 are both zero. By plugging equation (9.14) into (9.10), we get y􏱪(􏱬0 􏱕􏱬3􏱛0)􏱕(􏱬1 􏱕􏱬3􏱛1)x1 􏱕(􏱬2 􏱕􏱬3􏱛2)x2 􏱕 􏱬3􏱛3x3 􏱕 u 􏱕 􏱬3v3, [9.15] from which it follows that plim(􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬3􏱛1 and plim(􏱬ˆ2) 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 􏱬3􏱛2. [This follows because the error in (9.15), u 􏱕 􏱬3v3, has zero mean and is uncorrelated with x1, x2, and x3.] In the previous example where x1 􏱪 educ and x*3 􏱪 abil, 􏱬3 􏱰 0, so there is a positive bias (inconsistency) if abil has a positive partial correlation with educ (􏱛1 􏱰 0). Thus, we could still be getting an upward bias in the return to education by using IQ as a proxy for abil if IQ is not a good proxy. But we can reasonably hope that this bias is smaller than if we ignored the problem of omitted ability entirely. A complaint that is sometimes aired about including variables such as IQ in a re- gression that includes educ is that it exacerbates the problem of multicollinearity, likely leading to a less precise estimate of 􏱬educ. But this complaint misses two important points. First, the inclusion of IQ reduces the error variance because the part of ability explained by IQ has been removed from the error. Typically, this will be reflected in a smaller standard error of the regression (although it need not get smaller because of its degrees-of-freedom adjustment). Second, and most importantly, the added multicollinearity is a necessary evil if we want to get an estimator of 􏱬educ with less bias: the reason educ and IQ are correlated is that educ and abil are thought to be correlated, and IQ is a proxy for abil. If we could observe abil we would include it in the regression, and of course there would be unavoid- able multicollinearity caused by correlation between educ and abil. Proxy variables can come in the form of binary information as well. In Example 7.9 [see equation (7.15)], we discussed Krueger’s (1993) estimates of the return to using a computer on Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 313 the job. Krueger also included a binary variable indicating whether the worker uses a computer at home (as well as an interaction term between computer usage at work and at home). His pri- mary reason for including computer usage at home in the equation was to proxy for unobserved “technical ability” that could affect wage directly and be related to computer usage at work. Using Lagged Dependent Variables as Proxy Variables In some applications, like the earlier wage example, we have at least a vague idea about which unobserved factor we would like to control for. This facilitates choosing proxy variables. In other applications, we suspect that one or more of the independent variables is correlated with an omitted variable, but we have no idea how to obtain a proxy for that omitted variable. In such cases, we can include, as a control, the value of the dependent variable from an earlier time period. This is especially useful for policy analysis. Using a lagged dependent variable in a cross-sectional equation increases the data requirements, but it also provides a simple way to account for historical factors that cause current differences in the dependent variable that are difficult to account for in other ways. For example, some cities have had high crime rates in the past. Many of the same unobserved factors contrib- ute to both high current and past crime rates. Likewise, some universities are traditionally better in academics than other universities. Inertial effects are also captured by putting in lags of y. Consider a simple equation to explain city crime rates: crime 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unem 􏱕 􏱬2expend 􏱕 􏱬3crime􏱦1 􏱕 u, [9.16] where crime is a measure of per capita crime, unem is the city unemployment rate, expend is per capita spending on law enforcement, and crime􏱦1 indicates the crime rate measured in some earlier year (this could be the past year or several years ago). We are interested in the effects of unem on crime, as well as of law enforcement expenditures on crime. What is the purpose of including crime􏱦1 in the equation? Certainly, we expect that 􏱬3 􏱰 0 because crime has inertia. But the main reason for putting this in the equation is that cities with high historical crime rates may spend more on crime prevention. Thus, factors unobserved to us (the econometricians) that affect crime are likely to be correlated with expend (and unem). If we use a pure cross-sectional analysis, we are unlikely to get an unbiased estimator of the causal effect of law enforcement expenditures on crime. But, by including crime􏱦1 in the equation, we can at least do the following experiment: if two cities have the same previous crime rate and current unemployment rate, then 􏱬2 measures the effect of another dollar of law enforcement on crime. EXAMPLE 9.4 CITY CRIME RATES We estimate a constant elasticity version of the crime model in equation (9.16) (unem, because it is a percentage, is left in level form). The data in CRIME2.RAW are from 46 cities for the year 1987. The crime rate is also available for 1982, and we use that as an additional independent variable in trying to control for city unobservables that affect crime and may be correlated with current law enforcement expenditures. Table 9.3 contains the results. Without the lagged crime rate in the equation, the effects of the unemployment rate and expenditures on law enforcement are counterintuitive; neither is statistically signifi- cant, although the t statistic on log(lawexpc87) is 1.17. One possibility is that increased law enforcement expenditures improve reporting conventions, and so more crimes are reported. But it is also likely that cities with high recent crime rates spend more on law enforcement. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 314 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data T A B L E 9 . 3 Dependent Variable: log(crmrte87) Independent Variables (1) (2) unem87 􏱦.029 (.032) .009 (.020) log(lawexpc87) .203 (.173) 􏱦.140 (.109) log(crmrte82) — 1.194 (.132) intercept 3.34 (1.25) .076 (.821) Observations R-squared 46 .057 46 .680 Adding the log of the crime rate from five years earlier has a large effect on the expenditures coefficient. The elasticity of the crime rate with respect to expenditures be- comes 􏱦.14, with t 􏱪 􏱦1.28. This is not strongly significant, but it suggests that a more sophisticated model with more cities in the sample could produce significant results. Not surprisingly, the current crime rate is strongly related to the past crime rate. The estimate indicates that if the crime rate in 1982 was 1% higher, then the crime rate in 1987 is predicted to be about 1.19% higher. We cannot reject the hypothesis that the elasticity of current crime with respect to past crime is unity [t 􏱪 (1.194 􏱦 1)/.132 􏱴 1.47]. Adding the past crime rate increases the explanatory power of the regression markedly, but this is no surprise. The primary reason for including the lagged crime rate is to obtain a better estimate of the ceteris paribus effect of log(lawexpc87) on log(crmrte87). The practice of putting in a lagged y as a general way of controlling for unobserved variables is hardly perfect. But it can aid in getting a better estimate of the effects of policy variables on various outcomes. Adding a lagged value of y is not the only way to use two years of data to control for omitted factors. When we discuss panel data methods in Chapters 13 and 14, we will cover other ways to use repeated data on the same cross-sectional units at different points in time. A Different Slant on Multiple Regression The discussion of proxy variables in this section suggests an alternative way of interpreting a multiple regression analysis when we do not necessarily observe all relevant explanatory variables. Until now, we have specified the population model of interest with an additive error, as in equation (9.9). Our discussion of that example hinged upon whether we have a suitable proxy variable (IQ score in this case, other test scores more generally) for the unobserved explanatory variable, which we called “ability.” A less structured, more general approach to multiple regression is to forego specify- ing models with unobservables. Rather, we begin with the premise that we have access to a set of observable explanatory variables—which includes the variable of primary interest, such as years of schooling, and controls, such as observable test scores. We then model the mean of y conditional on the observed explanatory variables. For example, in the wage example with lwage denoting log(wage), we can estimate E(lwage􏰫educ,exper,tenure, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 315 south,urban,black,IQ)—exactly what is reported in Table 9.2. The difference now is that we set our goals more modestly. Namely, rather than introduce the nebulous concept of “abil- ity” in equation (9.9), we state from the outset that we will estimate the ceteris paribus effect of education holding IQ (and the other observed factors) fixed. There is no need to discuss whether IQ is a suitable proxy for ability. Consequently, while we may not be answering the question underlying equation (9.9), we are answering a question of interest: if two people have the same IQ levels (and same values of experience, tenure, and so on), yet they differ in education levels by a year, what is the expected difference in their log wages? As another example, if we include as an explanatory variable the poverty rate in a school- level regression to assess the effects of spending on standardized test scores, we should rec- ognize that the poverty rate only crudely captures the relevant differences in children and parents across schools. But often it is all we have, and it is better to control for the poverty rate than to do nothing because we cannot find suitable proxies for student “ability,” parental “involvement,” and so on. Almost certainly controlling for the poverty rate gets us closer to the ceteris paribus effects of spending than if we leave the poverty rate out of the analysis. In some applications of regression analysis, we are interested simply in predicting the outcome, y, given a set of explanatory variables, (x1, ..., xk). In such cases, it makes little sense to think in terms of “bias” in estimated coefficients due to omitted variables. Instead, we should focus on obtaining a model that predicts as well as possible, and make sure we do not include as regressors variables that cannot be observed at the time of prediction. For example, an admissions officer for a college or university might be interested in predicting success in college, as measured by grade point average, in terms of variables that can be measured at application time. Those variables would include high school per- formance (maybe just grade point average, but perhaps performance in specific kinds of courses), standardized test scores, participation in various activities (such as debate or math club), and even family background variables. We would not include a variable measuring college class attendance because we do not observe attendance in college at application time. Nor would we wring our hands about potential “biases” caused by omit- ting an attendance variable: we have no interest in, say, measuring the effect of high school GPA holding attendance in college fixed. Likewise, we would not worry about biases in coefficients because we cannot observe factors such as motivation. Naturally, for predic- tive purposes it would probably help substantially if we had a measure of motivation, but in its absence we fit the best model we can with observed explanatory variables. 9.3 Models with Random Slopes In our treatment of regression so far, we have assumed that the slope coefficients are the same across individuals in the population, or that, if the slopes differ, they differ by mea- surable characteristics, in which case we are led to regression models containing interaction terms. For example, as we saw in Section 7.4, we can allow the return to education to differ by men and women by interacting education with a gender dummy in a log wage equation. Here we are interested in a related but different question: What if the partial effect of a variable depends on unobserved factors that vary by population unit? If we have only one explanatory variable, x, we can write a general model (for a random draw, i, from the population, for emphasis) as yi 􏱪 ai 􏱕 bi xi, [9.17] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 316 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data where ai is the intercept for unit i and bi is the slope. In the simple regression model from Chapter 2 we assumed bi 􏱪 􏱬 and labeled ai as the error, ui. The model in (9.17) is sometimes called a random coefficient model or random slope model because the unobserved slope coefficient, bi, is viewed as a random draw from the population along with the observed data, (xi,yi), and the unobserved intercept, ai. As an example, if yi 􏱪 log(wagei) and xi 􏱪 educi, then (9.17) allows the return to education, bi, to vary by person. If, say, bi contains unmeasured ability (just as ai would), the partial effect of another year of schooling can depend on ability. With a random sample of size n, we (implicitly) draw n values of bi along with n values of ai (and the observed data on x and y). Naturally, we cannot estimate a slope—or, for that matter, an intercept—for each i. But we can hope to estimate the average slope (and aver- age intercept), where the average is across the population. Therefore, define 􏱮 􏱪 E(ai) and 􏱬 􏱪 E(bi). Then 􏱬 is the average of the partial effect of x on y, and so we call 􏱬 the average partial effect (APE), or the average marginal effect (AME). In the context of a log wage equation, 􏱬 is the average return to a year of schooling in the population. If we write ai 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 ci and bi 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 di, then di is the individual-specific deviation from the APE. By construction, E(ci) 􏱪 0 and E(di) 􏱪 0. Substituting into (9.17) gives yi 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱬xi 􏱕ci 􏱕dixi 􏱲􏱮􏱕􏱬xi 􏱕ui, [9.18] where ui 􏱪 ci 􏱕 di xi. (To make the notation easier to follow, we now use 􏱮, the mean value of ai, as the intercept, and 􏱬, the mean of bi, as the slope.) In other words, we can write the random coefficient as a constant coefficient model but where the error term contains an interaction between an unobservable, di, and the observed explanatory variable, xi. When would a simple regression of yi on xi provide an unbiased estimate of 􏱬 (and 􏱮)? We can apply the result for unbiasedness from Chapter 2. If E(ui􏰫xi) 􏱪 0, then OLS is gener- ally unbiased. When ui 􏱪 ci 􏱕 di xi, sufficient is E(ci􏰫xi) 􏱪 E(ci) 􏱪 0 and E(di􏰫xi) 􏱪 E(di) 􏱪 0. We can write these in terms of the unit-specific intercept and slope as E(ai􏰫xi) 􏱪 E(ai) and E(bi􏰫xi) 􏱪 E(bi); [9.19] that is, ai and bi are both mean independent of xi. This is a useful finding: if we allow for unit-specific slopes, OLS consistently estimates the population average of those slopes when they are mean independent of the explanatory variable. (See Problem 6 for a weaker set of conditions that imply consistency of OLS.) The error term in (9.18) almost certainly contains heteroskedasticity. In fact, if Var(ci􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱧2c, Var(di􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱧2d, and Cov(ci,di􏰫xi) 􏱪 0, then Var(ui􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱧2c 􏱕 􏱧2d x2i , [9.20] and so there must be heteroskedasticity in ui unless 􏱧2d 􏱪 0, which means bi 􏱪 􏱬 for all i. We know how to account for heteroskedasticity of this kind. We can use OLS and com- pute heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors and test statistics, or we can estimate the variance function in (9.20) and apply weighted least squares. Of course the latter strategy imposes homoskedasticity on the random intercept and slope, and so we would want to make a WLS analysis fully robust to violations of (9.20). Because of equation (9.20), some authors like to view heteroskedasticity in regression models generally as arising from random slope coefficients. But we should remember that the form of (9.20) is special, and it does not allow for heteroskedasticity in ai or bi. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 317 We cannot convincingly distinguish between a random slope model, where the intercept and slope are independent of xi, and a constant slope model with heteroskedasticity in ai. The treatment for multiple regression is similar. Generally, write yi 􏱪 ai 􏱕 bi1xi1 􏱕 bi2xi2 ... 􏱕 bikxik. [9.21] Then, by writing ai 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 ci and bij 􏱪 􏱬j 􏱕 dij, we have yi 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱬1xi1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxik 􏱕ui, [9.22] where ui 􏱪 ci 􏱕 di1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 dikxik. If we maintain the mean independence assumptions E(ai􏰫xi) 􏱪 E(ai) and E(bij􏰫xi) 􏱪 E(bij), j 􏱪 1, ..., k, then E(yi􏰫xi) 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxik, and so OLS using a random sample produces unbiases estimators of 􏱮 and the 􏱬j. As in the simple regression case, Var(ui􏰫xi) is almost certainly heteroskedastic. We can allow the bij to depend on observable explanatory variables as well as unob- servables. For example, suppose with k 􏱪 2 the effect of xi2 depends on xi1, and we write bi2 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱕 􏱛1(xi1 􏱦 􏱙1) 􏱕 di2, where 􏱙1 􏱪 E(xi1). If we assume E(di2􏰫xi) 􏱪 0 (and similarly for ci and di1), then E(yi􏰫xi1, xi2) 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 􏱬2xi2 􏱕 􏱛1(xi1 􏱦 􏱙1)xi2, which means we have an interaction between xi1 and xi2. Because we have subtracted the mean 􏱙1 from xi1, 􏱬2 is the average partial effect of xi2. The bottom line of this section is that allowing for random slopes is fairly straightforward if the slopes are independent, or at least mean independent, of the explanatory variables. In addition, we can easily model the slopes as functions of the exogenous variables, which leads to models with squares and interactions. Of course, in Chapter 6 we discussed how such mod- els can be useful without ever introducing the notion of a random slope. The random slopes specification provides a separate justification for such models. Estimation becomes consider- ably more difficult if the random intercept as well as some slopes are correlated with some of the regressors. We cover the problem of endogenous explanatory variables in Chapter 15. 9.4 Properties of OLS under Measurement Error Sometimes, in economic applications, we cannot collect data on the variable that truly affects economic behavior. A good example is the marginal income tax rate facing a fam- ily that is trying to choose how much to contribute to charity in a given year. The marginal rate may be hard to obtain or summarize as a single number for all income levels. Instead, we might compute the average tax rate based on total income and tax payments. When we use an imprecise measure of an economic variable in a regression model, then our model contains measurement error. In this section, we derive the consequences of measurement error for ordinary least squares estimation. OLS will be consistent under certain assumptions, but there are others under which it is inconsistent. In some of these cases, we can derive the size of the asymptotic bias. As we will see, the measurement error problem has a similar statistical structure to the omitted variable–proxy variable problem discussed in the previous section, but they are con- ceptually different. In the proxy variable case, we are looking for a variable that is somehow associated with the unobserved variable. In the measurement error case, the variable that we do not observe has a well-defined, quantitative meaning (such as a marginal tax rate or annual income), but our recorded measures of it may contain error. For example, reported annual income is a measure of actual annual income, whereas IQ score is a proxy for ability. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 318 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Another important difference between the proxy variable and measurement error prob- lems is that, in the latter case, often the mismeasured independent variable is the one of pri- mary interest. In the proxy variable case, the partial effect of the omitted variable is rarely of central interest: we are usually concerned with the effects of the other independent variables. Before we consider details, we should remember that measurement error is an issue only when the variables for which the econometrician can collect data differ from the vari- ables that influence decisions by individuals, families, firms, and so on. Measurement Error in the Dependent Variable We begin with the case where only the dependent variable is measured with error. Let y* denote the variable (in the population, as always) that we would like to explain. For example, y* could be annual family savings. The regression model has the usual form y*􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, [9.23] and we assume it satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions. We let y represent the observable measure of y*. In the savings case, y is reported annual savings. Unfortunately, families are not perfect in their reporting of annual family savings; it is easy to leave out categories or to overestimate the amount contributed to a fund. Generally, we can expect y and y* to differ, at least for some subset of families in the population. The measurement error (in the population) is defined as the difference between the observed value and the actual value: e0 􏱪 y 􏱦 y*. [9.24] For a random draw i from the population, we can write ei0 􏱪 yi 􏱦 y*i , but the important thing is how the measurement error in the population is related to other factors. To obtain an estimable model, we write y* 􏱪 y 􏱦 e0, plug this into equation (9.23), and rearrange: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u􏱕e0. [9.25] The error term in equation (9.25) is u 􏱕 e0. Because y, x1, x2, ..., xk are observed, we can estimate this model by OLS. In effect, we just ignore the fact that y is an imperfect mea- sure of y* and proceed as usual. When does OLS with y in place of y* produce consistent estimators of the 􏱬j? Since the original model (9.23) satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, u has zero mean and is uncorrelated with each xj. It is only natural to assume that the measurement error has zero mean; if it does not, then we simply get a biased estimator of the intercept, 􏱬0, which is rarely a cause for concern. Of much more importance is our assumption about the relationship between the measurement error, e0, and the explanatory variables, xj. The usual assumption is that the measurement error in y is statistically independent of each explanatory variable. If this is true, then the OLS estimators from (9.25) are unbi- ased and consistent. Further, the usual OLS inference procedures (t, F, and LM statis- tics) are valid. If e0 and u are uncorrelated, as is usually assumed, then Var(u 􏱕 e0) 􏱪 􏱧2u 􏱕 􏱧20 􏱰 􏱧2u. This means that measurement error in the dependent variable results in a larger error vari- ance than when no error occurs; this, of course, results in larger variances of the OLS estimators. This is to be expected, and there is nothing we can do about it (except collect Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 319 better data). The bottom line is that, if the measurement error is uncorrelated with the independent variables, then OLS estimation has good properties. EXAMPLE 9.5 SAVINGS FUNCTION WITH MEASUREMENT ERROR Consider a savings function sav* 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2size 􏱕 􏱬3educ 􏱕 􏱬4age 􏱕 u, but where actual savings (sav*) may deviate from reported savings (sav). The question is whether the size of the measurement error in sav is systematically related to the other vari- ables. It might be reasonable to assume that the measurement error is not correlated with inc, size, educ, and age. On the other hand, we might think that families with higher incomes, or more education, report their savings more accurately. We can never know whether the measurement error is correlated with inc or educ, unless we can collect data on sav*; then, the measurement error can be computed for each observation as ei0 􏱪 savi 􏱦 sav*i . When the dependent variable is in logarithmic form, so that log(y*) is the dependent variable, it is natural for the measurement error equation to be of the form log(y) 􏱪 log(y*) 􏱕 e0. [9.26] This follows from a multiplicative measurement error for y: y 􏱪 y*a0, where a0 􏱰 0 and e0 􏱪 log(a0). EXAMPLE 9.6 MEASUREMENT ERROR IN SCRAP RATES In Section 7.6, we discussed an example where we wanted to determine whether job train- ing grants reduce the scrap rate in manufacturing firms. We certainly might think the scrap rate reported by firms is measured with error. (In fact, most firms in the sample do not even report a scrap rate.) In a simple regression framework, this is captured by log(scrap*) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1grant 􏱕 u, where scrap* is the true scrap rate and grant is the dummy variable indicating whether a firm received a grant. The measurement error equation is log(scrap) 􏱪 log(scrap*) 􏱕 e0. Is the measurement error, e0, independent of whether the firm receives a grant? A cynical person might think that a firm receiving a grant is more likely to underreport its scrap rate in order to make the grant look effective. If this happens, then, in the estimable equation, log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1grant 􏱕 u 􏱕 e0, the error u 􏱕 e0 is negatively correlated with grant. This would produce a downward bias in 􏱬1, which would tend to make the training program look more effective than it actu- ally was. (Remember, a more negative 􏱬1 means the program was more effective, since increased worker productivity is associated with a lower scrap rate.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 320 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data The bottom line of this subsection is that measurement error in the dependent variable can cause biases in OLS if it is systematically related to one or more of the explanatory variables. If the measurement error is just a random reporting error that is independent of the explanatory variables, as is often assumed, then OLS is perfectly appropriate. Measurement Error in an Explanatory Variable Traditionally, measurement error in an explanatory variable has been considered a much more important problem than measurement error in the dependent variable. In this subsec- tion, we will see why this is the case. We begin with the simple regression model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x*1 􏱕u, [9.27] and we assume that this satisfies at least the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions. This means that estimation of (9.27) by OLS would produce unbiased and consistent estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. The problem is that x*1 is not observed. Instead, we have a measure of x*1; call it x1. For example, x*1 could be actual income, and x1 could be reported income. The measurement error in the population is simply e1 􏱪 x1 􏱦 x*1, [9.28] and this can be positive, negative, or zero. We assume that the average measurement error in the population is zero: E(e1) 􏱪 0. This is natural, and, in any case, it does not affect the important conclusions that follow. A maintained assumption in what follows is that u is un- correlated with x*1 and x1. In conditional expectation terms, we can write this as E(y􏰫x*1, x1) 􏱪 E(y􏰫x*1), which just says that x1 does not affect y after x*1 has been controlled for. We used the same assumption in the proxy variable case, and it is not controversial; it holds almost by definition. We want to know the properties of OLS if we simply replace x*1 with x1 and run the regression of y on x1. They depend crucially on the assumptions we make about the mea- surement error. Two assumptions have been the focus in econometrics literature, and they both represent polar extremes. The first assumption is that e1 is uncorrelated with the ob- served measure, x1: Cov(x1,e1) 􏱪 0. [9.29] From the relationship in (9.28), if assumption (9.29) is true, then e1 must be correlated with the unobserved variable x*1. To determine the properties of OLS in this case, we write x*1 􏱪 x1 􏱦 e1 and plug this into equation (9.27): y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕(u􏱦􏱬1e1). [9.30] Because we have assumed that u and e1 both have zero mean and are uncorrelated with x1, u 􏱦 􏱬1e1 has zero mean and is uncorrelated with x1. It follows that OLS estimation with x1 in place of x*1 produces a consistent estimator of 􏱬1 (and also 􏱬0). Since u is uncorrelated with e1, the variance of the error in (9.30) is Var(u 􏱦 􏱬1e1) 􏱪 􏱧2u 􏱕 􏱬21􏱧2e1. Thus, except when 􏱬1 􏱪 0, measurement error increases the error vaˆriance. But this does not affect any of the OLS properties (except that the variances of the 􏱬j will be larger than if we observe x*1 directly). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 321 The assumption that e1 is uncorrelated with x1 is analogous to the proxy variable assumption we made in Section 9.2. Since this assumption implies that OLS has all of its nice properties, this is not usually what econometricians have in mind when they refer to measure- ment error in an explanatory variable. The classical errors-in-variables (CEV) assumption is that the measurement error is uncorrelated with the unobserved explanatory variable: Cov(x*1,e1) 􏱪 0. [9.31] This assumption comes from writing the observed measure as the sum of the true explana- tory variable and the measurement error, x 1 􏱪 x *1 􏱕 e 1 , and then assuming the two components of x1 are uncorrelated. (This has nothing to do with assumptions about u; we always maintain that u is uncorrelated with x*1 and x1, and therefore with e1.) If assumption (9.31) holds, then x1 and e1 must be correlated: Cov(x1,e1) 􏱪 E(x1e1) 􏱪 E(x*1e1) 􏱕 E(e21) 􏱪 0 􏱕 􏱧2e1 􏱪 􏱧2e1. [9.32] Thus, the covariance between x1 and e1 is equal to the variance of the measurement error under the CEV assumption. Referring to equation (9.30), we can see that correlation between x1 and e1 is going to cause problems. Because u and x1 are uncorrelated, the covariance between x1 and the composite error u 􏱦 􏱬1e1 is Cov(x1,u 􏱦 􏱬1e1) 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1Cov(x1,e1) 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1􏱧2e1. Thus, in the CEV case, the OLS regression of y on x1 gives a biased and inconsistent estimator. Using the asymptotic results in Chapter 5, we can determine the amount of inconsis- tency in OLS. The probability limit of 􏱬ˆ1 is 􏱬1 plus the ratio of the covariance between x1 and u 􏱦 􏱬1e1 and the variance of x1: Cov(x ,u􏱦􏱬 e ) plim(􏱬ˆ1)􏱪􏱬1􏱕_____1_______1_1_ Var(x1) where we have used the fact that Var(x1) 􏱪 Var(x*1) 􏱕 Var(e1). Equation (9.33) is very interesting. The term multiplying 􏱬1, which is the ratio Var (x*1)/ Var(x1), is always less than one [an implication of the CEV assumption (9.31)]. Thus, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱬 􏱧2 ______1__ 􏱪􏱬􏱦1e 1 􏱧 2x *1 􏱕 􏱧 2e 1 [9.33] 1 _____e 1___ 􏱪 􏱬 􏱓1 􏱦 􏱧2 􏰱 􏱓􏱧2* 􏰱 􏱪􏱬1 _____x1___ , 􏱧 2x *1 􏱕 􏱧 2e 1 2 􏱧 x *1 􏱕 􏱧 2e 1 322 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data plim(􏱬ˆ1) is always closer to zero than is 􏱬1. This is called the attenuation bias in OLS due to classical errors-in-variables: on average (or in large samples), the estimated OLS effect will be attenuated. In particular, if 􏱬1 is positive, 􏱬ˆ1 will tend to underestimate 􏱬1. This is an important conclusion, but it relies on the CEV setup. If the variance of x*1 is large relative to the variance in the measurement error, then the inconsistency in OLS will be small. This is because Var(x*1)/Var(x1) will be close to unity when 􏱧2x*1/􏱧2e1 is large. Therefore, depending on how much variation there is in x*1 relative to e1, measurement error need not cause large biases. Things are more complicated when we add more explanatory variables. For illustra- tion, consider the model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x*1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u, [9.34] where the first of the three explanatory variables is measured with error. We make the natural assumption that u is uncorrelated with x*1, x2, x3, and x1. Again, the crucial assump- tion concerns the measurement error e1. In almost all cases, e1 is assumed to be uncor- related with x2 and x3—the explanatory variables not measured with error. The key issue is whether e1 is uncorrelated with x1. If it is, then the OLS regression of y on x1, x2, and x3 produces consistent estimators. This is easily seen by writing y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕􏱬3x3 􏱕u􏱦􏱬1e1, [9.35] where u and e1 are both uncorrelated with all the explanatory variables. Under the CEV assumption in (9.31), OLS will be biased and inconsistent, because e1 is correlated with x1 in equation (9.35). Remember, this means that, in general, all OLS estima- tors will be biased, not just 􏱬ˆ1. What about the attenuation bias derived in equation (9.33)? It turns out that there is still an attenuation bias for estimating 􏱬1: it can be shown that 􏱧2* plim(􏱬ˆ)􏱪􏱬 ____r_1___, [9.36] 1 1 􏱵 􏱧 2r *1 􏱕 􏱧 2e 1 􏱷 where r*1 is the population error in the equation x*1 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1x2 􏱕 􏱮2x3 􏱕 r*1. Formula (9.36) also works in the general k variable case when x1 is the only mismeasured variable. Things are less clear-cut for estimating the 􏱬j on the variables not measured with error. In the special case that x*1 is uncorrelated with x2 and x3, 􏱬ˆ2 and 􏱬ˆ3 are consistent. But this is rare in practice. Generally, measurement error in a single variable causes inconsis- tency in all estimators. Unfortunately, the sizes, and even the directions of the biases, are not easily derived. EXAMPLE 9.7 GPA EQUATION WITH MEASUREMENT ERROR Consider the problem of estimating the effect of family income on college grade point average, after controlling for hsGPA (high school grade point average) and SAT (scholastic aptitude test). It could be that, though family income is important for performance before college, it has no direct effect on college performance. To test this, we might postulate the model colGPA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 faminc* 􏱕 􏱬2hsGPA 􏱕 􏱬3SAT 􏱕 u, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 323 where faminc* is actual annual family income. (This might appear in logarithmic form, but for the sake of illustration we leave it in level form.) Precise data on colGPA, hsGPA, and SAT are relatively easy to obtain. But family income, especially as reported by stu- dents, could be easily mismeasured. If faminc 􏱪 faminc* 􏱕 e1 and the CEV assumptions hold, then using reported family income in place of actual family income will bias the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 toward zero. One consequence of the downward bias is that a test of H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 will have less chance of detecting 􏱬1 􏱰 0. Of course, measurement error can be present in more than one explanatory variable, or in some explanatory variables and the dependent variable. As we discussed earlier, any measurement error in the dependent variable is usually assumed to be uncorrelated with all the explanatory variables, whether it is observed or not. Deriving the bias in the OLS estimators under extensions of the CEV assumptions is complicated and does not lead to clear results. In some cases, it is clear that the CEV assumption in (9.31) cannot be true. Consider a variant on Example 9.7: colGPA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1smoked* 􏱕 􏱬2hsGPA 􏱕 􏱬3SAT 􏱕 u, where smoked* is the actual number of times a student smoked marijuana in the last 30 days. The variable smoked is the answer to this question: On how many separate occasions did you smoke marijuana in the last 30 days? Suppose we postulate the standard measurement error model smoked 􏱪 smoked* 􏱕 e1. Even if we assume that students try to report the truth, the CEV assumption is unlikely to hold. People who do not smoke marijuana at all—so that smoked* 􏱪 0—are likely to report smoked 􏱪 0, so the measurement error is probably zero for students who never smoke mari- juana. When smoked* 􏱰 0, it is much more likely that the student miscounts how many times he or she smoked marijuana in the last 30 days. This means that the measurement error e1 and the actual number of times smoked, smoked*, are correlated, which violates the CEV assumption in (9.31). Unfortunately, deriving the implications of measurement error that do not satisfy (9.29) or (9.31) is difficult and beyond the scope of this text. Before leaving this section, we emphasize that the CEV assumption (9.31), while more believable than assumption (9.29), is still a strong assumption. The truth is probably somewhere in between, and if e1 is correlated with both x*1 and x1, OLS is inconsistent. This raises an important question: Must we live with inconsistent estimators under classical errors-in-variables, or other kinds of measurement error that are correlated with x1? Fortunately, the answer is no. Chapter 15 shows how, under certain assumptions, the parameters can be consistently estimated in the presence of general measurement error. We postpone this discussion until later because it requires us to leave the realm of OLS estimation. (See Problem 7 for how multiple measures can be used to reduce the attenuation bias.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 9.3 Let educ* be actual amount of schooling, measured in years (which can be a non- integer), and let educ be reported highest grade completed. Do you think educ and educ* are related by the classical errors- in-variables model? 324 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data 9.5 Missing Data, Nonrandom Samples, and Outlying Observations The measurement error problem discussed in the previous section can be viewed as a data problem: we cannot obtain data on the variables of interest. Further, under the classical errors-in-variables model, the composite error term is correlated with the mismeasured independent variable, violating the Gauss-Markov assumptions. Another data problem we discussed frequently in earlier chapters is multicollinearity among the explanatory variables. Remember that correlation among the explanatory vari- ables does not violate any assumptions. When two independent variables are highly corre- lated, it can be difficult to estimate the partial effect of each. But this is properly reflected in the usual OLS statistics. In this section, we provide an introduction to data problems that can violate the random sampling assumption, MLR.2. We can isolate cases in which nonrandom sam- pling has no practical effect on OLS. In other cases, nonrandom sampling causes the OLS estimators to be biased and inconsistent. A more complete treatment that establishes sev- eral of the claims made here is given in Chapter 17. Missing Data The missing data problem can arise in a variety of forms. Often, we collect a random sample of people, schools, cities, and so on, and then discover later that information is missing on some key variables for several units in the sample. For example, in the data set BWGHT.RAW, 197 of the 1,388 observations have no information on either mother’s education, father’s education, or both. In the data set on median starting law school sala- ries, LAWSCH85.RAW, six of the 156 schools have no reported information on median LSAT scores for the entering class; other variables are also missing for some of the law schools. If data are missing for an observation on either the dependent variable or one of the independent variables, then the observation cannot be used in a standard multiple regres- sion analysis. In fact, provided missing data have been properly indicated, all modern regression packages keep track of missing data and simply ignore observations when com- puting a regression. We saw this explicitly in the birth weight scenario in Example 4.9, when 197 observations were dropped due to missing information on parents’ education. Other than reducing the sample size available for a regression, are there any statistical consequences of missing data? It depends on why the data are missing. If the data are miss- ing at random, then the size of the random sample available from the population is simply reduced. Although this makes the estimators less precise, it does not introduce any bias: the random sampling assumption, MLR.2, still holds. There are ways to use the information on observations where only some variables are missing, but this is not often done in practice. The improvement in the estimators is usually slight, while the methods are somewhat com- plicated. In most cases, we just ignore the observations that have missing information. Nonrandom Samples Missing data are more problematic when it results in a nonrandom sample from the pop- ulation. For example, in the birth weight data set, what if the probability that education is missing is higher for those people with lower than average levels of education? Or, in Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 325 Section 9.2, we used a wage data set that included IQ scores. This data set was constructed by omitting several people from the sample for whom IQ scores were not available. If obtaining an IQ score is easier for those with higher IQs, the sample is not representa- tive of the population. The random sampling assumption MLR.2 is violated, and we must worry about these consequences for OLS estimation. Fortunately, certain types of nonrandom sampling do not cause bias or inconsistency in OLS. Under the Gauss-Markov assumptions (but without MLR.2), it turns out that the sample can be chosen on the basis of the independent variables without causing any sta- tistical problems. This is called sample selection based on the independent variables, and it is an example of exogenous sample selection. To illustrate, suppose that we are esti- mating a saving function, where annual saving depends on income, age, family size, and perhaps some other factors. A simple model is saving 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1income 􏱕 􏱬2age 􏱕 􏱬3size 􏱕 u. [9.37] Suppose that our data set was based on a survey of people over 35 years of age, thereby leaving us with a nonrandom sample of all adults. While this is not ideal, we can still get unbiased and consistent estimators of the parameters in the population model (9.37), using the nonrandom sample. We will not show this formally here, but the reason OLS on the nonrandom sample is unbiased is that the regression function E(saving􏰫income,age,size) is the same for any subset of the population described by income, age, or size. Provided there is enough variation in the independent variables in the subpopulation, selection on the basis of the independent variables is not a serious problem, other than that it results in smaller sample sizes. In the IQ example just mentioned, things are not so clear-cut, because no fixed rule based on IQ is used to include someone in the sample. Rather, the probability of being in the sample increases with IQ. If the other factors determining selection into the sample are independent of the error term in the wage equation, then we have another case of exog- enous sample selection, and OLS using the selected sample will have all of its desirable properties under the other Gauss-Markov assumptions. The situation is much different when selection is based on the dependent variable, y, which is called sample selection based on the dependent variable and is an example of endogenous sample selection. If the sample is based on whether the dependent variable is above or below a given value, bias always occurs in OLS in estimating the popula- tion model. For example, suppose we wish to estimate the relationship between individual wealth and several other factors in the population of all adults: wealth 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 u. [9.38] Suppose that only people with wealth below $250,000 are included in the sample. This is a nonrandom sample from the population of interest, and it is based on the value of the dependent variable. Using a sample on people with wealth below $250,000 will result in biased and inconsistent estimators of the parameters in (9.32). Briefly, this occurs because the population regression E(wealth􏰫educ,exper,age) is not the same as the expected value conditional on wealth being less than $250,000. Other sampling schemes lead to nonrandom samples from the population, usually inten- tionally. A common method of data collection is stratified sampling, in which the popula- tion is divided into nonoverlapping, exhaustive groups, or strata. Then, some groups are sampled more frequently than is dictated by their population representation, and some groups are sampled less frequently. For example, some surveys purposely oversample minority Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 326 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data groups or low-income groups. Whether special methods are needed again hinges on whether the stratification is exogenous (based on exogenous explanatory variables) or endogenous (based on the dependent variable). Suppose that a survey of military personnel oversampled women because the initial interest was in studying the factors that determine pay for women in the military. (Oversampling a group that is relatively small in the population is common in collecting stratified samples.) Provided men were sampled as well, we can use OLS on the stratified sample to estimate any gender differential, along with the returns to education and experience for all military personnel. (We might be willing to assume that the returns to education and experience are not gender specific.) OLS is unbiased and consistent because the stratification is with respect to an explanatory variable, namely, gender. If, instead, the survey oversampled lower-paid military personnel, then OLS using the stratified sample does not consistently estimate the parameters of the military wage equa- tion because the stratification is endogenous. In such cases, special econometric methods are needed [see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19)]. Stratified sampling is a fairly obvious form of nonrandom sampling. Other sample selection issues are more subtle. For instance, in several previous examples, we have es- timated the effects of various variables, particularly education and experience, on hourly wage. The data set WAGE1.RAW that we have used throughout is essentially a random sample of working individuals. Labor economists are often interested in estimating the effect of, say, education on the wage offer. The idea is this: every person of working age faces an hourly wage offer, and he or she can either work at that wage or not work. For someone who does work, the wage offer is just the wage earned. For people who do not work, we usually cannot observe the wage offer. Now, since the wage offer equation log(wageo) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 u [9.39] represents the population of all working-age people, we cannot estimate it using a random sample from this population; instead, we have data on the wage offer only for working people (although we can get data on educ and exper for nonworking people). If we use a random sample on working people to estimate (9.39), will we get unbiased estimators? This case is not clear-cut. Since the sample is selected based on someone’s decision to work (as opposed to the size of the wage offer), this is not like the previous case. However, since the decision to work might be related to unobserved factors that affect the wage offer, selection might be endogenous, and this can result in a sample selection bias in the OLS estimators. We will cover methods that can be used to test and correct for sample selection bias in Chapter 17. Outliers and Influential Observations In some applications, especially, but not only, with small data sets, the OLS estimates are sensitive to the inclusion of one or several observations. A complete treatment of outliers and influential observations is beyond the scope of this book, because a formal develop- ment requires matrix algebra. Loosely speaking, an observation is an influential obser- vation if dropping it from the analysis changes the key OLS estimates by a practically Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 9.4 Suppose we are interested in the effects of campaign expenditures by incumbents on voter support. Some incumbents choose not to run for reelection. If we can only collect voting and spending outcomes on incum- bents that actually do run, is there likely to be endogenous sample selection? CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 327 “large” amount. The notion of an outlier is also a bit vague, because it requires comparing values of the variables for one observation with those for the remaining sample. Neverthe- less, one wants to be on the lookout for “unusual” observations because they can greatly affect the OLS estimates. OLS is susceptible to outlying observations because it minimizes the sum of squared residuals: large residuals (positive or negative) receive a lot of weight in the least squares minimization problem. If the estimates change by a practically large amount when we slightly modify our sample, we should be concerned. When statisticians and econometricians study the problem of outliers theoretically, sometimes the data are viewed as being from a random sample from a given population— albeit with an unusual distribution that can result in extreme values—and sometimes the outliers are assumed to come from a different population. From a practical perspective, outlying observations can occur for two reasons. The easiest case to deal with is when a mistake has been made in entering the data. Adding extra zeros to a number or misplacing a decimal point can throw off the OLS estimates, especially in small sample sizes. It is always a good idea to compute summary statistics, especially minimums and maximums, in order to catch mistakes in data entry. Unfortunately, incorrect entries are not always obvious. Outliers can also arise when sampling from a small population if one or several mem- bers of the population are very different in some relevant aspect from the rest of the popu- lation. The decision to keep or drop such observations in a regression analysis can be a difficult one, and the statistical properties of the resulting estimators are complicated. Outlying observations can provide important information by increasing the variation in the explanatory variables (which reduces standard errors). But OLS results should prob- ably be reported with and without outlying observations in cases where one or several data points substantially change the results. EXAMPLE 9.8 R&D INTENSITY AND FIRM SIZE Suppose that R&D expenditures as a percentage of sales (rdintens) are related to sales (in millions) and profits as a percentage of sales ( profmarg): rdintens 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sales 􏱕 􏱬2 profmarg 􏱕 u. The OLS equation using data on 32 chemical companies in RDCHEM.RAW is Neither sales nor profmarg is statistically significant at even the 10% level in this regression. Of the 32 firms, 31 have annual sales less than $20 billion. One firm has annual sales of almost $40 billion. Figure 9.1 shows how far this firm is from the rest of the sample. In terms of sales, this firm is over twice as large as every other firm, so it might be a good idea to estimate the model without it. When we do this, we obtain 􏱾rdintens 􏱪 2.625 􏱕 .000053 sales 􏱕 .0446 profmarg (0.586) (.000044) (.0462) n􏱪32,R2 􏱪.0761,R-2 􏱪.0124. 􏱾rdintens􏱪 2.297 􏱕 .000186 sales 􏱕 .0478 profmarg (0.592) (.000084) (.0445) n􏱪31,R2 􏱪.1728,R-2 􏱪.1137. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. [9.40] 328 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data F I G U R E 9 . 1 Scatterplot of R&D intensity against firm sales. 10 R&D as a percentage of sales 5 0 possible outlier 10,000 20,000 firm sales (in millions of dollars) 30,000 40,000 When the largest firm is dropped from the regression, the coefficient on sales more than triples, and it now has a t statistic over two. Using the sample of smaller firms, we would conclude that there is a statistically significant positive effect between R&D intensity and firm size. The profit margin is still not significant, and its coefficient has not changed by much. Sometimes, outliers are defined by the size of the residual in an OLS regression, where all of the observations are used. Generally, this is not a good idea because the OLS esti- mates adjust to make the sum of squared residuals as small as possible. In the previous example, including the largest firm flattened the OLS regression line considerably, which made the residual for that estimation not especially large. In fact, the residual for the largest firm is 􏱦1.62 when all 32 observations are used. This value of the residual is not even one estimated standard deviation, 􏱧ˆ 􏱪 1.82, from the mean of the residuals, which is zero by construction. Studentized residuals are obtained from the original OLS residuals by dividing them by an estimate of their standard deviation (conditional on the explanatory variables in the sample). The formula for the studentized residuals relies on matrix algebra, but it turns out there is a simple trick to compute a studentized residual for any observation. Namely, define a dummy variable equal to one for that observation—say, observation h—and then include the dummy variable in the regression (using all observations) along with the other explana- tory variables. The coefficient on the dummy variable has a useful interpretation: it is the re- sidual for observation h computed from the regression line using only the other observations. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 329 Therefore, the dummy’s coefficient can be used to see how far off the observation is from the regression line obtained without using that observation. Even better, the t statistic on the dummy variable is equal to the studentized residual for observation h. Under the classical linear model assumptions, this t statistic has a tn􏱦k􏱦2 distribution. Therefore, a large value of the t statistic (in absolute value) implies a large residual relative to its estimated standard deviation. For Example 9.8, if we define a dummy variable for the largest firm (observation 10 in the data file), and include it as an additional regressor, its coefficient is 􏱦6.57, verify- ing that the observation for the largest firm is very far from the regression line obtained using the other observations. However, when studentized, the residual is only 􏱦1.82. While this is a marginally significant t statistic (two-sided p-value 􏱪 .08), it is not close to being the largest studentized residual in the sample. If we use the same method for the observation with the highest value of rdintens—the first observation, with rdintens 􏱴 9.42—the coefficient on the dummy variable is 6.72 with a t statistic of 4.56. Therefore, by this measure, the first observation is more of an outlier than the tenth. Yet dropping the first observation changes the coefficient on sales by only a small amount (to about .000051 from .000053), although the coefficient on profmarg becomes larger and sta- tistically significant. So, is the first observation an “outlier” too? These calculations show the conundrum one can enter when trying to determine observations that should be excluded from a regression analysis, even when the data set is small. Unfortunately, the size of the studentized residual need not correspond to how influential an observation is for the OLS slope estimates, and certainly not for all of them at once. A general problem with using studentized residuals is that, in effect, all other ob- servations are used to estimate the regression line to compute the residual for a particu- lar observation. In other words, when the studentized residual is obtained for the first observation, the tenth observation has been used in estimating the intercept and slope. Given how flat the regression line is with the largest firm (tenth observation) included, it is not too surprising that the first observation, with its high value of rdintens, is far off the regression line. Of course, we can add two dummy variables at the same time—one for the first obser- vation and one for the tenth—which has the effect of using only the remaining 30 observa- tions to estimate the regression line. If we estimate the equation without the first and tenth observations, the results are 􏱾rdintens 􏱪 1.939 􏱕 .000160 sales 􏱕 .0701 profmarg (0.459) (.00065) (.0343) n 􏱪 30, R2 􏱪 .2711,R-2 􏱪 .2171 The coefficient on the dummy for the first observation is 6.47 (t 􏱪 4.58), and for the tenth observation it is 􏱦5.41 (t 􏱪 􏱦1.95). Notice that the coefficients on the sales and profmarg are both statistically significant, the latter at just about the 5% level against a two-sided alternative ( p-value 􏱪 .051). Even in this regression there are still two observations with studentized residuals greater than two (corresponding to the two remaining observations with R&D intensities above six). Certain functional forms are less sensitive to outlying observations. In Section 6.2 we mentioned that, for most economic variables, the logarithmic transformation significantly narrows the range of the data and also yields functional forms—such as constant elasticity models—that can explain a broader range of data. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 330 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data EXAMPLE 9.9 R&D INTENSITY We can test whether R&D intensity increases with firm size by starting with the model rd 􏱪 sales􏱬1exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬2 profmarg 􏱕 u). [9.41] Then, holding other factors fixed, R&D intensity increases with sales if and only if 􏱬1 􏱰 1. Taking the log of (9.41) gives log(rd ) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2 profmarg 􏱕 u. When we use all 32 firms, the regression equation is [9.42] 􏱾log(rd) 􏱪 􏱦4.378 􏱕 1.084 log(sales) 􏱕 .0217 profmarg, (.468) (.060) (.0128) n􏱪32,R2 􏱪.9180,R-2 􏱪.9123, while dropping the largest firm gives 􏱾log(rd) 􏱪 􏱦4.404 􏱕 1.088 log(sales) 􏱕 .0218 profmarg, (.511) (.067) (.0130) n􏱪31,R2 􏱪.9037,R-2 􏱪.8968. Practically, these results are the same. In neither case do we reject the null H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 1 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱰 1. (Why?) In some cases, certain observations are suspected at the outset of being fundamen- tally different from the rest of the sample. This often happens when we use data at very aggregated levels, such as the city, county, or state level. The following is an example. EXAMPLE 9.10 STATE INFANT MORTALITY RATES Data on infant mortality, per capita income, and measures of health care can be obtained at the state level from the Statistical Abstract of the United States. We will provide a fairly simple analysis here just to illustrate the effect of outliers. The data are for the year 1990, and we have all 50 states in the United States, plus the District of Columbia (D.C.). The variable infmort is number of deaths within the first year per 1,000 live births, pcinc is per capita income, physic is physicians per 100,000 members of the civilian population, and popul is the population (in thousands). The data are contained in INFMRT.RAW. We include all independent variables in logarithmic form: [9.43] 􏱾 infmort 􏱪 33.86 􏱦 4.68 log( pcinc) 􏱕 4.15 log(physic) (20.43) (2.60) (1.51) 􏱦.088 log(popul) (.287) - n 􏱪 51, R2 􏱪 .139, R2 􏱪 .084. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 331 Higher per capita income is estimated to lower infant mortality, an expected result. But more physicians per capita is associated with higher infant mortality rates, something that is counterintuitive. Infant mortality rates do not appear to be related to population size. The District of Columbia is unusual in that it has pockets of extreme poverty and great wealth in a small area. In fact, the infant mortality rate for D.C. in 1990 was 20.7, compared with 12.4 for the highest state. It also has 615 physicians per 100,000 of the civilian population, compared with 337 for the highest state. The high number of physi- cians coupled with the high infant mortality rate in D.C. could certainly influence the results. If we drop D.C. from the regression, we obtain 􏱾infmort 􏱪 23.95 􏱦 .57 log(pcinc) 􏱦 2.74 log(physic) (12.42) (1.64) (1.19) 􏱕 .629 log(popul) (.191) - n 􏱪 50, R2 􏱪 .273, R2 􏱪 .226. [9.44] We now find that more physicians per capita lowers infant mortality, and the estimate is statistically different from zero at the 5% level. The effect of per capita income has fallen sharply and is no longer statistically significant. In equation (9.44), infant mortality rates are higher in more populous states, and the relationship is very statistically significant. Also, much more variation in infmort is explained when D.C. is dropped from the regres- sion. Clearly, D.C. had substantial influence on the initial estimates, and we would prob- ably leave it out of any further analysis. As Example 9.8 demonstrates, inspecting observations in trying to determine which are outliers, and even which ones have substantial influence on the OLS estimates, is a difficult endeavor. More advanced treatments allow more formal approaches to determine which observations are likely to be influential observations. Using matrix algebra, Bels- ley, Kuh, and Welsh (1980) define the leverage of an observation, which formalizes the notion that an observation has a large or small influence on the OLS estimates. These au- thors also provide a more in-depth discussion of standardized and studentized residuals. 9.6 Least Absolute Deviations Estimation Rather than trying to determine which observations, if any, have undue influence on the OLS estimates, a different approach to guarding against outliers is to use an estimation method that is less sensitive to outliers than OLS. One such method, which has become popular among applied econometricians, is called least absolute deviations (LAD). The LAD estimators of the 􏱬j in a linear model minimize the sum of the absolute values of the residuals, ∑n b0,b1,...,bk i􏱪1 Unlike OLS, which minimizes the sum of squared residuals, the LAD estimates are not available in closed form—that is, we cannot write down formulas for them. In fact, his- torically, solving the problem in equation (9.45) was computationally difficult, especially Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. min 􏰫y􏱦b􏱦bx 􏱦...􏱦bx􏰫. [9.45] i 0 1 i1 k ik 332 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data FIGURE 9.2 The OLS and LAD objective functions. 15 10 5 0 OLS LAD –4 –2 0 2 4 u with large sample sizes and many explanatory variables. But with the vast improvements in computational speed over the past two decades, LAD estimates are fairly easy to obtain even for large data sets. Figure 9.2 shows the OLS and LAD objective functions. The LAD objective function is linear on either side of zero, so that if, say, a positive residual increases by one unit, the LAD objective function increases by one unit. By contrast, the OLS objective function gives increasing importance to large residuals, and this makes OLS more sensitive to outlying observations. Because LAD does not give increasing weight to larger residuals, it is much less sen- sitive to changes in the extreme values of the data than OLS. In fact, it is known that LAD is designed to estimate the parameters of the conditional median of y given x1, x2, ..., xk rather than the conditional mean. Because the median is not affected by large changes in the extreme observations, it follows that the LAD parameter estimates are more resilient to outlying observations. (See Section A.1 for a brief discussion of the sample median.) In choosing the estimates, OLS squares each residual, and so the OLS estimates can be very sensitive to outlying observations, as we saw in Examples 9.8 and 9.10. In addition to LAD being more computationally intensive than OLS, a second draw- back of LAD is that all statistical inference involving the LAD estimators is justified only as the sample size grows. [The formulas are somewhat complicated and require matrix algebra, and we do not need them here. Koenker (2005) provides a comprehensive treatment.] Recall that, under the classical linear model assumptions, the OLS t statistics have exact t distributions, and F statistics have exact F distributions. While asymptotic versions of these statistics are available for LAD—and reported routinely by software packages that compute LAD estimates—these are justified only in large samples. Like the additional computa- tional burden involved in computing LAD estimates, the lack of exact inference for LAD is only of minor concern, because most applications of LAD involve several hundred, if not Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 333 several thousand, observations. Of course, we might be pushing it if we apply large-sample approximations in an example such as Example 9.8, with n 􏱪 32. In a sense, this is not very different from OLS because, more often than not, we must appeal to large sample approxi- mations to justify OLS inference whenever any of the CLM assumptions fail. A more subtle but important drawback to LAD is that it does not always consistently estimate the parameters appearing in the conditional mean function, E(y􏰫x1, ..., xk). As men- tioned earlier, LAD is intended to estimate the effects on the conditional median. Generally, the mean and median are the same only when the distribution of y given the covariates x1, ..., xk is symmetric about 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk. (Equivalently, the population error term, u, is symmetric about zero.) Recall that OLS produces unbiased and consistent estimators of the parameters in the conditional mean whether or not the error distribution is symmetric; symmetry does not appear among the Gauss-Markov assumptions. When LAD and OLS are applied to cases with asymmetric distributions, the estimated partial effect of, say, x1, obtained from LAD can be very different from the partial effect obtained from OLS. But such a difference could just reflect the difference between the median and the mean and might not have anything to do with outliers. See Computer Exercise C9 for an example. If we assume that the population error u in model (9.2) is independent of (x1, ..., xk), then the OLS and LAD slope estimates should differ only by sampling error whether or not the distribution of u is symmetric. The intercept estimates generally will be different to reflect the fact that, if the mean of u is zero, then its median is different from zero under asymmetry. Unfortunately, independence between the error and the explanatory variables is often unrealistically strong when LAD is applied. In particular, independence rules out het- eroskedasticity, a problem that often arises in applications with asymmetric distributions. An advantage that LAD has over OLS is that, because LAD estimates the median, it is easy to obtain partial effects—and predictions—using monotonic transformations. Here we consider the most common transformation, taking the natural log. Suppose that log(y) follows a linear model where the error has a zero conditional median: log(y) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬 􏱕 u [9.46] Med(u|x) 􏱪 0, [9.47] which implies that Med[log(y)|x] 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬 A well-known feature of the conditional median—see, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 12)—is that it passes through increasing functions. Therefore, Med(y|x) 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬). [9.48] It follows that 􏱬j is the semi-elasticity of Med(y|x) with respect to xj. In other words, the partial effect of xj in the linear equation (9.46) can be used to uncover the partial effect in the nonlinear model (9.48). It is important to understand that this holds for any distribution of u such that (9.47) holds, and we need not assume u and x are independent. By contrast, if we specify a linear model for E[log(y)|x] then, in general, there is no way to uncover E(y|x). If we make a full distributional assumption for u given x then, in principle, we can recover E(y|x). We covered the special case in equation (6.40) under the assumption that log(y) follows a classical linear model. However, in general there is no way to find E(y|x) from a model for E[log(y)|x], even though we can always obtain Med(y|x) from Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 334 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Med[log(y)|x]. Problem 9 investigates how heteroskedasticity in a linear model for log(y) confounds our ability to find E(y|x). Least absolute deviations is a special case of what is often called robust regression. Unfortunately, the way “robust” is used here can be confusing. In the statistics literature, a robust regression estimator is relatively insensitive to extreme observations. Effectively, observations with large residuals are given less weight than in least squares. [Berk (1990) contains an introductory treatment of estimators that are robust to outlying observations.] Based on our earlier discussion, in econometric parlance, LAD is not a robust estimator of the conditional mean because it requires extra assumptions in order to consistently esti- mate the conditional mean parameters. In equation (9.2), either the distribution of u given (x1, ..., xk) has to be symmetric about zero, or u must be independent of (x1, ..., xk). Neither of these is required for OLS. LAD is also a special case of quantile regression, which is used to estimate the effect of the xj on different parts of the distribution—not just the median (or mean). For example, in a study to see how having access to a particular pension plan affects wealth, it could be that access affects high-wealth people differently from low-wealth people, and these effects both differ from the median person. Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 12) contains a treatment and examples of quantile regression. Summary We have further investigated some important specification and data issues that often arise in empirical cross-sectional analysis. Misspecified functional form makes the estimated equation difficult to interpret. Nevertheless, incorrect functional form can be detected by adding quadrat- ics, computing RESET, or testing against a nonnested alternative model using the Davidson- MacKinnon test. No additional data collection is needed. Solving the omitted variables problem is more difficult. In Section 9.2, we discussed a possible solution based on using a proxy variable for the omitted variable. Under reasonable assumptions, including the proxy variable in an OLS regression eliminates, or at least reduces, bias. The hurdle in applying this method is that proxy variables can be difficult to find. A gen- eral possibility is to use data on a dependent variable from a prior year. Applied economists are often concerned with measurement error. Under the classical errors- in-variables (CEV) assumptions, measurement error in the dependent variable has no effect on the statistical properties of OLS. In contrast, under the CEV assumptions for an independent vari- able, the OLS estimator for the coefficient on the mismeasured variable is biased toward zero. The bias in coefficients on the other variables can go either way and is difficult to determine. Nonrandom samples from an underlying population can lead to biases in OLS. When sam- ple selection is correlated with the error term u, OLS is generally biased and inconsistent. On the other hand, exogenous sample selection—which is either based on the explanatory variables or is otherwise independent of u—does not cause problems for OLS. Outliers in data sets can have large impacts on the OLS estimates, especially in small samples. It is important to at least informally identify outliers and to reestimate models with the suspected outliers excluded. Least absolute deviations estimation is an alternative to OLS that is less sensitive to outliers and that delivers consistent estimates of conditional median parameters. In the past 20 years, with computational advances and improved understanding of the pros and cons of LAD and OLS, LAD is used more and more in empirical research–often as a supplement to OLS. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Key Terms Attenuation Bias Average Marginal Effect Average Partial Effect (APE) Classical Errors-in-Variables (CEV) Conditional Median Davidson-MacKinnon Test Endogenous Explanatory Variable Endogenous Sample Selection Exogenous Sample Functional Form Misspecification Influential Observations Lagged Dependent Variable Least Absolute Deviations (LAD) Measurement Error Missing Data Multiplicative Measurement Error Nonnested Models Nonrandom Sample Outliers Plug-In Solution to the Omitted Variables Problem Proxy Variable Random Coefficient (Slope) Model Regression Specification Error Test (RESET) Stratified Sampling Studentized Residuals CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 335 Selection Problems 1 In Problem 11 in Chapter 4, the R-squared from estimating the model log(salary) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2log(mktval) 􏱕 􏱬3 profmarg 􏱕 􏱬4ceoten 􏱕 􏱬5comten 􏱕 u, using the data in CEOSAL2.RAW, was R2 􏱪 .353 (n 􏱪 177). When ceoten2 and comten2 are added, R2 􏱪 .375. Is there evidence of functional form misspecification in this model? 2 LetusmodifyComputerExerciseC4inChapter8byusingvotingoutcomesin1990for incumbents who were elected in 1988. Candidate A was elected in 1988 and was seeking reelection in 1990; voteA90 is Candidate A’s share of the two-party vote in 1990. The 1988 voting share of Candidate A is used as a proxy variable for quality of the candidate. All other variables are for the 1990 election. The following equations were estimated, using the data in VOTE2.RAW: and 􏱾voteA90 􏱪 75.71 􏱕 .312 prtystrA 􏱕 4.93 democA (9.25) (.046) (1.01) 􏱦.929 log(expendA) 􏱦 1.950 log(expendB) (.684) - (.281) n􏱪186,R2 􏱪.495,R2 􏱪.483, 􏱾voteA90 􏱪 70.81 􏱕 .282 prtystrA 􏱕 4.52 democA (10.01) (.052) (1.06) 􏱦.839 log(expendA) 􏱦 1.846 log(expendB) 􏱕 .067 voteA88 (.687) - (.292) (.053) n 􏱪 186, R2 􏱪 .499,R2 􏱪 .485. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 336 PART 1 (i) (ii) Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data Interpret the coefficient on voteA88 and discuss its statistical significance. Does adding voteA88 have much effect on the other coefficients? 3 Let math10 denote the percentage of students at a Michigan high school receiving a passing score on a standardized math test (see also Example 4.2). We are interested in estimating the effect of per student spending on math performance. A simple model is math10 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(expend) 􏱕 􏱬2log(enroll) 􏱕 􏱬3 poverty 􏱕 u, where poverty is the percentage of students living in poverty. (i) The variable lnchprg is the percentage of students eligible for the federally funded school lunch program. Why is this a sensible proxy variable for poverty? (ii) The table that follows contains OLS estimates, with and without lnchprg as an explanatory variable. Dependent Variable: math10 Independent Variables (1) (2) log(expend) 11.13 (3.30) 7.75 (3.04) log(enroll) .022 (.615) –1.26 (.58) lnchprg — –.324 (.036) intercept 􏱦69.24 (26.72) 􏱦23.14 (24.99) Observations R-squared 428 .0297 428 .1893 Explain why the effect of expenditures on math10 is lower in column (2) than in col- umn (1). Is the effect in column (2) still statistically greater than zero? (iii) Does it appear that pass rates are lower at larger schools, other factors being equal? Explain. (iv) Interpret the coefficient on lnchprg in column (2). (v) What do you make of the substantial increase in R2 from column (1) to column (2)? 4 Thefollowingequationexplainsweeklyhoursoftelevisionviewingbyachildintermsof the child’s age, mother’s education, father’s education, and number of siblings: tvhours* 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1age 􏱕 􏱬2age2 􏱕 􏱬3motheduc 􏱕 􏱬4 fatheduc 􏱕 􏱬5sibs 􏱕 u. We are worried that tvhours* is measured with error in our survey. Let tvhours denote the reported hours of television viewing per week. (i) What do the classical errors-in-variables (CEV) assumptions require in this application? (ii) Do you think the CEV assumptions are likely to hold? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 [Hint: The plim of 􏱬- 1 CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 337 5 InExample4.4,weestimatedamodelrelatingnumberofcampuscrimestostudentenroll- ment for a sample of colleges. The sample we used was not a random sample of colleges in the United States, because many schools in 1992 did not report campus crimes. Do you think that college failure to report crimes can be viewed as exogenous sample selection? Explain. 6 In the model (9.17), show that OLS consistently estimates 􏱮 and 􏱬 if ai is uncorrelated with xi and bi is uncorrelated with xi and x2i , which are weaker assumptions than (9.19). [Hint: Write the equation as in (9.18) and recall from Chapter 5 that sufficient for consis- tency of OLS for the intercept and slope is E(ui) 􏱪 0 and Cov(xi, ui) 􏱪 0.] 7 Consider the simple regression model with classical measurement error, y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x* 􏱕 u, wherewehavemmeasuresonx*.Writetheseaszh 􏱪x*􏱕eh,h􏱪1,...,m.Assumethatx* is uncorrelated with u, e1, ...., em, that the measurement errors are pairwise uncorrelated, and have the same variance, 􏱧2e. Let w 􏱪 (z 􏱕 ... 􏱕 z )/m be the average of the measures on x*, 1m so that, for each observation i, wi 􏱪 (zi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 zim)/m is the average of the m measures. Let 􏱬1 be the OLS estimator from the simple regression yi on 1, wi , i 􏱪 1, ..., n, using a random sample of data. (i) Show that - 􏱪􏱧2x* 􏲁 plim(􏱬1) 􏱪 􏱬1 _____________ . [􏱧2x* 􏱕 (􏱧2e􏱚m)] is Cov(w, y)/Var(w).] - (ii) How does the inconsistency in 􏱬1 compare with that when only a single measure is available (that is, m 􏱪 1)? What happens as m grows? Comment. 8 Thepointofthisexerciseistoshowthattestsforfunctionalformcannotbereliedonasa general test for omitted variables. Suppose that, conditional on the explanatory variables x1 and x2, a linear model relating y to x1 and x2 satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions: y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕u E(u|x1, x2) 􏱪 0 Var(u|x1, x2) 􏱪 􏱧2. To make the question interesting, assume 􏱬2 ≠ 0. Suppose further that x2 has a simple linear relationship with x1: - (i) Show that x2 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1x1 􏱕r E(r|x1) 􏱪 0 Var(r|x1)􏱪 􏰫2 E(y|x1) 􏱪 (􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬2􏱛0) 􏱕 (􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2􏱛1) x1. Under random sampling, what is the probability limit of the OLS estimator from the sim- ple regression of y on x1? Is the simple regression estimator generally consistent for 􏱬1? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 338 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data If you run the regression of y on x1, x21, what will be the probability limit of the OLS estimator of the coefficient on x21? Explain. (ii) (iii) Using substitution, show that we can write y􏱪(􏱬0 􏱕􏱬2􏱛0)􏱕(􏱬1 􏱕􏱬2􏱛1)x1 􏱕u􏱕􏱬2r Itcanbeshownthat,ifwedefinev􏱪u􏱕􏱬2rthenE(v|x1)􏱪0,Var(v|x1)􏱪􏱧2 􏱕􏱬2 􏰫2. What consequences does this have for the t statistic on x21 from the regression in part (ii)? (iv) What do you conclude about adding a nonlinear function of x1—in particular, x21—in an attempt to detect omission of x2? 9 Suppose that log(y) follows a linear model with a linear form of heteroskedasticity. We write this as log(y)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕x􏱬􏱕u u|x ~ Normal(0,h(x)), so that, conditional on x, u has a normal distribution with mean (and median) zero but with variance h(x) that depends on x. Because Med(u|x) 􏱪 0, equation (9.48) holds: Med(y|x) 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬). Further, using an extension of the result from Chapter 6, it can be shown that E(y|x) 􏱪 exp[􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬 􏱕 h(x)/2]. (i) Given that h(x) can be any positive function, is it possible to conclude ∂E(y|x)/∂xj is the same sign as 􏱬j? (ii) Suppose h(x) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 x􏱛 (and ignore the problem that linear functions are not necessarily always positive). Show that a particular variable, say x1, can have a negative effect on Med(y|x) but a positive effect on E(y|x). (iii) Consider the case covered in Section 6.4, where h(x) 􏱪 􏱧2. How would you predict y using an estimate of E(y|x)? How would you predict y using an estimate of Med(y|x)? Which prediction is always larger? Computer Exercises C1 (i) Apply RESET from equation (9.3) to the model estimated in Computer Exercise C5 in Chapter 7. Is there evidence of functional form misspecification in the equation? (ii) Compute a heteroskedasticity-robust form of RESET. Does your conclusion from part (i) change? C2 Use the data set WAGE2.RAW for this exercise. (i) Use the variable KWW (the “knowledge of the world of work” test score) as a proxy for ability in place of IQ in Example 9.3. What is the estimated return to education in this case? (ii) Now, use IQ and KWW together as proxy variables. What happens to the esti- mated return to education? (iii) In part (ii), are IQ and KWW individually significant? Are they jointly significant? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 339 the data from JTRAIN.RAW for this exercise. C3 Use (i) Consider the simple regression model log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1grant 􏱕 u, where scrap is the firm scrap rate and grant is a dummy variable indicating whether a firm received a job training grant. Can you think of some reasons why the unobserved factors in u might be correlated with grant? (ii) Estimate the simple regression model using the data for 1988. (You should have 54 observations.) Does receiving a job training grant significantly lower a firm’s scrap rate? (iii) Now, add as an explanatory variable log(scrap87). How does this change the estimated effect of grant? Interpret the coefficient on grant. Is it statistically significant at the 5% level against the one-sided alternative H1: 􏱬grant 􏱷 0? (iv) Test the null hypothesis that the parameter on log(scrap87) is one against the two-sided alternative. Report the p-value for the test. (v) Repeat parts (iii) and (iv), using heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors, and briefly discuss any notable differences. C4 Use (i) Reestimate equation (9.43), but now include a dummy variable for the observation the data for the year 1990 in INFMRT.RAW for this exercise. on the District of Columbia (called DC). Interpret the coefficient on DC and com- ment on its size and significance. (ii) Compare the estimates and standard errors from part (i) with those from equa- tion (9.44). What do you conclude about including a dummy variable for a single observation? C5 Use mates and to see how LAD is less sensitive to outliers. The model is the data in RDCHEM.RAW to further examine the effects of outliers on OLS esti- rdintens 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1sales 􏱕 􏱬2sales2 􏱕 􏱬3 profmarg 􏱕 u, where you should first change sales to be in billions of dollars to make the estimates easier to interpret. (i) Estimate the above equation by OLS, both with and without the firm having annual sales of almost $40 billion. Discuss any notable differences in the estimated coefficients. (ii) Estimate the same equation by LAD, again with and without the largest firm. Discuss any important differences in estimated coefficients. (iii) Based on your findings in (i) and (ii), would you say OLS or LAD is more resilient to outliers? C6 Redo Example 4.10 by dropping schools where teacher benefits are less than 1% of salary. (i) How many observations are lost? (ii) Does dropping these observations have any important effects on the estimated tradeoff? C7 Use the data in LOANAPP.RAW for this exercise. (i) How many observations have obrat 􏱰 40, that is, other debt obligations more than 40% of total income? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 340 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (ii) Reestimate the model in part (iii) of Computer Exercise C8, excluding observa- tions with obrat 􏱰 40. What happens to the estimate and t statistic on white? (iii) Does it appear that the estimate of 􏱬white is overly sensitive to the sample used? C8 Use (i) The variable stotal is a standardized test variable, which can act as a proxy variable for unobserved ability. Find the sample mean and standard deviation of stotal. (ii) Run simple regressions of jc and univ on stotal. Are both college education variables statistically related to stotal? Explain. (iii) Add stotal to equation (4.17) and test the hypothesis that the returns to two- and four-year colleges are the same against the alternative that the return to four-year colleges is greater. How do your findings compare with those from Section 4.4? (iv) Add stotal2 to the equation estimated in part (iii). Does a quadratic in the test score variable seem necessary? (v) Add the interaction terms stotal·jc and stotal·univ to the equation from part (iii). Are these terms jointly significant? (vi) What would be your final model that controls for ability through the use of stotal? Justify your answer. C9 In this exercise, you are to compare OLS and LAD estimates of the effects of 401(k) plan eligibility on net financial assets. The model is nettfa 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2inc2 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 􏱬4age2 􏱕 􏱬5male 􏱕 􏱬6e401k 􏱕 u. (i) Use the data in 401KSUBS.RAW to estimate the equation by OLS and report the results in the usual form. Interpret the coefficient on e401k. (ii) Use the OLS residuals to test for heteroskedasticity using the Breusch-Pagan test. Is u independent of the explanatory variables? (iii) Estimate the equation by LAD and report the results in the same form as for OLS. Interpret the LAD estimate of 􏱬6. (iv) Reconcile your findings from parts (i) and (iii). C10 You need to use two data sets for this exercise, JTRAIN2.RAW and JTRAIN3.RAW. The former is the outcome of a job training experiment. The file JTRAIN3.RAW con- tains observational data, where individuals themselves largely determine whether they participate in job training. The data sets cover the same time period. (i) In the data set JTRAIN2.RAW, what fraction of the men received job training? What is the fraction in JTRAIN3.RAW? Why do you think there is such a big difference? (ii) Using JTRAIN2.RAW, run a simple regression of re78 on train. What is the estimated effect of participating in job training on real earnings? (iii) Now add as controls to the regression in part (ii) the variables re74, re75, educ, age, black, and hisp. Does the estimated effect of job training on re78 change much? How come? (Hint: Remember that these are experimental data.) (iv) Do the regressions in parts (ii) and (iii) using the data in JTRAIN3.RAW, reporting only the estimated coefficients on train, along with their t statistics. What is the effect now of controlling for the extra factors, and why? (v) Define avgre 􏱪 (re74 􏱕 re75)/2. Find the sample averages, standard deviations, and minimum and maximum values in the two data sets. Are these data sets representative of the same populations in 1978? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in TWOYEAR.RAW for this exercise. CHAPTER 9 More on Specification and Data Issues 341 (vi) Almost 96% of men in the data set JTRAIN2.RAW have avgre less than $10,000. Using only these men, run the regression re78 on train,re74,re75,educ,age,black,hisp and report the training estimate and its t statistic. Run the same regression for JTRAIN3.RAW, using only men with avgre 􏰯 10. For the subsample of low-in- come men, how do the estimated training effects compare across the experimental and nonexperimental data sets? (vii) Now use each data set to run the simple regression re78 on train, but only for men who were unemployed in 1974 and 1975. How do the training estimates compare now? (viii) Using your findings from the previous regressions, discuss the potential impor- tance of having comparable populations underlying comparisons of experimental and nonexperimental estimates. C11 Use will need to first obtain the lagged murder rate, say mrdrte􏱦1. (i) Run the regression of mrdrte on exec, unem. What are the coefficient and t statistic C12 Use Chapter 4. the data in MURDER.RAW only for the year 1993 for this question, although you on exec? Does this regression provide any evidence for a deterrent effect of capital punishment? (ii) How many executions are reported for Texas during 1993? (Actually, this is the sum of executions for the current and past two years.) How does this compare with the other states? Add a dummy variable for Texas to the regression in part (i). Is its t sta- tistic unusually large? From this, does it appear Texas is an “outlier”? ˆ (iii) To the regression in part (i) add the lagged murder rate. What happens to 􏱬exec and its statistical significance? (iv) For the regression in part (iii), does it appear Texas is an outlier? What is the effect on 􏱬ˆexec from dropping Texas from the regression? the data in ELEM94_95 to answer this question. See also Computer Exercise C10 in (i) Using all of the data, run the regression lavgsal on bs, lenrol, lstaff, and lunch. Report the coefficient on bs along with its usual and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. What do you conclude about the economic and statistical signifi- cance of 􏱬ˆbs? (ii) Now drop the four observations with bs 􏱰.5, that is, where average benefits are (supposedly) more than 50% of average salary. What is the coefficient on bs? Is it statistically significant using the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error? (iii) Verify that the four observations with bs 􏱰.5 are 68, 1,127, 1,508, and 1,670. Define four dummy variables for each of these observations. (You might call them d68, d1127, d1508, and d1670.) Add these to the regression from part (i), .and verify that the OLS coefficients and standard errors on the other variables are identical to those in part (ii). Which of the four dummies has a t statistic statisti- cally different from zero at the 5% level? (iv) Verify that, in this data set, the data point with the largest studentized residual (largest t statistic on the dummy variable) in part (iii) has a large influence on the OLS estimates. (That is, run OLS using all observations except the one with the large studentized residual.) Does dropping, in turn, each of the other observations with bs 􏱰.5 have important effects? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 342 PART 1 Regression Analysis with Cross-Sectional Data (v) What do you conclude about the sensitivity of OLS to a single observation, even with a large sample size? (vi) Verify that the LAD estimator is not sensitive to the inclusion of the observation identified in part (iii). C13 Use the data in CEOSAL2.RAW to answer this question. (i) Estimate the model lsalary 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lsales 􏱕 􏱬2lmktval 􏱕 􏱬3ceoten 􏱕 􏱬4ceoten2 􏱕 u by OLS using all of the observations, where lsalary, lsales, and lmktvale are all natural logarithms. Report the results in the usual form with the usual OLS standard errors. (You may verify that the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors are similar.) (ii) In the regression from part (i) obtain the studentized residuals; call these stri. How many studentized residuals are above 1.96 in absolute value? If the studentized re- siduals were independent draws from a standard normal distribution, about how many would you expect to be above two in absolute value with 177 draws? (iii) Reestimate the equation in part (i) by OLS using only the observations with |stri | ≤ 1. 96. How do the coefficients compare with those in part (i)? (iv) Estimate the equation in part (i) by LAD, using all of the data. Is the estimate of 􏱬1 closer to the OLS estimate using the full sample or the restricted sample? What about for 􏱬3? (v) Evaluate the following statement: “Dropping outliers based on extreme values of studentized residuals makes the resulting OLS estimates closer to the LAD estimates on the full sample.” Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Now that we have a solid understanding of how to use the multiple regression model for cross-sectional applications, we can turn to the econometric analysis of time series data. Since we will rely heavily on the method of ordinary least squares, most of the work concerning mechanics and inference has already been done. However, as we noted in Chapter 1, time series data have certain characteristics that cross-sectional data do not, and these can require special attention when applying OLS. Chapter 10 covers basic regression analysis and gives attention to problems unique to time series data. We provide a set of Gauss-Markov and classical linear model assumptions for time series applications. The problems of functional form, dummy variables, trends, and seasonality are also discussed. Because certain time series models necessarily violate the Gauss-Markov assump- tions, Chapter 11 describes the nature of these violations and presents the large sample properties of ordinary least squares. As we can no longer assume random sampling, we must cover conditions that restrict the temporal correlation in a time series in order to ensure that the usual asymptotic analysis is valid. Chapter 12 turns to an important new problem: serial correlation in the error terms in time series regressions. We discuss the consequences, ways of testing, and methods for dealing with serial correlation. Chapter 12 also contains an explanation of how heteroskedasticity can arise in time series models. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 343 CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data In this chapter, we begin to study the properties of OLS for estimating linear regression models using time series data. In Section 10.1, we discuss some conceptual differences between time series and cross-sectional data. Section 10.2 provides some examples of time series regressions that are often estimated in the empirical social sciences. We then turn our attention to the finite sample properties of the OLS estimators and state the Gauss- Markov assumptions and the classical linear model assumptions for time series regression. Although these assumptions have features in common with those for the cross-sectional case, they also have some significant differences that we will need to highlight. In addition, we return to some issues that we treated in regression with cross-sectional data, such as how to use and interpret the logarithmic functional form and dummy vari- ables. The important topics of how to incorporate trends and account for seasonality in multiple regression are taken up in Section 10.5. 10.1 The Nature of Time Series Data An obvious characteristic of time series data that distinguishes them from cross-sectional data is temporal ordering. For example, in Chapter 1, we briefly discussed a time series data set on employment, the minimum wage, and other economic variables for Puerto Rico. In this data set, we must know that the data for 1970 immediately precede the data for 1971. For analyzing time series data in the social sciences, we must recognize that the past can affect the future, but not vice versa (unlike in the Star Trek universe). To empha- size the proper ordering of time series data, Table 10.1 gives a partial listing of the data on U.S. inflation and unemployment rates from various editions of the Economic Report of the President, including the 2004 Report (Tables B-42 and B-64). Another difference between cross-sectional and time series data is more subtle. In Chapters 3 and 4, we studied statistical properties of the OLS estimators based on the notion that samples were randomly drawn from the appropriate population. Understanding why cross-sectional data should be viewed as random outcomes is fairly straightforward: a different sample drawn from the population will generally yield different values of the independent and dependent variables (such as education, experience, wage, and so on). 344 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 345 T A B L E 1 0 . 1 Partial Listing of Data on U.S. Inflation and Unemployment Rates, 1948–2003 Year Inflation Unemployment 1948 8.1 3.8 1949 􏱦1.2 5.9 1950 1.3 5.3 1951 7.9 3.3 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 􏱳 1998 1.6 4.5 1999 2.2 4.2 2000 3.4 4.0 2001 2.8 4.7 2002 1.6 5.8 2003 2.3 6.0 Therefore, the OLS estimates computed from different random samples will generally differ, and this is why we consider the OLS estimators to be random variables. How should we think about randomness in time series data? Certainly, economic time series satisfy the intuitive requirements for being outcomes of random variables. For example, today we do not know what the Dow Jones Industrial Average will be at the close of the next trading day. We do not know what the annual growth in output will be in Canada during the coming year. Since the outcomes of these variables are not foreknown, they should clearly be viewed as random variables. Formally, a sequence of random variables indexed by time is called a stochastic process or a time series process. (“Stochastic” is a synonym for random.) When we col- lect a time series data set, we obtain one possible outcome, or realization, of the stochastic process. We can only see a single realization, because we cannot go back in time and start the process over again. (This is analogous to cross-sectional analysis where we can collect only one random sample.) However, if certain conditions in history had been different, we would generally obtain a different realization for the stochastic process, and this is why we think of time series data as the outcome of random variables. The set of all possible realiza- tions of a time series process plays the role of the population in cross-sectional analysis. The sample size for a time series data set is the number of time periods over which we observe the variables of interest. 10.2 Examples of Time Series Regression Models In this section, we discuss two examples of time series models that have been useful in empirical time series analysis and that are easily estimated by ordinary least squares. We will study additional models in Chapter 11. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 346 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Static Models Suppose that we have time series data available on two variables, say y and z, where yt and zt are dated contemporaneously. A static model relating y to z is yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt 􏱕 ut, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. [10.1] The name “static model” comes from the fact that we are modeling a contemporaneous relationship between y and z. Usually, a static model is postulated when a change in z at time t is believed to have an immediate effect on y: 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧zt, when 􏰧ut 􏱪 0. Static regression models are also used when we are interested in knowing the tradeoff between y and z. An example of a static model is the static Phillips curve, given by inft 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unemt 􏱕 ut , [10.2] where inft is the annual inflation rate and unemt is the unemployment rate. This form of the Phillips curve assumes a constant natural rate of unemployment and constant inflationary expectations, and it can be used to study the contemporaneous tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. [See, for example, Mankiw (1994, Section 11.2).] Naturally, we can have several explanatory variables in a static regression model. Let mrdrtet denote the murders per 10,000 people in a particular city during year t, let convrtet denote the murder conviction rate, let unemt be the local unemployment rate, and let yngmlet be the fraction of the population consisting of males between the ages of 18 and 25. Then, a static multiple regression model explaining murder rates is mrdrtet 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1convrtet 􏱕 􏱬2unemt 􏱕 􏱬3 yngmlet 􏱕 ut. [10.3] Using a model such as this, we can hope to estimate, for example, the ceteris paribus effect of an increase in the conviction rate on a particular criminal activity. Finite Distributed Lag Models In a finite distributed lag (FDL) model, we allow one or more variables to affect y with a lag. For example, for annual observations, consider the model gfrt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0pet 􏱕 􏱛1pet􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2pet􏱦2 􏱕 ut, [10.4] where gfrt is the general fertility rate (children born per 1,000 women of childbearing age) and pet is the real dollar value of the personal tax exemption. The idea is to see whether, in the aggregate, the decision to have children is linked to the tax value of having a child. Equation (10.4) recognizes that, for both biological and behavioral reasons, decisions to have children would not immediately result from changes in the personal exemption. Equation (10.4) is an example of the model yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0zt 􏱕 􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2zt􏱦2 􏱕 ut, [10.5] which is an FDL of order two. To interpret the coefficients in (10.5), suppose that z is a constant, equal to c, in all time periods before time t. At time t, z increases by one unit Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 347 to c 􏱕 1 and then reverts to its previous level at time t 􏱕 1. (That is, the increase in z is temporary.) More precisely, ..., zt􏱦2 􏱪 c, zt􏱦1 􏱪 c, zt 􏱪 c 􏱕 1, zt􏱕1 􏱪 c, zt􏱕2 􏱪 c, .... To focus on the ceteris paribus effect of z on y, we set the error term in each time period to zero. Then, yt􏱦1 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0c􏱕􏱛1c􏱕􏱛2c, yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛1c􏱕􏱛2c, yt􏱕1 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0c􏱕􏱛1(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛2c, yt􏱕2 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0c􏱕􏱛1c􏱕􏱛2(c􏱕1), yt􏱕3 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0c􏱕􏱛1c􏱕􏱛2c, and so on. From the first two equations, yt 􏱦 yt􏱦1 􏱪 􏱛0, which shows that 􏱛0 is the immedi- ate change in y due to the one-unit increase in z at time t. 􏱛0 is usually called the impact propensity or impact multiplier. Similarly, 􏱛1 􏱪 yt􏱕1 􏱦 yt􏱦1 is the change in y one period after the temporary change, and 􏱛2 􏱪 yt􏱕2 􏱦 yt􏱦1 is the change in y two periods after the change. At time t 􏱕 3, y has reverted back to its initial level: yt􏱕3 􏱪 yt􏱦1. This is because we have assumed that only two lags of z appear in (10.5). When we graph the 􏱛j as a function of j, we obtain the lag distribution, which summarizes the dynamic effect that a temporary increase in z has on y. A possible lag distribu- tion for the FDL of order two is given in Figure 10.1. (Of course, we would never know the parameters 􏱛j; instead, we will estimate the 􏱛j and then plot the estimated lag distribution.) The lag distribution in Figure 10.1 implies that the largest effect is at the first lag. The lag distribution has a useful interpretation. If we standardize the initial value of y at yt􏱦1 􏱪 0, the lag distribution traces out all subsequent values of y due to a one-unit, temporary increase in z. F I G U R E 1 0 . 1 A lag distribution with two nonzero lags. The maximum effect is at the first lag. coefficient ( j) 01234 lag Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 348 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data We are also interested in the change in y due to a permanent increase in z. Before time t,zequalstheconstantc.Attimet,zincreasespermanentlytoc􏱕1:zs 􏱪c,s􏱷tandzs 􏱪 c 􏱕 1, s 􏱸 t. Again, setting the errors to zero, we have yt􏱦1 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0c􏱕􏱛1c􏱕􏱛2c, yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛1c􏱕􏱛2c, yt􏱕1 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛1(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛2c, yt􏱕2 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛1(c􏱕1)􏱕􏱛2(c􏱕1), and so on. With the permanent increase in z, after one period, y has increased by 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1, and after two periods, y has increased by 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1 􏱕 􏱛2. There are no further changes in y after two periods. This shows that the sum of the coefficients on current and lagged z, 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1 􏱕 􏱛2, is the long-run change in y given a permanent increase in z and is called the long-run propensity (LRP) or long-run multiplier. The LRP is often of interest in distributed lag models. As an example, in equation (10.4), 􏱛0 measures the immediate change in fertility due to a one-dollar increase in pe. As we mentioned earlier, there are reasons to believe that 􏱛0 is small, if not zero. But 􏱛1 or 􏱛2, or both, might be positive. If pe permanently increases by one dollar, then, after two years, gfr will have changed by 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1 􏱕 􏱛2. This model assumes that there are no further changes after two years. Whether this is actually the case is an empirical matter. A finite distributed lag model of order q is written as yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0zt 􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕...􏱕􏱛qzt􏱦q 􏱕ut. [10.6] This contains the static model as a special case by setting 􏱛1, 􏱛2, ..., 􏱛q equal to zero. Sometimes, a primary purpose for estimating a distributed lag model is to test whether z has a lagged effect on y. The impact propensity is always the coefficient on the contempo- raneous z, 􏱛0. Occasionally, we omit zt from (10.6), in which case the impact propensity is zero. In the general case the lag distribution can be plotted by graphing the (estimated) 􏱛j as a function of j. For any horizon h, we can define the cumulative effect as 􏱛0 + 􏱛1 +. . . +􏱛h, which is interpreted as the change in the expected outcome h periods after a permanent, one-unit increase in x. Once the 􏱛j have been estimated, one may plot the estimated cumu- lative effects as a function of h. The long-run propensity is the cumulative effect after all changes have taken place; it is simply the sum of all of the coefficients on the zt􏱦j: LRP􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1 􏱕...􏱕􏱛q. [10.7] Because of the often substantial correla- tion in z at different lags—that is, due to multicollinearity in (10.6)—it can be dif- ficult to obtain precise estimates of the individual 􏱛j. Interestingly, even when the 􏱛j cannot be precisely estimated, we can often get good estimates of the LRP. We will see an example later. We can have more than one explana- tory variable appearing with lags, or we can add contemporaneous variables to an FDL model. For example, the average education level for women of childbearing age could be added to (10.4), which allows us to account for changing education levels for women. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 10.1 In an equation for annual data, suppose that intt 􏱪 1.6 􏱕 .48 inft 􏱦 .15 inft􏱦1 􏱕 .32 inft􏱦2 􏱕 ut, where int is an interest rate and inf is the inflation rate. What are the impact and long-run propensities? CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 349 A Convention about the Time Index When models have lagged explanatory variables (and, as we will see in the next chapter, for models with lagged y), confusion can arise concerning the treatment of initial observa- tions. For example, if in (10.5) we assume that the equation holds starting at t 􏱪 1, then the explanatory variables for the first time period are z1, z0, and z􏱦1. Our convention will be that these are the initial values in our sample, so that we can always start the time index at t 􏱪 1. In practice, this is not very important because regression packages automatically keep track of the observations available for estimating models with lags. But for this and the next two chapters, we need some convention concerning the first time period being represented by the regression equation. 10.3 Finite Sample Properties of OLS under Classical Assumptions In this section, we give a complete listing of the finite sample, or small sample, properties of OLS under standard assumptions. We pay particular attention to how the assumptions must be altered from our cross-sectional analysis to cover time series regressions. Unbiasedness of OLS The first assumption simply states that the time series process follows a model that is linear in its parameters. Assumption TS.1 Linear in Parameters The stochastic process {(xt1, xt2, ..., xtk, yt): t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} follows the linear model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, [10.8] where {ut: t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is the sequence of errors or disturbances. Here, n is the number of observations (time periods). In the notation xtj, t denotes the time period, and j is, as usual, a label to indicate one of the k explanatory variables. The terminology used in cross-sectional regression applies here: yt is the dependent variable, explained variable, or regressand; the xtj are the indepen- dent variables, explanatory variables, or regressors. We should think of Assumption TS.1 as being essentially the same as Assumption MLR.1 (the first cross-sectional assumption), but we are now specifying a linear model for time series data. The examples covered in Section 10.2 can be cast in the form of (10.8) by appropriately defining xtj. For example, equation (10.5) is obtained by setting xt1 􏱪 zt, xt2 􏱪 zt􏱦1, and xt3 􏱪 zt􏱦2. To state and discuss several of the remaining assumptions, we let xt 􏱪 (xt1, xt2, ..., xtk) denote the set of all independent variables in the equation at time t. Further, X denotes the collection of all independent variables for all time periods. It is useful to think of X as being an array, with n rows and k columns. This reflects how time series data are stored Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 350 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data T A B L E 1 0 . 2 Example of X for the Explanatory Variables in Equation (10.3) t convrte unem yngmle 1 .46 .074 .12 2 .42 .071 .12 3 .42 .063 .11 4 .47 .062 .09 5 .48 .060 .10 6 .50 .059 .11 7 .55 .058 .12 8 .56 .059 .13 in econometric software packages: the tth row of X is xt, consisting of all independent variables for time period t. Therefore, the first row of X corresponds to t 􏱪 1, the second rowtot􏱪2,andthelastrowtot􏱪n.AnexampleisgiveninTable10.2,usingn􏱪8and the explanatory variables in equation (10.3). Naturally, as with cross-sectional regression, we need to rule out perfect collinearity among the regressors. We discussed this assumption at length in the context of cross-sectional data in Chapter 3. The issues are essentially the same with time series data. Remember, Assump- tion TS.2 does allow the explanatory variables to be correlated, but it rules out perfect correlation in the sample. The final assumption for unbiasedness of OLS is the time series analog of Assump- tion MLR.4, and it also obviates the need for random sampling in Assumption MLR.2. This is a crucial assumption, and we need to have an intuitive grasp of its meaning. As in the cross-sectional case, it is easiest to view this assumption in terms of uncorrelatedness: Assumption TS.3 implies that the error at time t, ut, is uncorrelated with each explanatory variable in every time period. The fact that this is stated in terms of the conditional expec- tation means that we must also correctly specify the functional relationship between yt and the explanatory variables. If ut is independent of X and E(ut) 􏱪 0, then Assumption TS.3 automatically holds. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Assumption TS.2 No Perfect Collinearity In the sample (and therefore in the underlying time series process), no independent variable is constant nor a perfect linear combination of the others. Assumption TS.3 Zero Conditional Mean For each t, the expected value of the error ut, given the explanatory variables for all time periods, is zero. Mathematically, E(ut􏰫X) 􏱪 0, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. [10.9] © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 351 Given the cross-sectional analysis from Chapter 3, it is not surprising that we require ut to be uncorrelated with the explanatory variables also dated at time t: in conditional mean terms, E(ut􏰫xt1, ..., xtk) 􏱪 E(ut􏰫xt) 􏱪 0. [10.10] When (10.10) holds, we say that the xtj are contemporaneously exogenous. Equa- tion (10.10) implies that ut and the explanatory variables are contemporaneously uncorrelated: Corr(xtj,ut) 􏱪 0, for all j. Assumption TS.3 requires more than contemporaneous exogeneity: ut must be uncor- related with xsj, even when s 􏱻 t. This is a strong sense in which the explanatory variables must be exogenous, and when TS.3 holds, we say that the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous. In Chapter 11, we will demonstrate that (10.10) is sufficient for proving consis- tency of the OLS estimator. But to show that OLS is unbiased, we need the strict exogeneity assumption. In the cross-sectional case, we did not explicitly state how the error term for, say, person i, ui, is related to the explanatory variables for other people in the sample. This was unnecessary because with random sampling (Assumption MLR.2), ui is automatically independent of the explanatory variables for observations other than i. In a time series con- text, random sampling is almost never appropriate, so we must explicitly assume that the expected value of ut is not related to the explanatory variables in any time periods. It is important to see that Assumption TS.3 puts no restriction on correlation in the independent variables or in the ut across time. Assumption TS.3 only says that the average value of ut is unrelated to the independent variables in all time periods. Anything that causes the unobservables at time t to be correlated with any of the explanatory variables in any time period causes Assumption TS.3 to fail. Two leading candidates for failure are omitted variables and measurement error in some of the regres- sors. But the strict exogeneity assumption can also fail for other, less obvious reasons. In the simple static regression model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1zt 􏱕ut, Assumption TS.3 requires not only that ut and zt are uncorrelated, but that ut is also un- correlated with past and future values of z. This has two implications. First, z can have no lagged effect on y. If z does have a lagged effect on y, then we should estimate a dis- tributed lag model. A more subtle point is that strict exogeneity excludes the possibility that changes in the error term today can cause future changes in z. This effectively rules out feedback from y to future values of z. For example, consider a simple static model to explain a city’s murder rate in terms of police officers per capita: mrdrtet 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1polpct 􏱕 ut. It may be reasonable to assume that ut is uncorrelated with polpct and even with past val- ues of polpct; for the sake of argument, assume this is the case. But suppose that the city adjusts the size of its police force based on past values of the murder rate. This means that, say, polpct􏱕1 might be correlated with ut (since a higher ut leads to a higher mrdrtet). If this is the case, Assumption TS.3 is generally violated. There are similar considerations in distributed lag models. Usually, we do not worry that ut might be correlated with past z because we are controlling for past z in the model. But feedback from u to future z is always an issue. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 352 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Explanatory variables that are strictly exogenous cannot react to what has happened to y in the past. A factor such as the amount of rainfall in an agricultural production func- tion satisfies this requirement: rainfall in any future year is not influenced by the output during the current or past years. But something like the amount of labor input might not be strictly exogenous, as it is chosen by the farmer, and the farmer may adjust the amount of labor based on last year’s yield. Policy variables, such as growth in the money supply, expenditures on welfare, and highway speed limits, are often influenced by what has hap- pened to the outcome variable in the past. In the social sciences, many explanatory vari- ables may very well violate the strict exogeneity assumption. Even though Assumption TS.3 can be unrealistic, we begin with it in order to con- clude that the OLS estimators are unbiased. Most treatments of static and finite distributed lag models assume TS.3 by making the stronger assumption that the explanatory variables are nonrandom, or fixed in repeated samples. The nonrandomness assumption is obvi- ously false for time series observations; Assumption TS.3 has the advantage of being more realistic about the random nature of the xtj, while it isolates the necessary assumption about how ut and the explanatory variables are related in order for OLS to be unbiased. The proof of this theorem is essentially the same as that for Theorem 3.1 in Chapter 3, and so we omit it. When comparing Theorem 10.1 to Theorem 3.1, we have been able to drop the random sampling assumption by assuming that, for each t, ut has zero mean given the explanatory variables at all time periods. If this assumption does not hold, OLS cannot be shown to be unbiased. The analysis of omitted variables bias, which we covered in Section 3.3, is essentially the same in the time series case. In particular, Table 3.2 and the discussion surrounding it can be used as before to determine the directions of bias due to omitted variables. The Variances of the OLS Estimators and the Gauss-Markov Theorem We need to add two assumptions to round out the Gauss-Markov assumptions for time series regressions. The first one is familiar from cross-sectional analysis. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. THEOREM 10.1 UNBIASEDNESS OF OLS Under Assumptions TS.1, TS.2, and TS.3, the OLS estimators are unbiased conditional on X, and therefore unconditionally as well: E(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 􏱬j, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k. EXPLORING FURTHER 10.2 IntheFDLmodelyt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0zt 􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕 ut , what do we need to assume about the sequence {z0, z1, ..., zn} in order for Assumption TS.3 to hold? Assumption TS.4 Homoskedasticity Conditional on X, the variance of ut is the same for all t: Var(ut􏰫X) 􏱪 Var(ut) 􏱪 􏱧2, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 353 This assumption means that Var(ut􏰫X) cannot depend on X—it is sufficient that ut and X are independent—and that Var(ut) must be constant over time. When TS.4 does not hold, we say that the errors are heteroskedastic, just as in the cross-sectional case. For example, consider an equation for determining three-month T-bill rates (i3t) based on the inflation rate (inft) and the federal deficit as a percentage of gross domestic product (deft): i3t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inft 􏱕 􏱬2deft 􏱕 ut. [10.11] Among other things, Assumption TS.4 requires that the unobservables affecting interest rates have a constant variance over time. Since policy regime changes are known to affect the variability of interest rates, this assumption might very well be false. Further, it could be that the variability in interest rates depends on the level of inflation or relative size of the deficit. This would also violate the homoskedasticity assumption. When Var(ut􏰫X) does depend on X, it often depends on the explanatory variables at time t, xt. In Chapter 12, we will see that the tests for heteroskedasticity from Chapter 8 can also be used for time series regressions, at least under certain assumptions. The final Gauss-Markov assumption for time series analysis is new. The easiest way to think of this assumption is to ignore the conditioning on X. Then, Assumption TS.5 is simply Corr(ut,us) 􏱪 0, for all t 􏱻 s. [10.12] (This is how the no serial correlation assumption is stated when X is treated as nonran- dom.) When considering whether Assumption TS.5 is likely to hold, we focus on equa- tion (10.12) because of its simple interpretation. When (10.12) is false, we say that the errors in (10.8) suffer from serial correlation, or autocorrelation, because they are correlated across time. Consider the case of errors from adjacent time periods. Suppose that when ut􏱦1 􏱰 0 then, on average, the error in the next time period, ut, is also positive. Then, Corr(ut,ut􏱦1) 􏱰 0, and the errors suffer from serial cor- relation. In equation (10.11), this means that if interest rates are unexpectedly high for this period, then they are likely to be above average (for the given levels of inflation and deficits) for the next period. This turns out to be a reasonable characterization for the error terms in many time series applications, which we will see in Chapter 12. For now, we assume TS.5. Importantly, Assumption TS.5 assumes nothing about temporal correlation in the independent variables. For example, in equation (10.11), inft is almost certainly correlated across time. But this has nothing to do with whether TS.5 holds. A natural question that arises is: In Chapters 3 and 4, why did we not assume that the errors for different cross-sectional observations are uncorrelated? The answer comes from the random sampling assumption: under random sampling, ui and uh are independent for any two observations i and h. It can also be shown that, under random sampling, the errors for different observations are independent conditional on the explanatory variables in the sample. Thus, for our purposes, we consider serial correlation only to be a potential Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Assumption TS.5 No Serial Correlation Conditional on X, the errors in two different time periods are uncorrelated: Corr(ut,us􏰫X) 􏱪 0, for all t 􏱻 s. 354 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data problem for regressions with times series data. (In Chapters 13 and 14, the serial correla- tion issue will come up in connection with panel data analysis.) Assumptions TS.1 through TS.5 are the appropriate Gauss-Markov assumptions for time series applications, but they have other uses as well. Sometimes, TS.1 through TS.5 are satis- fied in cross-sectional applications, even when random sampling is not a reasonable assump- tion, such as when the cross-sectional units are large relative to the population. Suppose that we have a cross-sectional data set at the city level. It might be that correlation exists across cities within the same state in some of the explanatory variables, such as property tax rates or per capita welfare payments. Correlation of the explanatory variables across observations does not cause problems for verifying the Gauss-Markov assumptions, provided the error terms are uncorrelated across cities. However, in this chapter, we are primarily interested in applying the Gauss-Markov assumptions to time series regression problems. THEOREM 10.2 OLS SAMPLING VARIANCES Under the time series Gauss-Markov Assumptions TS.1 through TS.5, the variance of 􏱬ˆj, conditional on X, is Var(􏱬ˆj􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2/[SSTj(1 􏱦 R2j )], j 􏱪 1, ..., k, [10.13] whereSSTjisthetotalsumofsquaresofxtjandR2j istheR-squaredfromtheregressionofxj on the other independent variables. Equation (10.13) is the same variance we derived in Chapter 3 under the cross- sectional Gauss-Markov assumptions. Because the proof is very similar to the one for Theorem 3.2, we omit it. The discussion from Chapter 3 about the factors causing large variances, including multicollinearity among the explanatory variables, applies immedi- ately to the time series case. The usual estimator of the error variance is also unbiased under Assumptions TS.1 through TS.5, and the Gauss-Markov Theorem holds. THEOREM 10.3 UNBIASED ESTIMATION OF 􏱧2 Under Assumptions TS.1 through TS.5, the estimator 􏱧ˆ2 􏱪 SSR/df is an unbiased estimator of 􏱧2, where df 􏱪 n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1. THEOREM 10.4 GAUSS-MARKOV THEOREM Under Assumptions TS.1 through TS.5, the OLS estimators are the best linear unbiased estimators conditional on X. The bottom line here is that OLS has the same desirable finite sample properties under TS.1 through TS.5 that it has under MLR.1 through MLR.5. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 10.3 IntheFDLmodelyt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0zt 􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕 ut, explain the nature of any multicollinearity in the explanatory variables. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 355 Inference under the Classical Linear Model Assumptions In order to use the usual OLS standard errors, t statistics, and F statistics, we need to add a final assumption that is analogous to the normality assumption we used for cross-sectional analysis. Assumption TS.6 implies TS.3, TS.4, and TS.5, but it is stronger because of the inde- pendence and normality assumptions. Assumption TS.6 Normality The errors ut are independent of X and are independently and identically distributed as Normal(0,􏱧2). THEOREM 10.5 NORMAL SAMPLING DISTRIBUTIONS Under Assumptions TS.1 through TS.6, the CLM assumptions for time series, the OLS estimators are normally distributed, conditional on X. Further, under the null hypothesis, each t statistic has a t distribution, and each F statistic has an F distribution. The usual construction of confidence intervals is also valid. The implications of Theorem 10.5 are of utmost importance. It implies that, when Assumptions TS.1 through TS.6 hold, everything we have learned about estimation and inference for cross-sectional regressions applies directly to time series regressions. Thus, t statistics can be used for testing statistical significance of individual explanatory variables, and F statistics can be used to test for joint significance. Just as in the cross-sectional case, the usual inference procedures are only as good as the underlying assumptions. The classical linear model assumptions for time series data are much more restrictive than those for cross-sectional data—in particular, the strict exogeneity and no serial correlation assumptions can be unrealistic. Nevertheless, the CLM framework is a good starting point for many applications. EXAMPLE 10.1 STATIC PHILLIPS CURVE To determine whether there is a tradeoff, on average, between unemployment and infla- tion, we can test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱷 0 in equation (10.2). If the classical linear model assumptions hold, we can use the usual OLS t statistic. We use the file PHILLIPS.RAW to estimate equation (10.2), restricting ourselves to the data through 1996. (In later exercises, for example, Computer Exercises C12 and C10 in Chapter 11 you are asked to use all years through 2003. In Chapter 18, we use the years 1997 through 2003 in various forecasting exercises.) The simple regression estimates are 􏱾inf 􏱪 1.42 􏱕 .468 unem tt (1.72) (.289) - [10.14] n􏱪49,R2 􏱪.053,R2 􏱪.033. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 356 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data This equation does not suggest a tradeoff between unem and inf: 􏱬ˆ1 􏱰 0. The t statistic for 􏱬ˆ1 is about 1.62, which gives a p-value against a two-sided alternative of about .11. Thus, if anything, there is a positive relationship between inflation and unemployment. There are some problems with this analysis that we cannot address in detail now. In Chapter 12, we will see that the CLM assumptions do not hold. In addition, the static Phillips curve is probably not the best model for determining whether there is a short- run tradeoff between inflation and unemployment. Macroeconomists generally prefer the expectations augmented Phillips curve, a simple example of which is given in Chapter 11. As a second example, we estimate equation (10.11) using annual data on the U.S. economy. EXAMPLE 10.2 EFFECTS OF INFLATION AND DEFICITS ON INTEREST RATES The data in INTDEF.RAW come from the 2004 Economic Report of the President (Tables B-73 and B-79) and span the years 1948 through 2003. The variable i3 is the three-month T-bill rate, inf is the annual inflation rate based on the consumer price index (CPI), and def is the federal budget deficit as a percentage of GDP. The estimated equation is 􏱾i3􏱪1.73􏱕.606inf 􏱕.513def ttt (0.43) (.082) - (.118) [10.15] n􏱪56,R2 􏱪.602,R2 􏱪.587. These estimates show that increases in inflation or the relative size of the deficit increase short-term interest rates, both of which are expected from basic economics. For example, a ceteris paribus one percentage point increase in the inflation rate increases i3 by .606 points. Both inf and def are very statistically significant, assuming, of course, that the CLM assumptions hold. 10.4 Functional Form, Dummy Variables, and Index Numbers All of the functional forms we learned about in earlier chapters can be used in time series regressions. The most important of these is the natural logarithm: time series regressions with constant percentage effects appear often in applied work. EXAMPLE 10.3 PUERTO RICAN EMPLOYMENT AND THE MINIMUM WAGE Annual data on the Puerto Rican employment rate, minimum wage, and other variables are used by Castillo-Freeman and Freeman (1992) to study the effects of the U.S. mini- mum wage on employment in Puerto Rico. A simplified version of their model is log( prepopt) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(mincovt) 􏱕 􏱬2log(usgnpt) 􏱕 ut , [10.16] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 357 where prepopt is the employment rate in Puerto Rico during year t (ratio of those working to total population), usgnpt is real U.S. gross national product (in billions of dollars), and mincov measures the importance of the minimum wage relative to average wages. In particular, mincov 􏱪 (avgmin/avgwage)·avgcov, where avgmin is the average mini- mum wage, avgwage is the average overall wage, and avgcov is the average coverage rate (the proportion of workers actually covered by the minimum wage law). Using the data in PRMINWGE.RAW for the years 1950 through 1987 gives 􏱾log(prepopt)􏱪 􏱦1.05 􏱦 .154 log(mincovt) 􏱦 .012 log(usgnpt) (0.77) (.065)- (.089) [10.17] n􏱪38,R2 􏱪.661,R2 􏱪.641. The estimated elasticity of prepop with respect to mincov is 􏱦.154, and it is statistically significant with t 􏱪 􏱦2.37. Therefore, a higher minimum wage lowers the employment rate, something that classical economics predicts. The GNP variable is not statistically sig- nificant, but this changes when we account for a time trend in the next section. We can use logarithmic functional forms in distributed lag models, too. For example, for quarterly data, suppose that money demand (Mt) and gross domestic product (GDPt) are related by log(Mt) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0log(GDPt) 􏱕 􏱛1log(GDPt􏱦1) 􏱕 􏱛2log(GDPt􏱦2) 􏱕 􏱛3log(GDPt􏱦3) 􏱕 􏱛4log(GDPt􏱦4) 􏱕 ut. The impact propensity in this equation, 􏱛0, is also called the short-run elasticity: it measures the immediate percentage change in money demand given a 1% increase in GDP. The long-run propensity, 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛4, is sometimes called the long-run elasticity: it measures the percentage increase in money demand after four quarters given a permanent 1% increase in GDP. Binary or dummy independent variables are also quite useful in time series applica- tions. Since the unit of observation is time, a dummy variable represents whether, in each time period, a certain event has occurred. For example, for annual data, we can indicate in each year whether a Democrat or a Republican is president of the United States by defin- ing a variable democt, which is unity if the president is a Democrat, and zero otherwise. Or, in looking at the effects of capital punishment on murder rates in Texas, we can define a dummy variable for each year equal to one if Texas had capital punishment during that year, and zero otherwise. Often, dummy variables are used to isolate certain periods that may be systematically different from other periods covered by a data set. EXAMPLE 10.4 EFFECTS OF PERSONAL EXEMPTION ON FERTILITY RATES The general fertility rate (gfr) is the number of children born to every 1,000 women of childbearing age. For the years 1913 through 1984, the equation, gfrt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1pet 􏱕 􏱬2ww2t 􏱕 􏱬3pillt 􏱕 ut, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 358 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data explains gfr in terms of the average real dollar value of the personal tax exemption (pe) and two binary variables. The variable ww2 takes on the value unity during the years 1941 through 1945, when the United States was involved in World War II. The variable pill is unity from 1963 on, when the birth control pill was made available for contraception. Using the data in FERTIL3.RAW, which were taken from the article by Whittington, Alm, and Peters (1990), gives 􏱾 n􏱪72,R2 􏱪.473,R2 􏱪.450. Each variable is statistically significant at the 1% level against a two-sided alternative. We see that the fertility rate was lower during World War II: given pe, there were about 24 fewer births for every 1,000 women of childbearing age, which is a large reduction. (From 1913 through 1984, gfr ranged from about 65 to 127.) Similarly, the fertility rate has been substantially lower since the introduction of the birth control pill. The variable of economic interest is pe. The average pe over this time period is $100.40, ranging from zero to $243.83. The coefficient on pe implies that a $12.00 increase in pe increases gfr by about one birth per 1,000 women of childbearing age. This effect is hardly trivial. In Section 10.2, we noted that the fertility rate may react to changes in pe with a lag. Estimating a distributed lag model with two lags gives gfrt􏱪 98.68 􏱕 .083 pet 􏱦 24.24 ww2t 􏱦 31.59 pillt (3.21) (.030) - (7.46) (4.08) [10.18] 􏱾gfrt􏱪 95.87 􏱕 .073 pet 􏱦 .0058 pet􏱦1 􏱕 .034 pet􏱦2 (3.28) (.126) (.1557) (.126) 􏱦 22.13 ww2t 􏱦 31.30 pillt (10.73) (3.98) n 􏱪 70, R2 􏱪 .499,R-2 􏱪 .459. [10.19] In this regression, we only have 70 observations because we lose two when we lag pe twice. The coefficients on the pe variables are estimated very imprecisely, and each one is individually insignificant. It turns out that there is substantial correlation between pet, pet􏱦1, and pet􏱦2, and this multicollinearity makes it difficult to estimate the effect at each lag. However, pet, pet􏱦1, and pet􏱦2 are jointly significant: the F statistic has a p-value 􏱪 .012. Thus, pe does have an effect on gfr [as we already saw in (10.18)], but we do not have good enough estimates to determine whether it is contemporaneous or with a one- or two-year lag (or some of each). Actually, pet􏱦1 and pet􏱦2 are jointly insignificant in this equation (p-value 􏱪 .95), so at this point, we would be justified in using the static model. But for illustrative purposes, let us obtain a confidence interval for the long-run propensity in this model. The estimated LRP in (10.19) is .073 􏱦 .0058 􏱕 .034 􏱴 .101. However, we do not have enough information in (10.19) to obtain the standard error of this estimate. To obtain the standard error of the estimated LRP, we use the trick suggested in Section 4.4. Let 􏰩0 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1 􏱕􏱛2 denotetheLRPandwrite􏱛0 intermsof􏰩0,􏱛1,and􏱛2 as􏱛0 􏱪􏰩0 􏱦􏱛1 􏱦􏱛2. Next, substitute for 􏱛0 in the model gfrt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0pet 􏱕 􏱛1pet􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2pet􏱦2 􏱕 ... Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. to get CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 359 gfrt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕(􏰩0 􏱦􏱛1 􏱦􏱛2)pet 􏱕􏱛1pet􏱦1 􏱕􏱛2pet􏱦2 􏱕... 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕􏰩0pet 􏱕 􏱛1(pet􏱦1 􏱦 pet) 􏱕 􏱛2(pet􏱦2 􏱦 pet) 􏱕 .... From this last equation, we can obtain 􏰩ˆ0 and its standard error by regressing gfrt on pet, ( pet􏱦1 􏱦 pet), ( pet􏱦2 􏱦 pet), ww2t, and pillt. The coefficient and associated standard error on pet are what we need. Running this regression gives 􏰩ˆ0 􏱪 .101 as the coefficient on pet (as we already knew) and se(􏰩ˆ0) 􏱪 .030 [which we could not compute from (10.19)]. Therefore, the t statistic for 􏰩ˆ0 is about 3.37, so 􏰩ˆ0 is statistically different from zero at small significance levels. Even though none of the 􏱛ˆj is individually significant, the LRP is very significant. The 95% confidence interval for the LRP is about .041 to .160. Whittington, Alm, and Peters (1990) allow for further lags but restrict the coefficients to help alleviate the multicollinearity problem that hinders estimation of the individual 􏱛j. (See Problem 6 for an example of how to do this.) For estimating the LRP, which would seem to be of primary interest here, such restrictions are unnecessary. Whittington, Alm, and Peters also control for additional variables, such as average female wage and the un- employment rate. Binary explanatory variables are the key component in what is called an event study. In an event study, the goal is to see whether a particular event influences some outcome. Economists who study industrial organization have looked at the effects of certain events on firm stock prices. For example, Rose (1985) studied the effects of new trucking regula- tions on the stock prices of trucking companies. A simple version of an equation used for such event studies is Rtf 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1Rmt 􏱕􏱬2dt 􏱕ut, where Rtf is the stock return for firm f during period t (usually a week or a month), Rmt is the market return (usually computed for a broad stock market index), and dt is a dummy variable indicating when the event occurred. For example, if the firm is an airline, dt might denote whether the airline experienced a publicized accident or near accident during week t. Including Rmt in the equation controls for the possibility that broad market movements might coincide with airline accidents. Sometimes, multiple dummy variables are used. For example, if the event is the imposition of a new regulation that might affect a certain firm, we might include a dummy variable that is one for a few weeks before the regula- tion was publicly announced and a second dummy variable for a few weeks after the regulation was announced. The first dummy variable might detect the presence of inside information. Before we give an example of an event study, we need to discuss the notion of an index number and the difference between nominal and real economic variables. An index number typically aggregates a vast amount of information into a single quantity. Index numbers are used regularly in time series analysis, especially in macroeconomic applica- tions. An example of an index number is the index of industrial production (IIP), com- puted monthly by the Board of Governors of the Federal Reserve. The IIP is a measure of production across a broad range of industries, and, as such, its magnitude in a particular year has no quantitative meaning. In order to interpret the magnitude of the IIP, we must Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 360 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data know the base period and the base value. In the 1997 Economic Report of the President (ERP), the base year is 1987, and the base value is 100. (Setting IIP to 100 in the base period is just a convention; it makes just as much sense to set IIP 􏱪 1 in 1987, and some indexes are defined with 1 as the base value.) Because the IIP was 107.7 in 1992, we can say that industrial production was 7.7% higher in 1992 than in 1987. We can use the IIP in any two years to compute the percentage difference in industrial output during those two years. For example, because IIP 􏱪 61.4 in 1970 and IIP 􏱪 85.7 in 1979, industrial production grew by about 39.6% during the 1970s. It is easy to change the base period for any index number, and sometimes we must do this to give index numbers reported with different base years a common base year. For example, if we want to change the base year of the IIP from 1987 to 1982, we simply divide the IIP for each year by the 1982 value and then multiply by 100 to make the base period value 100. Generally, the formula is newindext 􏱪 100(oldindext /oldindexnewbase), [10.20] where oldindexnewbase is the original value of the index in the new base year. For example, with base year 1987, the IIP in 1992 is 107.7; if we change the base year to 1982, the IIP in 1992 becomes 100(107.7/81.9) 􏱪 131.5 (because the IIP in 1982 was 81.9). Another important example of an index number is a price index, such as the con- sumer price index (CPI). We already used the CPI to compute annual inflation rates in Example 10.1. As with the industrial production index, the CPI is only meaningful when we compare it across different years (or months, if we are using monthly data). In the 1997 ERP, CPI 􏱪 38.8 in 1970, and CPI 􏱪 130.7 in 1990. Thus, the general price level grew by almost 237% over this 20-year period. (In 1997, the CPI is defined so that its average in 1982, 1983, and 1984 equals 100; thus, the base period is listed as 1982􏱦1984.) In addition to being used to compute inflation rates, price indexes are necessary for turning a time series measured in nominal dollars (or current dollars) into real dollars (or constant dollars). Most economic behavior is assumed to be influenced by real, not nominal, variables. For example, classical labor economics assumes that labor supply is based on the real hourly wage, not the nominal wage. Obtaining the real wage from the nominal wage is easy if we have a price index such as the CPI. We must be a little careful to first divide the CPI by 100, so that the value in the base year is 1. Then, if w denotes the average hourly wage in nominal dollars and p 􏱪 CPI/100, the real wage is simply w/p. This wage is measured in dollars for the base period of the CPI. For example, in Table B-45 in the 1997 ERP, average hourly earnings are reported in nominal terms and in 1982 dollars (which means that the CPI used in computing the real wage had the base year 1982). This table reports that the nominal hourly wage in 1960 was $2.09, but measured in 1982 dollars, the wage was $6.79. The real hourly wage had peaked in 1973, at $8.55 in 1982 dollars, and had fallen to $7.40 by 1995. Thus, there was a nontrivial decline in real wages over those 22 years. (If we compare nominal wages from 1973 and 1995, we get a very misleading picture: $3.94 in 1973 and $11.44 in 1995. Because the real wage fell, the increase in the nominal wage was due entirely to inflation.) Standard measures of economic output are in real terms. The most important of these is gross domestic product, or GDP. When growth in GDP is reported in the popular press, it is always real GDP growth. In the 2012 ERP, Table B-2, GDP is reported in billions of 2005 dollars. We used a similar measure of output, real gross national product, in Example 10.3. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 361 Interesting things happen when real dollar variables are used in combination with natural logarithms. Suppose, for example, that average weekly hours worked are related to the real wage as log(hours) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(w/p) 􏱕 u. Using the fact that log(w/p) 􏱪 log(w) 􏱦 log(p), we can write this as log(hours) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(w) 􏱕 􏱬2log(p) 􏱕 u, [10.21] but with the restriction that 􏱬2 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1. Therefore, the assumption that only the real wage influences labor supply imposes a restriction on the parameters of model (10.21). If 􏱬2 􏱻 􏱦􏱬1, then the price level has an effect on labor supply, something that can happen if workers do not fully understand the distinction between real and nominal wages. There are many practical aspects to the actual computation of index numbers, but it would take us too far afield to cover those here. Detailed discussions of price indexes can be found in most intermediate macroeconomic texts, such as Mankiw (1994, Chapter 2). For us, it is important to be able to use index numbers in regression analysis. As men- tioned earlier, since the magnitudes of index numbers are not especially informative, they often appear in logarithmic form, so that regression coefficients have percentage change interpretations. We now give an example of an event study that also uses index numbers. EXAMPLE 10.5 ANTIDUMPING FILINGS AND CHEMICAL IMPORTS Krupp and Pollard (1996) analyzed the effects of antidumping filings by U.S. chemical industries on imports of various chemicals. We focus here on one industrial chemical, barium chloride, a cleaning agent used in various chemical processes and in gasoline production. The data are contained in the file BARIUM.RAW. In the early 1980s, U.S. barium chloride producers believed that China was offering its U.S. imports at an unfairly low price (an action known as dumping), and the barium chloride industry filed a com- plaint with the U.S. International Trade Commission (ITC) in October 1983. The ITC ruled in favor of the U.S. barium chloride industry in October 1984. There are several questions of interest in this case, but we will touch on only a few of them. First, were imports unusually high in the period immediately preceding the initial filing? Second, did imports change noticeably after an antidumping filing? Finally, what was the reduc- tion in imports after a decision in favor of the U.S. industry? To answer these questions, we follow Krupp and Pollard by defining three dummy variables: befile6 is equal to 1 during the six months before filing, affile6 indicates the six months after filing, and afdec6 denotes the six months after the positive decision. The dependent variable is the volume of imports of barium chloride from China, chnimp, which we use in logarithmic form. We include as explanatory variables, all in logarith- mic form, an index of chemical production, chempi (to control for overall demand for barium chloride), the volume of gasoline production, gas (another demand variable), and an exchange rate index, rtwex, which measures the strength of the dollar against several other currencies. The chemical production index was defined to be 100 in June 1977. The analysis here differs somewhat from Krupp and Pollard in that we use natural logarithms of all variables (except the dummy variables, of course), and we include all three dummy variables in the same regression. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 362 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Using monthly data from February 1978 through December 1988 gives the following: 􏱾log(chnimp)􏱪 􏱦17.80 􏱕 3.12 log(chempi) 􏱕 .196 log(gas) (21.05) (.48) (.907) 􏱕 .983 log(rtwex) 􏱕 .060 befile6 􏱦 .032 affile6 􏱦 .565 afdec6 [10.22] (.400) - (.261) (.264) (.286) n 􏱪 131, R2 􏱪 .305,R2 􏱪 .271. The equation shows that befile6 is statistically insignificant, so there is no evidence that Chinese imports were unusually high during the six months before the suit was filed. Further, although the estimate on affile6 is negative, the coefficient is small (indicating about a 3.2% fall in Chinese imports), and it is statistically very insignificant. The coef- ficient on afdec6 shows a substantial fall in Chinese imports of barium chloride after the decision in favor of the U.S. industry, which is not surprising. Since the effect is so large, we compute the exact percentage change: 100[exp(􏱦.565) 􏱦 1] 􏱴 􏱦43.2%. The coefficient is statistically significant at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative. The coefficient signs on the control variables are what we expect: an increase in over- all chemical production increases the demand for the cleaning agent. Gasoline production does not affect Chinese imports significantly. The coefficient on log(rtwex) shows that an increase in the value of the dollar relative to other currencies increases the demand for Chinese imports, as is predicted by economic theory. (In fact, the elasticity is not statisti- cally different from 1. Why?) Interactions among qualitative and quantitative variables are also used in time series analysis. An example with practical importance follows. EXAMPLE 10.6 ELECTION OUTCOMES AND ECONOMIC PERFORMANCE Fair (1996) summarizes his work on explaining presidential election outcomes in terms of economic performance. He explains the proportion of the two-party vote going to the Democratic candidate using data for the years 1916 through 1992 (every four years) for a total of 20 observations. We estimate a simplified version of Fair’s model (using variable names that are more descriptive than his): demvote 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 partyWH 􏱕 􏱬2incum 􏱕 􏱬3 partyWH·gnews 􏱕 􏱬4 partyWH·inf 􏱕 u, where demvote is the proportion of the two-party vote going to the Democratic candi- date. The explanatory variable partyWH is similar to a dummy variable, but it takes on the value 1 if a Democrat is in the White House and 􏱦1 if a Republican is in the White House. Fair uses this variable to impose the restriction that the effects of a Republican or a Democrat being in the White House have the same magnitude but the opposite sign. This is a natural restriction because the party shares must sum to one, by defini- tion. It also saves two degrees of freedom, which is important with so few observations. Similarly, the variable incum is defined to be 1 if a Democratic incumbent is running, 􏱦1 if a Republican incumbent is running, and zero otherwise. The variable gnews is the number of quarters, during the administration’s first 15 quarters, when the quarterly Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 363 growth in real per capita output was above 2.9% (at an annual rate), and inf is the average annual inflation rate over the first 15 quarters of the administration. See Fair (1996) for precise definitions. Economists are most interested in the interaction terms partyWH·gnews and partyWH·inf. Since partyWH equals 1 when a Democrat is in the White House, 􏱬3 measures the effect of good economic news on the party in power; we expect 􏱬3 􏱰 0. Similarly, 􏱬4 measures the effect that inflation has on the party in power. Because infla- tion during an administration is considered to be bad news, we expect 􏱬4 􏱷 0. The estimated equation using the data in FAIR.RAW is 􏱾demvote􏱪 .481 􏱦 .0435 partyWH 􏱕 .0544 incum (.012) (.0405) (.0234) 􏱕 .0108 partyWH·gnews 􏱦 .0077 partyWH·inf (.0041) - (.0033) n􏱪20,R2 􏱪.663,R2 􏱪.573. [10.23] All coefficients, except that on partyWH, are statistically significant at the 5% level. Incumbency is worth about 5.4 percentage points in the share of the vote. (Remember, demvote is measured as a proportion.) Further, the economic news variable has a positive effect: one more quarter of good news is worth about 1.1 percentage points. Inflation, as expected, has a negative effect: if average annual inflation is, say, two percentage points higher, the party in power loses about 1.5 percentage points of the two-party vote. We could have used this equation to predict the outcome of the 1996 presidential election between Bill Clinton, the Democrat, and Bob Dole, the Republican. (The inde- pendent candidate, Ross Perot, is excluded because Fair’s equation is for the two-party vote only.) Because Clinton ran as an incumbent, partyWH 􏱪 1 and incum 􏱪 1. To predict the election outcome, we need the variables gnews and inf. During Clinton’s first 15 quar- ters in office, the annual growth rate of per capita real GDP exceeded 2.9% three times, so gnews 􏱪 3. Further, using the GDP price deflator reported in Table B-4 in the 1997 ERP, the average annual inflation rate (computed using Fair’s formula) from the fourth quarter in 1991 to the third quarter in 1996 was 3.019. Plugging these into (10.23) gives 􏱾demvote 􏱪 .481 􏱦 .0435 􏱕 .0544 􏱕 .0108(3) 􏱦 .0077(3.019) 􏱴 .5011. Therefore, based on information known before the election in November, Clinton was pre- dicted to receive a very slight majority of the two-party vote: about 50.1%. In fact, Clinton won more handily: his share of the two-party vote was 54.65%. 10.5 Trends and Seasonality Characterizing Trending Time Series Many economic time series have a common tendency of growing over time. We must recog- nize that some series contain a time trend in order to draw causal inference using time series data. Ignoring the fact that two sequences are trending in the same or opposite directions can lead us to falsely conclude that changes in one variable are actually caused by changes Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 364 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data in another variable. In many cases, two time series processes appear to be correlated only because they are both trending over time for reasons related to other unobserved factors. Figure 10.2 contains a plot of labor productivity (output per hour of work) in the United States for the years 1947 through 1987. This series displays a clear upward trend, which reflects the fact that workers have become more productive over time. Other series, at least over certain time periods, have clear downward trends. Because positive trends are more common, we will focus on those during our discussion. What kind of statistical models adequately capture trending behavior? One popular formulation is to write the series {yt} as yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1t 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [10.24] where, in the simplest case, {et} is an independent, identically distributed (i.i.d.) sequence with E(et) 􏱪 0 and Var(et) 􏱪 􏱧2e . Note how the parameter 􏱮1 multiplies time, t, resulting in a linear time trend. Interpreting 􏱮1 in (10.24) is simple: holding all other factors (those in et) fixed, 􏱮1 measures the change in yt from one period to the next due to the passage of time. We can write this mathematically by defining the change in et from period t􏱦1 to t as 􏰧et = et 􏱦 et􏱦1. Equation (10.24) implies that if 􏰧et 􏱪 0 then ∆yt 􏱪yt 􏱦yt􏱦1 􏱪􏱮1. Another way to think about a sequence that has a linear time trend is that its average value is a linear function of time: E(yt) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1t. [10.25] If 􏱮1 􏱰 0, then, on average, yt is growing over time and therefore has an upward trend. If 􏱮1 􏱷 0, then yt has a downward trend. The values of yt do not fall exactly on the line in (10.25) due to randomness, but the expected values are on the line. Unlike the mean, the variance of yt is constant across time: Var(yt) 􏱪 Var(et) 􏱪 􏱧2e . F I G U R E 1 0 . 2 Output per labor hour in the United States during the years 1947–1987; 1977 􏲁 100. output 110 per hour 80 50 1947 1967 1987 year Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 365 If {et} is an i.i.d. sequence, then {yt} is an independent, though not identically, distributed sequence. A more realistic characterization of trending time series allows {et} to be correlated over time, but this does not change the flavor of a linear time trend. In fact, what is important for re- gression analysis under the classical linear model assumptions is that E(yt) is linear in t. When we cover large sample properties of OLS in Chapter 11, we will have to discuss how much temporal cor- relation in {et} is allowed. Many economic time series are bet- ter approximated by an exponential trend, which follows when a series has the same av- erage growth rate from period to period. Figure 10.3 plots data on annual nominal imports for the United States during the years 1948 through 1995 (ERP 1997, Table B-101). In the early years, we see that the change in imports over each year is relatively small, whereas the change increases as time passes. This is consistent with a constant average growth rate: the percentage change is roughly the same in each period. In practice, an exponential trend in a time series is captured by modeling the natural logarithm of the series as a linear trend (assuming that yt 􏱰 0): log(yt) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1t 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, .... [10.26] Exponentiating shows that yt itself has an exponential trend: yt 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1t 􏱕 et). Because we will want to use exponentially trending time series in linear regression models, (10.26) turns out to be the most convenient way for representing such series. EXPLORING FURTHER 10.4 In Example 10.4, we used the general fertility rate as the dependent variable in a finite distributed lag model. From 1950 through the mid-1980s, the gfr has a clear downward trend. Can a linear trend with 􏱮1 􏱷 0 be realistic for all future time periods? Explain. F I G U R E 1 0 . 3 Nominal U.S. imports during the years 1948–1995 (in billions of U.S. dollars). U.S. 750 imports 400 100 7 1948 1972 1995 year Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 366 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data How do we interpret 􏱬1 in (10.26)? Remember that, for small changes, ∆log(yt) 􏱪 log(yt) 􏱦 log(yt􏱦1) is approximately the proportionate change in yt: ∆log( yt) 􏱴 (yt 􏱦 yt􏱦1)/yt􏱦1. [10.27] The right-hand side of (10.27) is also called the growth rate in y from period t 􏱦 1 to period t. To turn the growth rate into a percentage, we simply multiply by 100. If yt follows (10.26), then, taking changes and setting ∆et 􏱪 0, ∆log(yt) 􏱪 􏱬1, for all t. [10.28] In other words, 􏱬1 is approximately the average per period growth rate in yt. For example, if t denotes year and 􏱬1 􏱪 .027, then yt grows about 2.7% per year on average. Although linear and exponential trends are the most common, time trends can be more complicated. For example, instead of the linear trend model in (10.24), we might have a quadratic time trend: yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱮1t􏱕􏱮2t2 􏱕et. [10.29] If 􏱮1 and 􏱮2 are positive, then the slope of the trend is increasing, as is easily seen by com- puting the approximate slope (holding et fixed): ∆yt ___ 􏱴 􏱮1 􏱕 2􏱮2t. [10.30] [If you are familiar with calculus, you recognize the right-hand side of (10.30) as the derivativeof􏱮0 􏱕􏱮1t􏱕􏱮2t2 withrespecttot.]If􏱮1 􏱰0,but􏱮2 􏱷0,thetrendhasa hump shape. This may not be a very good description of certain trending series because it requires an increasing trend to be followed, eventually, by a decreasing trend. Neverthe- less, over a given time span, it can be a flexible way of modeling time series that have more complicated trends than either (10.24) or (10.26). Using Trending Variables in Regression Analysis Accounting for explained or explanatory variables that are trending is fairly straightfor- ward in regression analysis. First, nothing about trending variables necessarily violates the classical linear model assumptions TS.1 through TS.6. However, we must be careful to allow for the fact that unobserved, trending factors that affect yt might also be correlated with the explanatory variables. If we ignore this possibility, we may find a spurious rela- tionship between yt and one or more explanatory variables. The phenomenon of finding a relationship between two or more trending variables simply because each is growing over time is an example of a spurious regression problem. Fortunately, adding a time trend eliminates this problem. For concreteness, consider a model where two observed factors, xt1 and xt2, affect yt. In addition, there are unobserved factors that are systematically growing or shrinking over time. A model that captures this is yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕􏱬2xt2 􏱕􏱬3t􏱕ut. [10.31] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∆t CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 367 This fits into the multiple linear regression framework with xt3 􏱪 t. Allowing for the trend in this equation explicitly recognizes that yt may be growing (􏱬3 􏱰 0) or shrinking (􏱬3 􏱷 0) over time for reasons essentially unrelated to xt1 and xt2. If (10.31) satisfies assumptions TS.1, TS.2, and TS.3, then omitting t from the regression and regressing yt on xt1, xt2 will generally yield biased estimators of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2: we have effectively omitted an important variable, t, from the regression. This is especially true if xt1 and xt2 are themselves trend- ing, because they can then be highly correlated with t. The next example shows how omit- ting a time trend can result in spurious regression. EXAMPLE 10.7 HOUSING INVESTMENT AND PRICES The data in HSEINV.RAW are annual observations on housing investment and a housing price index in the United States for 1947 through 1988. Let invpc denote real per capita housing investment (in thousands of dollars) and let price denote a housing price index (equal to 1 in 1982). A simple regression in constant elasticity form, which can be thought of as a supply equation for housing stock, gives 􏱾log(invpc)􏱪 􏱦.550 􏱕 1.241 log(price) (.043) (.382) [10.32] The elasticity of per capita investment with respect to price is very large and statistically significant; it is not statistically different from one. We must be careful here. Both invpc and price have upward trends. In particular, if we regress log(invpc) on t, we obtain a coefficient on the trend equal to .0081 (standard error 􏱪 .0018); the regression of log(price) on t yields a trend coefficient equal to .0044 (standard error 􏱪 .0004). Although the standard errors on the trend coefficients are not necessarily reliable—these regressions tend to contain substantial serial correlation—the coefficient estimates do reveal upward trends. To account for the trending behavior of the variables, we add a time trend: 􏱾log(invpc)􏱪 􏱦.913 􏱦 .381 log(price) 􏱕 .0098 t (.136) (.679)- (.0035) [10.33] n􏱪42,R2 􏱪.341,R2 􏱪.307. The story is much different now: the estimated price elasticity is negative and not statis- tically different from zero. The time trend is statistically significant, and its coefficient implies an approximate 1% increase in invpc per year, on average. From this analysis, we cannot conclude that real per capita housing investment is influenced at all by price. There are other factors, captured in the time trend, that affect invpc, but we have not modeled these. The results in (10.32) show a spurious relationship between invpc and price due to the fact that price is also trending upward over time. In some cases, adding a time trend can make a key explanatory variable more significant. This can happen if the dependent and independent variables have different kinds of trends (say, one upward and one downward), but movement in the independent variable about its trend line causes movement in the dependent variable away from its trend line. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. n 􏱪 42, R2 􏱪 .208,R-2 􏱪 .189. 368 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data EXAMPLE 10.8 FERTILITY EQUATION If we add a linear time trend to the fertility equation (10.18), we obtain 􏱾gfrt􏱪 111.77 􏱕 .279 pet 􏱦 35.59 ww2t 􏱕 .997 pillt 􏱦 1.15 t (3.36) (.040)- (6.30) (6.626) (.19) [10.34] n􏱪72,R2 􏱪.662,R2 􏱪.642. The coefficient on pe is more than triple the estimate from (10.18), and it is much more statistically significant. Interestingly, pill is not significant once an allowance is made for a linear trend. As can be seen by the estimate, gfr was falling, on average, over this period, other factors being equal. Since the general fertility rate exhibited both upward and downward trends during the period from 1913 through 1984, we can see how robust the estimated effect of pe is when we use a quadratic trend: 􏱾gfrt􏱪 124.09 􏱕 .348 pet 􏱦 35.88 ww2t 􏱦 10.12 pillt (4.36) (.040) (5.71) (6.34) The coefficient on pe is even larger and more statistically significant. Now, pill has the expected negative effect and is marginally significant, and both trend terms are statisti- cally significant. The quadratic trend is a flexible way to account for the unusual trending behavior of gfr. You might be wondering in Example 10.8: Why stop at a quadratic trend? Nothing prevents us from adding, say, t3 as an independent variable, and, in fact, this might be warranted (see Computer Exercise C6). But we have to be careful not to get carried away when including trend terms in a model. We want relatively simple trends that capture broad movements in the dependent variable that are not explained by the independent variables in the model. If we include enough polynomial terms in t, then we can track any series pretty well. But this offers little help in finding which explanatory variables affect yt. A Detrending Interpretation of Regressions with a Time Trend Including a time trend in a regression model creates a nice interpretation in terms of detrending the original data series before using them in regression analysis. For concrete- ness, we focus on model (10.31), but our conclusions are much more general. When we regress yt on xt1, xt2, and t, we obtain the fitted equation yˆt 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xt1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2xt2 􏱕 􏱬ˆ3t. [10.36] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱦 2.53 t 􏱕 .0196 t2 (.39) (.0050) [10.35] n 􏱪 72, R2 􏱪 .727,R-2 􏱪 .706. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 369 We can extend the results on the partialling out interpretation of OLS that we covered in Chapter 3 to show that 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 can be obtained as follows. (i) Regress each of yt, xt1, and xt2 on a constant and the time trend t and save the residuals, say, ̇y ̇t, ̇x ̇t1, ̇x ̇t2, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. For example, ̇y ̇t 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏱮ˆ0 􏱦 􏱮ˆ1t. T h u s , w e c a n t h i n k o f ̇y ̇ t a s b e i n g l i n e a r l y d e t r e n d e d . I n d e t r e n d i n g y t , w e h a v e e s t i m a t e d the model yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱮1t􏱕et by OLS; the residuals from this regression, eˆt 􏱪 ̇y ̇t, have the time trend removed (at least in the sample). A similar interpretation holds for ̇x ̇t1 and ̇x ̇t2. (ii) Run the regression of ̇y ̇t on ̇x ̇t1, ̇x ̇t2. [10.37] If t is omitted from (10.36), then no detrending occurs, and yt might seem to be related to one or more of the xtj simply because each contains a trend; we saw this in Example 10.7. If the trend term is statistically significant, and the results change in important ways when a time trend is added to a regression, then the initial results without a trend should be treated with suspicion. ˆ ˆ The interpretation of 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 shows that it is a good idea to include a trend in the regression if any independent variable is trending, even if yt is not. If yt has no noticeable trend, but, say, xt1 is growing over time, then excluding a trend from the regression may make it look as if xt1 has no effect on yt, even though movements of xt1 about its trend may affect yt. This will be captured if t is included in the regression. (No intercept is necessary, but including an intercept affects nothing: the intercept will be estimated to be zero.) This regression exactly yields 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 from (10.36). This means that the estimates of primary interest, 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2, can be interpreted as coming from a regression without a time trend, but where we first detrend the dependent variable and all other independent variables. The same conclusion holds with any number of independent variables and if the trend is quadratic or of some other polynomial degree. EXAMPLE 10.9 PUERTO RICAN EMPLOYMENT When we add a linear trend to equation (10.17), the estimates are 􏱾log(prepopt)􏱪 􏱦8.70 􏱦 .169 log(mincovt) 􏱕 1.06 log(usgnpt) (1.30) (.044) 􏱦 .032 t [10.38] The coefficient on log(usgnp) has changed dramatically: from 􏱦.012 and insignificant to 1.06 and very significant. The coefficient on the minimum wage has changed only slightly, although the standard error is notably smaller, making log(mincov) more significant than before. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. (.005) n􏱪38,R2 􏱪.847,R2 􏱪.834. (0.18) - 370 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data The variable prepopt displays no clear upward or downward trend, but log(usgnp) has an upward, linear trend. [A regression of log(usgnp) on t gives an estimate of about .03, so that usgnp is growing by about 3% per year over the period.] We can think of the estimate 1.06 as follows: when usgnp increases by 1% above its long-run trend, prepop increases by about 1.06%. Computing R-Squared when the Dependent Variable Is Trending R-squareds in time series regressions are often very high, especially compared with typical R-squareds for cross-sectional data. Does this mean that we learn more about factors affecting y from time series data? Not necessarily. On one hand, time series data often come in aggregate form (such as average hourly wages in the U.S. economy), and aggregates are often easier to explain than outcomes on individuals, families, or firms, which is often the nature of cross-sectional data. But the usual and adjusted R-squareds for time series regressions can be artificially high when the dependent variable is trending. Remember that R2 is a measure of how large the error variance is relative to the variance of y. The formula for the adjusted R-squared shows this directly: R-2 􏱪1􏱦(􏱧ˆ2u/􏱧ˆ2y), w∑here 􏱧ˆ 2u is the unbiased estimator of the error variance, 􏱧ˆ 2y 􏱪 SST/(n 􏱦 1), and SST 􏱪 n (yt 􏱦 y-)2. Now, estimating the error variance when yt is trending is no problem, pro- t􏱪1 vided a time trend is included in the regression. However, when E(yt) follows, say, a linear time trend [see (10.24)], SST/(n 􏱦 1) is no longer an unbiased or consistent estimator of Var(yt). In fact, SST/(n 􏱦 1) can substantially overestimate the variance in yt, because it does not account for the trend in yt. When the dependent variable satisfies linear, quadratic, or any other polynomial trends, it is easy to compute a goodness-of-fit measure that first nets out the effect of any time trend on yt. The simplest method is to compute the usual R-squared in a regression where the dependent variable has already been detrended. For example, if the model is (10.31), then we first regress yt on t and obtain the residuals ̇y ̇t. Then, we regress ̇y ̇t on xt1, xt2, and t. The R-squared from this regression is ̇y ̇2t t􏱪1 [10.39] [10.40] 1 􏱦 _S∑_S_R_ n , w∑here SSR is identical to the sum of squared residuals from (10.36). Since ∑n ̇y ̇2t 􏰯 greater than, and usually less than, the R-squared from (10.36). (The sum of squared resid- uals is identical in both regressions.) When yt contains a strong linear time trend, (10.40) can be much less than the usual R-squared. The R-squared in (10.40) better reflects how well xt1 and xt2 explain yt because it nets out the effect of the time trend. After all, we can always explain a trending variable Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. t􏱪1 t􏱪1 (yt 􏱦 y) (and usually the inequality is strict), the R-squared from (10.40) is no n -2 CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 371 with some sort of trend, but this does not mean we have uncovered any factors that cause movements in yt. An adjusted R-squared can also be compu∑ted based on (10.40): divide SSR by (n 􏱦 4) because this is the df in (10.36) and divide n ̇y ̇2t by (n 􏱦 2), as there are two trend parameters estimated in detrending y . In gen∑ t􏱪1 intheusualregression(thatincludesanytimetrends),and t􏱪1 ̇y ̇ isdividedby(n􏱦p), t where p is the number of trend parameters estimated in detrending yt. Wooldridge (1991a) provides detailed suggestions for degrees-of-freedom corrections, but a computationally simple approach is fine as an approximation: use the adjusted R-squared from the regres- sion ÿt on t, t2, ..., tp, xt1, ..., xtk. This requires us only to remove the trend from yt to obtain ÿt, and then we can use ÿt to compute the usual kinds of goodness-of-fit measures. EXAMPLE 10.10 HOUSING INVESTMENT In Example 10.7, we saw that including a linear time trend along with log( price) in the housing investment equation had a substantial effect on the price elasticity. But the R-squared from regression (10.33), taken literally, says that we are “explaining” 34.1% of the variation in log(invpc). This is misleading. If we first detrend log(invpc) and regress the detrended variable on log( price) and t, the R-squared becomes .008, and the adjusted R-squared is actually negative. Thus, movements in log(price) about its trend have virtu- ally no explanatory power for movements in log(invpc) about its trend. This is consistent with the fact that the t statistic on log(price) in equation (10.33) is very small. Before leaving this subsection, we must make a final point. In computing the R-squared form of an F statistic for testing multiple hypotheses, we just use the usual R-squareds without any detrending. Remember, the R-squared form of the F statistic is just a computational device, and so the usual formula is always appropriate. Seasonality If a time series is observed at monthly or quarterly intervals (or even weekly or daily), it may exhibit seasonality. For example, monthly housing starts in the Midwest are strongly influenced by weather. Although weather patterns are somewhat random, we can be sure that the weather during January will usually be more inclement than in June, and so hous- ing starts are generally higher in June than in January. One way to model this phenomenon is to allow the expected value of the series, yt, to be different in each month. As another example, retail sales in the fourth quarter are typically higher than in the previous three quarters because of the Christmas holiday. Again, this can be captured by allowing the average retail sales to differ over the course of a year. This is in addition to possibly al- lowing for a trending mean. For example, retail sales in the most recent first quarter were higher than retail sales in the fourth quarter from 30 years ago, because retail sales have been steadily growing. Nevertheless, if we compare average sales within a typical year, the seasonal holiday factor tends to make sales larger in the fourth quarter. Even though many monthly and quarterly data series display seasonal patterns, not all of them do. For example, there is no noticeable seasonal pattern in monthly interest or inflation rates. In addition, series that do display seasonal patterns are often seasonally adjusted before they are reported for public use. A seasonally adjusted series is one that, in principle, has had the seasonal factors removed from it. Seasonal adjustment can be Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. eral, SSR is divided by the df tn2 372 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data done in a variety of ways, and a careful discussion is beyond the scope of this text. [See Harvey (1990) and Hylleberg (1992) for detailed treatments.] Seasonal adjustment has become so common that it is not possible to get seasonally unadjusted data in many cases. Quarterly U.S. GDP is a leading example. In the annual Economic Report of the President, many macroeconomic data sets reported at monthly frequencies (at least for the most recent years) and those that display seasonal patterns are all seasonally adjusted. The major sources for macroeconomic time series, including Citibase, also seasonally adjust many of the series. Thus, the scope for using our own sea- sonal adjustment is often limited. Sometimes, we do work with seasonally unadjusted data, and it is useful to know that simple methods are available for dealing with seasonality in regression models. Generally, we can include a set of seasonal dummy variables to account for seasonality in the dependent variable, the independent variables, or both. The approach is simple. Suppose that we have monthly data, and we think that seasonal patterns within a year are roughly constant across time. For example, since Christmas always comes at the same time of year, we can expect retail sales to be, on average, higher in months late in the year than in earlier months. Or, since weather patterns are broadly similar across years, housing starts in the Midwest will be higher on average during the summer months than the winter months. A general model for monthly data that captures these phenomena is yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱛1febt 􏱕􏱛2mart 􏱕􏱛3aprt 􏱕...􏱕􏱛11dect 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, [10.41] where febt, mart, ..., dect are dummy variables indicating whether time period t corresponds to the appropriate month. In this formulation, January is the base month, and 􏱬0 is the intercept for Janu- ary. If there is no seasonality in yt, once the xt j have been controlled for, then 􏱛1 through 􏱛11 are all zero. This is easily tested via an F test. EXAMPLE 10.11 EFFECTS OF ANTIDUMPING FILINGS In Example 10.5, we used monthly data (in the file BARIUM.RAW) that have not been seasonally adjusted. Therefore, we should add seasonal dummy variables to make sure none of the important conclusions change. It could be that the months just before the suit was filed are months where imports are higher or lower, on average, than in other months. When we add the 11 monthly dummy variables as in (10.41) and test their joint signifi- cance, we obtain p-value 􏱪 .59, and so the seasonal dummies are jointly insignificant. In addition, nothing important changes in the estimates once statistical significance is taken into account. Krupp and Pollard (1996) actually used three dummy variables for the sea- sons (fall, spring, and summer, with winter as the base season), rather than a full set of monthly dummies; the outcome is essentially the same. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 10.5 In equation (10.41), what is the intercept for March? Explain why seasonal dummy variables satisfy the strict exogeneity assumption. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 373 If the data are quarterly, then we would include dummy variables for three of the four quarters, with the omitted category being the base quarter. Sometimes, it is useful to in- teract seasonal dummies with some of the xtj to allow the effect of xtj on yt to differ across the year. Just as including a time trend in a regression has the interpretation of initially detrend- ing the data, including seasonal dummies in a regression can be interpreted as deseason- alizing the data. For concreteness, consider equation (10.41) with k 􏱪 2. The OLS slope coefficients 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2 on x1 and x2 can be obtained as follows: (i) Regress each of yt, xt1, and xt2 on a constant and the monthly dummies, febt, mart, ..., dect, and save the residuals, say, ̇y ̇t, ̇x ̇t1, and ̇x ̇t2, for all t 􏱪 1, 2 ..., n. For example, ̇y ̇t 􏱪yt 􏱦􏱮ˆ0 􏱦􏱮ˆ1febt 􏱦􏱮ˆ2mart 􏱦...􏱦􏱮ˆ11dect. This is one method of deseasonalizing a monthly time series. A similar interpretation holds for ̇x ̇t1 and ̇x ̇t2. (ii) Run the regression, without the monthly dummies, of ̇y ̇t on ̇x ̇t1 and ̇x ̇t2 [ just as in (10.37)]. This gives 􏱬ˆ1 and 􏱬ˆ2. In some cases, if yt has pronounced seasonality, a better goodness-of-fit measure is an R-squared based on the deseasonalized yt. This nets out any seasonal effects that are not explained by the xtj. Wooldridge (1991a) suggests specific degrees-of-freedom adjust- ments, or one may simply use the adjusted R-squared where the dependent variable has been deseasonalized. Time series exhibiting seasonal patterns can be trending as well, in which case we should estimate a regression model with a time trend and seasonal dummy variables. The regressions can then be interpreted as regressions using both detrended and deseasonal- ized series. Goodness-of-fit statistics are discussed in Wooldridge (1991a): essentially, we detrend and deseasonalize yt by regressing on both a time trend and seasonal dummies before computing R-squared or adjusted R-squared. Summary In this chapter, we have covered basic regression analysis with time series data. Under as- sumptions that parallel those for cross-sectional analysis, OLS is unbiased (under TS.1 through TS.3), OLS is BLUE (under TS.1 through TS.5), and the usual OLS standard errors, t statistics, and F statistics can be used for statistical inference (under TS.1 through TS.6). Because of the temporal correlation in most time series data, we must explicitly make assumptions about how the errors are related to the explanatory variables in all time periods and about the tempo- ral correlation in the errors themselves. The classical linear model assumptions can be pretty restrictive for time series applications, but they are a natural starting point. We have applied them to both static regression and finite distributed lag models. Logarithms and dummy variables are used regularly in time series applications and in event studies. We also discussed index numbers and time series measured in terms of nominal and real dollars. Trends and seasonality can be easily handled in a multiple regression framework by includ- ing time and seasonal dummy variables in our regression equations. We presented problems with the usual R-squared as a goodness-of-fit measure and suggested some simple alternatives based on detrending or deseasonalizing. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 374 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data CLASSICAL LINEAR MODEL ASSUMPTIONS FOR TIME SERIES REGRESSION Following is a summary of the six classical linear model (CLM) assumptions for time series regression applications. Assumptions TS.1 through TS.5 are the time series versions of the Gauss-Markov assumptions (which implies that OLS is BLUE and has the usual sampling vari- ances). We only needed TS.1, TS.2, and TS.3 to establish unbiasedness of OLS. As in the case of cross-sectional regression, the normality assumption, TS.6, was used so that we could per- form exact statistical inference for any sample size. Assumption TS.1 (Linear in Parameters) The stochastic process {(xt1, xt2, ..., xtk, yt): t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} follows the linear model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕􏱬2xt2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, where {ut : t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is the sequence of errors or disturbances. Here, n is the number of observations (time periods). Assumption TS.2 (No Perfect Collinearity) In the sample (and therefore in the underlying time series process), no independent variable is constant nor a perfect linear combination of the others. Assumption TS.3 (Zero Conditional Mean) For each t, the expected value of the error ut, given the explanatory variables for all time peri- ods, is zero. Mathematically, E(ut􏰫X) 􏱪 0, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. Assumption TS.3 replaces MLR.4 for cross-sectional regression, and it also means we do not have to make the random sampling assumption MLR.2. Remember, Assumption TS.3 implies that the error in each time period t is uncorrelated with all explanatory variables in all time periods (including, of course, time period t). Assumption TS.4 (Homoskedasticity) Conditional on X, the variance of ut is the same for all t: Var(ut􏰫X) 􏱪 Var(ut) 􏱪 􏱧2, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. Assumption TS.5 (No Serial Correlation) Conditional on X, the errors in two different time periods are uncorrelated: Corr(ut, us􏰫X) 􏱪 0, for all t 􏱻 s. Recall that we added the no serial correlation assumption, along with the homoskedastic- ity assumption, to obtain the same variance formulas that we derived for cross-sectional regres- sion under random sampling. As we will see in Chapter 12, Assumption TS.5 is often violated in ways that can make the usual statistical inference very unreliable. Assumption TS.6 (Normality) The errors ut are independent of X and are independently and identically distributed as Normal (0, 􏱧2). Key Terms Autocorrelation Base Period Base Value Contemporaneously Exogenous Cumulative Effect Deseasonalizing Detrending Event Study Exponential Trend Finite Distributed Lag (FDL) Model Growth Rate Impact Multiplier Impact Propensity Index Number Lag Distribution Linear Time Trend Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Problems Long-Run Elasticity Long-Run Multiplier Long-Run Propensity (LRP) Seasonal Dummy Variables Seasonality Seasonally Adjusted Serial Correlation Short-Run Elasticity Spurious Regression Problem Static Model Stochastic Process Strictly Exogenous Time Series Process Time Trend CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 375 1 Decide if you agree or disagree with each of the following statements and give a brief explanation of your decision: (i) Like cross-sectional observations, we can assume that most time series observa- tions are independently distributed. (ii) The OLS estimator in a time series regression is unbiased under the first three Gauss-Markov assumptions. (iii) A trending variable cannot be used as the dependent variable in multiple regression analysis. (iv) Seasonality is not an issue when using annual time series observations. 2 Let gGDPt denote the annual percentage change in gross domestic product and let intt denote a short-term interest rate. Suppose that gGDPt is related to interest rates by gGDPt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0 intt 􏱕 􏱛1intt􏱦1 􏱕 ut, where ut is uncorrelated with intt, intt􏱦1, and all other past values of interest rates. Suppose that the Federal Reserve follows the policy rule: intt 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1(gGDPt􏱦1 􏱦 3) 􏱕 vt, where 􏰸1 􏱰 0. (When last year’s GDP growth is above 3%, the Fed increases interest rates to prevent an “overheated” economy.) If vt is uncorrelated with all past values of intt and ut, argue that intt must be correlated with ut􏱦1. (Hint: Lag the first equation for one time period and substitute for gGDPt􏱦1 in the second equation.) Which Gauss- Markov assumption does this violate? 3 Suppose yt follows a second order FDL model: yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0zt 􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕􏱛2zt􏱦2 􏱕ut. Let z* denote the equilibrium value of zt and let y* be the equilibrium value of yt, such that y* 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0z* 􏱕􏱛1z* 􏱕􏱛2z*. Show that the change in y*, due to a change in z*, equals the long-run propensity times the change in z*: This gives an alternative way of interpreting the LRP. 4 When the three event indicators befile6, affile6, and afdec6 are dropped from equation (10.22), we obtain R2 􏱪 .281 and R- 2 􏱪 .264. Are the event indicators jointly significant at the 10% level? ∆y* 􏱪 LRP􏱳∆z*. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 376 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 5 Suppose you have quarterly data on new housing starts, interest rates, and real per capita income. Specify a model for housing starts that accounts for possible trends and season- ality in the variables. 6 In Example 10.4, we saw that our estimates of the individual lag coefficients in a distrib- uted lag model were very imprecise. One way to alleviate the multicollinearity problem is to assume that the 􏱛j follow a relatively simple pattern. For concreteness, consider a model with four lags: yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱛0zt 􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕􏱛2zt􏱦2 􏱕􏱛3zt􏱦3 􏱕􏱛4zt􏱦4 􏱕ut. Now, let us assume that the 􏱛j follow a quadratic in the lag, j: 􏱛j 􏱪􏰸0 􏱕􏰸1j􏱕􏰸2j2, for parameters 􏰸0, 􏰸1, and 􏰸2. This is an example of a polynomial distributed lag (PDL) model. (i) Plug the formula for each 􏱛j into the distributed lag model and write the model in terms of the parameters 􏰸h, for h 􏱪 0,1,2. (ii) Explain the regression you would run to estimate the 􏰸h. (iii) The polynomial distributed lag model is a restricted version of the general model. How many restrictions are imposed? How would you test these? (Hint: Think F test.) 7 In Example 10.4, we wrote the model that explicitly contains the long-run propensity, 􏰩0, as gfrt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰩0pet 􏱕􏱛1(pet􏱦1 􏱦pet)􏱕􏱛2(pet􏱦2 􏱦pet)􏱕ut, where we omit the other explanatory variables for simplicity. As always with multiple regression analysis, 􏰩0 should have a ceteris paribus interpretation. Namely, if pet increases by one (dollar) holding (pet􏱦1 􏱦 pet) and (pet􏱦2 􏱦 pet) fixed, gfrt should change by 􏰩0. (i) If (pet􏱦1 􏱦 pet) and (pet􏱦2 􏱦 pet) are held fixed but pet is increasing, what must be true about changes in pet􏱦1 and pet􏱦2? (ii) How does your answer in part (i) help you to interpret 􏰩0 in the above equation as the LRP? 8 In the linear model given in equation (10.8), the explanatory variables xt 􏱪 (xt1, ..., xtk) are said to be sequentially exogenous (sometimes called weakly exogenous) if E(ut􏰫xt, xt􏱦1, ..., x1)􏱪0, t􏱪1, 2, ..., so that the errors are unpredictable given current and all past values of the explanatory variables. (i) Explain why sequential exogeneity is implied by strict exogeneity. (ii) Explain why contemporaneous exogeneity is implied by sequential exogeneity. (iii) Are the OLS estimators generally unbiased under the sequential exogeneity as- sumption? Explain. (iv) Consider a model to explain the annual rate of HIV infections (HIVrate) as a distributed lag of per capita condom usage (pccon) for a state, region, or province: E(HIVratet􏰫pccont, pccontt􏱦1, ...,) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0 pccont 􏱕 􏱛1 pccont􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2 pccont􏱦2 􏱕 􏱛3 pccont􏱦3. Explain why this model satisfies the sequential exogeneity assumption. Does it seem likely that strict exogeneity holds too? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 377 Computer Exercises C1 In October 1979, the Federal Reserve changed its policy of using finely tuned interest rate adjustments and instead began targeting the money supply. Using the data in INTDEF.RAW, define a dummy variable equal to 1 for years after 1979. Include this dummy in equation (10.15) to see if there is a shift in the interest rate equation after 1979. What do you conclude? C2 Use the data in BARIUM.RAW for this exercise. (i) Add a linear time trend to equation (10.22). Are any variables, other than the trend, statistically significant? (ii) In the equation estimated in part (i), test for joint significance of all variables except the time trend. What do you conclude? (iii) Add monthly dummy variables to this equation and test for seasonality. Does in- cluding the monthly dummies change any other estimates or their standard errors in important ways? C3 Add the variable log( prgnp) to the minimum wage equation in (10.38). Is this variable significant? Interpret the coefficient. How does adding log( prgnp) affect the estimated minimum wage effect? C4 Use the data in FERTIL3.RAW to verify that the standard error for the LRP in equation (10.19) is about .030. C5 Use the data in EZANDERS.RAW for this exercise. The data are on monthly unemploy- ment claims in Anderson Township in Indiana, from January 1980 through November 1988. In 1984, an enterprise zone (EZ) was located in Anderson (as well as other cities in Indiana). [See Papke (1994) for details.] (i) Regress log(uclms) on a linear time trend and 11 monthly dummy variables. What was the overall trend in unemployment claims over this period? (Interpret the coefficient on the time trend.) Is there evidence of seasonality in unemployment claims? (ii) Add ez, a dummy variable equal to 1 in the months Anderson had an EZ, to the regression in part (i). Does having the enterprise zone seem to decrease unemploy- ment claims? By how much? [You should use formula (7.10) from Chapter 7.] (iii) What assumptions do you need to make to attribute the effect in part (ii) to the creation of an EZ? C6 Use the data in FERTIL3.RAW for this exercise. ·· (i) Regress gfrt on t and t2 and save the residuals. This gives a detrended gfrt, say, g ft . ·· 2 (ii) Regress g ft on all of the variables in equation (10.35), including t and t . Compare the R-squared with that from (10.35). What do you conclude? (iii) Reestimate equation (10.35) but add t3 to the equation. Is this additional term sta- tistically significant? C7 Use the data set CONSUMP.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate a simple regression model relating the growth in real per capita con- sumption (of nondurables and services) to the growth in real per capita disposable income. Use the change in the logarithms in both cases. Report the results in the usual form. Interpret the equation and discuss statistical significance. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 378 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data (ii) Add a lag of the growth in real per capita disposable income to the equation from part (i). What do you conclude about adjustment lags in consumption growth? (iii) Add the real interest rate to the equation in part (i). Does it affect consumption growth? C8 Use the data in FERTIL3.RAW for this exercise. (i) Add pet􏱦3 and pet􏱦4 to equation (10.19). Test for joint significance of these lags. (ii) Find the estimated long-run propensity and its standard error in the model from part (i). Compare these with those obtained from equation (10.19). (iii) Estimate the polynomial distributed lag model from Problem 6. Find the estimated LRP and compare this with what is obtained from the unrestricted model. C9 Use the data in VOLAT.RAW for this exercise. The variable rsp500 is the monthly return on the Standard & Poor’s 500 stock market index, at an annual rate. (This in- cludes price changes as well as dividends.) The variable i3 is the return on three-month T-bills, and pcip is the percentage change in industrial production; these are also at an annual rate. (i) Consider the equation rsp500t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1pcipt 􏱕 􏱬2i3t 􏱕 ut. What signs do you think 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 should have? (ii) Estimate the previous equation by OLS, reporting the results in standard form. In- terpret the signs and magnitudes of the coefficients. (iii) Which of the variables is statistically significant? (iv) Does your finding from part (iii) imply that the return on the S&P 500 is predictable? Explain. C10 Consider the model estimated in (10.15); use the data in INTDEF.RAW. (i) Find the correlation between inf and def over this sample period and comment. (ii) Add a single lag of inf and def to the equation and report the results in the usual form. (iii) Compare the estimated LRP for the effect of inflation with that in equation (10.15). Are they vastly different? (iv) Are the two lags in the model jointly significant at the 5% level? C11 The file TRAFFIC2.RAW contains 108 monthly observations on automobile accidents, traffic laws, and some other variables for California from January 1981 through December 1989. Use this data set to answer the following questions. (i) During what month and year did California’s seat belt law take effect? When did the highway speed limit increase to 65 miles per hour? (ii) Regress the variable log(totacc) on a linear time trend and 11 monthly dummy variables, using January as the base month. Interpret the coefficient estimate on the time trend. Would you say there is seasonality in total accidents? (iii) Add to the regression from part (ii) the variables wkends, unem, spdlaw, and belt- law. Discuss the coefficient on the unemployment variable. Does its sign and mag- nitude make sense to you? (iv) In the regression from part (iii), interpret the coefficients on spdlaw and beltlaw. Are the estimated effects what you expected? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. C12 (i) Estimate equation (10.2) using all the data in PHILLIPS.RAW and report the CHAPTER 10 Basic Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 379 (v) The variable prcfat is the percentage of accidents resulting in at least one fatality. Note that this variable is a percentage, not a proportion. What is the average of prcfat over this period? Does the magnitude seem about right? (vi) Run the regression in part (iii) but use prcfat as the dependent variable in place of log(totacc). Discuss the estimated effects and significance of the speed and seat belt law variables. results in the usual form. How many observations do you have now? (ii) Compare the estimates from part (i) with those in equation (10.14). In particu- lar, does adding the extra years help in obtaining an estimated tradeoff between inflation and unemployment? Explain. (iii) Now run the regression using only the years 1997 through 2003. How do these estimates differ from those in equation (10.14)? Are the estimates using the most recent seven years precise enough to draw any firm conclusions? Explain. (iv) Consider a simple regression setup in which we start with n time series observations and then split them into an early time period and a later time period. In the first time period we have n1 observations and in the second period n2 observations. Draw on the previous parts of this exercise to evaluate the following statement: “Generally, we can expect the slope estimate using all n observations to be roughly equal to a weighted average of the slope estimates on the early and later subsamples, where the weights are n1/n and n2/n, respectively.” C13 Use the data in MINWAGE.RAW for this exercise. In particular, use the employment and wage series for sector 232 (Men’s and Boys’ Furnishings). The variable gwage232 is the monthly growth (change in logs) in the average wage in sector 232, gemp232 is the growth in employment in sector 232, gmwage is the growth in the federal minimum wage, and gcpi is the growth in the (urban) Consumer Price Index. (i) Run the regression gwage232 on gmwage, gcpi. Do the sign and magnitude of 􏱬ˆgmwage make sense to you? Explain. Is gmwage statistically significant? (ii) Add lags 1 through 12 of gmwage to the equation in part (i). Do you think it is necessary to include these lags to estimate the long-run effect of minimum wage growth on wage growth in sector 232? Explain. (iii) Run the regression gemp232 on gmwage,gcpi. Does minimum wage growth appear to have a contemporaneous effect on gemp232? (iv) Add lags 1 through 12 to the employment growth equation. Does growth in the minimum wage have a statistically significant effect on employment growth, either in the short run or long run? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 380 In Chapter 10, we discussed the finite sample properties of OLS for time series data under increasingly stronger sets of assumptions. Under the full set of classical linear model assumptions for time series, TS.1 through TS.6, OLS has exactly the same desirable properties that we derived for cross-sectional data. Likewise, statistical inference is carried out in the same way as it was for cross-sectional analysis. From our cross-sectional analysis in Chapter 5, we know that there are good reasons for studying the large sample properties of OLS. For example, if the error terms are not drawn from a normal distribution, then we must rely on the central limit theorem to justify the usual OLS test statistics and confidence intervals. Large sample analysis is even more important in time series contexts. (This is some- what ironic given that large time series samples can be difficult to come by; but we often have no choice other than to rely on large sample approximations.) In Section 10.3, we explained how the strict exogeneity assumption (TS.3) might be violated in static and distributed lag models. As we will show in Section 11.2, models with lagged dependent variables must violate Assumption TS.3. Unfortunately, large sample analysis for time series problems is fraught with many more difficulties than it was for cross-sectional analysis. In Chapter 5, we obtained the large sample properties of OLS in the context of random sampling. Things are more com- plicated when we allow the observations to be correlated across time. Nevertheless, the major limit theorems hold for certain, although not all, time series processes. The key is whether the correlation between the variables at different time periods tends to zero quickly enough. Time series that have substantial temporal correlation require special attention in regression analysis. This chapter will alert you to certain issues pertaining to such series in regression analysis. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 381 11.1 Stationary and Weakly Dependent Time Series In this section, we present the key concepts that are needed to apply the usual large sample approximations in regression analysis with time series data. The details are not as important as a general understanding of the issues. Stationary and Nonstationary Time Series Historically, the notion of a stationary process has played an important role in the analy- sis of time series. A stationary time series process is one whose probability distributions are stable over time in the following sense: If we take any collection of random variables in the sequence and then shift that sequence ahead h time periods, the joint probability distribution must remain unchanged. A formal definition of stationarity follows. Stationary Stochastic Process. The stochastic process {xt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is stationary if for every collection of time indices 1 􏰯 t1 􏱷 t2 􏱷 ... 􏱷 tm, the joint distribution of (xt1, xt2, ..., xtm) is the same as the joint distribution of (xt1􏱕h, xt2􏱕h, ..., xtm􏱕h) for all integers h 􏱸 1. This definition is a little abstract, but its meaning is pretty straightforward. One impli- cation (by choosing m 􏱪 1 and t1 􏱪 1) is that xt has the same distribution as x1 for all t 􏱪 2, 3, .... In other words, the sequence {xt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is identically distributed. Stationarity requires even more. For example, the joint distribution of (x1, x2) (the first two terms in the sequence) must be the same as the joint distribution of (xt, xt􏱕1) for any t 􏱸 1. Again, this places no restrictions on how xt and xt􏱕1 are related to one another; indeed, they may be highly correlated. Stationarity does require that the nature of any correlation between adjacent terms is the same across all time periods. A stochastic process that is not stationary is said to be a nonstationary process. Since stationarity is an aspect of the underlying stochastic process and not of the available single realization, it can be very difficult to determine whether the data we have collected were generated by a stationary process. However, it is easy to spot certain sequences that are not stationary. A process with a time trend of the type covered in Section 10.5 is clearly nonstationary: at a minimum, its mean changes over time. Sometimes, a weaker form of stationarity suffices. If {xt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} has a finite second moment, that is, E(xt2) 􏱷 􏱵 for all t, then the following definition applies. Covariance Stationary Process. A stochastic process {xt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} with a finite second moment [E(xt2) 􏱷 􏱵] is covariance stationary if (i) E(xt) is constant; (ii) Var(xt) is constant; and (iii) for any t, h 􏱸 1, Cov(xt, xt􏱕h) depends only on h and not on t. Covariance stationarity focuses only on the first two moments of a stochastic process: the mean and variance of the pro- cess are constant across time, and the co- variance between xt and xt􏱕h depends only on the distance between the two terms, h, and not on the location of the initial time period, t. It follows immediately that the correlation between xt and xt􏱕h also de- pends only on h. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 11.1 Suppose that {yt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is generated byyt 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1t􏱕et,where􏱛1 􏱻0,and {et: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is an i.i.d. sequence with mean zero and variance 􏱧e2. (i) Is {yt } cova- riance stationary? (ii) Is yt 􏱦 E(yt) covariance stationary? 382 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data If a stationary process has a finite second moment, then it must be covariance stationary, but the converse is certainly not true. Sometimes, to emphasize that stationar- ity is a stronger requirement than covariance stationarity, the former is referred to as strict stationarity. Because strict stationarity simplifies the statements of some of our subsequent assumptions, “stationarity” for us will always mean the strict form. How is stationarity used in time series econometrics? On a technical level, stationarity sim- plifies statements of the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem, although we will not worry about formal statements in this chapter. On a practical level, if we want to understand the relationship between two or more variables using regression analysis, we need to assume some sort of stability over time. If we allow the relationship between two variables (say, yt and xt) to change arbitrarily in each time period, then we cannot hope to learn much about how a change in one variable affects the other variable if we only have access to a single time series realization. In stating a multiple regression model for time series data, we are assuming a certain form of stationarity in that the 􏱬j do not change over time. Further, Assumptions TS.4 and TS.5 imply that the variance of the error process is constant over time and that the correlation between errors in two adjacent periods is equal to zero, which is clearly constant over time. Weakly Dependent Time Series Stationarity has to do with the joint distributions of a process as it moves through time. A very different concept is that of weak dependence, which places restrictions on how strongly related the random variables xt and xt􏱕h can be as the time distance between them, h, gets large. The notion of weak dependence is most easily discussed for a stationary time series: loosely speaking, a stationary time series process {xt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is said to be weakly dependent if xt and xt􏱕h are “almost independent” as h increases without bound. A similar statement holds true if the sequence is nonstationary, but then we must assume that the concept of being almost independent does not depend on the starting point, t. The description of weak dependence given in the previous paragraph is necessarily vague. We cannot formally define weak dependence because there is no definition that covers all cases of interest. There are many specific forms of weak dependence that are formally defined, but these are well beyond the scope of this text. [See White (1984), Hamilton (1994), and Wooldridge (1994b) for advanced treatments of these concepts.] For our purposes, an intuitive notion of the meaning of weak dependence is sufficient. Covariance stationary sequences can be characterized in terms of correlations: a covariance stationary time series is weakly dependent if the correlation between xt and xt􏱕h goes to zero “sufficiently quickly” as h 􏱽 􏱵. (Because of covariance stationarity, the correlation does not depend on the starting point, t.) In other words, as the variables get farther apart in time, the correlation between them becomes smaller and smaller. Covariance stationary sequences where Corr(xt, xt􏱕h) 􏱽 0 as h 􏱽 􏱵 are said to be asymptotically uncorrelated. Intuitively, this is how we will usually characterize weak dependence. Technically, we need to assume that the correlation converges to zero fast enough, but we will gloss over this. Why is weak dependence important for regression analysis? Essentially, it replaces the assumption of random sampling in implying that the law of large numbers (LLN) and the central limit theorem (CLT) hold. The most well known central limit theorem for time series data requires stationarity and some form of weak dependence: thus, stationary, weakly depen- dent time series are ideal for use in multiple regression analysis. In Section 11.2, we will argue that OLS can be justified quite generally by appealing to the LLN and the CLT. Time series that are not weakly dependent—examples of which we will see in Section 11.3—do not gen- erally satisfy the CLT, which is why their use in multiple regression analysis can be tricky. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. substitution, CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 383 The simplest example of a weakly dependent time series is an independent, identically distributed sequence: a sequence that is independent is trivially weakly dependent. A more interesting example of a weakly dependent sequence is xt 􏱪 et 􏱕 􏱮1et􏱦1, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [11.1] where {et: t 􏱪 0, 1, ...} is an i.i.d. sequence with zero mean and variance 􏱧e2. The process {xt} is called a moving average process of order one [MA(1)]: xt is a weighted average of et and et􏱦1; in the next period, we drop et􏱦1, and then xt􏱕1 depends on et􏱕1 and et. Setting the coefficient of et to 1 in (11.1) is done without loss of generality. [In equation (11.1), we use xt and et as generic labels for time series processes. They need have nothing to do with the explanatory variables or errors in a time series regression model, although both the explanatory variables and errors could be MA(1) processes.] Why is an MA(1) process weakly dependent? Adjacent terms in the sequence are cor- related: because xt􏱕1 􏱪 et􏱕1 􏱕 􏱮1et, Cov(xt, xt􏱕1) 􏱪 􏱮1Var(et) 􏱪 􏱮1􏱧2e. Because Var(xt) 􏱪 (1 􏱕 􏱮21)􏱧e2, Corr(xt, xt􏱕1) 􏱪 􏱮1/(1 􏱕 􏱮21). For example, if 􏱮1 􏱪 .5, then Corr(xt, xt􏱕1) 􏱪 .4. [The maximum positive correlation occurs when 􏱮1 􏱪 1, in which case, Corr(xt, xt􏱕1) 􏱪 .5.] However, once we look at variables in the sequence that are two or more time periods apart, these variables are uncorrelated because they are independent. For example, xt􏱕2 􏱪 et􏱕2 􏱕 􏱮1et􏱕1 is independent of xt because {et} is independent across t. Due to the identical distribution assumption on the et, {xt} in (11.1) is actually stationary. Thus, an MA(1) is a stationary, weakly dependent sequence, and the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem can be applied to {xt}. A more popular example is the process yt 􏱪 􏰴1yt􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, .... [11.2] The starting point in the sequence is y0 (at t 􏱪 0), and {et: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is an i.i.d. sequence with zero mean and variance 􏱧e2. We also assume that the et are independent of y0 and that E(y0) 􏱪 0. This is called an autoregressive process of order one [AR(1)]. The crucial assumption for weak dependence of an AR(1) process is the stability con- dition 􏰫􏰴1􏰫 􏱷 1. Then, we say that {yt} is a stable AR(1) process. To see that a stable AR(1) process is asymptotically uncorrelated, it is useful to assume that the process is covariance stationary. (In fact, it can generally be shown that {yt} is strictly stationary, but the proof is somewhat technical.) Then, we know that E(yt) 􏱪 E(yt􏱦1), and from (11.2) with 􏰴1 􏱻 1, this can happen only if E(yt) 􏱪 0. Taking the variance of (11.2) and using the fact that et and yt􏱦1 are independent (and therefore uncorrelated), Var(yt) 􏱪 􏰴21Var(yt􏱦1) 􏱕 Var(et), and so, under covariance stationarity, we must have 􏱧y2 􏱪 􏰴21􏱧y2 􏱕 􏱧e2. Since 􏰴21 􏱷 1 by the stability condition, we can easily solve for 􏱧y2: 􏱧y2 􏱪 􏱧e2/(1 􏱶 􏰴21). [11.3] Now, we can find the covariance between yt and yt􏱕h for h 􏱸 1. Using repeated yt􏱕h 􏱪 􏰴1yt􏱕h􏱦1 􏱕 et􏱕h 􏱪 􏰴1(􏰴1yt􏱕h􏱦2 􏱕 et􏱕h􏱦1) 􏱕 et􏱕h 􏱪 􏰴21yt􏱕h􏱦2 􏱕 􏰴1et􏱕h􏱦1 􏱕 et􏱕h 􏱪 ... 􏱪 􏰴21yt 􏱕 􏰴1h–1et􏱕1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰴1et􏱕h􏱦1 􏱕 et􏱕h. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 384 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Because E(yt) 􏱪 0 for all t, we can multiply this last equation by yt and take expectations to obtain Cov(yt, yt􏱕h). Using the fact that et􏱕j is uncorrelated with yt for all j 􏱸 1 gives Cov(yt, yt􏱕h) 􏱪 E(ytyt􏱕h) 􏱪 􏰴h1E(y2t ) 􏱕 􏰴1h–1E(ytet􏱕1) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 E(ytet􏱕h) 􏱪 􏰴h1E(y2t ) 􏱪 􏰴h1􏱧2y. Because 􏱧y is the standard deviation of both yt and yt􏱕h, we can easily find the correlation between yt and yt􏱕h for any h 􏱸 1: Corr(yt, yt􏱕h) 􏱪 Cov(yt, yt􏱕h)/(􏱧y􏱧y) 􏱪 􏰴h1. [11.4] In particular, Corr(yt, yt􏱕1) 􏱪 􏰴1, so 􏰴1 is the correlation coefficient between any two adja- cent terms in the sequence. Equation (11.4) is important because it shows that, although yt and yt􏱕h are correlated for any h 􏱸 1, this correlation gets very small for large h: because 􏰫􏰴1􏰫 􏱷 1, 􏰴h1 􏱽 0 as h 􏱽 􏱵. Even when 􏰴1 is large—say, .9, which implies a very high, positive correlation between ad- jacent terms—the correlation between yt and yt􏱕h tends to zero fairly rapidly. For example, Corr(yt, yt􏱕5) 􏱪 .591, Corr(yt, yt􏱕10) 􏱪 .349, and Corr(yt, yt􏱕20) 􏱪 .122. If t indexes year, this means that the correlation between the outcome of two y that are 20 years apart is about .122. When 􏰴1 is smaller, the correlation dies out much more quickly. (You might try 􏰴1 􏱪 .5 to verify this.) This analysis heuristically demonstrates that a stable AR(1) process is weakly dependent. The AR(1) model is especially important in multiple regression analysis with time series data. We will cover additional applications in Chapter 12 and the use of it for forecasting in Chapter 18. There are many other types of weakly dependent time series, including hybrids of autore- gressive and moving average processes. But the previous examples work well for our purposes. Before ending this section, we must emphasize one point that often causes confu- sion in time series econometrics. A trending series, though certainly nonstationary, can be weakly dependent. In fact, in the simple linear time trend model in Chapter 10 [see equa- tion (10.24)], the series {yt} was actually independent. A series that is stationary about its time trend, as well as weakly dependent, is often called a trend-stationary process. (Notice that the name is not completely descriptive because we assume weak depen- dence along with stationarity.) Such processes can be used in regression analysis just as in Chapter 10, provided appropriate time trends are included in the model. 11.2 Asymptotic Properties of OLS In Chapter 10, we saw some cases in which the classical linear model assumptions are not satisfied for certain time series problems. In such cases, we must appeal to large sample properties of OLS, just as with cross-sectional analysis. In this section, we state the as- sumptions and main results that justify OLS more generally. The proofs of the theorems in this chapter are somewhat difficult and therefore omitted. See Wooldridge (1994b). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Assumption TS.1’ Linearity and Weak Dependence We assume the model is exactly as in Assumption TS.1, but now we add the assumption that {(xt, yt): t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is stationary and weakly dependent. In particular, the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem can be applied to sample averages. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 385 The linear in parameters requirement again means that we can write the model as yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, [11.5] where the 􏱬j are the parameters to be estimated. Unlike in Chapter 10, the xt j can include lags of the dependent variable. As usual, lags of explanatory variables are also allowed. We have included stationarity in Assumption TS.1' for convenience in stating and interpreting assumptions. If we were carefully working through the asymptotic proper- ties of OLS, as we do in Appendix E, stationarity would also simplify those derivations. But stationarity is not at all critical for OLS to have its standard asymptotic properties. (As mentioned in Section 11.1, by assuming the 􏱬j are constant across time, we are already assuming some form of stability in the distributions over time.) The important extra restriction in Assumption TS.1' as compared with Assumption TS.1 is the weak dependence assumption. In Section 11.1, we spent a fair amount of time discussing weak dependence because it is by no means an innocuous assumption. In the next section, we will present time series processes that clearly violate the weak dependence assumption and also discuss the use of such processes in multiple regression models. Naturally, we still rule out perfect collinearity. Assumption TS.2’ No Perfect Collinearity Same as Assumption TS.2. Assumption TS.3’ Zero Conditional Mean The explanatory variables xt 􏱪 (xt1, xt 2, ..., xtk) are contemporaneously exogenous as in equation (10.10): E(ut􏰫xt) 􏱪 0. This is the most natural assumption concerning the relationship between ut and the explan- atory variables. It is much weaker than Assumption TS.3 because it puts no restrictions on how ut is related to the explanatory variables in other time periods. We will see examples that satisfy TS.3' shortly. By stationarity, if contemporaneous exogeneity holds for one time period, it holds for them all. Relaxing stationarity would simply require us to assume the condition holds for all t 􏱪 1, 2, .... For certain purposes, it is useful to know that the following consistency result only requires ut to have zero unconditional mean and to be uncorrelated with each xtj: E(ut) 􏱪 0, Cov(xtj, ut) 􏱪 0, j 􏱪 1, ..., k. [11.6] We will work mostly with the zero conditional mean assumption because it leads to the most straightforward asymptotic analysis. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. THEOREM 11.1 CONSISTENCY OF OLS Under TS.1􏲃, TS.2􏲃, and TS.3􏲃, the OLS estimators are consistent: plim 􏱬ˆj 􏱪 􏱬j, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k. 386 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data There are some key practical differences between Theorems 10.1 and 11.1. First, in Theorem 11.1, we conclude that the OLS estimators are consistent, but not necessarily unbiased. Second, in Theorem 11.1, we have weakened the sense in which the explana- tory variables must be exogenous, but weak dependence is required in the underlying time series. Weak dependence is also crucial in obtaining approximate distributional results, which we cover later. EXAMPLE 11.1 STATIC MODEL Consider a static model with two explanatory variables: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt1 􏱕 􏱬2zt2 􏱕 ut. Under weak dependence, the condition sufficient for consistency of OLS is E(ut􏰫zt1, zt2) 􏱪 0. [11.7] [11.8] This rules out omitted variables that are in ut and are correlated with either zt1 or zt2. Also, no function of zt1 or zt2 can be correlated with ut, and so Assumption TS.3' rules out mis- specified functional form, just as in the cross-sectional case. Other problems, such as mea- surement error in the variables zt1 or zt2, can cause (11.8) to fail. Importantly, Assumption TS.3' does not rule out correlation between, say, ut􏱦1 and zt1. This type of correlation could arise if zt1 is related to past yt􏱦1, such as zt1 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1yt􏱦1 􏱕 vt. [11.9] For example, zt1 might be a policy variable, such as monthly percentage change in the money supply, and this change might depend on last month’s rate of inflation (yt􏱦1). Such a mechanism generally causes zt1 and ut􏱦1 to be correlated (as can be seen by plugging in for yt􏱦1). This kind of feedback is allowed under Assumption TS.3'. EXAMPLE 11.2 FINITE DISTRIBUTED LAG MODEL In the finite distributed lag model, yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0zt 􏱕 􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2zt􏱦2 􏱕 ut, [11.10] a very natural assumption is that the expected value of ut, given current and all past values of z, is zero: E(ut􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2, zt􏱦3, ...) 􏱪 0. [11.11] This means that, once zt, zt􏱦1, and zt􏱦2 are included, no further lags of z affect E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2, zt􏱦3, ...); if this were not true, we would put further lags into the equation. For example, yt could be the annual percentage change in investment and zt a measure of inter- est rates during year t. When we set xt 􏱪 (zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2), Assumption TS.3' is then satisfied: OLS will be consistent. As in the previous example, TS.3' does not rule out feedback from y to future values of z. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 387 The previous two examples do not necessarily require asymptotic theory because the explanatory variables could be strictly exogenous. The next example clearly violates the strict exogeneity assumption; therefore, we can only appeal to large sample properties of OLS. EXAMPLE 11.3 AR(1) MODEL Consider the AR(1) model, yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕 ut, where the error ut has a zero expected value, given all past values of y: E(ut􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0. Combined, these two equations imply that E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1yt􏱦1. [11.12] [11.13] [11.14] This result is very important. First, it means that, once y lagged one period has been con- trolled for, no further lags of y affect the expected value of yt. (This is where the name “first order” originates.) Second, the relationship is assumed to be linear. Because xt contains only yt􏱦1, equation (11.13) implies that Assumption TS.3' holds. By contrast, the strict exogeneity assumption needed for unbiasedness, Assumption TS.3, does not hold. Since the set of explanatory variables for all time periods includes all of the values on y except the last, (y0, y1, ..., yn􏱦1), Assumption TS.3 requires that, for all t, ut is uncorrelated with each of y0, y1, ..., yn􏱦1. This cannot be true. In fact, because ut is uncor- related with yt􏱦1 under (11.13), ut and yt must be correlated. In fact, it is easily seen that Cov(yt, ut) 􏱪 Var(ut) 􏱰 0. Therefore, a model with a lagged dependent variable cannot satisfy the strict exogeneity assumption TS.3. For the weak dependence condition to hold, we must assume that 􏰫􏱬1􏰫 􏱷 1, as we discussed in Section 11.1. If this condition holds, then Theorem 11.1 implies that the OLS estimator from the regression of yt on yt􏱦1 produces consistent estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1. Unfortunately, 􏱬ˆ1 is biased, and this bias can be large if the sample size is small or if 􏱬1 is near 1. (For 􏱬1 near 1, 􏱬ˆ1 can have a severe downward bias.) In moderate to large samples, 􏱬ˆ1 should be a good estimator of 􏱬1. When using the standard inference procedures, we need to impose versions of the ho- moskedasticity and no serial correlation assumptions. These are less restrictive than their classical linear model counterparts from Chapter 10. Assumption TS.4’ Homoskedasticity The errors are contemporaneously homoskedastic, that is, Var(ut􏰫xt) 􏱪 􏱧2. Assumption TS.5’ No Serial Correlation For all t 􏱻 s, E(utus􏰫xt, xs) 􏱪 0. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 388 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data In TS.4', note how we condition only on the explanatory variables at time t (compare to TS.4). In TS.5', we condition only on the explanatory variables in the time periods coin- ciding with ut and us. As stated, this assumption is a little difficult to interpret, but it is the right condition for studying the large sample properties of OLS in a variety of time series regressions. When considering TS.5', we often ignore the conditioning on xt and xs, and we think about whether ut and us are uncorrelated, for all t 􏱻 s. Serial correlation is often a problem in static and finite distributed lag regression mod- els: nothing guarantees that the unobservables ut are uncorrelated over time. Importantly, Assumption TS.5' does hold in the AR(1) model stated in equations (11.12) and (11.13). Since the explanatory variable at time t is yt􏱦1, we must show that E(utus􏰫yt􏱦1, ys􏱦1) 􏱪 0 for all t 􏱻 s. To see this, suppose that s 􏱷 t. (The other case follows by symmetry.) Then, since us 􏱪 ys – 􏱬0 – 􏱬1ys􏱦1, us is a function of y dated before time t. But by (11.13), E(ut􏰫us, yt􏱦1, ys􏱦1) 􏱪 0, and so E(utus􏰫us, yt􏱦1, ys􏱦1) 􏱪 usE(ut􏰫yt􏱦1, ys􏱦1) 􏱪 0. By the law of iter- ated expectations (see Appendix B), E(utus􏰫yt􏱦1, ys􏱦1) 􏱪 0. This is very important: as long as only one lag belongs in (11.12), the errors must be serially uncorrelated. We will dis- cuss this feature of dynamic models more generally in Section 11.4. We now obtain an asymptotic result that is practically identical to the cross-sectional case. This theorem provides additional justification for at least some of the examples estimated in Chapter 10: even if the classical linear model assumptions do not hold, OLS is still consistent, and the usual inference procedures are valid. Of course, this hinges on TS.1' through TS.5' being true. In the next section, we discuss ways in which the weak depen- dence assumption can fail. The problems of serial correlation and heteroskedasticity are treated in Chapter 12. EXAMPLE 11.4 EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS We can use asymptotic analysis to test a version of the efficient markets hypothesis (EMH). Let yt be the weekly percentage return (from Wednesday close to Wednesday close) on the New York Stock Exchange composite index. A strict form of the efficient markets hy- pothesis states that information observable to the market prior to week t should not help to predict the return during week t. If we use only past information on y, the EMH is stated as E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(yt). [11.15] If (11.15) is false, then we could use information on past weekly returns to predict the current return. The EMH presumes that such investment opportunities will be noticed and will disappear almost instantaneously. One simple way to test (11.15) is to specify the AR(1) model in (11.12) as the alternative model. Then, the null hypothesis is easily stated as H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0. Under the null hypothesis, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. THEOREM 11.2 ASYMPTOTIC NORMALITY OF OLS Under TS.1' through TS.5', the OLS estimators are asymptotically normally distributed. Further, the usual OLS standard errors, t statistics, F statistics, and LM statistics are asymp- totically valid. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 389 Assumption TS.3' is true by (11.15), and, as we discussed earlier, serial correlation is not an issue. The homoskedasticity assumption is Var(yt􏰫yt􏱦1) 􏱪 Var(yt) 􏱪 􏱧2, which we just assume is true for now. Under the null hypothesis, stock returns are serially uncor- related, so we can safely assume that they are weakly dependent. Then, Theorem 11.2 says we can use the usual OLS t statistic for 􏱬ˆ1 to test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱻 0. The weekly returns in NYSE.RAW are computed using data from January 1976 through March 1989. In the rare case that Wednesday was a holiday, the close at the next trading day was used. The average weekly return over this period was .196 in percentage form, with the largest weekly return being 8.45% and the smallest being 􏱦15.32% (during the stock market crash of October 1987). Estimation of the AR(1) model gives 􏱾returnt 􏱪 .180 􏱕 .059 returnt􏱦1 (.081) (.038) - [11.16] n 􏱪 689, R2 􏱪 .0035, R2 􏱪 .0020. The t statistic for the coefficient on returnt􏱦1 is about 1.55, and so H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 cannot be rejected against the two-sided alternative, even at the 10% significance level. The estimate does suggest a slight positive correlation in the NYSE return from one week to the next, but it is not strong enough to warrant rejection of the efficient markets hypothesis. In the previous example, using an AR(1) model to test the EMH might not detect cor- relation between weekly returns that are more than one week apart. It is easy to estimate models with more than one lag. For example, an autoregressive model of order two, or AR(2) model, is yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏱬2yt􏱦2 􏱕ut E(ut􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0. [11.17] There are stability conditions on 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 that are needed to ensure that the AR(2) pro- cess is weakly dependent, but this is not an issue here because the null hypothesis states that the EMH holds: H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱪 0. [11.18] If we add the homoskedasticity assumption Var(ut􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2) 􏱪 􏱧 2, we can use a stan- dard F statistic to test (11.18). If we estimate an AR(2) model for returnt, we obtain 􏱾returnt 􏱪 .186 􏱕 .060 returnt􏱦1 􏱦 .038 returnt􏱦2 (.081) (.038) - (.038) n 􏱪 688, R2 􏱪 .0048,R2 􏱪 .0019 (where we lose one more observation because of the additional lag in the equation). The two lags are individually insignificant at the 10% level. They are also jointly insignificant: using R2 􏱪 .0048, we find the F statistic is approximately F 􏱪 1.65; the p-value for this F statistic (with 2 and 685 degrees of freedom) is about .193. Thus, we do not reject (11.18) at even the 15% significance level. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 390 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data EXAMPLE 11.5 EXPECTATIONS AUGMENTED PHILLIPS CURVE A linear version of the expectations augmented Phillips curve can be written as inft 􏱦infet 􏱪􏱬1(unemt 􏱦􏱙0)􏱕et, where 􏱙0 is the natural rate of unemployment and inf et is the expected rate of inflation formed in year t 􏱦 1. This model assumes that the natural rate is constant, something that macroeconomists question. The difference between actual unemployment and the natural rate is called cyclical unemployment, while the difference between actual and expected inflation is called unanticipated inflation. The error term, et, is called a supply shock by macroeconomists. If there is a tradeoff between unanticipated inflation and cyclical unem- ployment, then 􏱬1 􏱷 0. [For a detailed discussion of the expectations augmented Phillips curve, see Mankiw (1994, Section 11.2).] To complete this model, we need to make an assumption about inflationary expecta- tions. Under adaptive expectations, the expected value of current inflation depends on re- cently observed inflation. A particularly simple formulation is that expected inflation this year is last year’s inflation: inf et 􏱪 inft􏱦1. (See Section 18.1 for an alternative formulation of adaptive expectations.) Under this assumption, we can write or inft 􏱦 inft􏱦1 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unemt 􏱕 et 􏰧inft 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unemt 􏱕 et, where 􏰧inft 􏱪 inft 􏱦 inft􏱦1 and 􏱬0 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1􏱙0. (􏱬0 is expected to be positive, since 􏱬1 􏱷 0 and 􏱙0 􏱰 0.) Therefore, under adaptive expectations, the expectations augmented Phillips curve relates the change in inflation to the level of unemployment and a supply shock, et. If et is uncorrelated with unemt, as is typically assumed, then we can consistently estimate 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 by OLS. (We do not have to assume that, say, future unemployment rates are unaffected by the current supply shock.) We assume that TS.1' through TS.5' hold. Using the data through 1996 in PHILLIPS.RAW we estimate 􏰧􏱾inf 􏱪 3.03 􏱦 .543 unem tt (1.38) (.230) - [11.19] n􏱪48,R2 􏱪.108,R2 􏱪.088. The tradeoff between cyclical unemployment and unanticipated inflation is pronounced in equation (11.19): a one-point increase in unem lowers unanticipated inflation by over one-half of a point. The effect is statistically significant (two-sided p-value 􏱿 .023). We can contrast this with the static Phillips curve in Example 10.1, where we found a slightly positive relationship between inflation and unemployment. Because we can write the natural rate as 􏱙0 􏱪 􏱬0 /(􏱦􏱬1), we can use (11.19) to obtain our own estimate of the natural rate: 􏱙ˆ0 􏱪 􏱬ˆ0/(􏱦􏱬ˆ1) 􏱪 3.03/.543 􏱿 5.58. Thus, we estimate the natural rate to be about 5.6, which is well within the range suggested by macroeconomists: historically, 5% to 6% is a common range cited for the natural rate of unemployment. A standard error of this estimate is difficult to obtain because we have a nonlinear function of the OLS estimators. Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 3) contains Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 391 the theory for general nonlinear functions. In the current application, the standard error is .657, which leads to an asymptotic 95% confidence interval (based on the standard normal distribution) of about 4.29 to 6.87 for the natural rate. Under Assumptions TS.1' through TS.5', we can show that the OLS estima- tors are asymptotically efficient in the class of estimators described in Theorem 5.3, but we replace the cross-sectional ob- servation index i with the time series index t. Finally, models with trending explanatory variables can effectively satisfy Assumptions TS.1' through TS.5', provided they are trend stationary. As long as time trends are included in the equations when needed, the usual inference procedures are asymptotically valid. 11.3 Using Highly Persistent Time Series in Regression Analysis The previous section shows that, provided the time series we use are weakly dependent, usual OLS inference procedures are valid under assumptions weaker than the classical linear model assumptions. Unfortunately, many economic time series cannot be character- ized by weak dependence. Using time series with strong dependence in regression analysis poses no problem, if the CLM assumptions in Chapter 10 hold. But the usual inference procedures are very susceptible to violation of these assumptions when the data are not weakly dependent, because then we cannot appeal to the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem. In this section, we provide some examples of highly persistent (or strongly dependent) time series and show how they can be transformed for use in regression analysis. Highly Persistent Time Series In the simple AR(1) model (11.2), the assumption 􏰫􏰴1􏰫 􏱷 1 is crucial for the series to be weakly dependent. It turns out that many economic time series are better characterized by the AR(1) model with 􏰴1 􏱪 1. In this case, we can write yt 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [11.20] where we again assume that {et: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is independent and identically distributed with mean zero and variance 􏱧e2. We assume that the initial value, y0, is independent of et for all t 􏱸 1. The process in (11.20) is called a random walk. The name comes from the fact that y at time t is obtained by starting at the previous value, yt􏱦1, and adding a zero mean random variable that is independent of yt􏱦1. Sometimes, a random walk is defined differently by assuming different properties of the innovations, et (such as lack of correlation rather than independence), but the current definition suffices for our purposes. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 11.2 Suppose that expectations are formed as inf et 􏱪 (1/2)inft􏱦1 􏱕 (1/2)inft􏱦2. What regression would you run to estimate the expectations augmented Phillips curve? 392 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data First, we find the expected value of yt. This is most easily done by using repeated substitution to get yt 􏱪et 􏱕et􏱦1 􏱕...􏱕e1 􏱕y0. Taking the expected value of both sides gives E(yt) 􏱪 E(et) 􏱕 E(et􏱦1) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 E(e1) 􏱕 E(y0) 􏱪 E(y0), for all t 􏱸 1. Therefore, the expected value of a random walk does not depend on t. A popular assump- tion is that y0 􏱪 0—the process begins at zero at time zero—in which case, E(yt) 􏱪 0 for all t. By contrast, the variance of a random walk does change with t. To compute the vari- ance of a random walk, for simplicity we assume that y0 is nonrandom so that Var(y0) 􏱪 0; this does not affect any important conclusions. Then, by the i.i.d. assumption for {et}, Var(yt) 􏱪 Var(et) 􏱕 Var(et􏱦1) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 Var(e1) 􏱪 􏱧e2t. [11.21] In other words, the variance of a random walk increases as a linear function of time. This shows that the process cannot be stationary. Even more importantly, a random walk displays highly persistent behavior in the sense that the value of y today is important for determining the value of y in the very dis- tant future. To see this, write for h periods hence, yt􏱕h 􏱪et􏱕h 􏱕et􏱕h􏱦1 􏱕...􏱕et􏱕1 􏱕yt. Now, suppose at time t, we want to compute the expected value of yt􏱕h given the current value yt. Since the expected value of et􏱕j, given yt, is zero for all j 􏱸 1, we have E(yt􏱕h􏰫yt) 􏱪 yt, for all h 􏱸 1. [11.22] This means that, no matter how far in the future we look, our best prediction of yt􏱕h is today’s value, yt. We can contrast this with the stable AR(1) case, where a similar argu- ment can be used to show that E(yt􏱕h􏰫yt) 􏱪 􏰴1hyt, for all h 􏱸 1. Under stability, 􏰫􏰴1􏰫 􏱷 1, and so E(yt􏱕h􏰫yt) approaches zero as h 􏱽 􏱵: the value of yt be- comes less and less important, and E(yt􏱕h􏰫yt) gets closer and closer to the unconditional expected value, E(yt) 􏱪 0. When h 􏱪 1, equation (11.22) is reminiscent of the adaptive expectations assumption we used for the inflation rate in Example 11.5: if inflation follows a random walk, then the expected value of inft, given past values of inflation, is simply inft􏱦1. Thus, a random walk model for inflation justifies the use of adaptive expectations. We can also see that the correlation between yt and yt􏱕h is close to 1 for large t when {yt} follows a random walk. If Var(y0) 􏱪 0, it can be shown that ________ Corr(yt, yt􏱕h) 􏱪 􏱯t/(t 􏱕 h) . Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 393 Thus, the correlation depends on the starting point, t (so that {yt} is not covariance stationary). Further, although for fixed t the correlation tends to zero as h 􏱽 􏱵, it does not do so very quickly. In fact, the larger t is, the more slowly the correlation tends to zero as h gets large. If we choose h to be something large—say, h 􏱪 100—we can always choose a large enough t such that the correlation between yt and yt􏱕h is arbitrarily close to one. (If h 􏱪 100 and we want the correlation to be greater than .95, then t 􏱰 1,000 does the trick.) Therefore, a random walk does not satisfy the requirement of an asymptotically uncor- related sequence. Figure 11.1 plots two realizations of a random walk, generated from a computer, with initial value y0 􏱪 0 and et 􏱷 Normal(0,1). Generally, it is not easy to look at a time series plot and determine whether it is a random walk. Next, we will discuss an informal method for making the distinction between weakly and highly dependent sequences; we will study formal statistical tests in Chapter 18. A series that is generally thought to be well characterized by a random walk is the three-month T-bill rate. Annual data are plotted in Figure 11.2 for the years 1948 through 1996. A random walk is a special case of what is known as a unit root process. The name comes from the fact that 􏰴1 􏱪 1 in the AR(1) model. A more general class of unit root pro- cesses is generated as in (11.20), but {et} is now allowed to be a general, weakly dependent series. [For example, {et} could itself follow an MA(1) or a stable AR(1) process.] When {et} is not an i.i.d. sequence, the properties of the random walk we derived earlier no lon- ger hold. But the key feature of {yt} is preserved: the value of y today is highly correlated with y even in the distant future. From a policy perspective, it is often important to know whether an economic time series is highly persistent or not. Consider the case of gross domestic product in the FIGURE 11.1 Two realizations of the random walk yt 􏲁 yt􏱶1 􏱦 et, with y0 􏲁 0, et 􏱘 Normal(0,1), and n 􏲁 50. yt 5 0 –5 –10 0 25 50 t Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 394 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data F I G U R E 1 1 . 2 The U.S. three-month T-bill rate, for the years 1948–1996. interest rate 14 8 1 1948 1972 1996 year United States. If GDP is asymptotically uncorrelated, then the level of GDP in the coming year is at best weakly related to what GDP was, say, 30 years ago. This means a policy that affected GDP long ago has very little lasting impact. On the other hand, if GDP is strongly dependent, then next year’s GDP can be highly correlated with the GDP from many years ago. Then, we should recognize that a policy that causes a discrete change in GDP can have long-lasting effects. It is extremely important not to confuse trending and highly persistent behaviors. A series can be trending but not highly persistent, as we saw in Chapter 10. Further, factors such as interest rates, inflation rates, and unemployment rates are thought by many to be highly persistent, but they have no obvious upward or downward trend. However, it is often the case that a highly persistent series also contains a clear trend. One model that leads to this behavior is the random walk with drift: yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 yt􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [ 1 1 . 2 3 ] where {et: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} and y0 satisfy the same properties as in the random walk model. What is new is the parameter 􏱮0, which is called the drift term. Essentially, to generate yt, the constant 􏱮0 is added along with the random noise et to the previous value yt􏱦1. We can show that the expected value of yt follows a linear time trend by using repeated substitution: yt 􏱪􏱮0t􏱕et 􏱕et􏱦1 􏱕...􏱕e1 􏱕y0. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 395 FIGURE 11.3 A realization of the random walk with drift, yt 􏲁 2 􏱦 yt􏱦1 􏱦 et, with y0 􏲁 0, et S Normal(0, 9), and n 􏲁 50. The dashed line is the expected value of yt, E(yt ) 􏲁 2t. yt 100 50 0 0 25 50 t Therefore, if y0 􏱪 0, E(yt) 􏱪 􏱮0t: the expected value of yt is growing over time if 􏱮0 􏱰 0 and shrinking over time if 􏱮0 􏱷 0. By reasoning as we did in the pure random walk case, we can show that E(yt􏱕h􏰫yt) 􏱪 􏱮0h 􏱕 yt, and so the best prediction of yt􏱕h at time t is yt plus the drift 􏱮0h. The variance of yt is the same as it was in the pure random walk case. Figure 11.3 contains a realization of a random walk with drift, where n 􏱪 50, y0􏱪 0, 􏱮0 􏱪 2, and the et are Normal(0, 9) random variables. As can be seen from this graph, yt tends to grow over time, but the series does not regularly return to the trend line. A random walk with drift is another example of a unit root process, because it is the special case 􏰴1 􏱪 1 in an AR(1) model with an intercept: yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰴1yt􏱦1 􏱕et. When 􏰴1 􏱪 1 and {et} is any weakly dependent process, we obtain a whole class of highly persistent time series processes that also have linearly trending means. Transformations on Highly Persistent Time Series Using time series with strong persistence of the type displayed by a unit root process in a regression equation can lead to very misleading results if the CLM assumptions are vio- lated. We will study the spurious regression problem in more detail in Chapter 18, but for now we must be aware of potential problems. Fortunately, simple transformations are available that render a unit root process weakly dependent. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 396 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Weakly dependent processes are said to be integrated of order zero, or I(0). Practi- cally, this means that nothing needs to be done to such series before using them in regres- sion analysis: averages of such sequences already satisfy the standard limit theorems. Unit root processes, such as a random walk (with or without drift), are said to be integrated of order one, or I(1). This means that the first difference of the process is weakly dependent (and often stationary). A time series that is I(1) is often said to be a difference-stationary process, although the name is somewhat misleading with its emphasis on stationarity after differencing rather than weak dependence in the differences. The concept of an I(1) process is easiest to see for a random walk. With {yt} gener- ated as in (11.20) for t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., 􏰧yt 􏱪 yt 􏱦 yt􏱦1 􏱪 et, t 􏱪 2, 3, ...; [11.24] therefore, the first-differenced series {􏰧yt: t 􏱪 2, 3, ...} is actually an i.i.d. sequence. More generally, if {yt} is generated by (11.24) where {et} is any weakly dependent process, then {􏰧yt} is weakly dependent. Thus, when we suspect processes are integrated of order one, we often first difference in order to use them in regression analysis; we will see some examples later. (Incidentally, the symbol “∆”can mean “change” as well as “difference.” In actual data sets, if an original variable is named y then its change or difference is often denoted cy or dy. For example, the change in price might be denoted cprice.) Many time series yt that are strictly positive are such that log(yt) is integrated of order one. In this case, we can use the first difference in the logs, 􏰧log(yt) 􏱪 log(yt) – log(yt􏱦1), in regression analysis. Alternatively, since 􏰧log(yt) 􏱿 (yt 􏱦 yt􏱦1)/yt􏱦1, [11.25] we can use the proportionate or percentage change in yt directly; this is what we did in Example 11.4 where, rather than stating the efficient markets hypothesis in terms of the stock price, pt, we used the weekly percentage change, returnt 􏱪 100[( pt – pt􏱦1)/pt􏱦1]. The quantity in equation (11.25) is often called the growth rate, measured as a proportionate change. When using a particular data set it is important to know how the growth rates are measured—whether as a proportionate or a percentage change. Sometimes if an original variable is y its growth rate is denoted gy, so that for each t, gyt 􏱪 log(yt) – log(yt􏱦1) or gyt 􏱪 (yt – yt−1)/yt−1. Often these quantities are multiplied by 100 to turn a proportionate change into a percentage change. Differencing time series before using them in regression analysis has another benefit: it removes any linear time trend. This is easily seen by writing a linearly trending variable as yt 􏱪􏰸0 􏱕􏰸1t􏱕vt, wherevt hasazeromean.Then,􏰧yt 􏱪􏰸1 􏱕􏰧vt,andsoE(􏰧yt)􏱪􏰸1 􏱕E(􏰧vt)􏱪􏰸1. In other words, E(􏰧yt) is constant. The same argument works for 􏰧log(yt) when log(yt) follows a linear time trend. Therefore, rather than including a time trend in a regression, we can instead difference those variables that show obvious trends. Deciding Whether a Time Series Is I(1) Determining whether a particular time series realization is the outcome of an I(1) versus an I(0) process can be quite difficult. Statistical tests can be used for this purpose, but these are more advanced; we provide an introductory treatment in Chapter 18. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 397 There are informal methods that provide useful guidance about whether a time series process is roughly characterized by weak dependence. A very simple tool is motivated by the AR(1) model: if 􏰫􏰴1􏰫 􏱷 1, then the process is I(0), but it is I(1) if 􏰴1 􏱪 1. Earlier, we showed that, when the AR(1) process is stable, 􏰴1 􏱪 Corr(yt, yt􏱦1). Therefore, we can estimate 􏰴1 from the sample correlation between yt and yt􏱦1. This sample correlation coef- ficient is called the first order autocorrelation of {yt}; we denote this by 􏰴ˆ1. By applying the law of large numbers, 􏰴ˆ1 can be shown to be consistent for 􏰴1 provided 􏰫􏰴1􏰫 􏱷 1. (However, 􏰴ˆ1 is not an unbiased estimator of 􏰴1.) We can use the value of 􏰴ˆ1 to help decide whether the process is I(1) or I(0). Unfor- tunately, because 􏰴ˆ1 is an estimate, we can never know for sure whether 􏰴1 􏱷 1. Ideally, we could compute a confidence interval for 􏰴1 to see if it excludes the value 􏰴1 􏱪 1, but this turns out to be rather difficult: the sampling distributions of the estimator of 􏰴ˆ1 are ex- tremely different when 􏰴1 is close to one and when 􏰴1 is much less than one. (In fact, when 􏰴1 is close to one, 􏰴ˆ1 can have a severe downward bias.) In Chapter 18, we will show how to test H0: 􏰴1 􏱪 1 against H1: 􏰴1 􏱷 1. For now, we can only use 􏰴ˆ1 as a rough guide for determining whether a series needs to be differenced. No hard and fast rule exists for making this choice. Most economists think that differenc- ing is warranted if 􏰴ˆ1 􏱰 .9; some would difference when 􏰴ˆ1 􏱰 .8. EXAMPLE 11.6 FERTILITY EQUATION In Example 10.4, we explained the general fertility rate, gfr, in terms of the value of the personal exemption, pe. The first order autocorrelations for these series are very large: 􏰴ˆ1􏱪.977 for gfr and 􏰴ˆ1 􏱪 .964 for pe. These autocorrelations are highly suggestive of unit root behavior, and they raise serious questions about our use of the usual OLS t statistics for this example back in Chapter 10. Remember, the t statistics only have exact t distribu- tions under the full set of classical linear model assumptions. To relax those assumptions in any way and apply asymptotics, we generally need the underlying series to be I(0) processes. We now estimate the equation using first differences (and drop the dummy vari- able, for simplicity): 􏰧􏱾gfr 􏱪 􏱦.785 􏱦 .043 􏰧pe (.502) (.028)- [11.26] n 􏱪 71, R2 􏱪 .032, R2 􏱪 .018. Now, an increase in pe is estimated to lower gfr contemporaneously, although the estimate is not statistically different from zero at the 5% level. This gives very different results than when we estimated the model in levels, and it casts doubt on our earlier analysis. If we add two lags of 􏰧pe, things improve: 􏰧􏱾gfr 􏱪 􏱦.964 􏱦 .036 􏰧pe 􏱦 .014 􏰧pe􏱦1 􏱕 .110 􏰧pe􏱦2 (.468) (.027)- (.028) (.027) [11.27] n 􏱪 69, R2 􏱪 .233, R2 􏱪 .197. Even though 􏰧pe and 􏰧pe􏱦1 have negative coefficients, their coefficients are small and jointly insignificant (p-value 􏱪 .28). The second lag is very significant and indicates Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 398 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data a positive relationship between changes in pe and subsequent changes in gfr two years hence. This makes more sense than having a contemporaneous effect. See Computer Exercise C5 for further analysis of the equation in first differences. When the series in question has an obvious upward or downward trend, it makes more sense to obtain the first order autocorrelation after detrending. If the data are not detrended, the autoregressive correlation tends to be overestimated, which biases toward finding a unit root in a trending process. EXAMPLE 11.7 WAGES AND PRODUCTIVITY The variable hrwage is average hourly wage in the U.S. economy, and outphr is output per hour. One way to estimate the elasticity of hourly wage with respect to output per hour is to estimate the equation, log(hrwaget) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(outphrt) 􏱕 􏱬2t 􏱕 ut, where the time trend is included because log(hrwaget) and log(outphrt) both display clear, upward, linear trends. Using the data in EARNS.RAW for the years 1947 through 1987, we obtain 􏱾log(hrwaget)􏱪 􏱦5.33 􏱕 1.64 log(outphrt) 􏱦 .018 t (.37) (.09)- (.002) [11.28] n 􏱪 41, R2 􏱪 .971, R2 􏱪 .970. (We have reported the usual goodness-of-fit measures here; it would be better to report those based on the detrended dependent variable, as in Section 10.5.) The estimated elas- ticity seems too large: a 1% increase in productivity increases real wages by about 1.64%. Because the standard error is so small, the 95% confidence interval easily excludes a unit elasticity. U.S. workers would probably have trouble believing that their wages increase by more than 1.5% for every 1% increase in productivity. The regression results in (11.28) must be viewed with caution. Even after linearly de- trending log(hrwage), the first order autocorrelation is .967, and for detrended log(outphr), 􏰴ˆ1 􏱪 .945. These suggest that both series have unit roots, so we reestimate the equation in first differences (and we no longer need a time trend): 􏱾􏰧log(hrwaget)􏱪 􏱦.0036 􏱕 .809 􏰧log(outphr) (.0042) (.173) [11.29] n􏱪40,R2 􏱪.364,R-2 􏱪.348. Now, a 1% increase in productivity is estimated to increase real wages by about .81%, and the estimate is not statistically different from one. The adjusted R-squared shows that the growth in output explains about 35% of the growth in real wages. See Computer Exercise C2 for a simple distributed lag version of the model in first differences. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 399 In the previous two examples, both the dependent and independent variables appear to have unit roots. In other cases, we might have a mixture of processes with unit roots and those that are weakly dependent (though possibly trending). An example is given in Computer Exercise C1. 11.4 Dynamically Complete Models and the Absence of Serial Correlation In the AR(1) model in (11.12), we showed that, under assumption (11.13), the errors {ut} must be serially uncorrelated in the sense that Assumption TS.5􏲃 is satisfied: assuming that no serial correlation exists is practically the same thing as assuming that only one lag of y appears in E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...). Can we make a similar statement for other regression models? The answer is yes, although the assumptions required for the errors to be serially uncorrelated might be im- plausible. Consider, for example, the simple static regression model yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt 􏱕 ut, [11.30] where yt and zt are contemporaneously dated. For consistency of OLS, we only need E(ut􏰫zt) 􏱪 0. Generally, the {ut} will be serially correlated. However, if we assume that E(ut􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 0, [11.31] then (as we will show generally later) Assumption TS.5􏲃 holds. In particular, the {ut} are serially uncorrelated. Naturally, assumption (11.31) implies that zt is contemporaneously exogenous, that is, E(ut􏰫zt) 􏱪 0. To gain insight into the meaning of (11.31), we can write (11.30) and (11.31) equiva- lently as E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫zt) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt, [11.32] where the first equality is the one of current interest. It says that, once zt has been con- trolled for, no lags of either y or z help to explain current y. This is a strong requirement and is implausible when the lagged dependent variable has predictive power, which is often the case, if it is false, then we can expect the errors to be serially correlated. Next, consider a finite distributed lag model with two lags: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt 􏱕 􏱬2zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬3zt􏱦2 􏱕 ut. [11.33] Since we are hoping to capture the lagged effects that z has on y, we would naturally as- sume that (11.33) captures the distributed lag dynamics: E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2, zt􏱦3, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2); [11.34] that is, at most two lags of z matter. If (11.31) holds, we can make a stronger statement: once we have controlled for z and its two lags, no lags of y or additional lags of z affect current y: E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2). [11.35] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 400 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Equation (11.35) is more likely than (11.32), but it still rules out lagged y having extra predictive power for current y. Next, consider a model with one lag of both y and z: yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1zt 􏱕􏱬2yt􏱦1 􏱕􏱬3zt􏱦1 􏱕ut. Since this model includes a lagged dependent variable, (11.31) is a natural assumption, as it implies that E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1); in other words, once zt, yt􏱦1, and zt􏱦1 have been controlled for, no further lags of either y or z affect current y. In the general model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, [11.36] where the explanatory variables xt 􏱪 (xt1, ..., xtk) may or may not contain lags of y or z, (11.31) becomes Written in terms of yt, E(ut􏰫xt, yt􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 0. [11.37] E(yt􏰫xt, yt􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫xt). [11.38] In other words, whatever is in xt, enough lags have been included so that further lags of y and the explanatory variables do not matter for explaining yt. When this condition holds, we have a dynamically complete model. As we saw earlier, dynamic completeness can be a very strong assumption for static and finite distributed lag models. Once we start putting lagged y as explanatory variables, we often think that the model should be dynamically complete. We will touch on some exceptions to this claim in Chapter 18. Since (11.37) is equivalent to E(ut􏰫xt, ut􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0, [11.39] we can show that a dynamically complete model must satisfy Assumption TS.5'. (This derivation is not crucial and can be skipped without loss of continuity.) For concreteness, take s 􏱷 t. Then, by the law of iterated expectations (see Appendix B), E(utus􏰫xt, xs) 􏱪 E[E(utus􏰫xt, xs, us)􏰫xt, xs] 􏱪 E[usE(ut􏰫xt, xs, us)􏰫xt, xs], where the second equality follows from E(utus􏰫xt, xs, us) 􏱪 usE(ut􏰫xt, xs, us). Now, since s 􏱷 t, (xt, xs, us) is a subset of the conditioning set in (11.39). Therefore, (11.39) implies that E(ut􏰫xt, xs, us) 􏱪 0, and so E(utus􏰫xt, xs) 􏱪 E(us·0􏰫xt, xs) 􏱪 0, which says that Assumption TS.5' holds. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 401 Since specifying a dynamically com- plete model means that there is no serial correlation, does it follow that all mod- els should be dynamically complete? As we will see in Chapter 18, for forecasting purposes, the answer is yes. Some think that all models should be dynamically complete and that serial correlation in the errors of a model is a sign of misspecification. This stance is too rigid. Sometimes, we really are interested in a static model (such as a Phillips curve) or a finite distributed lag model (such as measuring the long-run percent- age change in wages given a 1% increase in productivity). In the next chapter, we will show how to detect and correct for serial correlation in such models. EXAMPLE 11.8 FERTILITY EQUATION In equation (11.27), we estimated a distributed lag model for 􏰧gfr on 􏰧pe, allowing for two lags of 􏰧pe. For this model to be dynamically complete in the sense of (11.38), nei- ther lags of 􏰧gfr nor further lags of 􏰧pe should appear in the equation. We can easily see that this is false by adding 􏰧gfr􏱦1: the coefficient estimate is .300, and its t statistic is 2.84. Thus, the model is not dynamically complete in the sense of (11.38). What should we make of this? We will postpone an interpretation of general models with lagged dependent variables until Chapter 18. But the fact that (11.27) is not dynami- cally complete suggests that there may be serial correlation in the errors. We will see how to test and correct for this in Chapter 12. The notion of dynamic completeness should not be confused with a weaker assump- tion concerning including the appropriate lags in a model. In the model (11.36), the ex- planatory variables xt are said to be sequentially exogenous if E(ut􏰫xt, xt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 E(ut) 􏱪 0, t 􏱪 1, 2, ... . [11.40] As discussed in Problem 8 in Chapter 10, sequential exogeneity is implied by strict exogeneity and sequential exogeneity implies contemporaneous exogeneity. Further, because (xt, xt􏱦1, ...) is a subset of (xt, yt􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ...), sequential exogeneity is implied by dynamic completeness. If xt contains yt􏱦1, the dynamic completeness and sequential exogeneity are the same condition. The key point is that, when xt does not contain yt􏱦1, sequential exogeneity allows for the possibility that the dynamics are not complete in the sense of capturing the relationship between yt and all past values of y and other explanatory variables. But in finite distributed lag models—such as that estimated in equation (11.27)—we may not care whether past y has predictive power for current y. We are primarily interested in whether we have included enough lags of the explan- atory variables to capture the distributed lag dynamics. For example, if we assume E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2, zt􏱦3, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱛0zt 􏱕 􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2zt􏱦2, then the regressors xt 􏱪 (zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2) are sequentially exogenous because we have assumed that two lags suffice for the distributed lag dynamics. But typically the model would not be dynamically complete in the sense that E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, zt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, zt􏱦2), and we may not care. In addition, the explanatory variables in an FDL model may or may not be strictly exogenous. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 11.3 If (11.33) holds where ut 􏱪 et 􏱕 􏱮1et􏱦1 and where {et} is an i.i.d. sequence with mean zero and variance 􏱧2e, can equation (11.33) be dynamically complete? 402 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 11.5 The Homoskedasticity Assumption for Time Series Models The homoskedasticity assumption for time series regressions, particularly TS.4', looks very similar to that for cross-sectional regressions. However, since xt can contain lagged y as well as lagged explanatory variables, we briefly discuss the meaning of the homoske- dasticity assumption for different time series regressions. In the simple static model, say, yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt 􏱕 ut, [11.41] Assumption TS.4' requires that Var(ut􏰫zt) 􏱪 􏱧2. Therefore, even though E(yt􏰫zt) is a linear function of zt, Var(yt􏰫zt) must be constant. This is pretty straightforward. In Example 11.4, we saw that, for the AR(1) model in (11.12), the homoskedasticity assumption is Var(ut􏰫yt􏱦1) 􏱪 Var(yt􏰫yt􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱧2; even though E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1) depends on yt􏱦1, Var(yt􏰫yt􏱦1) does not. Thus, the spread in the distri- bution of yt cannot depend on yt􏱦1. Hopefully, the pattern is clear now. If we have the model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1zt 􏱕􏱬2yt􏱦1 􏱕􏱬3zt􏱦1 􏱕ut, the homoskedasticity assumption is Var(ut􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1) 􏱪 Var(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱧2, so that the variance of ut cannot depend on zt, yt􏱦1, or zt􏱦1 (or some other function of time). Generally, whatever explanatory variables appear in the model, we must assume that the variance of yt given these explanatory variables is constant. If the model contains lagged y or lagged explanatory variables, then we are explicitly ruling out dynamic forms of heteroske- dasticity (something we study in Chapter 12). But, in a static model, we are only concerned with Var(yt􏰫zt). In equation (11.41), no direct restrictions are placed on, say, Var(yt􏰫yt􏱦1). Summary In this chapter, we have argued that OLS can be justified using asymptotic analysis, provided certain conditions are met. Ideally, the time series processes are stationary and weakly depen- dent, although stationarity is not crucial. Weak dependence is necessary for applying the stan- dard large sample results, particularly the central limit theorem. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data Processes with deterministic trends that are weakly dependent can be used directly in regression analysis, provided time trends are included in the model (as in Section 10.5). A similar statement holds for processes with seasonality. When the time series are highly persistent (they have unit roots), we must exercise extreme caution in using them directly in regression models (unless we are convinced the CLM assump- tions from Chapter 10 hold). An alternative to using the levels is to use the first differences of the variables. For most highly persistent economic time series, the first difference is weakly dependent. Using first differences changes the nature of the model, but this method is often as informative as a model in levels. When data are highly persistent, we usually have more faith in first-difference results. In Chapter 18, we will cover some recent, more advanced methods for using I(1) variables in multiple regression analysis. When models have complete dynamics in the sense that no further lags of any variable are needed in the equation, we have seen that the errors will be serially uncorrelated. This is useful because certain models, such as autoregressive models, are assumed to have complete dynam- ics. In static and distributed lag models, the dynamically complete assumption is often false, which generally means the errors will be serially correlated. We will see how to address this problem in Chapter 12. THE “ASYMPTOTIC” GAUSS-MARKOV ASSUMPTIONS FOR TIME SERIES REGRESSION Following is a summary of the five assumptions that we used in this chapter to perform large- sample inference for time series regressions. Recall that we introduced this new set of as- sumptions because the time series versions of the classical linear model assumptions are often violated, especially the strict exogeneity, no serial correlation, and normality assumptions. A key point in this chapter is that some sort of weak dependence is required to ensure that the central limit theorem applies. We only used Assumptions TS.1' through TS.3' for consistency (not unbiasedness) of OLS. When we add TS.4' and TS.5', we can use the usual confidence intervals, t statistics, and F statistics as being approximately valid in large samples. Unlike the Gauss-Markov and classical linear model assumptions, there is no historically significant name attached to Assumptions TS.1' to TS.5'. Nevertheless, the assumptions are the analogs to the Gauss-Markov assumptions that allow us to use standard inference. As usual for large- sample analysis, we dispense with the normality assumption entirely. Assumption TS.1􏲆 (Linearity and Weak Dependence) The stochastic process {(xt1, xt2, ..., xtk , yt): t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is stationary, weakly dependent, and follows the linear model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕􏱬2xt2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, where {ut: t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is the sequence of errors or disturbances. Here, n is the number of observations (time periods). Assumption TS.2􏲆 (No Perfect Collinearity) In the sample (and therefore in the underlying time series process), no independent variable is constant nor a perfect linear combination of the others. Assumption TS.3􏲆 (Zero Conditional Mean) The explanatory variables are contemporaneously exogenous, that is, E(ut􏱍xt1, ..., xtk) 􏱪 0. Remember, TS.3' is notably weaker than the strict exogeneity assumption TS.3'. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 403 404 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Assumption TS.4􏲆 (Homoskedasticity) The errors are contemporaneously homoskedastic, that is, Var(ut􏱍xt) 􏱪 􏱧2, where xt is short- hand for (xt1, xt2, ..., xtk). Assumption TS.5􏲆 (No Serial Correlation) For all t 􏱻 s, E(ut us􏰫xt, xs) 􏱪 0. Key Terms Asymptotically Uncorrelated Autoregressive Process of Order One [AR(1)] Contemporaneously Exogenous Contemporaneously Homoskedastic Covariance Stationary Difference-Stationary Process Dynamically Complete Model First Difference Problems First Order Autocorrelation Growth Rate Highly Persistent Integrated of Order One [I(1)] Integrated of Order Zero [I(0)] Moving Average Process of Order One [MA(1)] Nonstationary Process Random Walk Random Walk with Drift Sequentially Exogenous Serially Uncorrelated Stable AR(1) Process Stationary Process Strongly Dependent Trend-Stationary Process Unit Root Process Weakly Dependent 1 Let {xt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} be a covariance stationary process and define 􏰸h 􏱪 Cov(xt, xt􏱕h) for h 􏱸 0. [Therefore, 􏰸0 􏱪 Var(xt).] Show that Corr(xt, xt􏱕h) 􏱪 􏰸h/􏰸0. 2 Let {et: t 􏱪 􏱦1, 0, 1, ...} be a sequence of independent, identically distributed random variables with mean zero and variance one. Define a stochastic process by xt 􏱪 et 􏱶 (1/2)et􏱦1 􏱕 (1/2)et􏱦2, t 􏱪 1, 2, .... (i) Find E(xt) and Var(xt). Do either of these depend on t? (ii) Show that Corr(xt, xt􏱕1) 􏱪 􏱦1/2 and Corr(xt, xt􏱕2) 􏱪 1/3. (Hint: It is easiest to use the formula in Problem 1.) (iii) What is Corr(xt, xt􏱕h) for h 􏱰 2? (iv) Is {xt} an asymptotically uncorrelated process? 3 Suppose that a time series process {yt} is generated by yt 􏱪 z 􏱕 et, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., where {et} is an i.i.d. sequence with mean zero and variance 􏱧e2. The random variable z does not change over time; it has mean zero and variance 􏱧z2. Assume that each et is uncor- related with z. (i) Find the expected value and variance of yt. Do your answers depend on t? (ii) Find Cov(yt, yt􏱕h) for any t and h. Is {yt} covariance stationary? (iii) Use parts (i) and (ii) to show that Corr(yt, yt􏱕h) 􏱪 􏱧z2/(􏱧z2 􏱕 􏱧e2) for all t and h. (iv) Does yt satisfy the intuitive requirement for being asymptotically uncorrelated? Explain. 4 Let{y:t􏱪1,2,...}followarandomwalk,asin(11.20),withy 􏱪0.Showthat t _______ 0 Corr(yt, yt􏱕h)􏱪􏱯t/(t􏱕h) fort􏱸1,h􏱰0. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data 5 FortheU.S.economy,letgpricedenotethemonthlygrowthintheoverallpriceleveland let gwage be the monthly growth in hourly wages. [These are both obtained as differences of logarithms: gprice 􏱪 􏰧log( price) and gwage 􏱪 􏰧log(wage).] Using the monthly data in WAGEPRC.RAW, we estimate the following distributed lag model: gprice􏱪 􏱦.00093 􏱕 .119 gwage 􏱕 .097 gwage􏱦1 􏱕 .040 gwage􏱦2 (.00057) (.052) (.039) (.039) 􏱕 .038 gwage􏱦3 􏱕 .081 gwage􏱦4 􏱕 .107 gwage􏱦5 􏱕 .095 gwage􏱦6 (.039) (.039) (.039) (.039) 􏱕 .104 gwage􏱦7 􏱕 .103 gwage􏱦8 􏱕 .159 gwage􏱦9 􏱕 .110 gwage􏱦10 (.039) (.039) (.039) (.039) 􏱕 .103 gwage􏱦11 􏱕.016 gwage􏱦12 - (.039) (.052) n 􏱪 273, R2 􏱪 .317,R2 􏱪 .283. (i) Sketch the estimated lag distribution. At what lag is the effect of gwage on gprice largest? Which lag has the smallest coefficient? (ii) For which lags are the t statistics less than two? (iii) What is the estimated long-run propensity? Is it much different than one? Explain what the LRP tells us in this example. (iv) What regression would you run to obtain the standard error of the LRP directly? (v) How would you test the joint significance of six more lags of gwage? What would be the dfs in the F distribution? (Be careful here; you lose six more observations.) 6 Let hy6t denote the three-month holding yield (in percent) from buying a six-month T-bill at time (t – 1) and selling it at time t (three months hence) as a three-month T-bill. Let hy3t􏱦1 be the three-month holding yield from buying a three-month T-bill at time (t – 1). At time (t – 1), hy3t􏱦1 is known, whereas hy6t is unknown because p3t (the price of three-month T-bills) is unknown at time (t – 1). The expectations hypoth- esis (EH) says that these two different three-month investments should be the same, on average. Mathematically, we can write this as a conditional expectation: E(hy6t􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 hy3t􏱦1, where It􏱦1 denotes all observable information up through time t – 1. This suggests estimating the model hy6t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 ut, and testing H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 1. (We can also test H0: 􏱬0 􏱪 0, but we often allow for a term pre- mium for buying assets with different maturities, so that 􏱬0 􏱻 0.) (i) Estimating the previous equation by OLS using the data in INTQRT.RAW (spaced every three months) gives 􏱾hy6t 􏱪 􏱦.058 􏱕 1.104 hy3t􏱦1 (.070) (.039) n 􏱪 123, R2 􏱪 .866. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 405 406 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Do you reject H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 1 against H0: 􏱬1 􏱻 1 at the 1% significance level? Does the estimate seem practically different from one? (ii) Another implication of the EH is that no other variables dated as t 􏱦 1 or earlier should help explain hy6t, once hy3t􏱦1 has been controlled for. Including one lag of the spread between six-month and three-month T-bill rates gives 􏱾hy6t 􏱪 􏱦.123 􏱕 1.053 hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 .480 (r6t􏱦1 􏱦 r3t􏱦1) (.067) (.039) (.109) n 􏱪 123, R2 􏱪 .885. Now, is the coefficient on hy3t􏱦1 statistically different from one? Is the lagged spread term significant? According to this equation, if, at time t 􏱦 1, r6 is above r3, should you invest in six-month or three-month T-bills? (iii) The sample correlation between hy3t and hy3t􏱦1 is .914. Why might this raise some concerns with the previous analysis? (iv) How would you test for seasonality in the equation estimated in part (ii)? 7 A partial adjustment model is yt* 􏱪􏰸0 􏱕􏰸1xt 􏱕et yt 􏱦yt􏱦1 􏱪􏲇(yt* 􏱦yt􏱦1)􏱕at, where yt* is the desired or optimal level of y, and yt is the actual (observed) level. For example, yt* is the desired growth in firm inventories, and xt is growth in firm sales. The parameter 􏰸1 measures the effect of xt on yt*. The second equation describes how the actual y adjusts depending on the relationship between the desired y in time t and the actual y in time t 􏱦 1. The parameter 􏲇 measures the speed of adjustment and satisfies 0 􏱷 􏲇 􏱷 1. (i) Plug the first equation for yt* into the second equation and show that we can write yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏱬2xt 􏱕ut. In particular, find the 􏱬j in terms of the 􏰸j and 􏲇 and find ut in terms of et and at. Therefore, the partial adjustment model leads to a model with a lagged dependent variable and a contemporaneous x. (ii) If E(et􏰫xt, yt􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 E(at􏰫xt, yt􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 0 and all series are weakly depen- dent, how would you estimate the 􏱬j? (iii) If 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 .7 and 􏱬ˆ2 􏱪 .2, what are the estimates of 􏰸1 and 􏲇? 8 Suppose that the equation yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛t􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut satisfies the sequential exogeneity assumption in equation (11.40). (i) Suppose you difference the equation to obtain 􏰧yt 􏱪􏱛􏱕􏱬1􏰧xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬k􏰧xtk 􏱕􏰧ut. How come applying OLS on the differenced equation does not generally result in consistent estimators of the 􏱬j? (ii) What assumption on the explanatory variables in the original equation would ensure that OLS on the differences consistently estimates the 􏱬j? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data (iii) Let zt1, ..., ztk be a set of explanatory variables dated contemporaneously with yt. If we specify the static regression model yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kztk 􏱕 ut, describe what we need to assume for xt 􏱪 zt to be sequentially exogenous. Do you think the assumptions are likely to hold in economic applications? Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in HSEINV.RAW for this exercise. (i) Find the first order autocorrelation in log(invpc). Now, find the autocorrelation after linearly detrending log(invpc). Do the same for log( price). Which of the two series may have a unit root? (ii) Based on your findings in part (i), estimate the equation log(invpct) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧log(pricet) 􏱕 􏱬2t 􏱕 ut and report the results in standard form. Interpret the coefficient 􏱬ˆ1 and determine whether it is statistically significant. (iii) Linearly detrend log(invpct) and use the detrended version as the dependent variable in the regression from part (ii) (see Section 10.5). What happens to R2? (iv) Now use 􏰧log(invpct) as the dependent variable. How do your results change from part (ii)? Is the time trend still significant? Why or why not? C2 In Example 11.7, define the growth in hourly wage and output per hour as the change in the natural log: ghrwage 􏱪 􏰧log(hrwage) and goutphr 􏱪 􏰧log(outphr). Consider a simple extension of the model estimated in (11.29): ghrwaget 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1goutphrt 􏱕 􏱬2goutphrt􏱦1 􏱕 ut. This allows an increase in productivity growth to have both a current and lagged effect on wage growth. (i) Estimate the equation using the data in EARNS.RAW and report the results in standard form. Is the lagged value of goutphr statistically significant? (ii) If 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2 􏱪 1, a permanent increase in productivity growth is fully passed on in higher wage growth after one year. Test H0: 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2 􏱪 1 against the two-sided al- ternative. Remember, one way to do this is to write the equation so that 􏰩 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬2 appears directly in the model, as in Example 10.4 from Chapter 10. (iii) Does goutphrt􏱦2 need to be in the model? Explain. C3 (i) In Example 11.4, it may be that the expected value of the return at time t, given past returns, is a quadratic function of returnt􏱦1. To check this possibility, use the data in NYSE.RAW to estimate returnt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1returnt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬2returnt2􏱦1 􏱕 ut; report the results in standard form. (ii) State and test the null hypothesis that E(returnt􏰫returnt􏱦1) does not depend on returnt􏱦1. (Hint: There are two restrictions to test here.) What do you conclude? (iii) Drop returnt2􏱦1 from the model, but add the interaction term returnt􏱦1·returnt􏱦2. Now test the efficient markets hypothesis. (iv) What do you conclude about predicting weekly stock returns based on past stock returns? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 407 408 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data C4 Use the data in PHILLIPS.RAW for this exercise, but only through 1996. (i) In Example 11.5, we assumed that the natural rate of unemployment is constant. An alternative form of the expectations augmented Phillips curve allows the natural rate of unemployment to depend on past levels of unemployment. In the simplest case, the natural rate at time t equals unemt􏱦1. If we assume adaptive expectations, we ob- tain a Phillips curve where inflation and unemployment are in first differences: 􏰧inf 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧unem 􏱕 u. Estimate this model, report the results in the usual form, and discuss the sign, size, C5 (i) Add a linear time trend to equation (11.27). Is a time trend necessary in the first- and statistical significance of 􏱬ˆ1. (ii) Which model fits the data better, (11.19) or the model from part (i)? Explain. difference equation? (ii) Drop the time trend and add the variables ww2 and pill to (11.27) (do not differ- ence these dummy variables). Are these variables jointly significant at the 5% level? (iii) Add the linear time trend, ww2, and pill all to equation (11.27). What happens to the magnitude and statistical significance of the time trend as compared with that in part (i)? What about the coefficient on pill as compared with that in part (ii)? (iv) Using the model from part (iii), estimate the LRP and obtain its standard error. Compare this to (10.19), where gfr and pe appeared in levels rather than in first differences. Would you say that the link between fertility and the value of the per- sonal exemption is a particularly robust finding? C6 Let invent be the real value inventories in the United States during year t, let GDPt denote real gross domestic product, and let r3t denote the (ex post) real interest rate on three- month T-bills. The ex post real interest rate is (approximately) r3t 􏱪 i3t – inft, where i3t is the rate on three-month T-bills and inft is the annual inflation rate [see Mankiw (1994, Section 6.4)]. The change in inventories, cinvent, is the inventory investment for the year. The accelerator model of inventory investment relates cinven to the cGDP, the change in GDP: cinvent 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1cGDPt 􏱕 ut, where 􏱬1 􏱰 0. [See, for example, Mankiw (1994), Chapter 17.] (i) Use the data in INVEN.RAW to estimate the accelerator model. Report the results in the usual form and interpret the equation. Is 􏱬ˆ1 statistically greater than zero? (ii) If the real interest rate rises, then the opportunity cost of holding inventories rises, and so an increase in the real interest rate should decrease inventories. Add the real interest rate to the accelerator model and discuss the results. (iii) Does the level of the real interest rate work better than the first difference, cr3t? C7 Use CONSUMP.RAW for this exercise. One version of the permanent income hypothesis (PIH) of consumption is that the growth in consumption is unpredictable. [Another version is that the change in consumption itself is unpredictable; see Mankiw (1994, Chapter 15) for discussion of the PIH.] Let gct 􏱪 log(ct) 􏱦 log(ct􏱦1) be the growth in real per capita consumption (of nondurables and services). Then the PIH implies that E(gct􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 E(gct), where It􏱦1 denotes information known at time (t 􏱦 1); in this case, t denotes a year. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data (i) Test the PIH by estimating gct 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gct􏱦1 􏱕 ut. Clearly state the null and al- ternative hypotheses. What do you conclude? (ii) To the regression in part (i) add the variables gyt−1, i3t−1, and inft−1. Are these new variables individually or jointly significant at the 5% level? (Be sure to report the appropriate p-values.) (iii) In the regression from part (ii), what happens to the p-value for the t statistic on gct−1? Does this mean the PIH hypothesis is now supported by the data? (iv) In the regression from part(ii), what is the F statistic and its associated p-value for joint significance of the four explanatory variables? Does your conclusion about the PIH now agree with what you found in part (i)? C8 Use (i) Estimate an AR(1) model for the unemployment rate. Use this equation to predict the unemployment rate for 2004. Compare this with the actual unemployment rate for 2004. (You can find this information in a recent Economic Report of the President.) (ii) Add a lag of inflation to the AR(1) model from part (i). Is inft􏱦1 statistically significant? (iii) Use the equation from part (ii) to predict the unemployment rate for 2004. Is the result better or worse than in the model from part (i)? (iv) Use the method from Section 6.4 to construct a 95% prediction interval for the 2004 unemployment rate. Is the 2004 unemployment rate in the interval? the data in PHILLIPS.RAW for this exercise. C9 Use previously asked for an analysis of these data. (i) Compute the first order autocorrelation coefficient for the variable prcfat. Are you the data in TRAFFIC2.RAW for this exercise. Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 10 concerned that prcfat contains a unit root? Do the same for the unemployment rate. (ii) Estimate a multiple regression model relating the first difference of prcfat, 􏰧prcfat, to the same variables in part (vi) of Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 10, except you should first difference the unemployment rate, too. Then, include a linear time trend, monthly dummy variables, the weekend variable, and the two policy variables; do not difference these. Do you find any interesting results? (iii) Comment on the following statement: “We should always first difference any time series we suspect of having a unit root before doing multiple regression because it is the safe strategy and should give results similar to using the levels.” [In answering this, you may want to do the regression from part (vi) of Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 10, if you have not already.] C10 Use all the data in PHILLIPS.RAW to answer this question. You should now use 56 years of data. (i) Reestimate equation (11.19) and report the results in the usual form. Do the inter- cept and slope estimates change notably when you add the recent years of data? (ii) Obtain a new estimate of the natural rate of unemployment. Compare this new estimate with that reported in Example 11.5. (iii) Compute the first order autocorrelation for unem. In your opinion, is the root close to one? (iv) Use cunem as the explanatory variable instead of unem. Which explanatory variable gives a higher R-squared? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 409 410 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data C11 Okun’s Law—see, for example, Mankiw (1994, Chapter 2)—implies the following relationship between the annual percentage change in real GDP, pcrgdp, and the change in the annual unemployment rate, cunem: pcrgdp 􏱪 3 􏱦 2 􏱳 cunem. If the unemployment rate is stable, real GDP grows at 3% annually. For each percent- age point increase in the unemployment rate, real GDP grows by two percentage points less. (This should not be interpreted in any causal sense; it is more like a statistical description.) To see if the data on the U.S. economy support Okun’s Law, we specify a model that allows deviations via an error term, pcrgdpt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1cunemt 􏱕 ut. (i) Use the data in OKUN.RAW to estimate the equation. Do you get exactly 3 for the intercept and 􏱦2 for the slope? Did you expect to? (ii) Find the t statistic for testing H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦2. Do you reject H0 against the two-sided alternative at any reasonable significance level? (iii) Find the t statistic for testing H0: 􏱬0 􏱪 3. Do you reject H0 at the 5% level against the two-sided alternative? Is it a “strong” rejection? (iv) Find the F statistic and p-value for testing H0: 􏱬0 􏱪 3, 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱦2 against the alternative that H0 is false. Does the test reject at the 10% level? Overall, would you say the data reject or tend to support Okun’s Law? C12 Use the data in MINWAGE.RAW for this exercise, focusing on the wage and employ- ment series for sector 232 (Men’s and Boys’ Furnishings). The variable gwage232 is the monthly growth (change in logs) in the average wage in sector 232; gemp232 is the growth in employment in sector 232; gmwage is the growth in the federal minimum wage; and gcpi is the growth in the (urban) Consumer Price Index. (i) Find the first order autocorrelation in gwage232. Does this series appear to be weakly dependent? (ii) Estimate the dynamic model gwage232t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gwage232t−1 􏱕 􏱬2gmwaget 􏱕 􏱬3gcpit 􏱕 ut by OLS. Holding fixed last month’s growth in wage and the growth in the CPI, does an increase in the federal minimum result in a contemporaneous increase in gwage232t? Explain. (iii) Now add the lagged growth in employment, gemp232t−1, to the equation in part (ii). Is it statistically significant? (iv) Compared with the model without gwage232t−1 and gemp232t−1, does adding the two lagged variables have much of an effect on the gmwage coefficient? (v) Run the regression of gmwaget on gwage232t−1 and gemp232t−1, and report the R-squared. Comment on how the value of R-squared helps explain your answer to part (iv). C13 Use the data in BEVERIDGE.RAW to answer this question. The data set includes monthly observations on vacancy rates and unemployment rates for the U.S. from December 2000 through February 2012. (i) Find the correlation beween urate and urate_1. Would you say the correlation points more toward a unit root process or a weakly dependent process? (ii) Repeat part (i) but with the vacancy rate, vrate. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 11 Further Issues in Using OLS with Time Series Data (iii) The Beveridge Curve relates the unemployment rate to the vacancy rate, with the simplest relationship being linear: uratet 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1vratet 􏱕 ut where 􏱬1 􏱼 0 is expected. Estimate 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 by OLS and report the results in the usual form. Do you find a negative relationship? (iv) Explain why you cannot trust the confidence interval for 􏱬1 reported by the OLS output in part (iii). [The tools needed to study regressions of this type are presented in Chapter18.] (v) If you difference urate and vrate before running the regression, how does the estimated slope coefficient compare with part (iii)? Is it statistically different from zero? [This example shows that differencing before running an OLS regression is not always a sensible strategy. But we cannot say more until Chapter 18.] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 411 CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions In this chapter, we discuss the critical problem of serial correlation in the error terms of a multiple regression model. We saw in Chapter 11 that when, in an appropriate sense, the dynamics of a model have been completely specified, the errors will not be serially cor- related. Thus, testing for serial correlation can be used to detect dynamic misspecification. Furthermore, static and finite distributed lag models often have serially correlated errors even if there is no underlying misspecification of the model. Therefore, it is important to know the consequences and remedies for serial correlation for these useful classes of models. In Section 12.1, we present the properties of OLS when the errors contain serial cor- relation. In Section 12.2, we demonstrate how to test for serial correlation. We cover tests that apply to models with strictly exogenous regressors and tests that are asymptotically valid with general regressors, including lagged dependent variables. Section 12.3 explains how to correct for serial correlation under the assumption of strictly exogenous explanatory variables, while Section 12.4 shows how using differenced data often eliminates serial cor- relation in the errors. Section 12.5 covers more recent advances on how to adjust the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics in the presence of very general serial correlation. In Chapter 8, we discussed testing and correcting for heteroskedasticity in cross- sectional applications. In Section 12.6, we show how the methods used in the cross- sectional case can be extended to the time series case. The mechanics are essentially the same, but there are a few subtleties associated with the temporal correlation in time series observations that must be addressed. In addition, we briefly touch on the consequences of dynamic forms of heteroskedasticity. 12.1 Properties of OLS with Serially Correlated Errors Unbiasedness and Consistency In Chapter 10, we proved unbiasedness of the OLS estimator under the first three Gauss-Markov assumptions for time series regressions (TS.1 through TS.3). In particular, 412 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 413 Theorem 10.1 assumed nothing about serial correlation in the errors. It follows that, as long as the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous, the 􏱬ˆj are unbiased, regardless of the degree of serial correlation in the errors. This is analogous to the observation that heteroskedasticity in the errors does not cause bias in the 􏱬ˆj. In Chapter 11, we relaxed the strict exogeneity assumption to E(ut􏰫xt) 􏱪 0 and showed that, when the data are weakly dependent, the 􏱬ˆj are still consistent (although not necessarily unbiased). This result did not hinge on any assumption about serial correlation in the errors. Efficiency and Inference Because the Gauss-Markov Theorem (Theorem 10.4) requires both homoskedasticity and serially uncorrelated errors, OLS is no longer BLUE in the presence of serial correlation. Even more importantly, the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics are not valid, even asymptotically. We can see this by computing the variance of the OLS estimator un- der the first four Gauss-Markov assumptions and the AR(1) serial correlation model for the error terms. More precisely, we assume that ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n [12.1] 􏰫􏰴 􏰫 􏱷 1, [12.2] where the et are uncorrelated random variables with mean zero and variance 􏱧2e; recall from Chapter 11 that assumption (12.2) is the stability condition. We consider the variance of the OLS slope estimator in the simple regression model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt 􏱕ut, and, just to simplify the formula, we assume that the sample average of the xt is zero (x- 􏱪 0). Then, the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ1 of 􏱬1 can be written as ˆ 􏱦 1 ∑n 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 SSTx xtut, [12.3] t􏱪1 where SSTx 􏱪 ∑ n x2t . Now, in computing the variance of 􏱬ˆ 1 (conditional on X), we t􏱪1 must account for the serial correlation in the ut: t􏱪1 ˆ 􏱦2 ∑n Var( 􏱬1) 􏱪 SSTx Var 􏱵 ∑n xtut 􏱷 n􏱦1 n􏱦t 􏱦2 2 􏱪SSTx 􏱵 xtVar(u)􏱕2 ∑∑ t􏱪1 j􏱪1 xx E(uu )􏱷 t t􏱕j t t􏱕j [12.4] t􏱪1 􏱪 􏱧2/SSTx 􏱕 2(􏱧2/SST2x) ∑∑ t􏱪1 j􏱪1 􏰴jx x , t t􏱕j 2j2 where 􏱧 􏱪 Var(ut) and we have used the fact that E(utut􏱕j) 􏱪 Cov(ut, ut􏱕j) 􏱪 􏰴ˆ􏱧 [see equation (11.4)]. The first term in equation (12.4), 􏱧2/SSTx, is the variance of 􏱬1 when Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. t n􏱦1 n􏱦t 414 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data 􏰴 􏱪 0, which is the familiar OLS variance under the Gauss-Markov assumptions. If we ignore the serial correlation and estimate the variance in the usual way, the variance esti- mator will usually be biased when 􏰴 􏱻 0 because it ignores the second term in (12.4). As we will see through later examples, 􏰴 􏱰 0 is most common, in which case, 􏰴 j 􏱰 0 for all j. Further, the independent variables in regression models are often positively correlated t t􏱕j over time, so that x x is positive for most pairs t and t 􏱕 j. Therefore, in most economic ∑∑ mula 􏱧2/SSTx understates the true variance of the OLS estimator. If 􏰴 is large or xt has a tt􏱕jn􏱦1 n􏱦tj applications, the term t􏱪1 j􏱪1 􏰴 x x is positive, and so the usual OLS variance for- high degree of positive serial correlation—a common case—the bias in the usual OLS variance estimator can be substantial. We will tend to think the OLS slope estimator is more precise than it actually is. When 􏰴 􏱷 0, 􏰴j is negative when j is odd and positive when j is even, and EXPLORING FURTHER 12.1 Suppose that, rather than the AR(1) model, ut follows the MA(1) model ut 􏱪 et 􏱕 􏱮et􏱦1. Find Var(ˆ􏱬1) and show that it is different from the usual formula if 􏱮 􏱻 0. ˆ In either case, the usual variance estima- tor will be biased for Var(􏱬1) in the presence of serial correlation. Because the standard error of 􏱬ˆ1 is an estimate of the standard deviation of 􏱬ˆ1, using the usual OLS standard error in the presence of serial correlation is invalid. Therefore, t statistics are no longer valid for testing single hypotheses. Since a smaller standard error means a larger t statistic, the usual t statistics will often be too large when 􏰴 􏱰 0. The usual F and LM statistics for testing multiple hypotheses are also invalid. Goodness-of-Fit Sometimes one sees the claim that serial correlation in the errors of a time series regression model invalidates our usual goodness-of-fit measures, R-squared, and adjusted R-squared. Fortunately, this is not the case, provided the data are stationary and weakly dependent. To see why these measures are still valid, recall that we defined the popula- tion R-squared in a cross-sectional context to be 1 􏱦 􏱧2u/􏱧2y (see Section 6.3). This defini- tion is still appropriate in the context of time series regressions with stationary, weakly dependent data: the variances of both the errors and the dependent variable do not change over time. By the law of large numbers, R2 and R- 2 both consistently estimate the popu- lation R-squared. The argument is essentially the same as in the cross-sectional case in the presence of heteroskedasticity (see Section 8.1). Because there is never an unbiased estimator of the population R-squared, it makes no sense to talk about bias in R2 caused by serial correlation. All we can really say is that our goodness-of-fit measures are still consistent estimators of the population parameter. This argument does not go through if {yt} is an I(1) process because Var(yt) grows with t; goodness-of-fit does not make much sense in this case. As we discussed in Section 10.5, trends in the mean of yt, or seasonality, can and should be accounted for in computing an R-squared. Other departures from stationarity do not cause difficulty in interpreting R2 and -R2 in the usual ways. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. so it is difficult to determine the sign of ∑n􏱦1∑n􏱦t􏰴jxx .Infact,itispossible t t􏱕j that the usual OLS variance formula ac- t􏱪1 j􏱪1 tually overstates the true variance of 􏱬ˆ1. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 415 Serial Correlation in the Presence of Lagged Dependent Variables Beginners in econometrics are often warned of the dangers of serially correlated errors in the presence of lagged dependent variables. Almost every textbook on econometrics con- tains some form of the statement “OLS is inconsistent in the presence of lagged dependent variables and serially correlated errors.” Unfortunately, as a general assertion, this state- ment is false. There is a version of the statement that is correct, but it is important to be very precise. To illustrate, suppose that the expected value of yt given yt􏱦1 is linear: E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1yt􏱦1, [12.5] where we assume stability, 􏰫 􏱬1􏰫 􏱷 1. We know we can always write this with an error term as yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕 ut, [12.6] E(ut􏰫yt􏱦1) 􏱪 0. [12.7] By construction, this model satisfies the key zero conditional mean Assumption TS.3􏲃 for consistency of OLS; therefore, the OLS estimators 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 are consistent. It is im- portant to see that, without further assumptions, the errors {ut} can be serially correlated. Condition (12.7) ensures that ut is uncorrelated with yt􏱦1, but ut and yt􏱦2 could be cor- related. Then, because ut􏱦1 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1yt􏱦2, the covariance between ut and ut􏱦1 is 􏱦􏱬1Cov(ut, yt􏱦2), which is not necessarily zero. Thus, the errors exhibit serial correlation and the model contains a lagged dependent variable, but OLS consistently estimates 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 because these are the parameters in the conditional expectation (12.5). The serial correlation in the errors will cause the usual OLS statistics to be invalid for testing pur- poses, but it will not affect consistency. So when is OLS inconsistent if the errors are serially correlated and the regressors contain a lagged dependent variable? This happens when we write the model in error form, exactly as in (12.6), but then we assume that {ut} follows a stable AR(1) model as in (12.1) and (12.2), where E(et􏰫ut􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(et􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0. [12.8] Because et is uncorrelated with yt􏱦1 by assumption, Cov(yt􏱦1, ut) 􏱪 􏰴Cov(yt􏱦1, ut􏱦1), which is not zero unless 􏰴 􏱪 0. This causes the OLS estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 from the regression of yt on yt􏱦1 to be inconsistent. We now see that OLS estimation of (12.6) when the errors ut also follow an AR(1) model leads to inconsistent estimators. However, the correctness of this statement makes it no less wrongheaded. We have to ask: What would be the point in estimating the parameters in (12.6) when the errors follow an AR(1) model? It is difficult to think of cases where this would be interesting. At least in (12.5) the parameters tell us the expected value of yt given yt􏱦1. When we combine (12.6) and (12.1), we see that yt really follows a second Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 416 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data order autoregressive model, or AR(2) model. To see this, write ut􏱦1 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1yt􏱦2 and plug this into ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et. Then, (12.6) can be rewritten as yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏰴(yt􏱦1 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1yt􏱦2)􏱕et 􏱪􏱬0(1􏱦􏰴)􏱕(􏱬1 􏱕􏰴)yt􏱦1 􏱦􏰴􏱬1yt􏱦2 􏱕et 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱮2yt􏱦2 􏱕 et, where 􏱮0 􏱪 􏱬0(1 􏱦 􏰴), 􏱮1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 􏰴, and 􏱮2 􏱪 􏱦􏰴􏱬1. Given (12.8), it follows that E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱮2 yt􏱦2. [12.9] This means that the expected value of yt, given all past y, depends on two lags of y. It is equation (12.9) that we would be interested in using for any practical purpose, including forecasting, as we will see in Chapter 18. We are especially interested in the parameters 􏱮j. Under the appropriate stability conditions for an AR(2) model—which we will cover in Section 12.3—OLS estimation of (12.9) produces consistent and asymptotically normal estimators of the 􏱮j. The bottom line is that you need a good reason for having both a lagged dependent variable in a model and a particular model of serial correlation in the errors. Often, serial correlation in the errors of a dynamic model simply indicates that the dynamic regression function has not been completely specified: in the previous example, we should add yt􏱦2 to the equation. In Chapter 18 we will see examples of models with lagged dependent variables where the errors are serially correlated and are also correlated with yt􏱦1. But even in these cases the errors do not follow an autoregressive process. 12.2 Testing for Serial Correlation In this section, we discuss several methods of testing for serial correlation in the error terms in the multiple linear regression model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut. We first consider the case when the regressors are strictly exogenous. Recall that this requires the error, ut, to be uncorrelated with the regressors in all time periods (see Section 10.3), so, among other things, it rules out models with lagged dependent variables. A t Test for AR(1) Serial Correlation with Strictly Exogenous Regressors Although there are numerous ways in which the error terms in a multiple regression model can be serially correlated, the most popular model—and the simplest to work with—is the AR(1) model in equations (12.1) and (12.2). In the previous section, we explained the implications of performing OLS when the errors are serially correlated in general, and we derived the variance of the OLS slope estimator in a simple regression model with AR(1) errors. We now show how to test for the presence of AR(1) serial correlation. The null hypothesis is that there is no serial correlation. Therefore, just as with tests for heteroske- dasticity, we assume the best and require the data to provide reasonably strong evidence that the ideal assumption of no serial correlation is violated. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 417 We first derive a large-sample test under the assumption that the explanatory vari- ables are strictly exogenous: the expected value of ut, given the entire history of indepen- dent variables, is zero. In addition, in (12.1), we must assume that and E(et􏰫ut􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0 [12.10] Var(et􏰫ut􏱦1) 􏱪 Var(et) 􏱪 􏰴2e. [12.11] These are standard assumptions in the AR(1) model (which follow when {et} is an i.i.d. sequence), and they allow us to apply the large-sample results from Chapter 11 for dynamic regression. As with testing for heteroskedasticity, the null hypothesis is that the appropriate Gauss-Markov assumption is true. In the AR(1) model, the null hypothesis that the errors are serially uncorrelated is H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0. [12.12] How can we test this hypothesis? If the ut were observed, then, under (12.10) and (12.11), we could immediately apply the asymptotic normality results from Theorem 11.2 to the dynamic regression model ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 2, ..., n. [12.13] (Under the null hypothesis 􏰴 􏱪 0, {ut} is clearly weakly dependent.) In other words, we could estimate 􏰴 from the regression of ut on ut􏱦1, for all t 􏱪 2, ..., n, without an inter- cept, and use the usual t statistic for 􏰴ˆ. This does not work because the errors ut are not observed. Nevertheless, just as with testing for heteroskedasticity, we can replace ut with thecorrespondingOLSresidual,uˆt.Sinceuˆt dependsontheOLSestimators􏱬ˆ0,􏱬ˆ1,...,􏱬ˆk, it is not obvious that using uˆt for ut in the regression has no effect on the distribution of the t sta- tistic. Fortunately, it turns out that, because of the strict exogeneity assumption, the large-sample distribution of the t statistic is not affected by using the OLS residuals in place of the errors. A proof is well beyond the scope of this text, but it follows from the work of Wooldridge (1991b). We can summarize the asymptotic test for AR(1) serial correlation very simply. Testing for AR(1) Serial Correlation with Strictly Exogenous Regressors: (i) Run the OLS regression of yt on xt1, ..., xtk and obtain the OLS residuals, uˆt, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. (ii) Run the regression of uˆt on uˆt􏱦1, for all t 􏱪 2, ..., n, [12.14] obtaining the coefficient 􏰴ˆ on uˆt􏱦1 and its t statistic, t􏰴ˆ. (This regression may or may not contain an intercept; the t statistic for 􏰴ˆ will be slightly affected, but it is asymptotically valid either way.) (iii) Use t􏰴ˆ to test H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏰴 􏱻 0 in the usual way. (Actually, since 􏰴 􏱰 0 is often expected a priori, the alternative can be H1: 􏰴 􏱰 0.) Typically, we conclude that serial correlation is a problem to be dealt with only if H0 is rejected at the 5% level. As always, it is best to report the p-value for the test. In deciding whether serial correlation needs to be addressed, we should remember the difference between practical and statistical significance. With a large sample size, it is possible to find serial correlation even though 􏰴ˆ is practically small; when 􏰴ˆ is close to zero, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 418 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data the usual OLS inference procedures will not be far off [see equation (12.4)]. Such outcomes are somewhat rare in time series applications because time series data sets are usually small. EXAMPLE 12.1 TESTING FOR AR(1) SERIAL CORRELATION IN THE PHILLIPS CURVE In Chapter 10, we estimated a static Phillips curve that explained the inflation- unemployment tradeoff in the United States (see Example 10.1). In Chapter 11, we studied a particular expectations augmented Phillips curve, where we assumed adaptive expecta- tions (see Example 11.5). We now test the error term in each equation for serial correla- tion. Since the expectations augmented curve uses ∆inft 􏱪 inft 􏱦 inft􏱦1 as the dependent variable, we have one fewer observation. For the static Phillips curve, the regression in (12.14) yields 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .573, t 􏱪 4.93, and p-value 􏱪 .000 (with 48 observations through 1996). This is very strong evidence of posi- tive, first order serial correlation. One consequence of this is that the standard errors and t statistics from Chapter 10 are not valid. By contrast, the test for AR(1) serial correlation in the expectations augmented curve gives 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.036, t 􏱪 􏱦.287, and p-value 􏱪 .775 (with 47 observations): there is no evidence of AR(1) serial correlation in the expectations augmented Phillips curve. Although the test from (12.14) is derived from the AR(1) model, the test can detect other kinds of serial correlation. Remember, 􏰴ˆ is a consistent estimator of the correlation between ut and ut􏱦1. Any serial correlation that causes adjacent errors to be correlated can be picked up by this test. On the other hand, it does not detect serial correlation where adjacent errors are uncorrelated, Corr(ut, ut􏱦1) 􏱪 0. (For example, ut and ut􏱦2 could be correlated.) In using the usual t statistic from (12.14), we must assume that the errors in (12.13) satisfy the appropriate homo- skedasticity assumption, (12.11). In fact, it is easy to make the test robust to het- eroskedasticity in et: we simply use the usual, heteroskedasticity-robust t statistic from Chapter 8. For the static Phillips curve in Example 12.1, the heteroskedasticity- robust t statistic is 4.03, which is smaller than the nonrobust t statistic but still very sig- nificant. In Section 12.6, we further discuss heteroskedasticity in time series regressions, including its dynamic forms. The Durbin-Watson Test under Classical Assumptions Another test for AR(1) serial correlation is the Durbin-Watson test. The Durbin-Watson (DW) statistic is also based on the OLS residuals: [12.15] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 12.2 How would you use regression (12.14) to construct an approximate 95% confidence interval for 􏰴? ∑n t t􏱦1 ___t_􏱪_2∑ DW 􏱪 n t􏱪1 uˆ2 t (uˆ􏱦uˆ )2 __________ . CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 419 Simple algebra shows that DW and 􏰴ˆ from (12.14) are closely linked: DW 􏱴 2(1 􏱦 􏰴ˆ). [12.16] One reason this relationship is not exact is that 􏰴ˆ has ∑ n uˆ 2t􏱦1 in its denominator, while t􏱪2 the DW statistic has the sum of squares of all OLS residuals in its denominator. Even with moderate sample sizes, the approximation in (12.16) is often pretty close. Therefore, tests based on DW and the t test based on 􏰴ˆ are conceptually the same. Durbin and Watson (1950) derive the distribution of DW (conditional on X), some- thing that requires the full set of classical linear model assumptions, including normality of the error terms. Unfortunately, this distribution depends on the values of the indepen- dent variables. (It also depends on the sample size, the number of regressors, and whether the regression contains an intercept.) Although some econometrics packages tabulate criti- cal values and p-values for DW, many do not. In any case, they depend on the full set of CLM assumptions. Several econometrics texts report upper and lower bounds for the critical values that depend on the desired significance level, the alternative hypothesis, the number of observations, and the number of regressors. (We assume that an intercept is included in the model.) Usually, the DW test is computed for the alternative H1: 􏰴 􏱰 0. [12.17] From the approximation in (12.16), 􏰴ˆ 􏱴 0 implies that DW 􏱴 2, and 􏰴ˆ 􏱰 0 implies that DW 􏱷 2. Thus, to reject the null hypothesis (12.12) in favor of (12.17), we are looking for a value of DW that is significantly less than two. Unfortunately, because of the problems in obtaining the null distribution of DW, we must compare DW with two sets of critical values. These are usually labeled as dU (for upper) and dL (for lower). If DW 􏱷 dL, then we rejectH0 infavorof(12.17);ifDW􏱰dU,wefailtorejectH0.IfdL􏰯DW􏰯dU,thetestis inconclusive. As an example, if we choose a 5% significance level with n 􏱪 45 and k 􏱪 4, dU 􏱪 1.720 and dL 􏱪 1.336 [see Savin and White (1977)]. If DW 􏱷 1.336, we reject the null of no serial correlation at the 5% level; if DW 􏱰 1.72, we fail to reject H0; if 1.336 􏰯 DW 􏰯 1.72, the test is inconclusive. In Example 12.1, for the static Phillips curve, DW is computed to be DW 􏱪 .80. We can obtain the lower 1% critical value from Savin and White (1977) for k 􏱪 1 and n 􏱪 50: dL 􏱪 1.32. Therefore, we reject the null of no serial correlation against the alternative of positive serial correlation at the 1% level. (Using the previous t test, we can conclude that the p-value equals zero to three decimal places.) For the expectations augmented Phil- lips curve, DW 􏱪 1.77, which is well within the fail-to-reject region at even the 5% level (dU 􏱪 1.59). The fact that an exact sampling distribution for DW can be tabulated is the only advantage that DW has over the t test from (12.14). Given that the tabulated critical values are exactly valid only under the full set of CLM assumptions and that they can lead to a wide inconclusive region, the practical disadvantages of the DW statistic are substantial. The t statistic from (12.14) is simple to compute and asymptotically valid without nor- mally distributed errors. The t statistic is also valid in the presence of heteroskedasticity that depends on the xtj. Plus, it is easy to make it robust to any form of heteroskedasticity. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 420 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Testing for AR(1) Serial Correlation without Strictly Exogenous Regressors When the explanatory variables are not strictly exogenous, so that one or more xtj are cor- related with ut􏱦1, neither the t test from regression (12.14) nor the Durbin-Watson statistic are valid, even in large samples. The leading case of nonstrictly exogenous regressors occurs when the model contains a lagged dependent variable: yt􏱦1 and ut􏱦1 are obviously correlated. Durbin (1970) suggested two alternatives to the DW statistic when the model contains a lagged dependent variable and the other regressors are nonrandom (or, more generally, strictly exogenous). The first is called Durbin’s h statistic. This statistic has a practical drawback in that it cannot always be computed, so we do not cover it here. Durbin’s alternative statistic is simple to compute and is valid when there are any number of nonstrictly exogenous explanatory variables. The test also works if the explana- tory variables happen to be strictly exogenous. Testing for Serial Correlation with General Regressors: (i) Run the OLS regression of yt on xt1, ..., xtk and obtain the OLS residuals, uˆt, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. (ii) Run the regression of uˆt on xt1, xt2, ..., xtk, uˆt􏱦1, for all t 􏱪 2, ..., n [12.18] to obtain the coefficient 􏰴ˆ on uˆ and its t statistic, t . t􏱦1 􏰴ˆ (iii) Use t􏰴ˆ to test H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏰴 􏱻 0 in the usual way (or use a one-sided alternative). In equation (12.18), we regress the OLS residuals on all independent variables, including an intercept, and the lagged residual. The t statistic on the lagged residual is a valid test of (12.12) in the AR(1) model (12.13) [when we add Var(ut􏰫xt, ut􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱧2 under H0]. Any number of lagged dependent variables may appear among the xtj, and other nonstrictly exogenous explanatory variables are allowed as well. The inclusion of xt1, ..., xtk explicitly allows for each xtj to be correlated with ut􏱦1, and this ensures that t􏰴ˆ has an approximate t distribution in large samples. The t statistic from (12.14) ignores possible correlation between xtj and ut􏱦1, so it is not valid without strictly exogenous regressors. Incidentally, because uˆt 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1xt1 􏱦 ... 􏱦 􏱬ˆkxtk, it can be shown that the t statistic on uˆt􏱦1 is the same if yt is used in place of uˆt as the dependent vari- able in (12.18). The t statistic from (12.18) is easily made robust to heteroskedasticity of unknown form [in particular, when Var(ut􏰫xt, ut􏱦1) is not constant]: just use the heteroskedasticity- robust t statistic on uˆt􏱦1. EXAMPLE 12.2 TESTING FOR AR(1) SERIAL CORRELATION IN THE MINIMUM WAGE EQUATION In Chapter 10 (see Example 10.9), we estimated the effect of the minimum wage on the Puerto Rican employment rate. We now check whether the errors appear to contain serial correlation, using the test that does not assume strict exogeneity of the minimum wage or GNP variables. [We add the log of Puerto Rican real GNP to equation (10.38), as in Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 421 Computer Exercise C3 in Chapter 10.] We are assuming that the underlying stochastic processes are weakly dependent, but we allow them to contain a linear time trend by including t in the regression. Letting uˆt denote the OLS residuals, we run the regression of uˆt on log(mincovt), log(prgnpt), log(usgnpt), t, and uˆt􏱦1, using the 37 available observations. The estimated coefficient on uˆt􏱦1 is 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .481 with t 􏱪 2.89 (two-sided p-value 􏱪 .007). Therefore, there is strong evidence of AR(1) serial correlation in the errors, which means the t statistics for the 􏱬ˆj that we obtained before are not valid for inference. Remember, though, the 􏱬ˆj are still consistent if ut is contempora- neously uncorrelated with each explanatory variable. Incidentally, if we use regression (12.14) instead, we obtain 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .417 and t 􏱪 2.63, so the outcome of the test is similar in this case. Testing for Higher Order Serial Correlation The test from (12.18) is easily extended to higher orders of serial correlation. For example, suppose that we wish to test in the AR(2) model, H0:􏰴1 􏱪0,􏰴2 􏱪0 [12.19] ut 􏱪 􏰴1ut􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴2ut􏱦2 􏱕 et. This alternative model of serial correlation allows us to test for second order serial corre- lation. As always, we estimate the model by OLS and obtain the OLS residuals, uˆt. Then, we can run the regression of uˆt on xt1, xt2, ..., xtk, uˆt􏱦1, and uˆt􏱦2, for all t 􏱪 3, ..., n, to obtain the F test for joint significance of uˆt􏱦1 and uˆt􏱦2. If these two lags are jointly significant at a small enough level, say, 5%, then we reject (12.19) and conclude that the errors are serially correlated. More generally, we can test for serial correlation in the autoregressive model of order q: ut 􏱪 􏰴1ut􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴2ut􏱦2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰴qut􏱦q 􏱕 et. [12.20] The null hypothesis is H0: 􏰴1 􏱪 0, 􏰴2 􏱪 0, ..., 􏰴q 􏱪 0. [12.21] Testing for AR(q) Serial Correlation: (i) Run the OLS regression of yt on xt1, ..., xtk and obtain the OLS residuals, uˆt, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. (ii) Run the regression of uˆt on xt1, xt2, ..., xtk, uˆt􏱦1, uˆt􏱦2, ..., uˆt􏱦q, for all t 􏱪 (q 􏱕 1), ..., n. [12.22] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 422 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data (iii) Compute the F test for joint significance of uˆt􏱦1, uˆt􏱦2, ..., uˆt􏱦q in (12.22). [The F statistic with yt as the dependent variable in (12.22) can also be used, as it gives an iden- tical answer.] If the xtj are assumed to be strictly exogenous, so that each xtj is uncorrelated with ut􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ..., ut􏱦q, then the xtj can be omitted from (12.22). Including the xtj in the regression makes the test valid with or without the strict exogeneity assumption. The test requires the homoskedasticity assumption Var(ut􏰫xt, ut􏱦1, ..., ut􏱦q) 􏱪 􏱧2. [12.23] A heteroskedasticity-robust version can be computed as described in Chapter 8. An alternative to computing the F test is to use the Lagrange multiplier (LM) form of the statistic. (We covered the LM statistic for testing exclusion restrictions in Chapter 5 for cross-sectional analysis.) The LM statistic for testing (12.21) is simply LM 􏱪 (n 􏱦 q)R2, [12.24] uˆ where R2 is just the usual R-squared from regression (12.22). Under the null hypothesis, uˆ LM ~a 􏱚2q. This is usually called the Breusch-Godfrey test for AR(q) serial correlation. The LM statistic also requires (12.23), but it can be made robust to heteroskedasticity. [For details, see Wooldridge (1991b).] EXAMPLE 12.3 TESTING FOR AR(3) SERIAL CORRELATION In the event study of the barium chloride industry (see Example 10.5), we used monthly data, so we may wish to test for higher orders of serial correlation. For illustration purposes, we test for AR(3) serial correlation in the errors underlying equation (10.22). Using regression (12.22), we find the F statistic for joint significance of uˆt􏱦1, uˆt􏱦2, and uˆt􏱦3 is F 􏱪 5.12. Originally, we had n 􏱪 131, and we lose three observations in the auxiliary regres- sion (12.22). Because we estimate 10 parameters in (12.22) for this example, the df in the F statistic are 3 and 118. The p-value of the F statistic is .0023, so there is strong evidence of AR(3) serial correlation. With quarterly or monthly data that have not been seasonally adjusted, we sometimes wish to test for seasonal forms of serial correlation. For example, with quarterly data, we might postulate the autoregressive model ut 􏱪 􏰴4ut􏱦4 􏱕 et. [12.25] From the AR(1) serial correlation tests, it is pretty clear how to proceed. When the regres- sors are strictly exogenous, we can use a t test on uˆt􏱦4 in the regression of uˆt on uˆt􏱦4, for all t 􏱪 5, ..., n. A modification of the Durbin-Watson statistic is also available [see Wallis (1972)]. When the xtj are not strictly exogenous, we can use the regression in (12.18), with uˆt􏱦4 replacing uˆt􏱦1. In Example 12.3, the data are monthly and are not seasonally adjusted. Therefore, it makes sense to test for correlation between ut and ut􏱦12. A regression of uˆt on uˆt􏱦12 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 423 yields 􏰴ˆ12 􏱪 􏱦.187 and p-value 􏱪 .028, so there is evidence of negative sea- sonal autocorrelation. (Including the re- gressors changes things only modestly: 􏰴ˆ12 􏱪 􏱦.170 and p-value 􏱪 .052.) This is somewhat unusual and does not have an obvious explanation. 12.3 Correcting for Serial Correlation with Strictly Exogenous Regressors If we detect serial correlation after applying one of the tests in Section 12.2, we have to do something about it. If our goal is to estimate a model with complete dynamics, we need to respecify the model. In applications where our goal is not to estimate a fully dynamic model, we need to find a way to carry out statistical inference: as we saw in Section 12.1, the usual OLS test statistics are no longer valid. In this section, we begin with the impor- tant case of AR(1) serial correlation. The traditional approach to this problem assumes fixed regressors. What are actually needed are strictly exogenous regressors. Therefore, at a minimum, we should not use these corrections when the explanatory variables include lagged dependent variables. Obtaining the Best Linear Unbiased Estimator in the AR(1) Model We assume the Gauss-Markov assumptions TS.1 through TS.4, but we relax Assumption TS.5. In particular, we assume that the errors follow the AR(1) model ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, .... [12.26] Remember that Assumption TS.3 implies that ut has a zero mean conditional on X. In the following analysis, we let the conditioning on X be implied in order to simplify the nota- tion. Thus, we write the variance of ut as Var(ut) 􏱪 􏱧2e/(1 􏱦 􏰴2). [12.27] For simplicity, consider the case with a single explanatory variable: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt 􏱕 ut, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. Because the problem in this equation is serial correlation in the ut, it makes sense to trans- form the equation to eliminate the serial correlation. For t 􏱸 2, we write yt􏱦1 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt􏱦1 􏱕 ut􏱦1 yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt 􏱕ut. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 12.3 Suppose you have quarterly data and you want to test for the presence of first order or fourth order serial correlation. With strictly exogenous regressors, how would you proceed? 424 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Now, if we multiply this first equation by 􏰴 and subtract it from the second equation, we get where we have used the fact that et 􏱪 ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1. We can write this as where yt 􏱦􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱪(1􏱦􏰴)􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1(xt 􏱦􏰴xt􏱦1)􏱕et,t􏱸2, y ̃t 􏱪(1􏱦􏰴)􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x ̃t 􏱕et,t􏱸2, y ̃t 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏰴yt􏱦1, x ̃t 􏱪 xt 􏱦 􏰴xt􏱦1 [12.28] [12.29] are called the quasi-differenced data. (If 􏰴 􏱪 1, these are differenced data, but remember we are assuming 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1.) The error terms in (12.28) are serially uncorrelated; in fact, this equation satisfies all of the Gauss-Markov assumptions. This means that, if we knew 􏰴, we could estimate 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 by regressing y ̃t on x ̃t, provided we divide the estimated intercept by (1 􏱦 􏰴). The OLS estimators from (12.28) are not quite BLUE because they do not use the first time period. This is easily fixed by writing the equation for t 􏱪 1 as y1 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 u1. [12.30] Since each et is uncorrelated with u1, we can add (12.30) to (12.28) and still have serially un- correlated errors. However, using (12.27), Var(u1) 􏱪 􏱧2e /(1 􏱦 􏰴2) 􏱰 􏱧2e 􏱪 Var(et). [Equation (12.27) clearly does not hold when 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱸 1, which is why we assume the stability condition.] Thus, we must multiply (12.30) by (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2 to get errors with the same variance: or (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2y1 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1(1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2x1 􏱕 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2u1 y ̃1 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x ̃1 􏱕 u ̃1, [12.31] where u ̃1 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2u1, y ̃1 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2y1, and so on. The error in (12.31) has variance Var(u ̃1) 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)Var(u1) 􏱪 􏱧2e, so we can use (12.31) along with (12.28) in an OLS re- gression. This gives the BLUE estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 under Assumptions TS.1 through TS.4 and the AR(1) model for ut. This is another example of a generalized least squares (or GLS) estimator. We saw other GLS estimators in the context of heteroskedasticity in Chapter 8. Adding more regressors changes very little. For t 􏱸 2, we use the equation y ̃t 􏱪(1􏱦􏰴)􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x ̃t1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kx ̃tk 􏱕et, [12.32] where x ̃tj 􏱪 xtj 􏱦 􏰴xt􏱦1, j. For t 􏱪 1, we have y ̃1 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2y1, x ̃1j 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2x1j, and the intercept is (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2􏱬0. For given 􏰴, it is fairly easy to transform the data and to carry out OLS. Unless 􏰴 􏱪 0, the GLS estimator, that is, OLS on the transformed data, will generally be different from the original OLS estimator. The GLS estimator turns out to be BLUE, and, since the errors in the transformed equation are serially uncorrelated and homoskedastic, t and F statistics from the transformed equation are valid (at least asymp- totically, and exactly if the errors et are normally distributed). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 425 Feasible GLS Estimation with AR(1) Errors The problem with the GLS estimator is that 􏰴 is rarely known in practice. However, we already know how to get a consistent estimator of 􏰴: we simply regress the OLS residuals on their lagged counterparts, exactly as in equation (12.14). Next, we use this estimate, 􏰴ˆ, in place of 􏰴 to obtain the quasi-differenced variables. We then use OLS on the equation y ̃t 􏱪 􏱬0x ̃t0 􏱕 􏱬1x ̃t1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kx ̃tk 􏱕 errort, [12.33] where x ̃t0 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴ˆ) for t 􏱸 2, and x ̃10 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴ˆ2)1/2. This results in the feasible GLS (FGLS) estimator of the 􏱬j. The error term in (12.33) contains et and also the terms in- volving the estimation error in 􏰴ˆ. Fortunately, the estimation error in 􏰴ˆ does not affect the asymptotic distribution of the FGLS estimators. Feasible GLS Estimation of the AR(1) Model: (i) Run the OLS regression of yt on xt1, ..., xtk and obtain the OLS residuals, uˆt, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. (ii) Run the regression in equation (12.14) and obtain 􏰴ˆ. (iii) Apply OLS to equation (12.33) to estimate 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k. The usual standard er- rors, t statistics, and F statistics are asymptotically valid. The cost of using 􏰴ˆ in place of 􏰴 is that the feasible GLS estimator has no tractable finite sample properties. In particular, it is not unbiased, although it is consistent when the data are weakly dependent. Further, even if et in (12.32) is normally distributed, the t and F sta- tistics are only approximately t and F distributed because of the estimation error in 􏰴ˆ. This is fine for most purposes, although we must be careful with small sample sizes. Since the FGLS estimator is not unbiased, we certainly cannot say it is BLUE. Never- theless, it is asymptotically more efficient than the OLS estimator when the AR(1) model for serial correlation holds (and the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous). Again, this statement assumes that the time series are weakly dependent. There are several names for FGLS estimation of the AR(1) model that come from different methods of estimating 􏰴 and different treatment of the first observation. Cochrane-Orcutt (CO) estimation omits the first observation and uses 􏰴ˆ from (12.14), whereas Prais-Winsten (PW) estimation uses the first observation in the previously sug- gested way. Asymptotically, it makes no difference whether or not the first observation is used, but many time series samples are small, so the differences can be notable in applications. In practice, both the Cochrane-Orcutt and Prais-Winsten methods are used in an it- erative scheme. That is, once the FGLS estimator is found using 􏰴ˆ from (12.14), we can compute a new set of residuals, obtain a new estimator of 􏰴 from (12.14), transform the data using the new estimate of 􏰴, and estimate (12.33) by OLS. We can repeat the whole process many times, until the estimate of 􏰴 changes by very little from the previous itera- tion. Many regression packages implement an iterative procedure automatically, so there is no additional work for us. It is difficult to say whether more than one iteration helps. It seems to be helpful in some cases, but, theoretically, the large-sample properties of the iterated estimator are the same as the estimator that uses only the first iteration. For details on these and other methods, see Davidson and MacKinnon (1993, Chapter 10). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 426 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data EXAMPLE 12.4 PRAIS-WINSTEN ESTIMATION IN THE EVENT STUDY Again using the data in BARIUM.RAW, we estimate the equation in Example 10.5 using iter- ated Prais-Winsten estimation. For comparison, we also present the OLS results in Table 12.1. The coefficients that are statistically significant in the Prais-Winsten estimation do not differ by much from the OLS estimates [in particular, the coefficients on log(chempi), log(rtwex), and afdec6]. It is not surprising for statistically insignificant coefficients to change, perhaps markedly, across different estimation methods. Notice how the standard errors in the second column are uniformly higher than the standard errors in column (1). This is common. The Prais-Winsten standard errors account for serial correlation; the OLS standard errors do not. As we saw in Section 12.1, the OLS standard errors usually understate the actual sampling variation in the OLS estimates and should not be relied upon when significant serial correlation is present. Therefore, the ef- fect on Chinese imports after the International Trade Commission’s decision is now less statistically significant than we thought (tafdec6 􏱪 􏱦1.69). Finally, an R-squared is reported for the PW estimation that is well below the R-squared for the OLS estimation in this case. However, these R-squareds should not be compared. For OLS, the R-squared, as usual, is based on the regression with the untrans- formed dependent and independent variables. For PW, the R-squared comes from the final regression of the transformed dependent variable on the transformed independent vari- ables. It is not clear what this R2 is actually measuring; nevertheless, it is traditionally reported. T A B L E 1 2 . 1 Dependent Variable: log(chnimp) Coefficient OLS Prais-Winsten log(chempi) 3.12 (0.48) 2.94 (0.63) log(gas) .196 (.907) 1.05 (0.98) log(rtwex) .983 (.400) 1.13 (0.51) befile6 .060 (.261) 􏱦.016 (.322) affile6 􏱦.032 (.264) 􏱦.033 (.322) afdec6 􏱦.565 (.286) 􏱦.577 (.342) intercept 􏱦17.80 (21.05) 􏱦37.08 (22.78) 􏰴ˆ ——— .293 Observations R-squared 131 .305 131 .202 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 427 Comparing OLS and FGLS In some applications of the Cochrane-Orcutt or Prais-Winsten methods, the FGLS esti- mates differ in practically important ways from the OLS estimates. (This was not the case in Example 12.4.) Typically, this has been interpreted as a verification of feasible GLS’s superiority over OLS. Unfortunately, things are not so simple. To see why, consider the regression model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt 􏱕ut, where the time series processes are stationary. Now, assuming that the law of large num- bers holds, consistency of OLS for 􏱬1 holds if Cov(xt, ut) 􏱪 0. [12.34] Earlier, we asserted that FGLS was consistent under the strict exogeneity assumption, which is more restrictive than (12.34). In fact, it can be shown that the weakest assump- tion that must hold for FGLS to be consistent, in addition to (12.34), is that the sum of xt􏱦1 and xt􏱕1 is uncorrelated with ut: Cov[(xt􏱦1 􏱕 xt􏱕1), ut] 􏱪 0. [12.35] Practically speaking, consistency of FGLS requires ut to be uncorrelated with xt􏱦1, xt, and xt􏱕1. How can we show that condition (12.35) is needed along with (12.34)? The argument is simple if we assume 􏰴 is known and drop the first time period, as in Cochrane-Orcutt. The argument when we use 􏰴ˆ is technically harder and yields no additional insights. Since one observation cannot affect the asymptotic properties of an estimator, dropping it does not affect the argument. Now, with known 􏰴, the GLS estimator uses xt 􏱦 􏰴xt􏱦1 as the re- gressor in an equation where ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1 is the error. From Theorem 11.1, we know the key condition for consistency of OLS is that the error and the regressor are uncorrelated. In this case, we need E[(xt 􏱦 􏰴xt􏱦1)(ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1)] 􏱪 0. If we expand the expectation, we get E[(xt 􏱦 􏰴xt􏱦1)(ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1)] 􏱪 E(xtut) 􏱦 􏰴E(xt􏱦1ut) 􏱦 􏰴E(xtut􏱦1) 􏱕 􏰴2E(xt􏱦1ut􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱦􏰴[E(xt􏱦1ut) 􏱕 E(xtut􏱦1)] because E(xtut) 􏱪 E(xt􏱦1ut􏱦1) 􏱪 0 by assumption (12.34). Now, under stationarity, E(xtut􏱦1) 􏱪 E(xt􏱕1ut) because we are just shifting the time index one period forward. Therefore, E(xt􏱦1ut) 􏱕 E(xtut􏱦1) 􏱪 E[(xt􏱦1 􏱕 xt􏱕1)ut], and the last expectation is the covariance in equation (12.35) because E(ut) 􏱪 0. We have shown that (12.35) is necessary along with (12.34) for GLS to be consistent for 􏱬1. [Of course, if 􏰴 􏱪 0, we do not need (12.35) because we are back to doing OLS.] Our derivation shows that OLS and FGLS might give significantly different estimates because (12.35) fails. In this case, OLS—which is still consistent under (12.34)—is pre- ferred to FGLS (which is inconsistent). If x has a lagged effect on y, or xt􏱕1 reacts to changes in ut, FGLS can produce misleading results. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 428 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data Because OLS and FGLS are different estimation procedures, we never expect them to give the same estimates. If they provide similar estimates of the 􏱬j, then FGLS is pre- ferred if there is evidence of serial correlation, because the estimator is more efficient and the FGLS test statistics are at least asymptotically valid. A more difficult problem arises when there are practical differences in the OLS and FGLS estimates: it is hard to deter- mine whether such differences are statistically significant. The general method proposed by Hausman (1978) can be used, but it is beyond the scope of this text. The next example gives a case where OLS and FGLS are different in practically important ways. EXAMPLE 12.5 STATIC PHILLIPS CURVE Table 12.2 presents OLS and iterated Prais-Winsten estimates of the static Phillips curve from Example 10.1, using the observations through 1996. TABLE 12.2 Dependent Variable: inf Coefficient OLS Prais-Winsten unem .468 (.289) 􏱦.716 (.313) intercept 1.424 (1.719) 8.296 (2.231) 􏰴ˆ ——— .781 Observations R-squared 49 .053 49 .136 The coefficient of interest is on unem, and it differs markedly between PW and OLS. Because the PW estimate is consistent with the inflation-unemployment tradeoff, our ten- dency is to focus on the PW estimates. In fact, these estimates are fairly close to what is obtained by first differencing both inf and unem (see Computer Exercise C4 in Chapter 11), which makes sense because the quasi-differencing used in PW with 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .781 is similar to first differencing. It may just be that inf and unem are not related in levels, but they have a negative relationship in first differences. Examples like the static Phillips curve can pose difficult problems for empiri- cal researchers. On the one hand, if we are truly interested in a static relationship, and if unemployment and inflation are I(0) processes, then OLS produces consistent estima- tors without additional assumptions. But it could be that unemployment, inflation, or both have unit roots, in which case OLS need not have its usual desirable properties; we dis- cuss this further in Chapter 18. In Example 12.5, FGLS gives more economically sensible estimates; because it is similar to first differencing, FGLS has the advantage of (approxi- mately) eliminating unit roots. Correcting for Higher Order Serial Correlation It is also possible to correct for higher orders of serial correlation. A general treatment is given in Harvey (1990). Here, we illustrate the approach for AR(2) serial correlation: ut 􏱪 􏰴1ut􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴2ut􏱦2 􏱕 et, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 429 where {et} satisfies the assumptions stated for the AR(1) model. The stability conditions are more complicated now. They can be shown to be [see Harvey (1990)] 􏰴2 􏱰 􏱦1, 􏰴2 􏱦 􏰴1 􏱷 1, and 􏰴1 􏱕 􏰴2 􏱷 1. For example, the model is stable if 􏰴1 􏱪 .8 and 􏰴2 􏱪 􏱦.3; the model is unstable if 􏰴1 􏱪 .7 and 􏰴2 􏱪 .4. Assuming the stability conditions hold, we can obtain the transformation that elimi- nates the serial correlation. In the simple regression model, this is easy when t 􏱰 2: or yt 􏱦 􏰴1yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏰴2yt􏱦2 􏱪 􏱬0(1􏱦 􏰴1 􏱦 􏰴2) 􏱕 􏱬1(xt 􏱦 􏰴1xt􏱦1 􏱦 􏰴2xt􏱦2) 􏱕 et y ̃t 􏱪 􏱬0(1 􏱦 􏰴1 􏱦 􏰴2) 􏱕 􏱬1x ̃t 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 3, 4, ..., n. [12.36] If we know 􏰴1 and 􏰴2, we can easily estimate this equation by OLS after obtaining the transformed variables. Since we rarely know 􏰴1 and 􏰴2, we have to estimate them. As usual, we can use the OLS residuals, uˆt: obtain 􏰴ˆ1 and 􏰴ˆ2 from the regression of uˆt on uˆt􏱦1, uˆt􏱦2, t 􏱪 3, ..., n. [This is the same regression used to test for AR(2) serial correlation with strictly exog- enous regressors.] Then, we use 􏰴ˆ1 and 􏰴ˆ2 in place of 􏰴1 and 􏰴2 to obtain the transformed variables. This gives one version of the feasible GLS estimator. If we have multiple explanatory variables, then each one is transformed by x ̃tj 􏱪 xtj 􏱦 􏰴ˆ1xt􏱦1,j 􏱦 􏰴ˆ2xt􏱦2,j, when t 􏱰 2. The treatment of the first two observations is a little tricky. It can be shown that the dependent variable and each independent variable (including the intercept) should be transformed by z ̃1 􏱪 {(1 􏱕 􏰴2)[(1 􏱦 􏰴2)2 􏱦 􏰴21]/(1 􏱦 􏰴2)}1/2z1 z ̃2 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴2)1/2z2 􏱦 [􏰴1(1 􏱦 􏰴21)1/2/(1 􏱦 􏰴2)]z1, where z1 and z2 denote either the dependent or an independent variable at t 􏱪 1 and t 􏱪 2, respectively. We will not derive these transformations. Briefly, they eliminate the serial correlation between the first two observations and make their error variances equal to 􏱧e2. Fortunately, econometrics packages geared toward time series analysis easily esti- mate models with general AR(q) errors; we rarely need to directly compute the trans- formed variables ourselves. 12.4 Differencing and Serial Correlation In Chapter 11, we presented differencing as a transformation for making an integrated process weakly dependent. There is another way to see the merits of differencing when dealing with highly persistent data. Suppose that we start with the simple regression model: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt 􏱕 ut, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [12.37] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 430 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data where ut follows the AR(1) process in (12.26). As we mentioned in Section 11.3, and as we will discuss more fully in Chapter 18, the usual OLS inference procedures can be very misleading when the variables yt and xt are integrated of order one, or I(1). In the extreme case where the errors {ut} in (12.37) follow a random walk, the equation makes no sense because, among other things, the variance of ut grows with t. It is more logical to differ- ence the equation: ∆yt 􏱪 􏱬1∆xt 􏱕 ∆ut, t 􏱪 2, ..., n. [12.38] If ut follows a random walk, then et 􏱲 ∆ut has zero mean and a constant variance and is serially uncorrelated. Thus, assuming that et and ∆xt are uncorrelated, we can estimate (12.38) by OLS, where we lose the first observation. Even if ut does not follow a random walk, but 􏰴 is positive and large, first differencing is often a good idea: it will eliminate most of the serial correlation. Of course, equation (12.38) is different from (12.37), but at least we can have more faith in the OLS stan- dard errors and t statistics in (12.38). Allowing for multiple explanatory variables does not change anything. EXAMPLE 12.6 DIFFERENCING THE INTEREST RATE EQUATION In Example 10.2, we estimated an equation relating the three-month T-bill rate to inflation and the federal deficit [see equation (10.15)]. If we obtain the residuals obtained from esti- mating (10.15) and regress them on a single lag, we obtain 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .623 (.110), which is large and very statistically significant. Therefore, at a minimum, serial correlation is a problem in this equation. If we difference the data and run the regression, we obtain ∆i3t 􏱪 .042 􏱕 .149 ∆inft 􏱦 .181 ∆deft 􏱕 eˆt (.171) (.092) - (.148) n 􏱪 55, R2 􏱪 .176, R2 􏱪 .145 [12.39] The coefficients from this regression are very different from the equation in levels, sug- gesting either that the explanatory variables are not strictly exogenous or that one or more of the variables has a unit root. In fact, the correlation between i3t and i3t−1 is about .885, which may indicate a problem with interpreting (10.15) as a meaningful regression. Plus, the regression in differences has essentially no serial correlation: a regression of eˆt on eˆt−1 gives 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .072 (.134). Because first differencing eliminates possible unit roots as well as serial correlation, we probably have more faith in the estimates and standard errors from (12.39) than (10.15). The equation in differences shows that annual changes in interest rates are only weakly, positively related to annual changes in inflation, and the coefficient on ∆deft is actually negative (though not statistically significant at even the 20% signifi- cance level against a two-sided alternative). As we explained in Chapter 11, the decision of whether or not to difference is a tough one. But this discussion points out another benefit of differencing, which is that it removes serial correlation. We will come back to this issue in Chapter 18. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 12.4 Suppose after estimating a model by OLS that you estimate 􏰴 from regression (12.14) and you obtain 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .92. What would you do about this? CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 431 12.5 Serial Correlation-Robust Inference after OLS In recent years, it has become more popular to estimate models by OLS but to correct the standard errors for fairly arbitrary forms of serial correlation (and heteroskedasticity). Even though we know OLS will be inefficient, there are some good reasons for taking this approach. First, the explanatory variables may not be strictly exogenous. In this case, FGLS is not even consistent, let alone efficient. Second, in most applications of FGLS, the errors are assumed to follow an AR(1) model. It may be better to compute standard errors for the OLS estimates that are robust to more general forms of serial correlation. To get the idea, consider equation (12.4), which is the variance of the OLS slope esti- mator in a simple regression model with AR(1) errors. We can estimate this variance very simply by plugging in our standard estimators of 􏰴 and 􏱧2. The only problems with this are that it assumes the AR(1) model holds and also assumes homoskedasticity. It is possible to relax both of these assumptions. A general treatment of standard errors that are both heteroskedasticity- and serial correlation–robust is given in Davidson and MacKinnon (1993). Here, we provide a sim- ple method to compute the robust standard error of any OLS coefficient. Our treatment here follows Wooldridge (1989). Consider the standard multiple linear regression model yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxtk 􏱕 ut, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, [12.40] which we have estimated by OLS. For concreteness, we are interested in obtaining a serial correlation–robust standard error for 􏱬ˆ1. This turns out to be fairly easy. Write xt1 as a linear function of the remaining independent variables and an error term, xt1 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛2xt2 􏱕...􏱕􏱛kxtk 􏱕rt, where the error rt has zero mean and is uncorrelated with xt2, xt3, ..., xtk. ˆ Then, it can be shown that the asymptotic variance of the OLS estimator 􏱬1 is ˆ ∑n 􏱦2 ∑n Avar(􏱬1) 􏱪 􏱵 E(r2t )􏱷 Var 􏱵 rtut􏱷. Under the no serial correlation Assumption TS.5􏲃, {at 􏱲 rtut} is serially uncorrelated, so either the usual OLS standard errors (under homoskedasticity) or the heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors will be valid. But if TS.5􏲃 fails, our expression for Avar(􏱬ˆ1) must account for the correlation between at and as, when t 􏱻 s. In practice, it is common to as- sume that, once the terms are farther apart than a few periods, the correlation is essentially zero. Remember that under weak dependence, the correlation must be approaching zero, so this is a reasonable approach. Following the general framework of Newey and West (1987), Wooldridge (1989) shows that Avar(􏱬ˆ1) can be estimated as follows. Let “se(􏱬ˆ1)” denote the usual (but incor- rect) OLS standard error and let 􏱧ˆ be the usual standard error of the regression (or root mean squared error) from estimating (12.40) by OLS. Let rˆt denote the residuals from the auxiliary regression of xt1 on xt2, xt3, ..., xtk [12.41] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. t􏱪1 t􏱪1 432 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data (including a constant, as usual). For a chosen integer g 􏱰 0, define where and when g 􏱪 2, vˆ􏱪 ∑∑ t􏱪h􏱕1 [12.42] ∑ng n aˆ2 􏱕2 [1􏱦h/(g􏱕1)]􏱵 aˆaˆ 􏱷, t t􏱪1 h􏱪1 t t􏱦h aˆt 􏱪 rˆt uˆt, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. This looks somewhat complicated, but in practice it is easy to obtain. The integer g in (12.42) controls how much serial correlation we are allowing in computing the standard error. Once we have vˆ, the serial correlation–robust standard error of 􏱬ˆ1 is simply ˆˆ_ se(􏱬1) 􏱪 [“se(􏱬1)”/􏱧ˆ]2􏱯vˆ. [12.43] In other words, we take the usual OLS standard error of 􏱬ˆ 1, divide it by 􏱧ˆ , square the result, and then multiply by the square root of vˆ. This can be used to construct confidence intervals and t statistics for 􏱬ˆ1. It is useful to see what vˆ looks like in some simple cases. When g 􏱪 1, vˆ 􏱪 ∑n t􏱪1 aˆ2 􏱕 t ∑n t􏱪2 aˆ aˆ , t t􏱦1 [12.44] [12.45] n n ∑n vˆ􏱪∑aˆ2t 􏱕(4/3)􏱵∑aˆaˆ 􏱷􏱕(2/3) 􏱵 aˆaˆ 􏱷. t t􏱦1 t􏱪1 t􏱪2 t􏱪3 t t􏱦2 The larger that g is, the more terms are included to correct for serial correlation. The purpose of the factor [1 􏱦 h/(g 􏱕 1)] in (12.42) is to ensure that vˆ is in fact nonnegative [Newey and West (1987) verify this]. We clearly need vˆ 􏱸 0, since vˆ is estimating a vari- ance and the square root of vˆ appears in (12.43). The standard error in (12.43) is also robust to arbitrary heteroskedasticity. (In the time series literature, the serial correlation–robust standard errors are sometimes called heteroskedasticity and autocorrelation consistent, or HAC, standard errors.) In fact, if we drop the second term in (12.42), then (12.43) becomes the usual heteroskedasticity-robust standard error that we discussed in Chapter 8 (without the degrees of freedom adjustment). The theory underlying the standard error in (12.43) is technical and somewhat subtle. Remember, we started off by claiming we do not know the form of serial correlation. If this is the case, how can we select the integer g? Theory states that (12.43) works for fairly arbitrary forms of serial correlation, provided g grows with sample size n. The idea is that, with larger sample sizes, we can be more flexible about the amount of correlation in (12.42). There has been much recent work on the relationship between g and n, but we will not go into that here. For annual data, choosing a small g, such as g 􏱪 1 or g 􏱪 2, is likely to account for most of the serial correlation. For quarterly or monthly data, g should probably be larger (such as g 􏱪 4 or 8 for quarterly and g 􏱪 12 or 24 for monthly), assuming that we have enough data. Newey and West (1987) recommend tak- ing g to be the integer part of 4(n/100)2/9; others have suggested the integer part of n1/4. The Newey-West suggestion is implemented by the econometrics program Eviews®. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 433 For, say, n 􏱪 50 (which is reasonable for annual, postwar data from World War II), g 􏱪 3. (The integer part of n1/4 gives g 􏱪 2.) ˆ We summarize how to obtain a serial correlation–robust standard error for 􏱬1. Of course, since we can list any independent variable first, the following procedure works for computing a standard error for any slope coefficient. Serial Correlation–Robust Standard Error for 􏱬ˆ1: (i) Estimate (12.40) by OLS, which yields “se(ˆ􏱬1)”, ˆ􏱧, and the OLS residuals {uˆt: t 􏱪 1, ..., n}. (ii) Compute the residuals {rˆt: t 􏱪 1, ..., n} from the auxiliary regression (12.41). Then, form aˆt 􏱪 rˆt uˆt (for each t). (iii) For your choice of g, compute vˆ as in (12.42). (iv) Compute se(􏱬ˆ1) from (12.43). Empirically, the serial correlation–robust standard errors are typically larger than the usual OLS standard errors when there is serial correlation. This is true because, in most cases, the errors are positively serially correlated. However, it is possible to have substan- tial serial correlation in {ut} but to also have similarities in the usual and serial correlation– robust (SC-robust) standard errors of some coefficients: it is the sample autocorrelations of aˆt 􏱪 rˆtuˆt that determine the robust standard error for 􏱬ˆ1. The use of SC-robust standard errors has lagged behind the use of standard errors robust only to heteroskedasticity for several reasons. First, large cross sections, where the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors will have good properties, are more common than large time series. The SC-robust standard errors can be poorly behaved when there is substantial serial correlation and the sample size is small (where small can even be as large as, say, 100). Second, since we must choose the integer g in equation (12.42), computation of the SC-robust standard errors is not automatic. As mentioned earlier, some economet- rics packages have automated the selection, but you still have to abide by the choice. Another important reason that SC-robust standard errors are not yet routinely computed is that, in the presence of severe serial correlation, OLS can be very inefficient, especially in small sample sizes. After performing OLS and correcting the standard errors for serial correlation, we find the coefficients are often insignificant, or at least less significant than they were with the usual OLS standard errors. If we are confident that the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous, yet are skep- tical about the errors following an AR(1) process, we can still get estimators more efficient than OLS by using a standard feasible GLS estimator, such as Prais-Winsten or Cochrane- Orcutt. With substantial serial correlation, the quasi-differencing transformation used by PW and CO is likely to be better than doing nothing and just using OLS. But, if the errors do not follow an AR(1) model, then the standard errors reported from PW or CO esti- mation will be incorrect. Nevertheless, we can manually quasi-difference the data after estimating 􏰴, use pooled OLS on the transformed data, and then use SC-robust standard errors in the transformed equation. Computing an SC-robust standard error after quasi- differencing would ensure that any extra serial correlation is accounted for in statistical inference. In fact, the SC-robust standard errors probably work better after much serial cor- relation has been eliminated using quasi-differencing [or some other transformation, such as that used for AR(2) serial correlation]. Such an approach is analogous to using weighted least squares in the presence of heteroskedasticity but then computing standard errors that are robust to having the variance function incorrectly specified; see Section 8.4. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 434 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data The SC-robust standard errors after OLS estimation are most useful when we have doubts about some of the explanatory variables being strictly exogenous, so that methods such as Prais-Winsten and Cochrane-Orcutt are not even consistent. It is also valid to use the SC-robust standard errors in models with lagged dependent variables, assuming, of course, that there is good reason for allowing serial correlation in such models. EXAMPLE 12.7 THE PUERTO RICAN MINIMUM WAGE We obtain an SC-robust standard error for the minimum wage effect in the Puerto Rican employment equation. In Example 12.2, we found pretty strong evidence of AR(1) serial correlation. As in that example, we use as additional controls log(usgnp), log(prgnp), and a linear time trend. The OLS estimate of the elasticity of the employment rate with respect to the mini- mum wage is 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏱦.2123, and the usual OLS standard error is “se(􏱬ˆ1)” 􏱪 .0402. The standard error of the regression is 􏱧ˆ 􏱪 .0328. Further, using the previous procedure with g 􏱪 2 [see (12.45)], we obtain vˆ 􏱪 .000805. This gives the SC/heteroskedasticity-robust ˆ 2 _______ standard error as se(􏱬1) 􏱪 [(.0402/.0328) ] 􏱯 .000805 􏱴 .0426. Interestingly, the robust standard error is only slightly greater than the usual OLS standard error. The robust t statistic is about 􏱦4.98, and so the estimated elasticity is still very statistically significant. For comparison, the iterated PW estimate of 􏱬1 is 􏱦.1477, with a standard error of .0458. Thus, the FGLS estimate is closer to zero than the OLS estimate, and we might sus- pect violation of the strict exogeneity assumption. Or, the difference in the OLS and FGLS estimates might be explainable by sampling error. It is very difficult to tell. Kiefer and Vogelsang (2005) provide a different way to obtain valid inference in the presence of arbitrary serial correlation. Rather than worry about the rate at which g is allowed to grow (as a function of n) in order for the t statistics to have asymptotic standard normal distributions, Kiefer and Vogelsang derive the large-sample distribution of the t statistic when b 􏱪 (g 􏱕 1)/n is allowed to settle down to a nonzero fraction. [In the Newey-West setup, (g 􏱕 1)/n always converges to zero.] For example, when b 􏱪 1, g 􏱪 n 􏱦 1, which means that we include every covariance term in equation (12.42). The resulting t statistic does not have a large-sample standard normal distribution, but Kiefer and Vogelsang show that it does have an asymptotic distribution, and they tabulate the ap- propriate critical values. For a two-sided, 5% level test, the critical value is 4.771, and for a two-sided 10% level test, the critical value is 3.764. Compared with the critical values from the standard normal distribution, we need a t statistic substantially larger. But we do not have to worry about choosing the number of covariances in (12.42). Before leaving this section, we note that it is possible to construct serial correlation– robust, F-type statistics for testing multiple hypotheses, but these are too advanced to cover here. [See Wooldridge (1991b, 1995) and Davidson and MacKinnon (1993) for treatments.] 12.6 Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions We discussed testing and correcting for heteroskedasticity for cross-sectional applica- tions in Chapter 8. Heteroskedasticity can also occur in time series regression models, and the presence of heteroskedasticity, while not causing bias or inconsistency in the 􏱬ˆj, does Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 435 invalidate the usual standard errors, t statistics, and F statistics. This is just as in the cross- sectional case. In time series regression applications, heteroskedasticity often receives little, if any, attention: the problem of serially correlated errors is usually more pressing. Nevertheless, it is useful to briefly cover some of the issues that arise in applying tests and corrections for heteroskedasticity in time series regressions. Because the usual OLS statistics are asymptotically valid under Assumptions TS.1􏲃 through TS.5􏲃, we are interested in what happens when the homoskedasticity assumption, TS.4􏲃, does not hold. Assumption TS.3􏲃 rules out misspecifications such as omitted vari- ables and certain kinds of measurement error, while TS.5􏲃 rules out serial correlation in the errors. It is important to remember that serially correlated errors cause problems that adjustments for heteroskedasticity are not able to address. Heteroskedasticity-Robust Statistics In studying heteroskedasticity for cross-sectional regressions, we noted how it has no bearing on the unbiasedness or consistency of the OLS estimators. Exactly the same con- clusions hold in the time series case, as we can see by reviewing the assumptions needed for unbiasedness (Theorem 10.1) and consistency (Theorem 11.1). In Section 8.2, we discussed how the usual OLS standard errors, t statistics, and F statistics can be adjusted to allow for the presence of heteroskedasticity of unknown form. These same adjustments work for time series regressions under Assumptions TS.1􏲃, TS.2􏲃, TS.3􏲃, and TS.5􏲃. Thus, provided the only assumption violated is the homoskedasticity assumption, valid inference is easily obtained in most econometric packages. Testing for Heteroskedasticity Sometimes, we wish to test for heteroskedasticity in time series regressions, especially if we are concerned about the performance of heteroskedasticity-robust statistics in rela- tively small sample sizes. The tests we covered in Chapter 8 can be applied directly, but with a few caveats. First, the errors ut should not be serially correlated; any serial correla- tion will generally invalidate a test for heteroskedasticity. Thus, it makes sense to test for serial correlation first, using a heteroskedasticity-robust test if heteroskedasticity is sus- pected. Then, after something has been done to correct for serial correlation, we can test for heteroskedasticity. Second, consider the equation used to motivate the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity: u2t 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱛kxtk 􏱕vt, [12.46] where the null hypothesis is H0: 􏱛1 􏱪 􏱛2 􏱪 ... 􏱪 􏱛k 􏱪 0. For the F statistic—with û2t replacing u2t as the dependent variable—to be valid, we must assume that the errors {vt} are themselves homoskedastic (as in the cross-sectional case) and serially uncorrelated. These are implicitly assumed in computing all standard tests for heteroske- dasticity, including the version of the White test we cov- ered in Section 8.3. Assuming that the {vt} are serially Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 12.5 How would you compute the White test for heteroskedasticity in equation (12.47)? 436 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data uncorrelated rules out certain forms of dynamic heteroskedasticity, something we will treat in the next subsection. If heteroskedasticity is found in the ut (and the ut are not serially correlated), then the heteroskedasticity-robust test statistics can be used. An alternative is to use weighted least squares, as in Section 8.4. The mechanics of weighted least squares for the time series case are identical to those for the cross-sectional case. EXAMPLE 12.8 HETEROSKEDASTICITY AND THE EFFICIENT MARKETS HYPOTHESIS In Example 11.4, we estimated the simple model returnt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1returnt􏱦1 􏱕 ut. [12.47] The EMH states that 􏱬1 􏱪 0. When we tested this hypothesis using the data in NYSE. RAW, we obtained t􏱬1 􏱪 1.55 with n 􏱪 689. With such a large sample, this is not much evidence against the EMH. Although the EMH states that the expected return given past observable information should be constant, it says nothing about the conditional variance. In fact, the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity entails regressing the squared OLS residualsuˆ2t onreturnt􏱦1: uˆ2t 􏱪 4.66 􏱦 1.104 returnt􏱦1 􏱕 residualt (0.43) (0.201) [12.48] n 􏱪 689, R2 􏱪 .042. The t statistic on returnt􏱦1 is about 􏱦5.5, indicating strong evidence of heteroskedastic- ity. Because the coefficient on returnt􏱦1 is negative, we have the interesting finding that volatility in stock returns is lower when the previous return was high, and vice versa. Therefore, we have found what is common in many financial studies: the expected value of stock returns does not depend on past returns, but the variance of returns does. Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity In recent years, economists have become interested in dynamic forms of heteroskedastic- ity. Of course, if xt contains a lagged dependent variable, then heteroskedasticity as in (12.46) is dynamic. But dynamic forms of heteroskedasticity can appear even in models with no dynamics in the regression equation. To see this, consider a simple static regression model: yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1zt 􏱕ut, and assume that the Gauss-Markov assumptions hold. This means that the OLS estima- tors are BLUE. The homoskedasticity assumption says that Var(ut􏰫Z) is constant, where Z denotes all n outcomes of zt. Even if the variance of ut given Z is constant, there are other ways that heteroskedasticity can arise. Engle (1982) suggested looking at the con- ditional variance of ut given past errors (where the conditioning on Z is left implicit). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 437 Engle suggested what is known as the autoregressive conditional heteroskedasticity (ARCH) model. The first order ARCH model is E(u2t 􏰫ut􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 E(u2t 􏰫ut􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1u2t 􏱦1, [12.49] where we leave the conditioning on Z implicit. This equation represents the conditional variance of ut given past ut only if E(ut􏰫ut􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0, which means that the errors are serially uncorrelated. Since conditional variances must be positive, this model only makes sense if 􏱮0 􏱰 0 and 􏱮1 􏱸 0; if 􏱮1 􏱪 0, there are no dynamics in the variance equation. It is instructive to write (12.49) as u2t 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1u2t 􏱦1 􏱕 vt, [12.50] where the expected value of vt (given ut􏱦1, ut􏱦2, ...) is zero by definition. (However, the vt are not independent of past ut because of the constraint vt 􏱸 􏱦􏱮0 􏱦 􏱮1ut2􏱦1.) Equation (12.50) looks like an autoregressive model in ut2 (hence the name ARCH). The stability condition for this equation is 􏱮1 􏱷 1, just as in the usual AR(1) model. When 􏱮1 􏱰 0, the squared errors contain (positive) serial correlation even though the ut themselves do not. What implications does (12.50) have for OLS? Because we began by assuming the Gauss-Markov assumptions hold, OLS is BLUE. Further, even if ut is not normally dis- tributed, we know that the usual OLS test statistics are asymptotically valid under As- sumptions TS.1􏲃 through TS.5􏲃, which are satisfied by static and distributed lag models with ARCH errors. If OLS still has desirable properties under ARCH, why should we care about ARCH forms of heteroskedasticity in static and distributed lag models? We should be concerned for two reasons. First, it is possible to get consistent (but not unbiased) estimators of the 􏱬j that are asymptotically more efficient than the OLS estimators. A weighted least squares procedure, based on estimating (12.50), will do the trick. A maximum likelihood proce- dure also works under the assumption that the errors ut have a conditional normal distri- bution. Second, economists in various fields have become interested in dynamics in the conditional variance. Engle’s original application was to the variance of United Kingdom inflation, where he found that a larger magnitude of the error in the previous time period (larger u2t􏱦1) was associated with a larger error variance in the current period. Since vari- ance is often used to measure volatility, and volatility is a key element in asset pricing theories, ARCH models have become important in empirical finance. ARCH models also apply when there are dynamics in the conditional mean. Suppose we have the dependent variable, yt, a contemporaneous exogenous variable, zt, and E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt 􏱕 􏱬2yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬3zt􏱦1, so that at most one lag of y and z appears in the dynamic regression. The typical approach is to assume that Var(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) is constant, as we discussed in Chapter 11. But this variance could follow an ARCH model: Var(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 Var(ut􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1u2t􏱦1, where ut 􏱪 yt 􏱦 E(yt􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...). As we know from Chapter 11, the presence of ARCH does not affect consistency of OLS, and the usual heteroskedasticity-robust Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 438 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data standard errors and test statistics are valid. (Remember, these are valid for any form of heteroskedasticity, and ARCH is just one particular form of heteroskedasticity.) If you are interested in the ARCH model and its extensions, see Bollerslev, Chou, and Kroner (1992) and Bollerslev, Engle, and Nelson (1994) for recent surveys. EXAMPLE 12.9 ARCH IN STOCK RETURNS In Example 12.8, we saw that there was heteroskedasticity in weekly stock returns. This heteroskedasticity is actually better characterized by the ARCH model in (12.50). If we compute the OLS residuals from (12.47), square these, and regress them on the lagged squared residual, we obtain uˆ2t 􏱪2.95􏱕.337uˆ2t􏱦1􏱕residualt (.44) (.036) n 􏱪 688, R2 􏱪 .114. [12.51] The t statistic on uˆ2t􏱦1 is over nine, indicating strong ARCH. As we discussed earlier, a larger error at time t 􏱦 1 implies a larger variance in stock returns today. It is important to see that, though the squared OLS residuals are autocorrelated, the OLS residuals themselves are not (as is consistent with the EMH). Regressing uˆt on uˆt􏱦1 gives 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .0014 with t􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .038. Heteroskedasticity and Serial Correlation in Regression Models Nothing rules out the possibility of both heteroskedasticity and serial correlation being present in a regression model. If we are unsure, we can always use OLS and compute fully robust standard errors, as described in Section 12.5. Much of the time serial correlation is viewed as the most important problem, because it usually has a larger impact on standard errors and the efficiency of estimators than does heteroskedasticity. As we concluded in Section 12.2, obtaining tests for serial correlation that are robust to arbitrary heteroskedasticity is fairly straightforward. If we detect se- rial correlation using such a test, we can employ the Cochrane-Orcutt (or Prais-Winsten) transformation [see equation (12.32)] and, in the transformed equation, use heteroskedas- ticity-robust standard errors and test statistics. Or, we can even test for heteroskedasticity in (12.32) using the Breusch-Pagan or White tests. Alternatively, we can model heteroskedasticity and serial correlation and correct for both through a combined weighted least squares AR(1) procedure. Specifically, consider the model yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut __ ut 􏱪 􏱯htvt [12.52] vt 􏱪􏰴vt􏱦1 􏱕et,􏰫􏰴􏰫􏱷1, where the explanatory variables X are independent of et for all t, and ht is a function of the xtj. The process {et} has zero mean and constant variance 􏱧2e and is serially uncorrelated. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 439 Therefore, {vt} satisfies a stable AR(1) process. The error ut is heteroskedastic, in addition to containing serial correlation: 222 __ __ __ __ __ yt/􏱯ht 􏱪 􏱬0(1/􏱯ht) 􏱕 􏱬1(xt1/􏱯ht) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k(xtk/􏱯ht) 􏱕 vt [12.53] has AR(1) errors. Now, if we have a particular kind of heteroskedasticity in mind—that is, we know ht—we can estimate (12.52) using standard CO or PW methods. In most cases, we have to estimate ht first. The following method combines the weighted least squares method from Section 8.4 with the AR(1) serial correlation correc- tion from Section 12.3. Feasible GLS with Heteroskedasticity and AR(1) Serial Correlation: (i) Estimate (12.52) by OLS and save the residuals, uˆt. (ii) Regress log(uˆ2t ) on xt1, ..., xtk (or on yˆt, yˆ2t ) and obtain the fitted values, say, gˆt. (iii) Obtain the estimates of ht: hˆt 􏱪 exp(gˆt). (iv) Estimate the transformed equation hˆt􏱦1/2 yt 􏱪 hˆt􏱦1/2􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 hˆt􏱦1/2xt1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k hˆt􏱦1/2xtk 􏱕 errort [12.54] by standard Cochrane-Orcutt or Prais-Winsten methods. The feasible GLS estimators obtained from the procedure are asymptotically efficient provided the assumptions in model (12.52) hold. More importantly, all standard errors and test statistics from the CO or PW estimation are asymptotically valid. If we allow the vari- ance function to be misspecified, or allow the possibility that any serial correlation does not follow an AR(1) model, then we can apply quasi-differencing to (12.54), estimating the resulting equation by OLS, and then obtain the Newey-West standard errors. By doing so, we would be using a procedure that could be asymptotically efficient while ensuring that our inference is valid (asymptotically) if we have misspecified our model of either heteroskedasticity or serial correlation. Summary We have covered the important problem of serial correlation in the errors of multiple regres- sion models. Positive correlation between adjacent errors is common, especially in static and finite distributed lag models. This causes the usual OLS standard errors and statistics to be misleading (although the 􏱬ˆj can still be unbiased, or at least consistent). Typically, the OLS standard errors underestimate the true uncertainty in the parameter estimates. The most popular model of serial correlation is the AR(1) model. Using this as the starting point, it is easy to test for the presence of AR(1) serial correlation using the OLS residuals. An asymptotically valid t statistic is obtained by regressing the OLS residuals on the lagged resid- uals, assuming the regressors are strictly exogenous and a homoskedasticity assumption holds. Making the test robust to heteroskedasticity is simple. The Durbin-Watson statistic is available under the classical linear model assumptions, but it can lead to an inconclusive outcome, and it has little to offer over the t test. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Var(ut 􏰫xt) 􏱪 􏱧2vht, where 􏱧v 􏱪 􏱧e /(1 􏱦 􏰴 ). But vt 􏱪 ut /􏱯 h t is homoskedastic and follows a stable AR(1) model. Therefore, the transformed equation 440 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data For models with a lagged dependent variable or other nonstrictly exogenous regressors, the standard t test on uˆt􏱦1 is still valid, provided all independent variables are included as re- gressors along with uˆt􏱦1. We can use an F or an LM statistic to test for higher order serial correlation. In models with strictly exogenous regressors, we can use a feasible GLS procedure— Cochrane-Orcutt or Prais-Winsten—to correct for AR(1) serial correlation. This gives estimates that are different from the OLS estimates: the FGLS estimates are obtained from OLS on quasi-differenced variables. All of the usual test statistics from the transformed equation are asymptotically valid. Almost all regression packages have built-in features for estimating models with AR(1) errors. Another way to deal with serial correlation, especially when the strict exogeneity assump- tion might fail, is to use OLS but to compute serial correlation–robust standard errors (that are also robust to heteroskedasticity). Many regression packages follow a method suggested by Newey and West (1987); it is also possible to use standard regression packages to obtain one standard error at a time. Finally, we discussed some special features of heteroskedasticity in time series models. As in the cross-sectional case, the most important kind of heteroskedasticity is that which de- pends on the explanatory variables; this is what determines whether the usual OLS statistics are valid. The Breusch-Pagan and White tests covered in Chapter 8 can be applied directly, with the caveat that the errors should not be serially correlated. In recent years, economists— especially those who study the financial markets—have become interested in dynamic forms of heteroskedasticity. The ARCH model is the leading example. Key Terms AR(1) Serial Correlation Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (ARCH) Breusch-Godfrey Test Cochrane-Orcutt (CO) Estimation Durbin-Watson (DW) Statistic Feasible GLS (FGLS) Prais-Winsten (PW) Estimation Quasi-Differenced Data Serial Correlation–Robust Standard Error Weighted Least Squares Problems 1 WhentheerrorsinaregressionmodelhaveAR(1)serialcorrelation,whydotheOLSstan- dard errors tend to underestimate the sampling variation in the 􏱬ˆj? Is it always true that the OLS standard errors are too small? 2 Explain what is wrong with the following statement: “The Cochrane-Orcutt and Prais- Winsten methods are both used to obtain valid standard errors for the OLS estimates when there is a serial correlation.” 3 In Example 10.6, we estimated a variant on Fair’s model for predicting presidential elec- tion outcomes in the United States. (i) What argument can be made for the error term in this equation being serially uncor- related? (Hint: How often do presidential elections take place?) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 441 (ii) WhentheOLSresidualsfrom(10.23)areregressedonthelaggedresiduals,weobtain 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.068 and se(􏰴ˆ) 􏱪 .240. What do you conclude about serial correlation in the ut? (iii) Does the small sample size in this application worry you in testing for serial correlation? 4 True or false: “If the errors in a regression model contain ARCH, they must be serially correlated.” 5 (i) In the enterprise zone event study in Computer Exercise C5 in Chapter 10, a regres- sion of the OLS residuals on the lagged residuals produces 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .841 and se(􏰴ˆ) 􏱪 .053. What implications does this have for OLS? (ii) If you want to use OLS but also want to obtain a valid standard error for the EZ coef- ficient, what would you do? 6 In Example 12.8, we found evidence of heteroskedasticity in ut in equation (12.47). Thus, we compute the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors (in [􏱳]) along with the usual standard errors: 􏱾returnt 􏱪 .180 􏱕 .059 returnt􏱦1 (.081) (.038) [.085] [.069] - n 􏱪 689, R2 􏱪 .0035, R2 􏱪 .0020. What does using the heteroskedasticity-robust t statistic do to the significance of returnt􏱦1? 7 Consider a standard multiple linear regression model with time series data: yt = 􏱬0 + 􏱬1xt1 + . . . + 􏱬kxtk + ut. Assume that Assumptions TS.1, TS.2, TS.3, and TS.4 all hold. (i) Suppose we think that the errors {ut} follow an AR(1) model with parameter 􏰴 and so we apply the Prais-Winsten method. If the errors do not follow an AR(1) model– for example, suppose they follow an AR(2) model, or an MA(1) model–why will the usual Prais-Winsten standard errors be incorrect? (ii) Can you think of a way to use the Newey-West procedure, in conjunction with Prais- Winsten estimation, to obtain valid standard errors? Be very specific about the steps you would follow. [Hint: It may help to study equation (12.32) and note that, if {ut} does not follow an AR(1) process, et generally should be replaced by ut − 􏰴ut−1, where 􏰴 is the probability limit of the estimator 􏰴ˆ. Now, is the error {ut – 􏰴ut−1} seri- ally uncorrelated in general? What can you do if it is not?] (iii) Explain why your answer to part (ii) should not change if we drop Assumption TS.4. Computer Exercises C1 In Example 11.6, we estimated a finite DL model in first differences (changes): cgfrt 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏱛0cpet 􏱕 􏱛1cpet􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2cpet􏱦2 􏱕 ut. Use the data in FERTIL3.RAW to test whether there is AR(1) serial correlation in the errors. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 442 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data C2 (i) Using the data in WAGEPRC.RAW, estimate the distributed lag model from C6 (i) Are there notable changes in any t statistics? In Computer Exercise C7 in Chapter 10, you estimated a simple relationship be- tween consumption growth and growth in disposable income. Test the equation for AR(1) serial correlation (using CONSUMP.RAW). C7 (i) For Example 12.4, using the data in BARIUM.RAW, obtain the iterative Cochrane- Orcutt estimates. Problem 5 in Chapter 11. Use regression (12.14) to test for AR(1) serial correlation. (ii) Reestimate the model using iterated Cochrane-Orcutt estimation. What is your new estimate of the long-run propensity? (iii) Using iterated CO, find the standard error for the LRP. (This requires you to esti- mate a modified equation.) Determine whether the estimated LRP is statistically different from one at the 5% level. In part (i) of Computer Exercise C6 in Chapter 11, you were asked to estimate the accel- erator model for inventory investment. Test this equation for AR(1) serial correlation. C3 (i) (ii) If you find evidence of serial correlation, reestimate the equation by Cochrane- C4 (i) Orcutt and compare the results. Use NYSE.RAW to estimate equation (12.48). Let hˆt be the fitted values from this equation (the estimates of the conditional variance). How many hˆt are negative? (ii) Add return2t􏱦1 to (12.48) and again compute the fitted values, hˆt. Are any hˆt negative? (iii) Use the hˆt from part (ii) to estimate (12.47) by weighted least squares (as in Section 8.4). Compare your estimate of 􏱬1 with that in equation (11.16). Test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 and compare the outcome when OLS is used. (iv) Now, estimate (12.47) by WLS, using the estimated ARCH model in (12.51) to obtain the hˆt. Does this change your findings from part (iii)? C5 Consider the version of Fair’s model in Example 10.6. Now, rather than predicting the proportion of the two-party vote received by the Democrat, estimate a linear probability model for whether or not the Democrat wins. (i) Use the binary variable demwins in place of demvote in (10.23) and report the results in standard form. Which factors affect the probability of winning? Use the data only through 1992. (ii) How many fitted values are less than zero? How many are greater than one? (iii) Use the following prediction rule: if 􏱾demwins􏱰 .5, you predict the Democrat wins; otherwise, the Republican wins. Using this rule, determine how many of the 20 elections are correctly predicted by the model. (iv) Plug in the values of the explanatory variables for 1996. What is the predicted probability that Clinton would win the election? Clinton did win; did you get the correct prediction? (v) Use a heteroskedasticity-robust t test for AR(1) serial correlation in the errors. What do you find? (vi) Obtain the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the estimates in part (i). (ii) In Computer Exercise C7 in Chapter 11, you tested the permanent income hy- pothesis by regressing the growth in consumption on one lag. After running this regression, test for heteroskedasticity by regressing the squared residuals on gct􏱦1 and gc2t􏱦1. What do you conclude? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 443 (ii) Are the Prais-Winsten and Cochrane-Orcutt estimates similar? Did you expect them to be? C8 Use the data in TRAFFIC2.RAW for this exercise. (i) Run an OLS regression of prcfat on a linear time trend, monthly dummy variables, and the variables wkends, unem, spdlaw, and beltlaw. Test the errors for AR(1) serial correlation using the regression in equation (12.14). Does it make sense to use the test that assumes strict exogeneity of the regressors? (ii) Obtain serial correlation- and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the coefficients on spdlaw and beltlaw, using four lags in the Newey-West estimator. How does this affect the statistical significance of the two policy variables? (iii) Now, estimate the model using iterative Prais-Winsten and compare the estimates with the OLS estimates. Are there important changes in the policy variable coef- ficients or their statistical significance? C9 The file FISH.RAW contains 97 daily price and quantity observations on fish prices at the Fulton Fish Market in New York City. Use the variable log(avgprc) as the depen- dent variable. (i) Regress log(avgprc) on four daily dummy variables, with Friday as the base. Include a linear time trend. Is there evidence that price varies systematically within a week? (ii) Now, add the variables wave2 and wave3, which are measures of wave heights over the past several days. Are these variables individually significant? Describe a mechanism by which stormy seas would increase the price of fish. (iii) What happened to the time trend when wave2 and wave3 were added to the regres- sion? What must be going on? (iv) Explain why all explanatory variables in the regression are safely assumed to be strictly exogenous. (v) Test the errors for AR(1) serial correlation. (vi) Obtain the Newey-West standard errors using four lags. What happens to the t statistics on wave2 and wave3? Did you expect a bigger or smaller change compared with the usual OLS t statistics? (vii) Now, obtain the Prais-Winsten estimates for the model estimated in part (ii). Are wave2 and wave3 jointly statistically significant? C10 Use the data in PHILLIPS.RAW to answer these questions. (i) Using the entire data set, estimate the static Phillips curve equation inft 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 unemt 􏱕 ut by OLS and report the results in the usual form. (ii) Obtain the OLS residuals from part (i), ût, and obtain 􏰴 from the regression ût on ût􏱦1. (It is fine to include an intercept in this regression.) Is there strong evidence of serial correlation? (iii) Now estimate the static Phillips curve model by iterative Prais-Winsten. Compare the estimate of 􏱬1 with that obtained in Table 12.2. Is there much difference in the estimate when the later years are added? (iv) Rather than using Prais-Winsten, use iterative Cochrane-Orcutt. How similar are the final estimates of 􏰴? How similar are the PW and CO estimates of 􏱬1? C11 Use the data in NYSE.RAW to answer these questions. (i) Estimate the model in equation (12.47) and obtain the squared OLS residuals. Find the average, minimum, and maximum values of û2t over the sample. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 444 PART 2 Regression Analysis with Time Series Data (ii) Use the squared OLS residuals to estimate the following model of heteroskedasticity: Var(ut􏰫returnt􏱦1, returnt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 Var (ut􏰫returnt􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1 returnt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2 return2t􏱦1. Report the estimated coefficients, the reported standard errors, the R-squared, and the adjusted R-squared. (iii) Sketch the conditional variance as a function of the lagged return􏱦1. For what value of return􏱦1 is the variance the smallest, and what is the variance? (iv) For predicting the dynamic variance, does the model in part (ii) produce any nega- tive variance estimates? (v) Does the model in part (ii) seem to fit better or worse than the ARCH(1) model in Example 12.9? Explain. (vi) TotheARCH(1)regressioninequation(12.51),addthesecondlag,û2t􏱦2.Doesthis lag seem important? Does the ARCH(2) model fit better than the model in part (ii)? C12 Use Chapter 11. the data in INVEN.RAW for this exercise; see also Computer Exercise C6 in (i) Obtain the OLS residuals from the accelerator model ∆invent 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1∆GDPt 􏱕 ut and use the regression ût on ût􏱦1 to test for serial correlation. What is the estimate of 􏰴? How big a problem does serial correlation seem to be? (ii) Estimate the accelerator model by PW, and compare the estimate of 􏱬1 to the OLS estimate. Why do you expect them to be similar? C13 Use the data in OKUN.RAW to answer this question; see also Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 11. (i) Estimate the equation pcrgdpt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1cunemt 􏱕 ut and test the errors for AR(1) serial correlation, without assuming {cunemt: t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} is strictly exogenous. What do you conclude? (ii) Regress the squared residuals, û2t , on cunemt (this is the Breusch-Pagan test for heteroskedasticity in the simple regression case). What do you conclude?ˆ (iii) Obtain the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error for the OLS estimate 􏱬1. Is it substantially different from the usual OLS standard error? C14 Use the data in MINWAGE.RAW for this exercise, focusing on sector 232. (i) Estimate the equation gwage232t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gmwaget􏱕 􏱬2gcpii 􏱕 ut, and test the errors for AR(1) serial correlation. Does it matter whether you assume gmwaget and gcpit are strictly exogenous? What do you conclude overall? (ii) Obtain the Newey-West standard error for the OLS estimates in part (i), using a lag of 12. How do the Newey-West standard errors compare to the usual OLS standard errors? (iii) Now obtain the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for OLS, and compare them with the usual standard errors and the Newey-West standard errors. Does it appear that serial correlation or heteroskedasticity is more of a problem in this application? (iv) Use the Breusch-Pagan test in the original equation to verify that the errors exhibit strong heteroskedasticity. (v) Add lags 1 through 12 of gmwage to the equation in part (i). Obtain the p-value for the joint F test for lags 1 through 12, and compare it with the p-value for the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 12 Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity in Time Series Regressions 445 heteroskedasticity-robust test. How does adjusting for heteroskedasticity affect the significance of the lags? (vi) Obtain the p-value for the joint significance test in part (v) using the Newey-West approach. What do you conclude now? (vii) If you leave out the lags of gmwage, is the estimate of the long-run propensity much different? C15 Use the data in BARIUM.RAW to answer this question. (i) In Table 12.1 the reported standard errors for OLS are uniformly below those of the corresponding standard errors for GLS (Prais-Winsten). Explain why comparing the OLS and GLS standard erorrs is flawed. (ii) Reestimate the equation represented by the column labeled “OLS” in Table 12.1 by OLS, but now find the Newey-West standard errors using a window g = 4 (four months). How does the Newey-West standard error on lchempi compare to the usual OLS standard error? How does it compare to the P-W standard error? Make the same comparisons for the afdec6 variable. (iii) Redo part (ii) now using a window g = 12. What happens to the standard errors on lchempi and afdec6 when the window increases from 4 to 12? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. PART 3 Advanced Topics Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 447 447 We now turn to some more specialized topics that are not usually covered in a one-term, introductory course. Some of these topics require few more mathematical skills than the multiple regression analysis did in Parts 1 and 2. In Chapter 13, we show how to apply multiple regression to independently pooled cross sections. The issues raised are very similar to standard cross-sectional analysis, except that we can study how relationships change over time by including time dummy variables. We also illustrate how panel data sets can be analyzed in a regression framework. Chapter 14 covers more advanced panel data methods that are nevertheless used routinely in applied work. Chapters 15 and 16 investigate the problem of endogenous explanatory variables. In Chapter 15, we introduce the method of instrumental variables as a way of solving the omitted variable problem as well as the measurement error problem. The method of two-stage least squares is used quite often in empirical economics and is indispensable for estimating simultaneous equation models, a topic we turn to in Chapter 16. Chapter 17 covers some fairly advanced topics that are typically used in cross- sectional analysis, including models for limited dependent variables and methods for correcting sample selection bias. Chapter 18 heads in a different direction by covering some recent advances in time series econometrics that have proven to be useful in estimating dynamic relationships. Chapter 19 should be helpful to students who must write either a term paper or some other paper in the applied social sciences. The chapter offers suggestions for how to select a topic, collect and analyze the data, and write the paper. 448 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 13 CHAPTER Until now, we have covered multiple regression analysis using pure cross-sectional or pure time series data. Although these two cases arise often in applications, data sets that have both cross-sectional and time series dimensions are being used more and more often in empirical research. Multiple regression methods can still be used on such data sets. In fact, data with cross-sectional and time series aspects can often shed light on important policy questions. We will see several examples in this chapter. We will analyze two kinds of data sets in this chapter. An independently pooled cross section is obtained by sampling randomly from a large population at different points in time (usually, but not necessarily, different years). For instance, in each year, we can draw a random sample on hourly wages, education, experience, and so on from the population of working people in the United States. Or, in every other year, we draw a random sample on the selling price, square footage, number of bathrooms, and so on of houses sold in a particular metropolitan area. From a statistical standpoint, these data sets have an important feature: they consist of indepen- dently sampled observations. This was also a key aspect in our analysis of cross-sectional data: among other things, it rules out correlation in the error terms across different observations. An independently pooled cross section differs from a single random sample in that sampling from the population at different points in time likely leads to observations that are not identically distributed. For example, distributions of wages and education have changed over time in most countries. As we will see, this is easy to deal with in practice by allowing the intercept in a multiple regression model, and in some cases the slopes, to change over time. We cover such models in Section 13.1. In Section 13.2, we discuss how pooling cross sections over time can be used to evaluate policy changes. A panel data set, while having both a cross-sectional and a time series dimension, differs in some important respects from an independently pooled cross section. To collect panel data—sometimes called longitudinal data—we follow (or attempt to follow) the same individuals, families, firms, cities, states, or whatever, across time. For example, a panel data set on individual wages, hours, education, and other factors is collected by randomly selecting people from a population at a given point in time. Then, these same Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 449 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods people are reinterviewed at several subsequent points in time. This gives us data on wages, hours, education, and so on, for the same group of people in different years. Panel data sets are fairly easy to collect for school districts, cities, counties, states, and coun- tries, and policy analysis is greatly enhanced by using panel data sets; we will see some exam- ples in the following discussion. For the econometric analysis of panel data, we cannot assume that the observations are independently distributed across time. For example, unobserved factors (such as ability) that affect someone’s wage in 1990 will also affect that person’s wage in 1991; unobserved factors that affect a city’s crime rate in 1985 will also affect that city’s crime rate in 1990. For this reason, special models and methods have been developed to analyze panel data. In Sections 13.3, 13.4, and 13.5, we describe the straightforward method of differencing to remove time-constant, unobserved attributes of the units being studied. Because panel data methods are somewhat more advanced, we will rely mostly on intuition in describing the statistical properties of the estimation procedures, leaving detailed assumptions to the chapter appendix. We follow the same strategy in Chapter 14, which covers more complicated panel data methods. 13.1 Pooling Independent Cross Sections across Time Many surveys of individuals, families, and firms are repeated at regular intervals, often each year. An example is the Current Population Survey (or CPS), which randomly sam- ples households each year. (See, for example, CPS78_85.RAW, which contains data from the 1978 and 1985 CPS.) If a random sample is drawn at each time period, pooling the resulting random samples gives us an independently pooled cross section. One reason for using independently pooled cross sections is to increase the sample size. By pooling random samples drawn from the same population, but at different points in time, we can get more precise estimators and test statistics with more power. Pooling is helpful in this regard only insofar as the relationship between the dependent variable and at least some of the independent variables remains constant over time. As mentioned in the introduction, using pooled cross sections raises only minor sta- tistical complications. Typically, to reflect the fact that the population may have different distributions in different time periods, we allow the intercept to differ across periods, usu- ally years. This is easily accomplished by including dummy variables for all but one year, where the earliest year in the sample is usually chosen as the base year. It is also possible that the error variance changes over time, something we discuss later. Sometimes, the pattern of coefficients on the year dummy variables is itself of in- terest. For example, a demographer may be interested in the following question: After controlling for education, has the pattern of fertility among women over age 35 changed between 1972 and 1984? The following example illustrates how this question is simply answered by using multiple regression analysis with year dummy variables. EXAMPLE 13.1 WOMEN’S FERTILITY OVER TIME The data set in FERTIL1.RAW, which is similar to that used by Sander (1992), comes from the National Opinion Research Center’s General Social Survey for the even years from 1972 to 1984, inclusively. We use these data to estimate a model explaining the total number of kids born to a woman (kids). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 450 PART 3 Advanced Topics T A B L E 1 3 . 1 Determinants of Women’s Fertility Dependent Variable: kids Independent Variables Coefficients Standard Errors educ 􏱦.128 .018 age .532 .138 age2 􏱦.0058 .0016 black 1.076 .174 east .217 .133 northcen .363 .121 west .198 .167 farm 􏱦.053 .147 othrural 􏱦.163 .175 town .084 .124 smcity .212 .160 y74 .268 .173 y76 􏱦.097 .179 y78 􏱦.069 .182 y80 􏱦.071 .183 y82 􏱦.522 .172 y84 􏱦.545 .175 constant 􏱦7.742 3.052 n 􏱪 1,129 R2 􏱪 .1295 R-2 􏱪 .1162 One question of interest is: After controlling for other observable factors, what has happened to fertility rates over time? The factors we control for are years of education, age, race, region of the country where living at age 16, and living environment at age 16. The estimates are given in Table 13.1. The base year is 1972. The coefficients on the year dummy variables show a sharp drop in fertility in the early 1980s. For example, the coefficient on y82 implies that, holding education, age, and other factors fixed, a woman had on average .52 less children, or about one-half a child, in 1982 than in 1972. This is a very large drop: holding educ, age, and the other factors fixed, 100 women in 1982 are predicted to have about 52 fewer children than 100 comparable women in 1972. Since we are controlling for education, this drop is separate from the decline in fertility that is due to the increase in average education levels. (The aver- age years of education are 12.2 for 1972 and 13.3 for 1984.) The coefficients on y82 and y84 represent drops in fertility for reasons that are not captured in the explanatory variables. Given that the 1982 and 1984 year dummies are individually quite significant, it is not sur- prising that as a group the year dummies are jointly very significant: the R-squared for the re- gression without the year dummies is .1019, and this leads to F6,1111 􏱪 5.87 and p-value 􏱴 0. Women with more education have fewer children, and the estimate is very statistically significant. Other things being equal, 100 women with a college education will have about Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 451 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 51 fewer children on average than 100 women with only a high school education: .128(4) 􏱪 .512. Age has a diminishing effect on fertility. (The turning point in the quadratic is at about age 􏱪 46, by which time most women have finished having children.) The model estimated in Table 13.1 assumes that the effect of each explanatory vari- able, particularly education, has remained constant. This may or may not be true; you will be asked to explore this issue in Computer Exercise C1. Finally, there may be heteroskedasticity in the error term underlying the estimated equation. This can be dealt with using the methods in Chapter 8. There is one interesting difference here: now, the error variance may change over time even if it does not change with the values of educ, age, black, and so on. The heteroskedasticity-robust standard er- rors and test statistics are nevertheless valid. The Breusch-Pagan test would be obtained by regressing the squared OLS residuals on all of the independent variables in Table 13.1, in- cluding the year dummies. (For the special case of the White statistic, the fitted values 􏱱kids and the squared fitted values are used as the independent variables, as always.) A weighted least squares procedure should account for variances that possibly change over time. In the procedure discussed in Section 8.4, year dummies would be included in equation (8.32). We can also interact a year dummy variable with key explanatory variables to see if the effect of that variable has changed over a certain time period. The next example examines how the return to education and the gender gap have changed from 1978 to 1985. EXAMPLE 13.2 CHANGES IN THE RETURN TO EDUCATION AND THE GENDER WAGE GAP A log(wage) equation (where wage is hourly wage) pooled across the years 1978 (the base year) and 1985 is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 y85 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱛1 y85􏱳educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper [13.1] 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 􏱬4union 􏱕 􏱬5 female 􏱕 􏱛5y85􏱳female 􏱕 u, where most explanatory variables should by now be familiar. The variable union is a dummy variable equal to one if the person belongs to a union, and zero otherwise. The variable y85 is a dummy variable equal to one if the observation comes from 1985 and zero if it comes from 1978. There are 550 people in the sample in 1978 and a different set of 534 people in 1985. The intercept for 1978 is 􏱬0, and the intercept for 1985 is 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0. The return to edu- cation in 1978 is 􏱬1, and the return to education in 1985 is 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱛1. Therefore, 􏱛1 mea- sures how the return to another year of education has changed over the seven-year period. Finally, in 1978, the log(wage) differential between women and men is 􏱬5; the differential in 1985 is 􏱬5 􏱕 􏱛5. Thus, we can test the null hypothesis that nothing has happened to the gender differential over this seven-year period by testing H0: 􏱛5 􏱪 0. The alternative that the gender differential has been reduced is H1: 􏱛5 􏱰 0. For simplicity, we have assumed that experience and union membership have the same effect on wages in both time periods. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 13.1 In reading Table 13.1, someone claims that, if everything else is equal in the table, a black woman is expected to have one more child than a nonblack woman. Do you agree with this claim? 452 PART 3 Advanced Topics Before we present the estimates, there is one other issue we need to address—namely, hourly wage here is in nominal (or current) dollars. Since nominal wages grow simply due to inflation, we are really interested in the effect of each explanatory variable on real wages. Suppose that we settle on measuring wages in 1978 dollars. This requires deflat- ing 1985 wages to 1978 dollars. (Using the Consumer Price Index for the 1997 Economic Report of the President, the deflation factor is 107.6/65.2 􏱴 1.65.) Although we can easily divide each 1985 wage by 1.65, it turns out that this is not necessary, provided a 1985 year dummy is included in the regression and log(wage) (as opposed to wage) is used as the de- pendent variable. Using real or nominal wage in a logarithmic functional form only affects the coefficient on the year dummy, y85. To see this, let P85 denote the deflation factor for 1985 wages (1.65, if we use the CPI). Then, the log of the real wage for each person i in the 1985 sample is log(wagei /P85) 􏱪 log(wagei ) 􏱦 log(P85). Now, while wagei differs across people, P85 does not. Therefore, log(P85) will be absorbed into the intercept for 1985. (This conclusion would change if, for example, we used a different price index for people living in different parts of the country.) The bottom line is that, for studying how the return to education or the gender gap has changed, we do not need to turn nominal wages into real wages in equation (13.1). Computer Exercise C2 asks you to verify this for the current example. If we forget to allow different intercepts in 1978 and 1985, the use of nominal wages can produce seriously misleading results. If we use wage rather than log(wage) as the de- pendent variable, it is important to use the real wage and to include a year dummy. The previous discussion generally holds when using dollar values for either the dependent or independent variables. Provided the dollar amounts appear in logarith- mic form and dummy variables are used for all time periods (except, of course, the base period), the use of aggregate price deflators will only affect the intercepts; none of the slope estimates will change. Now, we use the data in CPS78_85.RAW to estimate the equation: log(wage) 􏱪 .459 􏱕 .118 y85 􏱕 .0747 educ 􏱕 .0185 y85􏱳educ (.093) (.124) (.0067) (.0094) 􏱕 .0296 exper 􏱦 .00040 exper2 􏱕 .202 union (.0036) (.00008) (.030) [13.2] 􏱦 .317 female 􏱕 .085 y85􏱳female (.037) (.051) n 􏱪 1,084, R2 􏱪 .426, R-2 􏱪 .422. The return to education in 1978 is estimated to be about 7.5%; the return to education in 1985 is about 1.85 percentage points higher, or about 9.35%. Because the t statistic on the interaction term is .0185/.0094 􏱴 1.97, the difference in the return to education is statisti- cally significant at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative. What about the gender gap? In 1978, other things being equal, a woman earned about 31.7% less than a man (27.2% is the more accurate estimate). In 1985, the gap in log(wage) is 􏱦.317 􏱕 .085 􏱪 􏱦.232. Therefore, the gender gap appears to have fallen from 1978 to 1985 by about 8.5 percentage points. The t statistic on the interaction term is about 1.67, which means it is significant at the 5% level against the positive one-sided alternative. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 453 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods What happens if we interact all independent variables with y85 in equation (13.2)? This is identical to estimating two separate equations, one for 1978 and one for 1985. Sometimes, this is desirable. For example, in Chapter 7, we discussed a study by Krueger (1993) in which he estimated the return to using a computer on the job. Krueger estimates two separate equations, one using the 1984 CPS and the other using the 1989 CPS. By comparing how the return to education changes across time and whether or not computer usage is controlled for, he estimates that one-third to one-half of the observed increase in the return to education over the five-year period can be attributed to increased computer usage. [See Tables VIII and IX in Krueger (1993).] The Chow Test for Structural Change across Time In Chapter 7, we discussed how the Chow test—which is simply an F test—can be used to determine whether a multiple regression function differs across two groups. We can ap- ply that test to two different time periods as well. One form of the test obtains the sum of squared residuals from the pooled estimation as the restricted SSR. The unrestricted SSR is the sum of the SSRs for the two separately estimated time periods. The mechanics of computing the statistic are exactly as they were in Section 7.4. A heteroskedasticity-robust version is also available (see Section 8.2). Example 13.2 suggests another way to compute the Chow test for two time periods by interacting each variable with a year dummy for one of the two years and testing for joint significance of the year dummy and all of the interaction terms. Since the intercept in a regression model often changes over time (due to, say, inflation in the housing price ex- ample), this full-blown Chow test can detect such changes. It is usually more interesting to allow for an intercept difference and then to test whether certain slope coefficients change over time (as we did in Example 13.2). A Chow test can also be computed for more than two time periods. Just as in the two- period case, it is usually more interesting to allow the intercepts to change over time and then test whether the slope coefficients have changed over time. We can test the constancy of slope coefficients generally by interacting all of the time-period dummies (except that defining the base group) with one, several, or all of the explanatory variables and test the joint significance of the interaction terms. Computer Exercises C1 and C2 are examples. For many time periods and explanatory variables, constructing a full set of interactions can be tedious. Alternatively, we can adapt the approach described in part (vi) of Com- puter Exercise C11 in Chapter 7. First, estimate the restricted model by doing a pooled regression allowing for different time intercepts; this gives SSRr. Then, run a regression for each of the, say, T time periods and obtain the sum of squared residuals for each time period. The unrestricted sum of squared residuals is obtained as SSRur 􏱪 SSR1 􏱕 SSR2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 SSRT . If there are k explanatory variables (not including the intercept or the time dummies) with T time periods, then we are testing (T 􏱦 1)k restrictions, and there are T 􏱕 Tk parameters estimated in the unrestricted model. So, if n 􏱪 n1 􏱕 n2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 nT is the total number of observations, then the df of the F test are (T 􏱦 1)k and n 􏱦 T 􏱦 Tk. We compute the F statistic as usual: [(SSRr 􏱦 SSRur)/SSRur][(n 􏱦 T 􏱦 Tk)/(T 􏱦 1)k]. Unfortunately, as with any F test based on sums of squared residuals or R-squareds, this test is not robust to heteroskedasticity (including changing variances across time). To obtain a heteroskedasticity-robust test, we must construct the interaction terms and do a pooled regression. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 454 PART 3 Advanced Topics 13.2 Policy Analysis with Pooled Cross Sections Pooled cross sections can be very useful for evaluating the impact of a certain event or policy. The following example of an event study shows how two cross-sectional data sets, collected before and after the occurrence of an event, can be used to determine the effect on economic outcomes. EXAMPLE 13.3 EFFECT OF A GARBAGE INCINERATOR’S LOCATION ON HOUSING PRICES Kiel and McClain (1995) studied the effect that a new garbage incinerator had on housing values in North Andover, Massachusetts. They used many years of data and a fairly com- plicated econometric analysis. We will use two years of data and some simplified models, but our analysis is similar. The rumor that a new incinerator would be built in North Andover began after 1978, and construction began in 1981. The incinerator was expected to be in operation soon af- ter the start of construction; the incinerator actually began operating in 1985. We will use data on prices of houses that sold in 1978 and another sample on those that sold in 1981. The hypothesis is that the price of houses located near the incinerator would fall relative to the price of more distant houses. For illustration, we define a house to be near the incinerator if it is within three miles. [In Computer Exercise C3, you are instead asked to use the actual distance from the house to the incinerator, as in Kiel and McClain (1995).] We will start by looking at the dollar effect on housing prices. This requires us to measure price in constant dollars. We mea- sure all housing prices in 1978 dollars, using the Boston housing price index. Let rprice denote the house price in real terms. A naive analyst would use only the 1981 data and estimate a very simple model: rprice 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1nearinc 􏱕 u, [13.3] where nearinc is a binary variable equal to one if the house is near the incinerator, and zero otherwise. Estimating this equation using the data in KIELMC.RAW gives 􏱱rprice 􏱪 101,307.5 􏱦 30,688.27 nearinc (3,093.0) (5,827.71) [13.4] n 􏱪 142, R2 􏱪 .165. Since this is a simple regression on a single dummy variable, the intercept is the aver- age selling price for homes not near the incinerator, and the coefficient on nearinc is the difference in the average selling price between homes near the incinerator and those that are not. The estimate shows that the average selling price for the former group was $30,688.27 less than for the latter group. The t statistic is greater than five in absolute value, so we can strongly reject the hypothesis that the average value for homes near and far from the incinerator are the same. Unfortunately, equation (13.4) does not imply that the siting of the incinerator is causing the lower housing values. In fact, if we run the same regression for 1978 (before the incinerator was even rumored), we obtain Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 455 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 􏱱rprice 􏱪 82,517.23 􏱦 18,824.37 nearinc (2,653.79) (4,744.59) [13.5] n 􏱪179, R2 􏱪 .082. Therefore, even before there was any talk of an incinerator, the average value of a home near the site was $18,824.37 less than the average value of a home not near the site ($82,517.23); the difference is statistically significant, as well. This is consistent with the view that the incinerator was built in an area with lower housing values. How, then, can we tell whether building a new incinerator depresses housing values? The key is to look at how the coefficient on nearinc changed between 1978 and 1981. The difference in average housing value was much larger in 1981 than in 1978 ($30,688.27 versus $18,824.37), even as a percentage of the average value of homes not near the incin- erator site. The difference in the two coefficients on nearinc is 􏱛ˆ1 􏱪 􏱦30,688.27 􏱦 (􏱦18,824.37) 􏱪 􏱦11,863.9. This is our estimate of the effect of the incinerator on values of homes near the incinerator site. In empirical economics, 􏱛ˆ1 has become known as the difference-in-differences estimator because it can be expressed as ˆ􏰲􏰲􏰲􏰲 􏱛1 􏱪 (rprice81, nr 􏱦 rprice81, fr) 􏱦 (rprice78, nr 􏱦 rprice78, fr), [13.6] where nr stands for “near the incinerator site” and fr stands for “farther away from the site.” In other words, 􏱛ˆ1 is the difference over time in the average difference of housing prices in the two locations. To test whether 􏱛ˆ1 is statistically different from zero, we need to find its standard er- ror by using a regression analysis. In fact, 􏱛ˆ1 can be obtained by estimating rprice 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 y81 􏱕 􏱬1nearinc 􏱕 􏱛1y81􏱳nearinc 􏱕 u, [13.7] using the data pooled over both years. The intercept, 􏱬0, is the average price of a home not near the incinerator in 1978. The parameter 􏱛0 captures changes in all housing val- ues in North Andover from 1978 to 1981. [A comparison of equations (13.4) and (13.5) shows that housing values in North Andover, relative to the Boston housing price in- dex, increased sharply over this period.] The coefficient on nearinc, 􏱬1, measures the location effect that is not due to the presence of the incinerator: as we saw in equation (13.5), even in 1978, homes near the incinerator site sold for less than homes farther away from the site. The parameter of interest is on the interaction term y81·nearinc: 􏱛1 measures the de- cline in housing values due to the new incinerator, provided we assume that houses both near and far from the site did not appreciate at different rates for other reasons. The estimates of equation (13.7) are given in column (1) of Table 13.2. The only number we could not obtain from equations (13.4) and (13.5) is the standard error of 􏱛ˆ1. The t statistic on 􏱛ˆ1 is about 􏱦1.59, which is marginally significant against a one-sided alternative (p-value 􏱴 .057). Kiel and McClain (1995) included various housing characteristics in their analysis of the incinerator siting. There are two good reasons for doing this. First, the kinds of homes Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 456 PART 3 Advanced Topics T A B L E 1 3 . 2 Effects of Incinerator Location on Housing Prices Dependent Variable: rprice Independent Variable (1) (2) (3) constant 82,517.23 (2,726.91) 89,116.54 (2,406.05) 13,807.67 (11,166.59) y81 18,790.29 (4,050.07) 21,321.04 (3,443.63) 13,928.48 (2,798.75) nearinc 􏱦18,824.37 (4,875.32) 9,397.94 (4,812.22) 3,780.34 (4,453.42) y81∙nearinc 􏱦11,863.90 (7,456.65) 􏱦21,920.27 (6,359.75) 􏱦14,177.93 (4,987.27) Other controls No age, age2 Full Set Observations R-squared 321 .174 321 .414 321 .660 selling near the incinerator in 1981 might have been systematically different than those selling near the incinerator in 1978; if so, it can be important to control for such character- istics. Second, even if the relevant house characteristics did not change, including them can greatly reduce the error variance, which can then shrink the standard error of 􏱛ˆ1. (See Section 6.3 for discussion.) In column (2), we control for the age of the houses, using a quadratic. This substantially increases the R-squared (by reducing the residual variance). The coeffi- cient on y81·nearinc is now much larger in magnitude, and its standard error is lower. In addition to the age variables in column (2), column (3) controls for distance to the interstate in feet (intst), land area in feet (land), house area in feet (area), number of rooms (rooms), and number of baths (baths). This produces an estimate on y81·nearinc closer to that without any controls, but it yields a much smaller standard error: the t statistic for 􏱛ˆ1 is about 􏱦2.84. Therefore, we find a much more significant effect in column (3) than in column (1). The column (3) estimates are preferred because they control for the most fac- tors and have the smallest standard errors (except in the constant, which is not important here). The fact that nearinc has a much smaller coefficient and is insignificant in column (3) indicates that the characteristics included in column (3) largely capture the housing characteristics that are most important for determining housing prices. For the purpose of introducing the method, we used the level of real housing prices in Table 13.2. It makes more sense to use log(price) [or log(rprice)] in the analysis in order to get an approximate percentage effect. The basic model becomes log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 y81 􏱕 􏱬1nearinc 􏱕 􏱛1y81·nearinc 􏱕 u. [13.8] Now, 100􏱳􏱛1 is the approximate percentage reduction in housing value due to the incinera- tor. [Just as in Example 13.2, using log(price) versus log(rprice) only affects the coeffi- cient on y81.] Using the same 321 pooled observations gives 􏱱log( price) 􏱪 11.29 􏱕 .457 y81 􏱦 .340 nearinc 􏱦 .063 y81·nearinc (.31) (.045) (.055) (.083) [13.9] n 􏱪 321, R2 􏱪 .409. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 457 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods The coefficient on the interaction term implies that, because of the new incinerator, houses near the incinerator lost about 6.3% in value. However, this estimate is not statistically different from zero. But when we use a full set of controls, as in column (3) of Table 13.2 (but with intst, land, and area appearing in logarithmic form), the coefficient on y81􏱳nearinc becomes 􏱦.132 with a t statistic of about 􏱦2.53. Again, controlling for other factors turns out to be important. Using the logarithmic form, we estimate that houses near the incinerator were devalued by about 13.2%. The methodology used in the previous example has numerous applications, especially when the data arise from a natural experiment (or a quasi-experiment). A natural experiment occurs when some exogenous event—often a change in government policy—changes the environment in which individuals, families, firms, or cities operate. A natural experiment always has a control group, which is not affected by the policy change, and a treatment group, which is thought to be affected by the policy change. Un- like a true experiment, in which treatment and control groups are randomly and explicitly chosen, the control and treatment groups in natural experiments arise from the particular policy change. To control for systematic differences between the control and treatment groups, we need two years of data, one before the policy change and one after the change. Thus, our sample is usefully broken down into four groups: the control group before the change, the control group after the change, the treatment group before the change, and the treatment group after the change. Call C the control group and T the treatment group, letting dT equal unity for those in the treatment group T, and zero otherwise. Then, letting d2 denote a dummy variable for the second (post–policy change) time period, the equation of interest is y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d2 􏱕 􏱬1dT 􏱕 􏱛1d2·dT 􏱕 other factors, [13.10] where y is the outcome variable of interest. As in Example 13.3, 􏱛1 measures the effect of the policy. Without other factors in the regression, 􏱛ˆ1 will be the difference-in-differences estimator: 􏱛ˆ1 􏱪 (y-2,T 􏱦 y-2,C) 􏱦 (y-1,T 􏱦 y-1,C), [13.11] where the bar denotes average, the first subscript denotes the year, and the second subscript denotes the group. The general difference-in-differences setup is shown in Table 13.3. Table 13.3 suggests that the parameter 􏱛1, sometimes called the average treatment effect (because it measures the effect of the “treatment” or policy on the average outcome of y), can be estimated in two ways: (1) Compute the differences in averages between the treatment and control groups in each time period, and then difference the results over time; this is just as Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. T A B L E 1 3 . 3 Illustration of the Difference-in-Differences Estimator Before After After – Before Control 􏱬0 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 􏱛0 Treatment 􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1 􏱬0 􏱕􏱛0 􏱕􏱬1 􏱕􏱛1 􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1 Treatment 􏱦 Control 􏱬1 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱛1 􏱛1 © Cengage Learning, 2013 458 PART 3 Advanced Topics in equation (13.11); (2) Compute the change in averages over time for each of the treat- ment and control groups, and then difference these changes, which means we simply write 􏱛ˆ1 􏱪 (y-2,T 􏱦 y-1,T) 􏱦 (y-2,C 􏱦 y-1,C). Naturally, the estimate 􏱛ˆ1 does not depend on how we do the differencing, as is seen by simple rearrangement. When explanatory variables are added to equation (13.10) (to control for the fact that the populations sampled may differ systematically over the two periods), the OLS esti- mate of 􏱛1 no longer has the simple form of (13.11), but its interpretation is similar. EXAMPLE 13.4 EFFECT OF WORKER COMPENSATION LAWS ON WEEKS OUT OF WORK Meyer, Viscusi, and Durbin (1995) (hereafter, MVD) studied the length of time (in weeks) that an injured worker receives workers’ compensation. On July 15, 1980, Ken- tucky raised the cap on weekly earnings that were covered by workers’ compensation. An increase in the cap has no effect on the benefit for low-income workers, but it makes it less costly for a high-income worker to stay on workers’ compensation. Therefore, the control group is low-income workers, and the treatment group is high-income workers; high-income workers are defined as those who were subject to the pre-policy change cap. Using random samples both before and after the policy change, MVD were able to test whether more generous workers’ compensation causes people to stay out of work longer (everything else fixed). They started with a difference-in-differences analysis, using log(durat) as the dependent variable. Let afchnge be the dummy variable for ob- servations after the policy change and highearn the dummy variable for high earners. Using the data in INJURY.RAW, the estimated equation, with standard errors in paren- theses, is 􏱱log(durat) 􏱪 1.126 􏱕 .0077 afchnge 􏱕 .256 highearn (0.031) (.0447) (.047) 􏱕 .191 afchnge􏱳highearn (.069) n 􏱪 5,626, R2 􏱪 .021. [13.12] Therefore, 􏱛ˆ1 􏱪 .191 (t 􏱪 2.77), which implies that the average length of time on work- ers’ compensation for high earners increased by about 19% due to the increased earnings cap. The coefficient on afchnge is small and statistically insignificant: as is expected, the increase in the earnings cap has no effect on duration for low-income workers. This is a good example of how we can get a fairly precise estimate of the effect of a policy change even though we cannot explain much of the variation in the dependent variable. The dummy variables in (13.12) explain only 2.1% of the variation in log(durat). This makes sense: there are clearly many factors, including severity of the injury, that affect how long someone receives workers’ compensation. Fortunately, we have a very large sample size, and this allows us to get a significant t statistic. MVD also added a variety of controls for gender, marital status, age, industry, and type of injury. This allows for the fact that the kinds of people and types of injuries may differ systematically by earnings group across the two years. Controlling for these factors turns out to have little effect on the estimate of 􏱛1. (See Computer Exercise C4.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 459 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods Sometimes, the two groups consist of people living in two neighboring states in the United States. For example, to assess the impact of changing cigarette taxes on cigarette consumption, we can obtain random samples from two states for two years. In State A, the control group, there was no change in the cigarette tax. In State B, the treatment group, the tax increased (or decreased) between the two years. The outcome variable would be a measure of cigarette consumption, and equation (13.10) can be estimated to determine the effect of the tax on cigarette consumption. For an interesting survey on natural experiment methodology and several additional examples, see Meyer (1995). 13.3 Two-Period Panel Data Analysis We now turn to the analysis of the simplest kind of panel data: for a cross section of in- dividuals, schools, firms, cities, or whatever, we have two years of data; call these t 􏱪 1 and t 􏱪 2. These years need not be adjacent, but t 􏱪 1 corresponds to the earlier year. For example, the file CRIME2.RAW contains data on (among other things) crime and unem- ployment rates for 46 cities for 1982 and 1987. Therefore, t 􏱪 1 corresponds to 1982, and t 􏱪 2 corresponds to 1987. What happens if we use the 1987 cross section and run a simple regression of crmrte on unem? We obtain 􏱱crmrte 􏱪 128.38 􏱦 4.16 unem (20.76) (3.42) n􏱪46,R2 􏱪.033. If we interpret the estimated equation causally, it implies that an increase in the unemploy- ment rate lowers the crime rate. This is certainly not what we expect. The coefficient on unem is not statistically significant at standard significance levels: at best, we have found no link between crime and unemployment rates. As we have emphasized throughout this text, this simple regression equation likely suffers from omitted variable problems. One possible solution is to try to control for more factors, such as age distribution, gender distribution, education levels, law enforcement ef- forts, and so on, in a multiple regression analysis. But many factors might be hard to con- trol for. In Chapter 9, we showed how including the crmrte from a previous year—in this case, 1982—can help to control for the fact that different cities have historically different crime rates. This is one way to use two years of data for estimating a causal effect. An alternative way to use panel data is to view the unobserved factors affecting the dependent variable as consisting of two types: those that are constant and those that vary over time. Letting i denote the cross-sectional unit and t the time period, we can write a model with a single observed explanatory variable as yit 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱛0d2t 􏱕􏱬1xit 􏱕ai 􏱕uit,t􏱪1,2. [13.13] In the notation yit, i denotes the person, firm, city, and so on, and t denotes the time pe- riod. The variable d2t is a dummy variable that equals zero when t 􏱪 1 and one when Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 13.2 What do you make of the coefficient and t statistic on highearn in equation (13.12)? 460 PART 3 Advanced Topics t 􏱪 2; it does not change across i, which is why it has no i subscript. Therefore, the intercept for t 􏱪 1 is 􏱬0, and the intercept for t 􏱪 2 is 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0. Just as in using independently pooled cross sections, allowing the intercept to change over time is important in most applica- tions. In the crime example, secular trends in the United States will cause crime rates in all U.S. cities to change, perhaps markedly, over a five-year period. The variable ai captures all unobserved, time-constant factors that affect yit. (The fact that ai has no t subscript tells us that it does not change over time.) Generically, ai is called an unobserved effect. It is also common in applied work to find ai referred to as a fixed effect, which helps us to remember that ai is fixed over time. The model in (13.13) is called an unobserved effects model or a fixed effects model. In applications, you might see ai referred to as unobserved heterogeneity as well (or individual heterogeneity, firm heterogeneity, city heterogeneity, and so on). The error uit is often called the idiosyncratic error or time-varying error, because it represents unobserved factors that change over time and affect yit. These are very much like the errors in a straight time series regression equation. A simple unobserved effects model for city crime rates for 1982 and 1987 is crmrteit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d87t 􏱕 􏱬1unemit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, [13.14] where d87 is a dummy variable for 1987. Since i denotes different cities, we call ai an unobserved city effect or a city fixed effect: it represents all factors affecting city crime rates that do not change over time. Geographical features, such as the city’s location in the United States, are included in ai. Many other factors may not be exactly constant, but they might be roughly constant over a five-year period. These might include certain demographic features of the population (age, race, and education). Different cities may have their own methods for reporting crimes, and the people living in the cities might have different attitudes toward crime; these are typically slow to change. For historical reasons, cities can have very different crime rates, and historical factors are effectively captured by the unobserved effect ai. How should we estimate the parameter of interest, 􏱬1, given two years of panel data? One possibility is just to pool the two years and use OLS, essentially as in Section 13.1. This method has two drawbacks. The most important of these is that, in order for pooled OLS to produce a consistent estimator of 􏱬1, we would have to assume that the unobserved effect, ai, is uncorrelated with xit. We can easily see this by writing (13.13) as yit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d2t 􏱕 􏱬1xit 􏱕 vit, t 􏱪 1,2, [13.15] where vit 􏱪 ai 􏱕 uit is often called the composite error. From what we know about OLS, we must assume that vit is uncorrelated with xit, where t 􏱪 1 or 2, for OLS to estimate 􏱬1 (and the other parameters consistently). This is true whether we use a single cross section or pool the two cross sections. Therefore, even if we assume that the idiosyncratic error uit is uncorrelated with xit, pooled OLS is biased and incon- sistent if ai and xit are correlated. The re- sulting bias in pooled OLS is sometimes called heterogeneity bias, but it is really just bias caused from omitting a time- constant variable. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 13.3 Suppose that ai, ui1, and ui2 have zero means and are pairwise uncorrelated. Show that Cov(vi1, vi2) 􏱪 Var(ai), so that the com- posite errors are positively serially corre- lated across time, unless ai 􏱪 0. What does this imply about the usual OLS standard er- rors from pooled OLS estimation? 461 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods To illustrate what happens, we use the data in CRIME2.RAW to estimate (13.14) by pooled OLS. Since there are 46 cities and two years for each city, there are 92 total observations: c􏱱rmrte 􏱪 93.42 􏱕 7.94 d87 􏱕 .427 unem (12.74) (7.98) (1.188) [13.16] n􏱪92,R2 􏱪.012. (When reporting the estimated equation, we usually drop the i and t subscripts.) The coef- ficient on unem, though positive in (13.16), has a very small t statistic. Thus, using pooled OLS on the two years has not substantially changed anything from using a single cross section. This is not surprising since using pooled OLS does not solve the omitted variables problem. (The standard errors in this equation are incorrect because of the serial correlation described in Question 13.3, but we ignore this since pooled OLS is not the focus here.) In most applications, the main reason for collecting panel data is to allow for the unobserved effect, ai, to be correlated with the explanatory variables. For example, in the crime equation, we want to allow the unmeasured city factors in ai that affect the crime rate also to be correlated with the unemployment rate. It turns out that this is simple to allow: because ai is constant over time, we can difference the data across the two years. More precisely, for a cross-sectional observation i, write the two years as yi2 􏱪(􏱬0 􏱕􏱛0)􏱕􏱬1xi2 􏱕ai 􏱕ui2 (t􏱪2) yi1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xi1 􏱕ai 􏱕ui1 (t􏱪1). If we subtract the second equation from the first, we obtain (yi2 􏱦yi1)􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱬1(xi2 􏱦xi1)􏱕(ui2 􏱦ui1), or ∆yi 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1∆xi 􏱕 ∆ui, where ∆ denotes the change from t 􏱪 1 to t 􏱪 2. The unobserved effect, ai, does not appear in (13.17): it has been “differenced away.” Also, the intercept in (13.17) is actually the change in the intercept from t 􏱪 1 to t 􏱪 2. Equation (13.17), which we call the first-differenced equation, is very simple. It is just a single cross-sectional equation, but each variable is differenced over time. We can analyze (13.17) using the methods we developed in Part 1, provided the key assumptions are satisfied. The most important of these is that ∆ui is uncorrelated with ∆xi. This assump- tion holds if the idiosyncratic error at each time t, uit, is uncorrelated with the explanatory variable in both time periods. This is another version of the strict exogeneity assumption that we encountered in Chapter 10 for time series models. In particular, this assumption rules out the case where xit is the lagged dependent variable, yi,t􏱦1. Unlike in Chapter 10, we allow xit to be correlated with unobservables that are constant over time. When we obtain the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 from (13.17), we call the resulting estimator the first-differenced estimator. In the crime example, assuming that ∆ui and ∆unemi are uncorrelated may be reason- able, but it can also fail. For example, suppose that law enforcement effort (which is in the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. [13.17] 462 PART 3 Advanced Topics idiosyncratic error) increases more in cities where the unemployment rate decreases. This can cause negative correlation between ∆ui and ∆unemi, which would then lead to bias in the OLS estimator. Naturally, this problem can be overcome to some extent by including more factors in the equation, something we will cover later. As usual, it is always possible that we have not accounted for enough time-varying factors. Another crucial condition is that ∆xi must have some variation across i. This qualifi- cation fails if the explanatory variable does not change over time for any cross-sectional observation, or if it changes by the same amount for every observation. This is not an issue in the crime rate example because the unemployment rate changes across time for almost all cities. But, if i denotes an individual and xit is a dummy variable for gender, ∆xi 􏱪 0 for all i; we clearly cannot estimate (13.17) by OLS in this case. This actually makes perfectly good sense: since we allow ai to be correlated with xit, we cannot hope to separate the effect of ai on yit from the effect of any variable that does not change over time. The only other assumption we need to apply to the usual OLS statistics is that (13.17) satisfies the homoskedasticity assumption. This is reasonable in many cases, and, if it does not hold, we know how to test and correct for heteroskedasticity using the methods in Chapter 8. It is sometimes fair to assume that (13.17) fulfills all of the classical linear model assumptions. The OLS estimators are unbiased and all statistical inference is exact in such cases. When we estimate (13.17) for the crime rate example, we get ∆c􏱱rmrte 􏱪 15.40 􏱕 2.22 ∆unem (4.70) (.88) [13.18 ] n􏱪46,R2 􏱪.127, which now gives a positive, statistically significant relationship between the crime and unemployment rates. Thus, differencing to eliminate time-constant effects makes a big difference in this example. The intercept in (13.18) also reveals something interesting. Even if ∆unem 􏱪 0, we predict an increase in the crime rate (crimes per 1,000 people) of 15.40. This reflects a secular increase in crime rates throughout the United States from 1982 to 1987. Even if we do not begin with the unobserved effects model (13.13), using differ- ences across time makes intuitive sense. Rather than estimating a standard cross-sectional relationship—which may suffer from omitted variables, thereby making ceteris paribus conclusions difficult—equation (13.17) explicitly considers how changes in the explana- tory variable over time affect the change in y over the same time period. Nevertheless, it is still very useful to have (13.13) in mind: it explicitly shows that we can estimate the effect of xit on yit, holding ai fixed. Although differencing two years of panel data is a powerful way to control for un- observed effects, it is not without cost. First, panel data sets are harder to collect than a single cross section, especially for individuals. We must use a survey and keep track of the individual for a follow-up survey. It is often difficult to locate some people for a second survey. For units such as firms, some will go bankrupt or merge with other firms. Panel data are much easier to obtain for schools, cities, counties, states, and countries. Even if we have collected a panel data set, the differencing used to eliminate ai can greatly reduce the variation in the explanatory variables. While xit frequently has substan- tial variation in the cross section for each t, ∆xi may not have much variation.We know from Chapter 3 that a little variation in ∆xi can lead to a large standard error for 􏱬ˆ1 when Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 463 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods estimating (13.17) by OLS. We can combat this by using a large cross section, but this is not always possible. Also, using longer differences over time is sometimes better than us- ing year-to-year changes. As an example, consider the problem of estimating the return to education, now using panel data on individuals for two years. The model for person i is log(wageit) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d2t 􏱕 􏱬1educit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, 2, where ai contains unobserved ability—which is probably correlated with educit. Again, we allow different intercepts across time to account for aggregate productivity gains (and inflation, if wageit is in nominal terms). Since, by definition, innate ability does not change over time, panel data methods seem ideally suited to estimate the return to education. The equation in first differences is ∆log(wagei) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1∆educi 􏱕 ∆ui, [13.19] and we can estimate this by OLS. The problem is that we are interested in working adults, and for most employed individuals, education does not change over time. If only a small fraction of our sample has ∆educi different from zero, it will be difficult to get a precise estimator of 􏱬1 from (13.19), unless we have a rather large sample size. In theory, using a first-differenced equation to estimate the return to education is a good idea, but it does not work very well with most currently available panel data sets. Adding several explanatory variables causes no difficulties. We begin with the unob- served effects model yit 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱛0d2t 􏱕􏱬1xit1 􏱕􏱬2xit2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxitk 􏱕ai 􏱕uit, [13.20] for t 􏱪 1 and 2. This equation looks more complicated than it is because each explanatory variable has three subscripts. The first denotes the cross-sectional observation number, the second denotes the time period, and the third is just a variable label. EXAMPLE 13.5 SLEEPING VERSUS WORKING We use the two years of panel data in SLP75_81.RAW, from Biddle and Hamermesh (1990), to estimate the tradeoff between sleeping and working. In Problem 3 in Chapter 3, we used just the 1975 cross section. The panel data set for 1975 and 1981 has 239 people, which is much smaller than the 1975 cross section that includes over 700 people. An unobserved effects model for total minutes of sleeping per week is slpnapit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d81t 􏱕 􏱬1totwrkit 􏱕 􏱬2educit 􏱕 􏱬3marrit 􏱕 􏱬4yngkidit 􏱕 􏱬5gdhlthit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, 2. The unobserved effect, ai, would be called an unobserved individual effect or an individual fixed effect. It is potentially important to allow ai to be correlated with totwrkit: the same factors (some biological) that cause people to sleep more or less (captured in ai) are likely correlated with the amount of time spent working. Some people just have more energy, and this causes them to sleep less and work more. The variable educ is years of education, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 464 PART 3 Advanced Topics marr is a marriage dummy variable, yngkid is a dummy variable indicating the presence of a small child, and gdhlth is a “good health” dummy variable. Notice that we do not include gender or race (as we did in the cross-sectional analysis), since these do not change over time; they are part of ai. Our primary interest is in 􏱬1. Differencing across the two years gives the estimable equation ∆slpnapi 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1∆totwrki 􏱕 􏱬2∆educi 􏱕 􏱬3∆marri 􏱕 􏱬4∆yngkidi 􏱕 􏱬5∆gdhlthi 􏱕 ∆ui. Assuming that the change in the idiosyncratic error, ∆ui, is uncorrelated with the changes in all explanatory variables, we can get consistent estimators using OLS. This gives ∆s􏱱lpnap 􏱪 􏱦92.63 􏱦 .227 ∆totwrk 􏱦 .024 ∆educ (45.87) (.036) (48.759) 􏱕 104.21 ∆marr 􏱕 94.67 ∆yngkid 􏱕 87.58 ∆gdhlth [13.21] (92.86) (87.65) (76.60) n 􏱪 239, R2 􏱪 .150. The coefficient on ∆totwrk indicates a tradeoff between sleeping and working: holding other factors fixed, one more hour of work is associated with .227(60) 􏱪 13.62 fewer minutes of sleeping. The t statistic (􏱦6.31) is very significant. No other estimates, except the intercept, are statistically different from zero. The F test for joint significance of all variables except ∆totwrk gives p-value 􏱪 .49, which means they are jointly insignificant at any reasonable significance level and could be dropped from the equation. The standard error on ∆educ is especially large relative to the estimate. This is the phenomenon described earlier for the wage equation. In the sample of 239 people, 183 (76.6%) have no change in education over the six-year period; 90% of the people have a change in education of at most one year. As reflected by the extremely large standard error of 􏱬ˆ2, there is not nearly enough variation in education to estimate 􏱬2 with any precision. Anyway, 􏱬ˆ2 is practically very small. Panel data can also be used to estimate finite distributed lag models. Even if we spec- ify the equation for only two years, we need to collect more years of data to obtain the lagged explanatory variables. The following is a simple example. EXAMPLE 13.6 DISTRIBUTED LAG OF CRIME RATE ON CLEAR-UP RATE Eide (1994) uses panel data from police districts in Norway to estimate a distributed lag model for crime rates. The single explanatory variable is the “clear-up percentage” (clrprc)—the percentage of crimes that led to a conviction. The crime rate data are from the years 1972 and 1978. Following Eide, we lag clrprc for one and two years: it is likely that past clear-up rates have a deterrent effect on current crime. This leads to the following unobserved effects model for the two years: log(crimeit) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d78t 􏱕 􏱬1clrprci, t􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬2clrprci, t􏱦2 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit. When we difference the equation and estimate it using the data in CRIME3.RAW, we get Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 465 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods ∆􏱱log(crime) 􏱪 .086 􏱦 .0040 ∆clrprc􏱦1 􏱦 .0132 ∆clrprc􏱦2 (.064) (.0047) - (.0052) [13.22] n 􏱪 53, R2 􏱪 .193, R2 􏱪 .161. The second lag is negative and statistically significant, which implies that a higher clear-up percentage two years ago would deter crime this year. In particular, a 10 percentage point increase in clrprc two years ago would lead to an estimated 13.2% drop in the crime rate this year. This suggests that using more resources for solving crimes and obtaining con- victions can reduce crime in the future. Organizing Panel Data In using panel data in an econometric study, it is important to know how the data should be stored. We must be careful to arrange the data so that the different time periods for the same cross-sectional unit (person, firm, city, and so on) are easily linked. For concrete- ness, suppose that the data set is on cities for two different years. For most purposes, the best way to enter the data is to have two records for each city, one for each year: the first record for each city corresponds to the early year, and the second record is for the later year. These two records should be adjacent. Therefore, a data set for 100 cities and two years will contain 200 records. The first two records are for the first city in the sample, the next two records are for the second city, and so on. (See Table 1.5 in Chapter 1 for an ex- ample.) This makes it easy to construct the differences to store these in the second record for each city, and to do a pooled cross-sectional analysis, which can be compared with the differencing estimation. Most of the two-period panel data sets accompanying this text are stored in this way (for example, CRIME2.RAW, CRIME3.RAW, GPA3.RAW, LOWBRTH.RAW, and RENTAL.RAW). We use a direct extension of this scheme for panel data sets with more than two time periods. A second way of organizing two periods of panel data is to have only one record per cross-sectional unit. This requires two entries for each variable, one for each time period. The panel data in SLP75_81.RAW are organized in this way. Each individual has data on the variables slpnap75, slpnap81, totwrk75, totwrk81, and so on. Creating the differences from 1975 to 1981 is easy. Other panel data sets with this structure are TRAFFIC1.RAW and VOTE2.RAW. Putting the data in one record, however, does not allow a pooled OLS analysis using the two time periods on the original data. Also, this organizational method does not work for panel data sets with more than two time periods, a case we will consider in Section 13.5. 13.4 Policy Analysis with Two-Period Panel Data Panel data sets are very useful for policy analysis and, in particular, program evaluation. In the simplest program evaluation setup, a sample of individuals, firms, cities, and so on is obtained in the first time period. Some of these units, those in the treatment group, then take part in a particular program in a later time period; the ones that do not are the control group. This is similar to the natural experiment literature discussed earlier, with one important difference: the same cross-sectional units appear in each time period. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 466 PART 3 Advanced Topics As an example, suppose we wish to evaluate the effect of a Michigan job training program on worker productivity of manufacturing firms (see also Computer Exercise C3) in Chapter 9. Let scrapit denote the scrap rate of firm i during year t (the number of items, per 100, that must be scrapped due to defects). Let grantit be a binary indicator equal to one if firm i in year t received a job training grant. For the years 1987 and 1988, the model is scrapit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0y88t 􏱕 􏱬1grantit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, 2, [13.23] where y88t is a dummy variable for 1988 and ai is the unobserved firm effect or the firm fixed effect. The unobserved effect contains such factors as average employee ability, capital, and managerial skill; these are roughly constant over a two-year period. We are concerned about ai being systematically related to whether a firm receives a grant. For example, administrators of the program might give priority to firms whose workers have lower skills. Or, the opposite problem could occur: to make the job training program appear effective, administrators may give the grants to employers with more productive workers. Actually, in this particular program, grants were awarded on a first-come, first- served basis. But whether a firm applied early for a grant could be correlated with worker productivity. In that case, an analysis using a single cross section or just a pooling of the cross sections will produce biased and inconsistent estimators. Differencing to remove ai gives ∆scrapi 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1∆granti 􏱕 ∆ui. [13.24] Therefore, we simply regress the change in the scrap rate on the change in the grant indicator. Because no firms received grants in 1987, granti1 􏱪 0 for all i, and so ∆granti 􏱪 granti2 􏱦 granti1 􏱪 granti2, which simply indicates whether the firm received a grant in 1988. How- ever, it is generally important to difference all variables (dummy variables included) be- cause this is necessary for removing ai in the unobserved effects model (13.23). Estimating the first-differenced equation using the data in JTRAIN.RAW gives ∆ scrap 􏱪 􏱦.564 􏱦 .739 ∆grant (.405) (.683) n􏱪54,R2 􏱪.022. Therefore, we estimate that having a job training grant lowered the scrap rate on average by 􏱦.739. But the estimate is not statistically different from zero. We get stronger results by using log(scrap) and estimating the percentage effect: ∆􏱱log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱦.057 􏱦 .317 ∆grant (.097) (.164) n􏱪54,R2 􏱪.067. Having a job training grant is estimated to lower the scrap rate by about 27.2%. [We obtain this estimate from equation (7.10): exp(􏱦.317) 􏱦 1 􏱴 􏱦.272.] The t statistic is about 􏱦1.93, which is marginally significant. By contrast, using pooled OLS of log(scrap) on y88 and grant gives 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 .057 (standard error 􏱪 .431). Thus, we find no significant rela- tionship between the scrap rate and the job training grant. Since this differs so much from the first-difference estimates, it suggests that firms that have lower-ability workers are more likely to receive a grant. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱱 467 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods It is useful to study the program evaluation model more generally. Let yit denote an outcome variable and let progit be a program participation dummy variable. The simplest unobserved effects model is yit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d2t 􏱕 􏱬1 progit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit. [13.25] If program participation only occurred in the second period, then the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 in the differenced equation has a very simple representation: ˆ That is, we compute the average change in y over the two time periods for the treatment and control groups. Then, 􏱬ˆ1 is the difference of these. This is the panel data version of the difference-in-differences estimator in equation (13.11) for two pooled cross sections. With panel data, we have a potentially important advantage: we can difference y across time for the same cross-sectional units. This allows us to control for person-, firm-, or city-specific effects, as the model in (13.25) makes clear. ˆ If program participation takes place in both periods, 􏱬1 cannot be written as in (13.26), but we interpret it in the same way: it is the change in the average value of y due to pro- gram participation. Controlling for time-varying factors does not change anything of significance. We simply difference those variables and include them along with ∆prog. This allows us to control for time-varying variables that might be correlated with program designation. The same differencing method works for analyzing the effects of any policy that var- ies across city or state. The following is a simple example. EXAMPLE 13.7 EFFECT OF DRUNK DRIVING LAWS ON TRAFFIC FATALITIES Many states in the United States have adopted different policies in an attempt to curb drunk driving. Two types of laws that we will study here are open container laws—which make it illegal for passengers to have open containers of alcoholic beverages—and admin- istrative per se laws—which allow courts to suspend licenses after a driver is arrested for drunk driving but before the driver is convicted. One possible analysis is to use a single cross section of states to regress driving fatalities (or those related to drunk driving) on dummy variable indicators for whether each law is present. This is unlikely to work well because states decide, through legislative processes, whether they need such laws. There- fore, the presence of laws is likely to be related to the average drunk driving fatalities in recent years. A more convincing analysis uses panel data over a time period where some states adopted new laws (and some states may have repealed existing laws). The file TRAFFIC1.RAW contains data for 1985 and 1990 for all 50 states and the District of Columbia. The dependent variable is the number of traffic deaths per 100 million miles driven (dthrte). In 1985, 19 states had open container laws, while 22 states had such laws in 1990. In 1985, 21 states had per se laws; the number had grown to 29 by 1990. Using OLS after first differencing gives ∆􏱱dthrte 􏱪 􏱦.497 􏱦 .420 ∆open 􏱦 .151 ∆admn (.052) (.206) (.117) [13.27] n􏱪51,R2 􏱪.119. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏰲􏰲 􏱬1 􏱪 ∆ytreat 􏱦 ∆ycontrol. [13.26] 468 PART 3 Advanced Topics The estimates suggest that adopting an open container law lowered the traffic fatality rate by .42, a nontrivial effect given that the average death rate in 1985 was 2.7 with a standard deviation of about .6. The estimate is statistically significant at the 5% level against a two- sided alternative. The administrative per se law has a smaller effect, and its t statistic is only 􏱦1.29; but the estimate is the sign we expect. The intercept in this equation shows that traffic fatalities fell substantially for all states over the five-year period, whether or not there were any law changes. The states that adopted an open container law over this period saw a further drop, on average, in fatality rates. Other laws might also affect traffic fatalities, such as seat belt laws, motorcycle helmet laws, and maximum speed limits. In addition, we might want to control for age and gen- der distributions, as well as measures of how influential an organization such as Mothers Against Drunk Driving is in each state. 13.5 Differencing with More Than Two Time Periods We can also use differencing with more than two time periods. For illustration, suppose we have N individuals and T 􏱪 3 time periods for each individual. A general fixed effects model is yit 􏱪􏱛1 􏱕􏱛2d2t 􏱕􏱛3d3t 􏱕􏱬1xit1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxitk 􏱕ai 􏱕uit, [13.28] for t 􏱪 1, 2, and 3. (The total number of observations is therefore 3N.) Notice that we now include two time-period dummies in addition to the intercept. It is a good idea to allow a separate intercept for each time period, especially when we have a small number of them. The base period, as always, is t 􏱪 1. The intercept for the second time period is 􏱛1 􏱕 􏱛2, and so on. We are primarily interested in 􏱬1, 􏱬2, ..., 􏱬k. If the unobserved effect ai is cor- related with any of the explanatory variables, then using pooled OLS on the three years of data results in biased and inconsistent estimates. The key assumption is that the idiosyncratic errors are uncorrelated with the explana- tory variable in each time period: Cov(xitj, uis) 􏱪 0, for all t, s, and j. [13.29] That is, the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous after we take out the unobserved effect, ai. (The strict exogeneity assumption stated in terms of a zero conditional expecta- tion is given in the chapter appendix.) Assumption (13.29) rules out cases where future explanatory variables react to current changes in the idiosyncratic errors, as must be the case if xitj is a lagged dependent variable. If we have omitted an important time-varying variable, then (13.29) is generally violated. Measurement error in one or more explanatory variables can cause (13.29) to be false, just as in Chapter 9. In Chapters 15 and 16, we will discuss what can be done in such cases. If ai is correlated with xitj, then xitj will be correlated with the composite error, vit 􏱪 ai 􏱕 uit, under (13.29). We can eliminate ai by differencing adjacent periods. In the T 􏱪 3 case, we subtract time period one from time period two and time period two from time period three. This gives Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 13.4 In Example 13.7, ∆admn 􏱪 􏱦1 for the state of Washington. Explain what this means. 469 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods ∆yit 􏱪 􏱛2∆d2t 􏱕 􏱛3∆d3t 􏱕 􏱬1∆xit1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k∆xitk 􏱕 ∆uit, [13.30] for t 􏱪 2 and 3. We do not have a differenced equation for t 􏱪 1 because there is nothing to subtract from the t 􏱪 1 equation. Now, (13.30) represents two time periods for each individual in the sample. If this equation satisfies the classical linear model assumptions, then pooled OLS gives unbiased estimators, and the usual t and F statistics are valid for hypothesis. We can also appeal to asymptotic results. The important requirement for OLS to be consistent is that ∆uit is uncorrelated with ∆xitj for all j and t 􏱪 2 and 3. This is the natural extension from the two time period case. Notice how (13.30) contains the differences in the year dummies, d2t and d3t. For t 􏱪 2,∆d2t 􏱪1and∆d3t 􏱪0;fort􏱪3,∆d2t 􏱪􏱦1and∆d3t 􏱪1.Therefore,(13.30)does not contain an intercept. This is inconvenient for certain purposes, including the computa- tion of R-squared. Unless the time intercepts in the original model (13.28) are of direct interest—they rarely are—it is better to estimate the first-differenced equation with an intercept and a single time-period dummy, usually for the third period. In other words, the equation becomes ∆yit 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮3d3t 􏱕 􏱬1∆xit1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k∆xitk 􏱕 ∆uit, for t 􏱪 2 and 3. The estimates of the 􏱬j are identical in either formulation. With more than three time periods, things are similar. If we have the same T time periods for each of N cross-sectional units, we say that the data set is a balanced panel: we have the same time periods for all individuals, firms, cities, and so on. When T is small relative to N, we should include a dummy variable for each time period to account for secular changes that are not being modeled. Therefore, after first differencing, the equa- tion looks like ∆yit 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱮3d3t 􏱕􏱮4d4t 􏱕...􏱕􏱮TdTt 􏱕􏱬1∆xit1 􏱕... 􏱕 􏱬k∆xitk 􏱕 ∆uit, t 􏱪 2, 3, ..., T, [13.31] where we have T 􏱦 1 time periods on each unit i for the first-differenced equation. The total number of observations is N(T 􏱦 1). It is simple to estimate (13.31) by pooled OLS, provided the observations have been properly organized and the differencing carefully done. To facilitate first differenc- ing, the data file should consist of NT records. The first T records are for the first cross- sectional observation, arranged chronologically; the second T records are for the second cross-sectional observations, arranged chronologically; and so on. Then, we compute the differences, with the change from t 􏱦 1 to t stored in the time t record. Therefore, the dif- ferences for t 􏱪 1 should be missing values for all N cross-sectional observations. Without doing this, you run the risk of using bogus observations in the regression analysis. An invalid observation is created when the last observation for, say, person i 􏱦 1 is subtracted from the first observation for person i. If you do the regression on the differenced data, and NT or NT 􏱦 1 observations are reported, then you forgot to set the t 􏱪 1 observations as missing. When using more than two time periods, we must assume that ∆uit is uncorrelated over time for the usual standard errors and test statistics to be valid. This assumption is sometimes reasonable, but it does not follow if we assume that the original idiosyncratic errors, uit, are uncorrelated over time (an assumption we will use in Chapter 14). In fact, if we assume the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 470 PART 3 Advanced Topics uit are serially uncorrelated with constant variance, then the correlation between ∆uit and ∆ui, t 􏱕1 can be shown to be 􏱦.5. If uit follows a stable AR(1) model, then ∆uit will be serially corre- lated. Only when uit follows a random walk will ∆uit be serially uncorrelated. It is easy to test for serial correlation in the first-differenced equation. Let rit 􏱪 ∆uit denote the first difference of the original error. If rit follows the AR(1) model rit 􏱪 􏰴ri,t􏱦1 􏱕 eit, then we can easily test H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0. First, we estimate (13.31) by pooled OLS and obtain the residuals, rˆit. Then, we run a simple pooled OLS regression of rˆit on rˆi, t􏱦1, t 􏱪 3, ..., T, i 􏱪 1, ..., N, and compute a standard t test for the coefficient on rˆi,t􏱦1. (Or we can make the t statis- tic robust to heteroskedasticity.) The coefficient 􏰴ˆ on rˆi, t􏱦1 is a consistent estimator of 􏰴. Because we are using the lagged residual, we lose another time period. For example, if we started with T 􏱪 3, the differenced equation has two time periods, and the test for serial correlation is just a cross-sectional regression of the residuals from the third time period on the residuals from the second time period. We will give an example later. We can correct for the presence of AR(1) serial correlation in rit by using feasible GLS. Essentially, within each cross-sectional observation, we would use the Prais- Winsten transformation based on ˆ􏰴 described in the previous paragraph. (We clearly pre- fer Prais-Winsten to Cochrane-Orcutt here, as dropping the first time period would now mean losing N cross-sectional observations.) Unfortunately, standard packages that per- form AR(1) corrections for time series regressions will not work. Standard Prais-Winsten methods will treat the observations as if they followed an AR(1) process across i and t; this makes no sense, as we are assuming the observations are independent across i. Corrections to the OLS standard errors that allow arbitrary forms of serial correlation (and heteroskedasticity) can be computed when N is large (and N should be notably larger than T ). A detailed treatment of standard errors and test statistics that are robust to any forms of serial correlation and het- eroskedasticity is beyond the scope of this text; see, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10). Nevertheless, such statistics are easy to compute in many economet- rics software packages, and the appendix contains an intuitive discussion. If there is no serial correlation in the errors, the usual methods for dealing with het- eroskedasticity are valid. We can use the Breusch-Pagan and White tests for heteroskedas- ticity from Chapter 8, and we can also compute robust standard errors. Differencing more than two years of panel data is very useful for policy analysis, as shown by the following example. EXAMPLE 13.8 EFFECT OF ENTERPRISE ZONES ON UNEMPLOYMENT CLAIMS Papke (1994) studied the effect of the Indiana enterprise zone (EZ) program on unemploy- ment claims. She analyzed 22 cities in Indiana over the period from 1980 to 1988. Six enterprise zones were designated in 1984, and four more were assigned in 1985. Twelve of the cities in the sample did not receive an enterprise zone over this period; they served as the control group. A simple policy evaluation model is log(uclmsit) 􏱪 􏰩t 􏱕 􏱬1ezit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 13.5 Does serial correlation in ∆uit cause the first-differenced estimator to be biased and inconsistent? Why is serial correlation a concern? 471 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods where uclmsit is the number of unemployment claims filed during year t in city i. The parameter 􏰩t just denotes a different intercept for each time period. Generally, unemploy- ment claims were falling statewide over this period, and this should be reflected in the different year intercepts. The binary variable ezit is equal to one if city i at time t was an enterprise zone; we are interested in 􏱬1. The unobserved effect ai represents fixed factors that affect the economic climate in city i. Because enterprise zone designation was not determined randomly—enterprise zones are usually economically depressed areas—it is likely that ezit and ai are positively correlated (high ai means higher unemployment claims, which lead to a higher chance of being given an EZ). Thus, we should difference the equation to eliminate ai: ∆log(uclmsit) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1d82t 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱮7d88t 􏱕 􏱬1∆ezit 􏱕 ∆uit. [13.32] The dependent variable in this equation, the change in log(uclmsit), is the approximate annual growth rate in unemployment claims from year t 􏱦 1 to t. We can estimate this equation for the years 1981 to 1988 using the data in EZUNEM.RAW; the total sample size is 22·8 􏱪 176. The estimate of 􏱬1 is 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏱦.182 (standard error 􏱪 .078). Therefore, it appears that the presence of an EZ causes about a 16.6% [exp(􏱦.182) 􏱦 1 􏱴 􏱦.166] fall in unemployment claims. This is an economically large and statistically significant effect. There is no evidence of heteroskedasticity in the equation: the Breusch-Pagan F test yields F 􏱪 .85, p-value 􏱪 .557. However, when we add the lagged OLS residuals to the differenced equation (and lose the year 1981), we get 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.197 (t 􏱪 􏱦2.44), so there is evidence of minimal negative serial correlation in the first-differenced errors. Unlike with positive serial correlation, the usual OLS standard errors may not greatly understate the correct standard errors when the errors are negatively correlated (see Section 12.1). Thus, the significance of the enterprise zone dummy variable will probably not be affected. EXAMPLE 13.9 COUNTY CRIME RATES IN NORTH CAROLINA Cornwell and Trumbull (1994) used data on 90 counties in North Carolina, for the years 1981 through 1987, to estimate an unobserved effects model of crime; the data are contained in CRIME4.RAW. Here, we estimate a simpler version of their model, and we difference the equation over time to eliminate ai, the unobserved effect. (Cornwell and Trumbull use a different transformation, which we will cover in Chapter 14.) Various factors including geographical location, attitudes toward crime, historical records, and reporting conventions might be contained in ai. The crime rate is number of crimes per person, prbarr is the estimated probability of arrest, prbconv is the estimated probability of conviction (given an arrest), prbpris is the probability of serving time in prison (given a conviction), avgsen is the average sentence length served, and polpc is the number of police officers per capita. As is standard in criminometric studies, we use the logs of all variables to estimate elasticities. We also include a full set of year dummies to con- trol for state trends in crime rates. We can use the years 1982 through 1987 to estimate the differenced equation. The quantities in parentheses are the usual OLS standard Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 472 PART 3 Advanced Topics errors; the quantities in brackets are standard errors robust to both serial correlation and heteroskedasticity: ∆􏱱log(crmrte)􏱪 .008 􏱦 .100 d83 􏱦 .048 d84 􏱦 .005 d85 (.017) (.024) (.024) (.023) [.014] [.022] [.020] [.025] 􏱕 .028 d86 􏱕 .041 d87 􏱦 .327 ∆log(prbarr) (.024) (.024) (.030) [.021] [.024] [.056] 􏱦 .238 ∆log(prbconv) 􏱦 .165 ∆log(prbpris) (.018) (.026) [.040] [.046] 􏱦 .022 ∆log(avgsen) 􏱕 .398 ∆log(polpc) (.022) (.027) [.026] - [.103] n 􏱪 540, R2 􏱪 .433,R2 􏱪 .422. The three probability variables—of arrest, conviction, and serving prison time—all have the expected sign, and all are statistically significant. For example, a 1% increase in the probability of arrest is predicted to lower the crime rate by about .33%. The average sen- tence variable shows a modest deterrent effect, but it is not statistically significant. The coefficient on the police per capita variable is somewhat surprising and is a fea- ture of most studies that seek to explain crime rates. Interpreted causally, it says that a 1% increase in police per capita increases crime rates by about .4%. (The usual t statistic is very large, almost 15.) It is hard to believe that having more police officers causes more crime. What is going on here? There are at least two possibilities. First, the crime rate variable is calculated from reported crimes. It might be that, when there are addi- tional police, more crimes are reported. Second, the police variable might be endogenous in the equation for other reasons: counties may enlarge the police force when they expect crime rates to increase. In this case, (13.33) cannot be interpreted in a causal fashion. In Chapters 15 and 16, we will cover models and estimation methods that can account for this additional form of endogeneity. The special case of the White test for heteroskedasticity in Section 8.3 gives F 􏱪 75.48 and p-value 􏱪 .0000, so there is strong evidence of heteroskedasticity. (Technically, this test is not valid if there is also serial correlation, but it is strongly suggestive.) Testing for AR(1) serial correlation yields 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.233, t 􏱪 􏱦4.77, so negative serial correlation exists. The standard errors in brackets adjust for serial correlation and heteroskedasticity. [We will not give the details of this; the calculations are similar to those described in Section 12.5 and are carried out by many econometric packages. See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10) for more dis- cussion.] No variables lose statistical significance, but the t statistics on the significant deter- rent variables get notably smaller. For example, the t statistic on the probability of conviction variable goes from 􏱦13.22 using the usual OLS standard error to 􏱦6.10 using the fully robust standard error. Equivalently, the confidence intervals constructed using the robust standard errors will, appropriately, be much wider than those based on the usual OLS standard errors. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. [13.33] 473 CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods Naturally, we can apply the Chow test to panel data models estimated by first differencing. As in the case of pooled cross sections, we rarely want to test whether the intercepts are constant over time; for many reasons, we expect the intercepts to be differ- ent. Much more interesting is to test whether slope coefficients have changed over time, and we can easily carry out such tests by interacting the explanatory variables of interest with time-period dummy variables. Interestingly, while we cannot estimate the slopes on variables that do not change over time, we can test whether the partial effects of time- constant variables have changed over time. As an illustration, suppose we observe three years of data on a random sample of people working in 2000, 2002, and 2004, and specify the model (for the log of wage, lwage), lwageit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1d02t 􏱕 􏱛2d04t 􏱕 􏱬1 femalei 􏱕 􏰸1d02t femalei 􏱕 􏰸2d04t femalei 􏱕 zit􏲇 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where zit􏲇 is shorthand for other explanatory variables included in the model and their coefficients. When we first difference, we eliminate the intercept for 2000, 􏱬0, and also the gender wage gap for 2000, 􏱬1. However, the change in d01t femalei is (∆d01t)femalei, which does not drop out. Consequently, we can estimate how the wage gap has changed in 2002 and 2004 relative to 2000, and we can test whether 􏰸1 􏱪 0, or 􏰸2 􏱪 0, or both. We might also ask whether the union wage premium has changed over time, in which case we include in the model unionit, d02tunionit, and d04tunionit. The coefficients on all of these explanatory variables can be estimated because unionit would presumably have some time variation. If one tries to estimate a model containing interactions by differencing by hand, it can be a bit tricky. For example, in the previous equation with union status, we must sim- ply difference the interaction terms, d02tunionit and d04tunionit. We cannot compute the proper differences as, say, d02t∆unionit and d04t∆unionit, or even replacing d02t and d04t with their first differences. As a general comment, it is important to return to the original model and remember that the differencing is used to eliminate ai. It is easiest to use a built-in command that al- lows first differencing as an option in panel data analysis. (We will see some of the other options in Chapter 14.) Potential Pitfalls in First Differencing Panel Data In this and previous sections, we have argued that differencing panel data over time, in order to eliminate a time-constant unobserved effect, is a valuable method for obtaining causal effects. Nevertheless, differencing is not free of difficulties. We have already dis- cussed potential problems with the method when the key explanatory variables do not vary much over time (and the method is useless for explanatory variables that never vary over time). Unfortunately, even when we do have sufficient time variation in the xitj, first- differenced (FD) estimation can be subject to serious biases. We have already mentioned that strict exogeneity of the regressors is a critical assumption. Unfortunately, as discussed in Wooldridge (2010, Section 11.1), having more time periods generally does not reduce the inconsistency in the FD estimator when the regressors are not strictly exogenous (say, if yi,t􏱦1 is included among the xitj). Another important drawback to the FD estimator is that it can be worse than pooled OLS if one or more of the explanatory variables is subject to measurement error, especially Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 474 PART 3 Advanced Topics the classical errors-in-variables model discussed in Section 9.3. Differencing a poorly measured regressor reduces its variation relative to its correlation with the differenced error caused by classical measurement error, resulting in a potentially sizable bias. Solving such problems can be very difficult. See Section 15.8 and Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 11). Summary We have studied methods for analyzing independently pooled cross-sectional and panel data sets. Independent cross sections arise when different random samples are obtained in differ- ent time periods (usually years). OLS using pooled data is the leading method of estimation, and the usual inference procedures are available, including corrections for heteroskedasticity. (Serial correlation is not an issue because the samples are independent across time.) Because of the time series dimension, we often allow different time intercepts. We might also interact time dummies with certain key variables to see how they have changed over time. This is especially important in the policy evaluation literature for natural experiments. Panel data sets are being used more and more in applied work, especially for policy analysis. These are data sets where the same cross-sectional units are followed over time. Panel data sets are most useful when controlling for time-constant unobserved features—of people, firms, cities, and so on—which we think might be correlated with the explanatory variables in our model. One way to remove the unobserved effect is to difference the data in adjacent time periods. Then, a standard OLS analysis on the differences can be used. Using two periods of data results in a cross-sectional regression of the differenced data. The usual inference procedures are asymptotically valid under homoskedasticity; exact inference is available under normality. For more than two time periods, we can use pooled OLS on the differenced data; we lose the first time period because of the differencing. In addition to homoskedasticity, we must assume that the differenced errors are serially uncorrelated in order to apply the usual t and F statistics. (The chapter appendix contains a careful listing of the assumptions.) Naturally, any variable that is constant over time drops out of the analysis. Key Terms Average Treatment Effect Balanced Panel Clustering Composite Error Difference-in-Differences Estimator First-Differenced Equation First-Differenced Estimator Fixed Effect Problems Fixed Effects Model Heterogeneity Bias Idiosyncratic Error Independently Pooled Cross Section Longitudinal Data Natural Experiment Panel Data Quasi-Experiment Strict Exogeneity Unobserved Effect Unobserved Effects Model Unobserved Heterogeneity Year Dummy Variables 1 In Example 13.1, assume that the averages of all factors other than educ have remained constant over time and that the average level of education is 12.2 for the 1972 sample and 13.3 in the 1984 sample. Using the estimates in Table 13.1, find the estimated change in Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 475 average fertility between 1972 and 1984. (Be sure to account for the intercept change and the change in average education.) 2 Using the data in KIELMC.RAW, the following equations were estimated using the years 1978 and 1981:􏱱log(price) 􏱪 11.49 􏱦 .547 nearinc 􏱕 .394 y81􏱳nearinc (.26) (.058) (.080) n􏱪321,R2 􏱪.220 and 􏱱log(price) 􏱪 11.18 􏱕 .563 y81 􏱦 .403 y81􏱳nearinc (.27) (.044) (.067) n 􏱪 321, R2 􏱪 .337. Compare the estimates on the interaction term y81􏱳nearinc with those from equation (13.9). Why are the estimates so different? 3 Why can we not use first differences when we have independent cross sections in two years (as opposed to panel data)? 4 If we think that 􏱬1 is positive in (13.14) and that ∆ui and ∆unemi are negatively correlated, what is the bias in the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 in the first-differenced equation? [Hint: Review equation (5.4).] 5 Suppose that we want to estimate the effect of several variables on annual saving and that we have a panel data set on individuals collected on January 31, 1990, and January 31, 1992. If we include a year dummy for 1992 and use first differencing, can we also include age in the original model? Explain. 6 In 1985, neither Florida nor Georgia had laws banning open alcohol containers in vehicle passenger compartments. By 1990, Florida had passed such a law, but Georgia had not. (i) Suppose you can collect random samples of the driving-age population in both states, for 1985 and 1990. Let arrest be a binary variable equal to unity if a person was arrested for drunk driving during the year. Without controlling for any other factors, write down a linear probability model that allows you to test whether the open container law reduced the probability of being arrested for drunk driving. Which coefficient in your model measures the effect of the law? (ii) Why might you want to control for other factors in the model? What might some of these factors be? (iii) Now,supposethatyoucanonlycollectdatafor1985and1990atthecountylevel for the two states. The dependent variable would be the fraction of licensed drivers arrested for drunk driving during the year. How does this data structure differ from the individual-level data described in part (i)? What econometric method would you use? 7 (i) Using the data in INJURY.RAW for Kentucky, we find the estimated equation when afchnge is d􏱱ropped from (13.12) is log(durat) 􏱪 1.129 􏱕 .253 highearn 􏱕 .198 afchnge·highearn (0.022) (.042) (.052) n 􏱪 5,626, R2 􏱪 .021. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 476 PART 3 Advanced Topics Is it surprising that the estimate on the interaction is fairly close to that in (13.12)? Explain. (ii) 􏱱When afchnge is included but highearn is dropped, the result is log(durat) 􏱪 1.233 􏱦 .100 afchnge 􏱕 .447 afchnge·highearn (0.023) (.040) (.050) n 􏱪 5,626, R2 􏱪 .016. Why is the coefficient on the interaction term now so much larger than in (13.12)? [Hint: In equation (13.10), what is the assumption being made about the treatment and control groups if 􏱬1 􏱪 0?] Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in FERTIL1.RAW for this exercise. (i) In the equation estimated in Example 13.1, test whether living environment at age 16 has an effect on fertility. (The base group is large city.) Report the value of the F statistic and the p-value. (ii) Test whether region of the country at age 16 (South is the base group) has an effect on fertility. (iii) Let u be the error term in the population equation. Suppose you think that the variance of u changes over time (but not with educ, age, and so on). A model that captures this is u2 􏱪􏰸0 􏱕􏰸1y74􏱕􏰸2y76􏱕...􏱕􏰸6y84􏱕v. Using this model, test for heteroskedasticity in u. (Hint: Your F test should have 6 and 1,122 degrees of freedom.) (iv) Addtheinteractiontermsy74􏱳educ,y76􏱳educ,...,y84·eductothemodelestimated in Table 13.1. Explain what these terms represent. Are they jointly significant? C2 Use the data in CPS78_85.RAW for this exercise. (i) How do you interpret the coefficient on y85 in equation (13.2)? Does it have an interesting interpretation? (Be careful here; you must account for the interaction terms y85􏱳educ and y85􏱳female.) (ii) Holding other factors fixed, what is the estimated percent increase in nominal wage for a male with 12 years of education? Propose a regression to obtain a con- fidence interval for this estimate. [Hint: To get the confidence interval, replace y85􏱳educ with y85􏱳(educ 􏱦 12); refer to Example 6.3.] (iii) Reestimate equation (13.2) but let all wages be measured in 1978 dollars. In par- ticular, define the real wage as rwage 􏱪 wage for 1978 and as rwage 􏱪 wage/1.65 for 1985. Now, use log(rwage) in place of log(wage) in estimating (13.2). Which coefficients differ from those in equation (13.2)? (iv) Explain why the R-squared from your regression in part (iii) is not the same as in equation (13.2). (Hint: The residuals, and therefore the sum of squared residuals, from the two regressions are identical.) (v) Describe how union participation changed from 1978 to 1985. (vi) Starting with equation (13.2), test whether the union wage differential changed over time. (This should be a simple t test.) (vii) Do your findings in parts (v) and (vi) conflict? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 477 C3 Use the data in KIELMC.RAW for this exercise. (i) The variable dist is the distance from each home to the incinerator site, in feet. Consider the model log(price) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 y81 􏱕 􏱬1log(dist) 􏱕 􏱛1y81􏱳log(dist) 􏱕 u. If building the incinerator reduces the value of homes closer to the site, what is the sign of 􏱛1? What does it mean if 􏱬1 􏱰 0? (ii) Estimate the model from part (i) and report the results in the usual form. Interpret the coefficient on y81􏱳log(dist). What do you conclude? (iii) Add age, age2, rooms, baths, log(intst), log(land), and log(area) to the equation. Now, what do you conclude about the effect of the incinerator on housing values? (iv) Whyisthecoefficientonlog(dist)positiveandstatisticallysignificantinpart(ii)but not in part (iii)? What does this say about the controls used in part (iii)? C4 Use the data in INJURY.RAW for this exercise. (i) Using the data for Kentucky, reestimate equation (13.12), adding as explanatory variables male, married, and a full set of industry and injury type dummy varia- bles. How does the estimate on afchnge􏱳highearn change when these other factors are controlled for? Is the estimate still statistically significant? (ii) What do you make of the small R-squared from part (i)? Does this mean the equa- tion is useless? (iii) Estimate equation (13.12) using the data for Michigan. Compare the estimates on the interaction term for Michigan and Kentucky. Is the Michigan estimate statisti- cally significant? What do you make of this? C5 Use the data in RENTAL.RAW for this exercise. The data for the years 1980 and 1990 include rental prices and other variables for college towns. The idea is to see whether a stronger presence of students affects rental rates. The unobserved effects model is log(rentit) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0 y90t 􏱕 􏱬1log( popit) 􏱕 􏱬2log(avgincit) 􏱕 􏱬3 pctstuit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where pop is city population, avginc is average income, and pctstu is student population as a percentage of city population (during the school year). (i) Estimate the equation by pooled OLS and report the results in standard form. What do you make of the estimate on the 1990 dummy variable? What do you get for 􏱬ˆpctstu? (ii) Are the standard errors you report in part (i) valid? Explain. (iii) Now, difference the equation and estimate by OLS. Compare your estimate of 􏱬pctstu with that from part (ii). Does the relative size of the student population appear to affect rental prices? (iv) Obtain the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the first-differenced equa- tion in part (iii). Does this change your conclusions? C6 Use CRIME3.RAW for this exercise. (i) In the model of Example 13.6, test the hypothesis H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2. (Hint: Define 􏰩1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱦 􏱬2 and write 􏱬1 in terms of 􏰩1 and 􏱬2. Substitute this into the equation and then rearrange. Do a t test on 􏰩1.) (ii) If 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2, show that the differenced equation can be written as Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 478 PART 3 Advanced Topics ∆log(crimei) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1∆avgclri 􏱕 ∆ui , where 􏱛1 􏱪 2􏱬1 and avgclri 􏱪 (clrprci,􏱦1 􏱕 clrprci,􏱦2)/2 is the average clear-up percentage over the previous two years. (iii) Estimate the equation from part (ii). Compare the adjusted R-squared with that in (13.22). Which model would you finally use? C7 Use GPA3.RAW for this exercise. The data set is for 366 student-athletes from a large university for fall and spring semesters. [A similar analysis is in Maloney and McCormick (1993), but here we use a true panel data set.] Because you have two terms of data for each student, an unobserved effects model is appropriate. The primary question of interest is this: Do athletes perform more poorly in school during the semester their sport is in season? (i) Use pooled OLS to estimate a model with term GPA (trmgpa) as the dependent variable. The explanatory variables are spring, sat, hsperc, female, black, white, frstsem, tothrs, crsgpa, and season. Interpret the coefficient on season. Is it statis- tically significant? (ii) Most of the athletes who play their sport only in the fall are football players. Sup- pose the ability levels of football players differ systematically from those of other athletes. If ability is not adequately captured by SAT score and high school per- centile, explain why the pooled OLS estimators will be biased. (iii) Now, use the data differenced across the two terms. Which variables drop out? Now, test for an in-season effect. (iv) Can you think of one or more potentially important, time-varying variables that have been omitted from the analysis? C8 VOTE2.RAW includes panel data on House of Representatives elections in 1988 and 1990. Only winners from 1988 who are also running in 1990 appear in the sample; these are the incumbents. An unobserved effects model explaining the share of the incum- bent’s vote in terms of expenditures by both candidates is voteit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d90t 􏱕 􏱬1log(inexpit) 􏱕 􏱬2log(chexpit) 􏱕 􏱬3incshrit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where incshrit is the incumbent’s share of total campaign spending (in percentage form). The unobserved effect ai contains characteristics of the incumbent—such as “quality”—as well as things about the district that are constant. The incum- bent’s gender and party are constant over time, so these are subsumed in ai. We are interested in the effect of campaign expenditures on election outcomes. (i) Difference the given equation across the two years and estimate the differenced equation by OLS. Which variables are individually significant at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative? (ii) In the equation from part (i), test for joint significance of ∆log(inexp) and ∆log(chexp). Report the p-value. (iii) Reestimate the equation from part (i) using ∆incshr as the only independent vari- able. Interpret the coefficient on ∆incshr. For example, if the incumbent’s share of spending increases by 10 percentage points, how is this predicted to affect the incumbent’s share of the vote? (iv) Redo part (iii), but now use only the pairs that have repeat challengers. [This al- lows us to control for characteristics of the challengers as well, which would be in ai. Levitt (1994) conducts a much more extensive analysis.] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 479 C9 Use CRIME4.RAW for this exercise. (i) Add the logs of each wage variable in the data set and estimate the model by first differencing. How does including these variables affect the coefficients on the criminal justice variables in Example 13.9? (ii) Do the wage variables in (i) all have the expected sign? Are they jointly signifi- cant? Explain. C10 For this exercise, we use JTRAIN.RAW to determine the effect of the job training grant on hours of job training per employee. The basic model for the three years is hrsempit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1d88t 􏱕 􏱛2d89t 􏱕 􏱬1grantit 􏱕 􏱬2granti, t􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬3log(employit) 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit. (i) Estimate the equation using first differencing. How many firms are used in the es- timation? How many total observations would be used if each firm had data on all variables (in particular, hrsemp) for all three time periods? (ii) Interpret the coefficient on grant and comment on its significance. (iii) Is it surprising that grant􏱦1 is insignificant? Explain. (iv) Do larger firms train their employees more or less, on average? How big are the differences in training? C11 The file MATHPNL.RAW contains panel data on school districts in Michigan for the years 1992 through 1998. It is the district-level analogue of the school-level data used by Papke (2005). The response variable of interest in this question is math4, the percentage of fourth graders in a district receiving a passing score on a standardized math test. The key explanatory variable is rexpp, which is real expenditures per pupil in the district. The amounts are in 1997 dollars. The spending variable will appear in logarithmic form. (i) Consider the static unobserved effects model math4it 􏱪 􏱛1y93t 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛6 y98t 􏱕 􏱬1log(rexppit) 􏱕 􏱬2log(enrolit) 􏱕 􏱬3lunchit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where enrolit is total district enrollment and lunchit is the percentage of students in the district eligible for the school lunch program. (So lunchit is a pretty good measure of the district-wide poverty rate.) Argue that 􏱬1/10 is the percentage point change in math4it when real per-student spending increases by roughly 10%. (ii) Use first differencing to estimate the model in part (i). The simplest approach is to allow an intercept in the first-differenced equation and to include dummy variables for the years 1994 through 1998. Interpret the coefficient on the spending variable. (iii) Now, add one lag of the spending variable to the model and reestimate using first differencing. Note that you lose another year of data, so you are only using changes starting in 1994. Discuss the coefficients and significance on the current and lagged spending variables. (iv) Obtain heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors for the first-differenced regres- sion in part (iii). How do these standard errors compare with those from part (iii) for the spending variables? (v) Now, obtain standard errors robust to both heteroskedasticity and serial correla- tion. What does this do to the significance of the lagged spending variable? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 480 PART 3 Advanced Topics (vi) Verify that the differenced errors rit 􏱪 ∆uit have negative serial correlation by carrying out a test of AR(1) serial correlation. (vii) Based on a fully robust joint test, does it appear necessary to include the enrollment and lunch variables in the model? C12 Use the data in MURDER.RAW for this exercise. (i) Using the years 1990 and 1993, estimate the equation mrdrteit 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1d93t 􏱕 􏱬1execit 􏱕 􏱬2unemit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, 2 by pooled OLS and report the results in the usual form. Do not worry that the usual OLS standard errors are inappropriate because of the presence of ai. Do you estimate a deterrent effect of capital punishment? (ii) Compute the FD estimates (use only the differences from 1990 to 1993; you should have 51 observations in the FD regression). Now what do you conclude about a deterrent effect? (iii) In the FD regression from part (ii), obtain the residuals, say, eˆi. Run the Breusch-Pagan regression eˆ2i on ∆execi, ∆unemi and compute the F test for heteroskedasticity. Do the same for the special case of the White test [that is, 22 regress eˆ on yˆ , yˆ , where the fitted values are from part (ii)]. What do you con- clude about heteroskedasticity in the FD equation? (iv) Run the same regression from part (ii), but obtain the heteroskedasticity-robust t statistics. What happens? (v) Which t statistic on ∆execi do you feel more comfortable relying on, the usual one or the heteroskedasticity-robust one? Why? C13 Use the data in WAGEPAN.RAW for this exercise. (i) Consider the unobserved effects model lwageit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1d81t 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛7 d87t 􏱕 􏱬1educi 􏱕 􏰸1d81t educi 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛7d87t educi 􏱕 􏱬2unionit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where ai is allowed to be correlated with educi and unionit. Which parameters can you estimate using first differencing? (ii) Estimate the equation from part (i) by FD, and test the null hypothesis that the re- turn to education has not changed over time. (iii) Test the hypothesis from part (ii) using a fully robust test, that is, one that allows arbitrary heteroskedasticity and serial correlation in the FD errors, ∆uit. Does your conclusion change? (iv) Now allow the union differential to change over time (along with education) and estimate the equation by FD. What is the estimated union differential in 1980? What about 1987? Is the difference statistically significant? (v) Test the null hypothesis that the union differential has not changed over time, and discuss your results in light of your answer to part (iv). C14 Use the data in JTRAIN3.RAW for this question. (i) Estimate the simple regression model re78 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1train 􏱕 u, and report the results in the usual form. Based on this regression, does it appear that job training, which took place in 1976 and 1977, had a positive effect on real labor earnings in 1978? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. iii CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 481 (ii) Now use the change in real labor earnings, cre 􏱪 re78 􏱦 re75, as the dependent variable. (We need not difference train because we assume there was no job train- ing prior to 1975. That is, if we define ctrain 􏱪 train78 􏱦 train75 then ctrain 􏱪 train78 because train75 􏱪 0.) Now what is the estimated effect of training? Dis- cuss how it compares with the estimate in part (i). (iii) Findthe95%confidenceintervalforthetrainingeffectusingtheusualOLSstandard error and the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error, and describe your findings. C15 The data set HAPPINESS.RAW contains independently pooled cross sections for the even years from 1994 through 2006, obtained from the General Social Survey. The dependent variable for this problem is a measure of “happiness,” vhappy, which is a binary variable equal to one if the person reports being “very happy” (as opposed to just “pretty happy” or “not too happy”). (i) Which year has the largest number of observations? Which has the smallest? What is the percentage of people in the sample reporting they are “very happy”? (ii) Regress vhappy on all of the year dummies, leaving out y94 so that 1994 is the base year. Compute a heteroskedasticity-robust statistic of the null hypothesis that the pro- portion of very happy people has not changed over time. What is the p-value of the test? (iii) Totheregressioninpart(ii),addthedummyvariablesoccattendandregattend.Inter- pret their coefficients. (Remember, the coefficients are interpreted relative to a base group.) How would you summarize the effects of church attendance on happiness? (iv) Define a variable, say highinc, equal to one if family income is above $25,000. (Unfortunately, the same threshold is used in each year, and so inflation is not accounted for. Also, $25,000 is hardly what one would consider “high income.”) Include highinc, unem10, educ, and teens in the regression in part (iii). Is the coefficient on regattend affected much? What about its statistical significance? (v) Discuss the signs, magnitudes, and statistical significance of the four new variables in part (iv). Do the estimates make sense? (vi) Controlling for the factors in part (iv), do there appear to be differences in happiness by gender or race? Justify your answer. APPENDIX 13A 13A.1 Assumptions for Pooled OLS Using First Differences In this appendix, we provide careful statements of the assumptions for the first- differencing estimator. Verification of these claims is somewhat involved, but it can be found in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10). Assumption FD.1 For each i, the model is yit 􏱪 􏱬1xit1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xitk 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, ..., T, where the 􏱬j are the parameters to estimate and ai is the unobserved effect. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 482 PART 3 Advanced Topics Assumption FD.2 We have a random sample from the cross section. Assumption FD.3 Each explanatory variable changes over time (for at least some i ), and no perfect linear relationships exist among the explanatory variables. For the next assumption, it is useful to let Xi denote the explanatory variables for all time periods for cross-sectional observation i; thus, Xi contains xitj, t 􏱪 1, ..., T, j 􏱪 1, ..., k. Assumption FD.4 For each t, the expected value of the idiosyncratic error given the explanatory variables in all time periods and the unobserved effect is zero: E(uit􏰫Xi, ai) 􏱪 0. When Assumption FD.4 holds, we sometimes say that the xitj are strictly exogenous con- ditional on the unobserved effect. The idea is that, once we control for ai, there is no cor- relation between the xisj and the remaining idiosyncratic error, uit, for all s and t. As stated, Assumption FD.4 is stronger than necessary. We use this form of the as- sumption because it emphasizes that we are interested in the equation E(yit􏰫Xi, ai) 􏱪 E(yit􏰫xit, ai) 􏱪 􏱬1xit1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xitk 􏱕 ai , so that the 􏱬j measure partial effects of the observed explanatory variables holding fixed, or “controlling for,” the unobserved effect, ai. Nevertheless, an important implication of FD.4, and one that is sufficient for the unbiasedness of the FD estimator, is E(∆uit􏰫Xi) 􏱪 0, t 􏱪 2, ..., T. In fact, for consistency we can simply assume that ∆xitj is uncorrelated with ∆uit for all t 􏱪 2, ..., T and j 􏱪 1, ..., k. See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10) for further discussion. Under these first four assumptions, the first-difference estimators are unbiased. The key assumption is FD.4, which is strict exogeneity of the explanatory variables. Under these same assumptions, we can also show that the FD estimator is consistent with a fixed T and as N 􏱽 􏱵 (and perhaps more generally). The next two assumptions ensure that the standard errors and test statistics resulting from pooled OLS on the first differences are (asymptotically) valid. Assumption FD.5 The variance of the differenced errors, conditional on all explanatory variables, is constant: Var(􏰧uit􏰫Xi) 􏱪 􏱧2, t 􏱪 2, ..., T. Assumption FD.6 For all t 􏱻 s, the differences in the idiosyncratic errors are uncorrelated (conditional on all explanatory variables): Cov(􏰧uit, 􏰧uis􏰫Xi) 􏱪 0, t 􏱻 s. Assumption FD.5 ensures that the differenced errors, ∆uit, are homoskedastic. Assumption FD.6 states that the differenced errors are serially uncorrelated, which means that the uit follow a random walk across time (see Chapter 11). Under Assumptions FD.1 through FD.6, the FD estimator of the 􏱬j is the best linear unbiased estimator (conditional on the explanatory variables). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 13 Pooling Cross Sections across Time: Simple Panel Data Methods 483 Assumption FD.7 Conditional on Xi, the 􏰧uit are independent and identically distributed normal random variables. When we add Assumption FD.7, the FD estimators are normally distributed, and the t and F statistics from pooled OLS on the differences have exact t and F distributions. Without FD.7, we can rely on the usual asymptotic approximations. 13A.2 Computing Standard Errors Robust to Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form Because the FD estimator is consistent as N 􏱽 ∞ under Assumptions FD.1 through FD.4, it would be very handy to have a simple method of obtaining proper standard errors and test statistics that allow for any kind of serial correlation or heteroskedasticity in the FD errors, eit 􏱪 ∆uit. Fortunately, provided N is moderately large, and T is not “too large,” fully robust standard errors and test statistics are readily available. As mentioned in the text, a detailed treatment is above the level of this text. The technical arguments com- bine the insights described in Chapters 8 and 12, where statistics robust to heteroske- dasticity and serial correlation are discussed. Actually, there is one important advantage with panel data: because we have a (large) cross section, we can allow unrestricted serial correlation in the errors {eit} provided T is not too large. We can contrast this situation with the Newey-West approach in Section 12.5, where the estimated covariances must be downweighted as the observations get farther apart in time. The general approach to obtaining fully robust standard errors and test statistics in the context of panel data is known as clustering, and ideas have been borrowed from the cluster sampling literature. The idea is that each cross-sectional unit is defined as a clus- ter of observations over time, and arbitrary correlation—serial correlation—and changing variances are allowed within each cluster. Because of the relationship to cluster sampling, many econometric software packages have options for clustering standard errors and test statistics. Most commands look something like regress cy cx1 cx2 ... cxk, cluster(id) where “id” is a variable containing unique identifiers for the cross-sectional units (and the “c” before each variable denotes “change”). The option “cluster(id)” at the end of the “regress” command tells the software to report all standard errors and test statistics— including t statistics and F-type statistics—so that they are valid, in large cross sections, with any kind of serial correlation or heteroskedasticity. Reporting such statistics is very common in modern empirical work with panel data. Often the corrected standard errors will be substantially larger than either the usual standard errors or those that only correct for heteroskedasticity. The larger standard errors better reflect the sampling error in the pooled OLS coefficients. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 484 Advanced Panel Data Methods 14 CHAPTER In this chapter, we focus on two methods for estimating unobserved effects panel data models that are at least as common as first differencing. Although these methods are some- what harder to describe and implement, several econometrics packages support them. In Section 14.1, we discuss the fixed effects estimator, which, like first differencing, uses a transformation to remove the unobserved effect ai prior to estimation. Any time- constant explanatory variables are removed along with ai. The random effects estimator in Section 14.2 is attractive when we think the unob- served effect is uncorrelated with all the explanatory variables. If we have good controls in our equation, we might believe that any leftover neglected heterogeneity only induces serial correlation in the composite error term, but it does not cause correlation between the composite errors and the explanatory variables. Estimation of random effects models by gen- eralized least squares is fairly easy and is routinely done by many econometrics packages. Section 14.3 introduces the relatively new correlated random effects approach, which provides a synthesis of fixed effects and random effects methods, and has been shown to be practically very useful. In Section 14.4, we show how panel data methods can be applied to other data struc- tures, including matched pairs and cluster samples. 14.1 Fixed Effects Estimation First differencing is just one of the many ways to eliminate the fixed effect, ai. An alternative method, which works better under certain assumptions, is called the fixed effects transformation. To see what this method involves, consider a model with a single explanatory variable: for each i, yit 5 􏱬1xit 1 ai 1 uit, t 5 1, 2, ..., T. [14.1] Now, for each i, average this equation over time. We get y-i 5􏱬1x-i 1ai 1u-i, [14.2] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 485 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods where y-i 5 T21 􏰭Tt51 yit, and so on. Because ai is fixed over time, it appears in both (14.1) and (14.2). If we subtract (14.2) from (14.1) for each t, we wind up with yit 2 y-i 5 􏱬1(xit 2 x-i) 1 uit 2 u-i, t 5 1, 2, ..., T, or ÿit 5 􏱬1x ̈it 1 üit, t 5 1, 2, ..., T, [14.3] where ÿit 5 yit 2 y-i is the time-demeaned data on y, and similarly for ̈xit and üit. The fixed effects transformation is also called the within transformation. The important thing about equation (14.3) is that the unobserved effect, ai, has disappeared. This suggests that we should estimate (14.3) by pooled OLS. A pooled OLS estimator that is based on the time-demeaned variables is called the fixed effects estimator or the within estimator. The latter name comes from the fact that OLS on (14.3) uses the time variation in y and x within each cross-sectional observation. The between estimator is obtained as the OLS estimator on the cross-sectional equa- tion (14.2) (where we include an intercept, 􏱬0): we use the time averages for both y and x and then run a cross-sectional regression. We will not study the between estimator in detail because it is biased when ai is correlated with x-i (see Problem 2). If we think ai is uncorrelated with xit, it is better to use the random effects estimator, which we cover in Section 14.2. The between estimator ignores important information on how the variables change over time. Adding more explanatory variables to the equation causes few changes. The original unobserved effects model is yit 5 􏱬1xit1 1 􏱬2xit2 1 ... 1 􏱬kxitk 1 ai 1 uit, t 5 1, 2, ..., T. [14.4] We simply use the time-demeaning on each explanatory variable—including things like time-period dummies—and then do a pooled OLS regression using all time-demeaned variables. The general time-demeaned equation for each i is ÿit 5 􏱬1x ̈ it1 1 􏱬2x ̈ it2 1 ... 1 􏱬k x ̈ itk 1 üit, t 5 1, 2, ..., T, [14.5] which we estimate by pooled OLS. Under a strict exogeneity assumption on the explanatory variables, the fixed effects estimator is unbiased: roughly, the idiosyncratic error uit should be uncorrelated with each explanatory variable across all time periods. (See the chapter appendix for precise state- ments of the assumptions.) The fixed effects estimator allows for arbitrary cor- relation between ai and the explanatory variables in any time period, just as with first differencing. Because of this, any explanatory variable that is constant over time for all i gets swept away by the fixed effects transformation: ̈xit 5 0 for all i and t, if xit is constant across t. Therefore, we cannot include variables such as gen- der or a city’s distance from a river. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 14.1 Suppose that in a family savings equation, for the years 1990, 1991, and 1992, we let kidsit denote the number of children in family i for year t. If the number of kids is constant over this three-year period for most families in the sample, what problems might this cause for estimating the effect that the number of kids has on savings? 486 PART 3 Advanced Topics The other assumptions needed for a straight OLS analysis to be valid are that the errors uit are homoskedastic and serially uncorrelated (across t); see the appendix to this chapter. There is one subtle point in determining the degrees of freedom for the fixed effects estimator. When we estimate the time-demeaned equation (14.5) by pooled OLS, we have NT total observations and k independent variables. [Notice that there is no in- tercept in (14.5); it is eliminated by the fixed effects transformation.] Therefore, we should apparently have NT 2 k degrees of freedom. This calculation is incorrect. For each cross-sectional observation i, we lose one df because of the time-demeaning. In other words, for each i, the demeaned errors üit add up to zero when summed across t, so we lose one degree of freedom. (There is no such constraint on the original idiosyn- cratic errors uit.) Therefore, the appropriate degrees of freedom is df 5 NT 2 N 2 k 5 N(T 2 1) 2 k. Fortunately, modern regression packages that have a fixed effects esti- mation feature properly compute the df. But if we have to do the time-demeaning and the estimation by pooled OLS ourselves, we need to correct the standard errors and test statistics. EXAMPLE 14.1 EFFECT OF JOB TRAINING ON FIRM SCRAP RATES We use the data for three years, 1987, 1988, and 1989, on the 54 firms that reported scrap rates in each year. No firms received grants prior to 1988; in 1988, 19 firms received grants; in 1989, 10 different firms received grants. Therefore, we must also allow for the possibility that the additional job training in 1988 made workers more productive in 1989. This is easily done by including a lagged value of the grant indicator. We also include year dummies for 1988 and 1989. The results are given in Table 14.1. We have reported the results in a way that emphasizes the need to interpret the esti- mates in light of the unobserved effects model, (14.4). We are explicitly controlling for the unobserved, time-constant effects in ai. The time-demeaning allows us to estimate the 􏱬j, but (14.5) is not the best equation for interpreting the estimates. Interestingly, the estimated lagged effect of the training grant is substantially larger than the contemporaneous effect: job training has an effect at least one year later. Because the dependent variable is in logarithmic form, obtaining a grant in 1988 is predicted to lower the firm scrap rate in 1989 by about 34.4% [exp(2.422) 2 1 􏱴 2.344]; the coefficient on grant21 is significant at the 5% level against a two- sided alternative. The coefficient on grant is significant at the 10% level, and the size of the coefficient is hardly trivial. Notice the df is obtained as N(T 2 1) 2 k 5 54(3 2 1) 2 4 5 104. The coefficient on d89 indicates that the scrap rate was substantially lower in 1989 than in the base year, 1987, even in the absence of job training grants. Thus, it is impor- tant to allow for these aggregate effects. If we omitted the year dummies, the secular increase in worker productivity would be attributed to the job training grants. Table 14.1 shows that, even after con- trolling for aggregate trends in produc- tivity, the job training grants had a large estimated effect. Finally, it is crucial to allow for the lagged effect in the model. If we omit Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 14.2 Under the Michigan program, if a firm received a grant in one year, it was not eligible for a grant the following year. What does this imply about the correlation between grant and grant􏱦1? 487 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods T A B L E 1 4 . 1 Fixed Effects Estimation of the Scrap Rate Equation Dependent Variable: log(scrap) Independent Variables Coefficient (Standard Error) d88 􏱦.080 (.109) d89 􏱦.247 (.133) grant 􏱦.252 (.151) grant􏱦1 􏱦.422 (.210) Observations Degrees of freedom R-squared 162 104 .201 grant21, then we are assuming that the effect of job training does not last into the next year. The estimate on grant when we drop grant21 is 2.082 (t 5 2.65); this is much smaller and statistically insignificant. When estimating an unobserved effects model by fixed effects, it is not clear how we should compute a goodness-of-fit measure. The R-squared given in Table 14.1 is based on the within transformation: it is the R-squared obtained from estimating (14.5). Thus, it is interpreted as the amount of time variation in the yit that is explained by the time varia- tion in the explanatory variables. Other ways of computing R-squared are possible, one of which we discuss later. Although time-constant variables cannot be included by themselves in a fixed effects model, they can be interacted with variables that change over time and, in particular, with year dummy variables. For example, in a wage equation where education is constant over time for each individual in our sample, we can interact education with each year dummy to see how the return to education has changed over time. But we cannot use fixed effects to estimate the return to education in the base period, which means we cannot estimate the return to education in any period; we can only see how the return to education in each year differs from that in the base period. Section 14.3 describes an approach that allows coeffi- cients on time-constant variables to be estimated while preserving the fixed effects nature of the analysis. When we include a full set of year dummies—that is, year dummies for all years but the first—we cannot estimate the effect of any variable whose change across time is constant. An example is years of experience in a panel data set where each person works in every year, so that experience always increases by one in each year, for every person in the sample. The presence of ai accounts for differences across people in their years of experience in the initial time period. But then the effect of a one-year increase in experi- ence cannot be distinguished from the aggregate time effects (because experience increases by the same amount for everyone). This would also be true if, in place of separate year dummies, we used a linear time trend: for each person, experience cannot be distinguished from a linear trend. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 488 PART 3 Advanced Topics EXAMPLE 14.2 HAS THE RETURN TO EDUCATION CHANGED OVER TIME? The data in WAGEPAN.RAW are from Vella and Verbeek (1998). Each of the 545 men in the sample worked in every year from 1980 through 1987. Some variables in the data set change over time: experience, marital status, and union status are the three important ones. Other variables do not change: race and education are the key examples. If we use fixed effects (or first differencing), we cannot include race, education, or experience in the equa- tion. However, we can include interactions of educ with year dummies for 1981 through 1987 to test whether the return to education was constant over this time period. We use log(wage) as the dependent variable, dummy variables for marital and union status, a full set of year dummies, and the interaction terms d81?educ, d82?educ, ..., d87?educ. The estimates on these interaction terms are all positive, and they generally get larger for more recent years. The largest coefficient of .030 is on d87?educ, with t 5 2.48. In other words, the return to education is estimated to be about 3 percentage points larger in 1987 than in the base year, 1980. (We do not have an estimate of the return to education in the base year for the reasons given earlier.) The other significant interaction term is d86?educ (coefficient 5 .027, t 5 2.23). The estimates on the earlier years are smaller and insignificant at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative. If we do a joint F test for sig- nificance of all seven interaction terms, we get p-value 5 .28: this gives an example where a set of variables is jointly insignificant even though some variables are individually sig- nificant. [The df for the F test are 7 and 3,799; the second of these comes from N(T 2 1) 2 k 5 545(8 2 1) 2 16 5 3,799.] Generally, the results are consistent with an increase in the return to education over this period. The Dummy Variable Regression A traditional view of the fixed effects approach is to assume that the unobserved effect, ai, is a parameter to be estimated for each i. Thus, in equation (14.4), ai is the intercept for person i (or firm i, city i, and so on) that is to be estimated along with the 􏱬j. (Clearly, we cannot do this with a single cross section: there would be N 1 k parameters to estimate with only N observations. We need at least two time periods.) The way we estimate an in- tercept for each i is to put in a dummy variable for each cross-sectional observation, along with the explanatory variables (and probably dummy variables for each time period). This method is usually called the dummy variable regression. Even when N is not very large (say, N 5 54 as in Example 14.1), this results in many explanatory variables—in most cases, too many to explicitly carry out the regression. Thus, the dummy variable method is not very practical for panel data sets with many cross-sectional observations. Nevertheless, the dummy variable regression has some interesting features. Most importantly, it gives us exactly the same estimates of the 􏱬j that we would obtain from the regression on time-demeaned data, and the standard errors and other major statistics are identical. Therefore, the fixed effects estimator can be obtained by the dummy vari- able regression. One benefit of the dummy variable regression is that it properly computes the degrees of freedom directly. This is a minor advantage now that many econometrics packages have programmed fixed effects options. The R-squared from the dummy variable regression is usually rather high. This occurs because we are including a dummy variable for each cross-sectional unit, which explains much of the variation in the data. For example, if we estimate the unobserved effects Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 489 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods model in Example 13.8 by fixed effects using the dummy variable regression (which is possible with N 5 22), then R2 5 .933. We should not get too excited about this large R- squared: it is not surprising that we can explain much of the variation in unemployment claims using both year and city dummies. Just as in Example 13.8, the estimate on the EZ dummy variable is more important than R2. The R-squared from the dummy variable regression can be used to compute F tests in the usual way, assuming, of course, that the classical linear model assumptions hold (see the chapter appendix). In particular, we can test the joint significance of all of the cross- sectional dummies (N 2 1, since one unit is chosen as the base group). The unrestricted R-squared is obtained from the regression with all of the cross-sectional dummies; the restricted R-squared omits these. In the vast majority of applications, the dummy variables will be jointly significant. Occasionally, the estimated intercepts, say aˆi, are of interest. This is the case if we want to study the distribution of the ˆai across i, or if we want to pick a particular firm or city to see whether its ˆai is above or below the average value in the sample. These estimates are directly available from the dummy variable regression, but they are rarely reported by packages that have fixed effects routines (for the practical reason that there are so many aˆi). After fixed effects estimation with N of any size, the aˆi are pretty easy to compute: aˆi 5y-i 2􏱬ˆ1x-i1 2...2􏱬ˆkx-ik,i51,...,N, [14.6] where the overbar refers to the time averages and the 􏱬ˆj are the fixed effects estimates. For example, if we have estimated a model of crime while controlling for various time- varying factors, we can obtain aˆi for a city to see whether the unobserved fixed effects that contribute to crime are above or below average. Some econometrics packages that support fixed effects estimation report an “intercept,” which can cause confusion in light of our earlier claim that the time-demeaning eliminates all time-constant variables, including an overall intercept. [See equation (14.5).] Reporting an overall intercept in fixed effects (FE) estimation arises from viewing the ai as parameters to estimate. Typically, the intercept reported is the average across i of the aˆi. In other words, the overall intercept is actually the average of the individual-specific intercepts, which is an unbiased, consistent estimator of 􏱮 5 E(ai). In most studies, the 􏱬ˆj are of interest, and so the time-demeaned equations are used to obtain these estimates. Further, it is usually best to view the ai as omitted variables that we control for through the within transformation. The sense in which the ai can be estimated is generally weak. In fact, even though aˆi is unbiased (under Assumptions FE.1 through FE.4 in the chapter appendix), it is not consistent with a fixed T as N 􏱽 `. The reason is that, as we add each additional cross-sectional observation, we add a new ai. No information accu- mulates on each ai when T is fixed. With larger T, we can get better estimates of the ai, but most panel data sets are of the large N and small T variety. Fixed Effects or First Differencing? So far, setting aside pooled OLS, we have seen two competing methods for estimating unobserved effects models. One involves differencing the data, and the other involves time-demeaning. How do we know which one to use? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 490 PART 3 Advanced Topics We can eliminate one case immediately: when T 5 2, the FE and FD estimates, as well as all test statistics, are identical, and so it does not matter which we use. Of course, the equivalance between the FE and FD estimates requires that we estimate the same model in each case. In particular, as we discussed in Chapter 13, it is natural to include an intercept in the FD equation; this intercept is actually the intercept for the second time period in the original model written for the two time periods. Therefore, FE estimation must include a dummy variable for the second time period in order to be identical to the FD estimates that include an intercept. With T 5 2, FD has the advantage of being straightforward to implement in any econometrics or statistical package that supports basic data manipulation, and it is easy to compute heteroskedasticity-robust statistics after FD estimation (because when T 5 2, FD estimation is just a cross-sectional regression). When T $ 3, the FE and FD estimators are not the same. Since both are unbiased under Assumptions FE.1 through FE.4, we cannot use unbiasedness as a criterion. Further, both are consistent (with T fixed as N 􏱽 `) under FE.1 through FE.4. For large N and small T, the choice between FE and FD hinges on the relative efficiency of the estimators, and this is determined by the serial correlation in the idiosyncratic errors, uit. (We will assume homoskedasticity of the uit, since efficiency comparisons require homoskedastic errors.) When the uit are serially uncorrelated, fixed effects is more efficient than first differ- encing (and the standard errors reported from fixed effects are valid). Since the unobserved effects model is typically stated (sometimes only implicitly) with serially uncorrelated idiosyncratic errors, the FE estimator is used more than the FD estimator. But we should remember that this assumption can be false. In many applications, we can expect the un- observed factors that change over time to be serially correlated. If uit follows a random walk—which means that there is very substantial, positive serial correlation—then the dif- ference Duit is serially uncorrelated, and first differencing is better. In many cases, the uit exhibit some positive serial correlation, but perhaps not as much as a random walk. Then, we cannot easily compare the efficiency of the FE and FD estimators. It is difficult to test whether the uit are serially uncorrelated after FE estimation: we can estimate the time-demeaned errors, üit, but not the uit. However, in Section 13.3, we showed how to test whether the differenced errors, Duit, are serially uncorrelated. If this seems to be the case, FD can be used. If there is substantial negative serial correlation in the Duit, FE is probably better. It is often a good idea to try both: if the results are not sen- sitive, so much the better. When T is large, and especially when N is not very large (for example, N 5 20 and T 5 30), we must exercise caution in using the fixed effects estimator. Although exact distributional results hold for any N and T under the classical fixed effects assumptions, inference can be very sensitive to violations of the assumptions when N is small and T is large. In particular, if we are using unit root processes—see Chapter 11—the spurious regression problem can arise. First differencing has the advantage of turning an integrated time series process into a weakly dependent process. Therefore, if we apply first differenc- ing, we can appeal to the central limit theorem even in cases where T is larger than N. Nor- mality in the idiosyncratic errors is not needed, and heteroskedasticity and serial correlation can be dealt with as we touched on in Chapter 13. Inference with the fixed effects estimator is potentially more sensitive to nonnormality, heteroskedasticity, and serial correlation in the idiosyncratic errors. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 491 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods Like the first difference estimator, the fixed effects estimator can be very sensitive to classical measurement error in one or more explanatory variables. However, if each xitj is uncorrelated with uit, but the strict exogeneity assumption is otherwise violated— for example, a lagged dependent variable is included among the regressors or there is feedback between uit and future outcomes of the explanatory variable—then the FE esti- mator likely has substantially less bias than the FD estimator (unless T 5 2). The impor- tant theoretical fact is that the bias in the FD estimator does not depend on T, while that for the FE estimator tends to zero at the rate 1/T. See Wooldridge (2010, Section 10.7) for details. Generally, it is difficult to choose between FE and FD when they give substantively different results. It makes sense to report both sets of results and to try to determine why they differ. Fixed Effects with Unbalanced Panels Some panel data sets, especially on individuals or firms, have missing years for at least some cross-sectional units in the sample. In this case, we call the data set an unbalanced panel. The mechanics of fixed effects estimation with an unbalanced panel are not much more difficult than with a balanced panel. If Ti is the number of time periods for cross- sectional unit i, we simply use these Ti observations in doing the time-demeaning. The total number of observations is then T1 1 T2 1 ... 1 TN. As in the balanced case, one degree of freedom is lost for every cross-sectional observation due to the time-demeaning. Any re- gression package that does fixed effects makes the appropriate adjustment for this loss. The dummy variable regression also goes through in exactly the same way as with a balanced panel, and the df is appropriately obtained. It is easy to see that units for which we have only a single time period play no role in a fixed effects analysis. The time-demeaning for such observations yields all zeros, which are not used in the estimation. (If Ti is at most two for all i, we can use first differencing: if Ti 5 1 for any i, we do not have two periods to difference.) The more difficult issue with an unbalanced panel is determining why the panel is un- balanced. With cities and states, for example, data on key variables are sometimes missing for certain years. Provided the reason we have missing data for some i is not correlated with the idiosyncratic errors, uit, the unbalanced panel causes no problems. When we have data on individuals, families, or firms, things are trickier. Imagine, for example, that we ob- tain a random sample of manufacturing firms in 1990, and we are interested in testing how unionization affects firm profitability. Ideally, we can use a panel data analysis to control for unobserved worker and management characteristics that affect profitability and might also be correlated with the fraction of the firm’s work force that is unionized. If we collect data again in subsequent years, some firms may be lost because they have gone out of business or have merged with other companies. If so, we probably have a nonrandom sample in subse- quent time periods. The question is: If we apply fixed effects to the unbalanced panel, when will the estimators be unbiased (or at least consistent)? If the reason a firm leaves the sample (called attrition) is correlated with the idiosyn- cratic error—those unobserved factors that change over time and affect profits—then the resulting sample section problem (see Chapter 9) can cause biased estimators. This is a serious consideration in this example. Nevertheless, one useful thing about a fixed effects analysis is that it does allow attrition to be correlated with ai, the unobserved effect. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 492 PART 3 Advanced Topics The idea is that, with the initial sampling, some units are more likely to drop out of the survey, and this is captured by ai. EXAMPLE 14.3 EFFECT OF JOB TRAINING ON FIRM SCRAP RATES We add two variables to the analysis in Table 14.1: log(salesit) and log(employit), where sales is annual firm sales and employ is number of employees. Three of the 54 firms drop out of the analysis entirely because they do not have sales or employment data. Five additional observations are lost due to missing data on one or both of these variables for some years, leaving us with n 5 148. Using fixed effects on the unbalanced panel does not change the basic story, although the estimated grant effect gets larger: 􏱬ˆgrant 5 2.297, tgrant 5 21.89; 􏱬ˆgrant21 5 2.536, tgrant21 5 22.389. Solving general attrition problems in panel data is complicated and beyond the scope of this text. [See, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19).] 14.2 Random Effects Models We begin with the same unobserved effects model as before, yit 5􏱬0 1􏱬1xit1 1...1􏱬kxitk 1ai 1uit, [14.7] where we explicitly include an intercept so that we can make the assumption that the un- observed effect, ai, has zero mean (without loss of generality). We would usually allow for time dummies among the explanatory variables as well. In using fixed effects or first differencing, the goal is to eliminate ai because it is thought to be correlated with one or more of the xitj. But suppose we think ai is uncorrelated with each explanatory vari- able in all time periods. Then, using a transformation to eliminate ai results in inefficient estimators. Equation (14.7) becomes a random effects model when we assume that the unob- served effect ai is uncorrelated with each explanatory variable: Cov(xitj, ai) 5 0, t 5 1, 2, ..., T; j 5 1, 2, ..., k. [14.8] In fact, the ideal random effects assumptions include all of the fixed effects assumptions plus the additional requirement that ai is independent of all explanatory variables in all time periods. (See the chapter appendix for the actual assumptions used.) If we think the unobserved effect ai is correlated with any explanatory variables, we should use first dif- ferencing or fixed effects. Under (14.8) and along with the random effects assumptions, how should we estimate the 􏱬j? It is important to see that, if we believe that ai is uncorrelated with the explanatory variables, the 􏱬j can be consistently estimated by using a single cross section: there is no need for panel data at all. But using a single cross section disregards much useful informa- tion in the other time periods. We can also use the data in a pooled OLS procedure: just run OLS of yit on the explanatory variables and probably the time dummies. This, too, pro- duces consistent estimators of the 􏱬j under the random effects assumption. But it ignores Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 493 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods a key feature of the model. If we define the composite error term as vit 5 ai 1 uit, then (14.7) can be written as yit 5􏱬0 1􏱬1xit1 1...1􏱬kxitk 1vit. [14.9] Because ai is in the composite error in each time period, the vit are serially correlated across time. In fact, under the random effects assumptions, Corr(vit, vis) 5 􏱧2a /(􏱧2a 1 􏱧2u), t fi s, where 􏱧a2 5 Var(ai) and 􏱧u2 5 Var(uit). This (necessarily) positive serial correlation in the error term can be substantial, and, because the usual pooled OLS standard errors ignore this correlation, they will be incorrect, as will the usual test statistics. In Chapter 12, we showed how generalized least squares can be used to estimate models with autoregressive serial correlation. We can also use GLS to solve the serial correlation problem here. For the procedure to have good properties, we should have large N and relatively small T. We assume that we have a balanced panel, although the method can be extended to unbal- anced panels. Deriving the GLS transformation that eliminates serial correlation in the errors re- quires sophisticated matrix algebra [see, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10)]. But the transformation itself is simple. Define 􏰩 5 1 2 [􏱧2u /(􏱧2u 1 T􏱧2a)]1/ 2, [14.10] which is between zero and one. Then, the transformed equation turns out to be yit 2􏰩y-i 5􏱬0(12􏰩)1􏱬1(xit1 2􏰩x-i1)1... 1 􏱬k(xitk 2 􏰩x-ik) 1 (vit 2 􏰩v-i), [14.11] where the overbar again denotes the time averages. This is a very interesting equation, as it involves quasi-demeaned data on each variable. The fixed effects estimator subtracts the time averages from the corresponding variable. The random effects transformation subtracts a fraction of that time average, where the fraction depends on 􏱧u2, 􏱧a2, and the number of time periods, T. The GLS estimator is simply the pooled OLS estimator of equation (14.11). It is hardly obvious that the errors in (14.11) are serially uncorrelated, but they are. (See Problem 3.) The transformation in (14.11) allows for explanatory variables that are constant over time, and this is one advantage of random effects (RE) over either fixed effects or first dif- ferencing. This is possible because RE assumes that the unobserved effect is uncorrelated with all explanatory variables, whether the explanatory variables are fixed over time or not. Thus, in a wage equation, we can include a variable such as education even if it does not change over time. But we are assuming that education is uncorrelated with ai, which con- tains ability and family background. In many applications, the whole reason for using panel data is to allow the unobserved effect to be correlated with the explanatory variables. The parameter 􏰩 is never known in practice, but it can always be estimated. There are different ways to doˆthis, which mayˆbe based on pooled OLS or fixed ef- fects, for example. Generally, 􏰩 takes the form 􏰩 5 1 2 {1/[1 1 T(􏱧a2 /􏱧ˆ u2)]}1/ 2, where 􏱧ˆa2 is a consistent estimator of 􏱧a2 and 􏱧ˆu2 is a consistent estimator of 􏱧u2. These estima- tors can be based on the pooled OLS or fixed effects residuals. One possibility is that Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 494 PART 3 Advanced Topics 􏱧ˆa2 5 [NT(T 2 1)/2 2 (k 1 1)]21 􏰭Ni51 􏰭T21 􏰭Ts5t11 vˆitvˆis, where the vˆit are the residuals t 51 from estimating (14.9) by pooled OLS. Given this, we can estimate 􏱧u2 by using 􏱧ˆ2u2 5 􏱧ˆv2 2 􏱧ˆa2,where􏱧ˆ2v isthesquareoftheusualstandarderroroftheregressionfrompooledOLS. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10) for additional discussion of these estimators.] Many econometrics packages support estimation of random effects models and auto- matically compute some version of 􏰩ˆ. The feasible GLS estimator that uses 􏰩ˆ in place of 􏰩 is called the random effects estimator. Under the random effects assumptions in the chapter appendix, the estimator is consistent (not unbiased) and asymptotically normally distributed as N gets large with fixed T. The properties of the random effects (RE) estimator with small N and large T are largely unknown, although it has certainly been used in such situations. Equation (14.11) allows us to relate the RE estimator to both pooled OLS and fixed effects. Pooled OLS is obtained when 􏰩 5 0, and FE is obtained when 􏰩 5 1. In practice, the estimate 􏰩ˆ is never zero or one. But if 􏰩ˆ is close to zero, the RE estimates will be close to the pooled OLS estimates. This is the case when the unobserved effect, ai, is relatively unimportant (because it has small variance relative to 􏱧u2). It is more common for 􏱧a2 to be large relative to 􏱧u2, in which case 􏰩ˆ will be closer to unity. As T gets large, 􏰩ˆ tends to one, by writing the quasi-demeaned error in equation (14.11) as vit 2 􏰩v-i 5 (1 2 􏰩)ai 1 uit 2 􏰩u-i . This simple expression makes it clear that the errors in the transformed equation used in random effects estimation weight the unobserved effect by (1 2 􏰩). Although correlation between ai and one or more xitj causes inconsistency in the random effects estimation, we see that the correlation is attenuated by the factor (1 2 􏰩). As 􏰩 􏱽 1, the bias term goes to zero, as it must because the RE estimator tends to the FE estimator. If 􏰩 is close to zero, we are leaving a larger fraction of the unobserved effect in the error term, and, as a conse- quence, the asymptotic bias of the RE estimator will be larger. In applications of FE and RE, it is usually informative also to compute the pooled OLS estimates. Comparing the three sets of estimates can help us determine the nature of the biases caused by leaving the unobserved effect, ai, entirely in the error term (as does pooled OLS) or partially in the error term (as does the RE transformation). But we must remember that, even if ai is uncorrelated with all explanatory variables in all time periods, the pooled OLS standard errors and test statistics are generally invalid: they ignore the often substantial serial correlation in the composite errors, vit 5 ai 1 uit. As we mentioned in Chapter 13 (see Example 13.9), it is possible to compute standard errors and test statistics that are robust to arbitrary serial correlation (and heteroskedasticity) in vit, and popular statistics packages often allow this option. [See, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10).] EXAMPLE 14.4 A WAGE EQUATION USING PANEL DATA We again use the data in WAGEPAN.RAW to estimate a wage equation for men. We use three methods: pooled OLS, random effects, and fixed effects. In the first two methods, we can include educ and race dummies (black and hispan), but these drop out of the fixed effects analysis. The time-varying variables are exper, exper2, union, and married. As we discussed in Section 14.1, exper is dropped in the FE analysis (although exper2 remains). Each regression also contains a full set of year dummies. The estimation results are in Table 14.2. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. and this makes the RE and FE estimates very similar. We can gain more insight on the relative merits of random effects versus fixed effects 495 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods T A B L E 1 4 . 2 Three Different Estimators of a Wage Equation Dependent Variable: log(wage) Independent Variables Pooled OLS Random Effects Fixed Effects educ .091 (.005) .092 (.011) ——— black 􏱦.139 (.024) 􏱦.139 (.048) ——— hispan .016 (.021) .022 (.043) ——— exper .067 (.014) .106 (.015) ——— exper2 􏱦.0024 (.0008) 􏱦.0047 (.0007) 􏱦.0052 (.0007) married .108 (.016) .064 (.017) .047 (.018) union .182 (.017) .106 (.018) .080 (.019) The coefficients on educ, black, and hispan are similar for the pooled OLS and random effects estimations. The pooled OLS standard errors are the usual OLS standard errors, and these underestimate the true standard errors because they ignore the positive serial correlation; we report them here for comparison only. The experience profile is somewhat different, and both the marriage and union premiums fall notably in the random effects estimation. When we eliminate the unobserved effect entirely by using fixed effects, the marriage premium falls to about 4.7%, although it is still statistically significant. The drop in the marriage premium is consistent with the idea that men who are more able—as cap- tured by a higher unobserved effect, ai—are more likely to be married. Therefore, in the pooled OLS estimation, a large part of the marriage premium reflects the fact that men who are married would earn more even if they were not married. The remaining 4.7% has at least two possible explanations: (1) marriage really makes men more productive or (2) employers pay married men a premium because marriage is a signal of stability. We cannot distinguish between these two hypotheses. The estimate of 􏰩 for the random effects estima- tion is 􏰩ˆ 5 .643, which helps explain why, on the time- varying variables, the RE estimates lie closer to the FE estimates than to the pooled OLS estimates. Random Effects or Fixed Effects? Because fixed effects allows arbitrary correlation between ai and the xitj, while random effects does not, FE is widely thought to be a more convincing tool for estimating ceteris paribus effects. Still, random effects is applied in certain situations. Most obviously, if Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 14.3 The union premium estimated by fixed effects is about 10 percentage points lower than the OLS estimate. What does this strongly sug- gest about the correlation between union and the unobserved effect? © Cengage Learning, 2013 496 PART 3 Advanced Topics the key explanatory variable is constant over time, we cannot use FE to estimate its effect on y. For example, in Table 14.2, we must rely on the RE (or pooled OLS) estimate of the return to education. Of course, we can only use random effects because we are willing to assume the unobserved effect is uncorrelated with all explanatory variables. Typically, if one uses random effects, as many time-constant controls as possible are included among the explanatory variables. (With an FE analysis, it is not necessary to include such con- trols.) RE is preferred to pooled OLS because RE is generally more efficient. If our interest is in a time-varying explanatory variable, is there ever a case to use RE rather than FE? Yes, but situations in which Cov(xitj, ai) 5 0 should be considered the exception rather than the rule. If the key policy variable is set experimentally—say, each year, children are randomly assigned to classes of different sizes—then random effects would be appropriate for estimating the effect of class size on performance. Unfortunately, in most cases the regressors are themselves outcomes of choice processes and likely to be correlated with individual preferences and abilities as captured by ai. It is still fairly common to see researchers apply both random effects and fixed effects, and then formally test for statistically significant differences in the coefficients on the time-varying explanatory variables. (So, in Table 14.2, these would be the coef- ficients on exper2, married, and union.) Hausman (1978) first proposed such a test, and some econometrics packages routinely compute the Hausman test under the full set of random effects assumptions listed in the appendix to this chapter. The idea is that one uses the random effects estimates unless the Hausman test rejects (14.8). In practice, a failure to reject means either that the RE and FE estimates are sufficiently close so that it does not matter which is used, or the sampling variation is so large in the FE estimates that one cannot conclude practically significant differences are statistically significant. In the latter case, one is left to wonder whether there is enough information in the data to provide precise estimates of the coefficients. A rejection using the Hausman test is taken to mean that the key RE assumption, (14.8), is false, and then the FE estimates are used. (Naturally, as in all applications of statistical inference, one should distinguish between a practically significant difference and a statistically significant difference.) Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10) contains further discussion. In the next section we dis- cuss an alternative, computationally simpler approach to choosing between the RE and FE approaches. A final word of caution. In reading empirical work, you may find that some authors decide on FE versus RE estimation based on whether the ai are properly viewed as parameters to estimate or as random variables. Such considerations are usually wrongheaded. In this chapter, we have treated the ai as random variables in the un- observed effects model (14.7), regardless of how we decide to estimate the 􏱬j. As we have emphasized, the key issue that determines whether we use FE or RE is whether we can plausibly assume ai is uncorrelated with all xitj. Nevertheless, in some applica- tions of panel data methods, we cannot treat our sample as a random sample from a large population, especially when the unit of observation is a large geographical unit (say, states or provinces). Then, it often makes sense to think of each ai as a separate intercept to estimate for each cross-sectional unit. In this case, we use fixed effects: remember, using FE is mechanically the same as allowing a different intercept for each cross-sectional unit. Fortunately, whether or not we engage in the philosophical debate about the nature of ai, FE is almost always much more convincing than RE for policy analysis using aggregated data. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 497 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 14.3 The Correlated Random Effects Approach In applications where it makes sense to view the ai (unobserved effects) as being ran- dom variables, along with the observed variables we draw, there is an alternative to fixed effects that still allows ai to be correlated with the observed explanatory variables. To describe the approach, consider again the simple model in equation (14.1), with a single, time-varying explanatory variable xit. Rather than assume ai is uncorrelated with {xit: t 5 1, 2, ..., T}—which is the random effects approach—or take away time averages to remove ai —the fixed effects approach—we might instead model correlation between ai and {xit: t 5 1, 2, ..., T}. Because ai is, by definition, constant over time, allowing it to be correlated with the average level of the xit has a certain appeal. More specifically, let x-i 5 T−1STt51xit be the time average, as before. Suppose we assume the simple linear relationship ai 5 a 1 gx-i 1 ri, [14.12] where we assume ri is uncorrelated with each xit. Because x-i is a linear function of the xit, Cov(x-i, ri) 􏱪 0. [14.13] Equations (14.12) and (14.13) imply that ai and x-i are correlated whenever 􏰿 􏱿 0. The correlated random effects (CRE) approach uses (14.12) in conjunction with (14.1): substituting the former in the latter gives yit 􏱪􏱬xit 􏱕􏲈􏱕􏰿x-i 􏱕ri 􏱕uit 􏱪􏲈􏱕􏱬xit 􏱕􏰿x-i 􏱕ri 􏱕uit. [14.14] Equation (14.14) is interesting because it still has a composite error term, ri 􏱕 uit, consisting of a time-constant unobservable ri and the idiosyncratic shocks, uit. Importantly, assump- tion (14.8) holds when we replace ai with ri. Also, because uit is assumed to be uncorre- lated with xis, all s and t, uit is also uncorrelated with x-i. All of these assumptions add up to random effects estimation of the equation yit 􏱪 􏲈 􏱕 􏱬xit 􏱕 􏰿x-i 􏱕 ri + uit, [14.15] which is like the usual equation underlying RE estimation with the important addition of the time-average variable, x-i. It is the addition of x-i that controls for the correlation between ai and the sequence {xit: t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., T}. What is left over, ri, is uncorrelated with the xit. In most econometrics packages it is easy to compute the unit-specific time averages, x- i. Assuming we have done that for each cross-sectional unit i, what can we expect to happen if we apply RE to equation (14.15)? Notice that estimation of (14.15) gives 􏲈ˆCRE, 􏱬ˆCRE, and 􏰿ˆCRE —the CRE estimators. As far as 􏱬ˆCRE goes, the answer is a bit anti- climactic. It can be shown—see, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10)—that 􏱬ˆCRE 􏱪􏱬ˆFE, [14.16] where 􏱬ˆFE denotes the FE estimator from equation (14.3). In other words, adding the time average x-i and using random effects is the same as subtracting the time averages and using pooled OLS. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 498 PART 3 Advanced Topics Even though (14.15) is not needed to obtain 􏱬ˆ FE, the equivalence of the CRE and FE estimates of 􏱬 provides a nice interpretation of FE: it controls for the average level, x-i, when measuring the partial effect of xit on yit. As an example, suppose that xit is a tax rate on firm profits in county i in year t, and yit is some measure of county-level economic output. By including x-i, the average tax rate in the county over the T years, we are allowing for systematic differences between historically high-tax and low-tax counties—differences that may also affect economic output. We can also use equation (14.15) to see why the FE estimators are often much less precise than the RE estimators. If we set 􏰸 = 0 in equation (14.15) then we obtain the usual RE estimator of 􏱬, 􏱬ˆRE. This means that correlation between xit and x-i has no bearing on the variance of the RE estimator. By contrast, we know from multiple regression analysis in Chapter 3 that correlation between xit and x-i—that is, multicollinearity—can result in a higher variance for 􏱬ˆFE. Sometimes the variance is much higher, particularly when there is little variation in xit across t, in which case xit and x-i tend to be highly correlated. In the limiting case where there is no variation across time for any i, the correlation is perfect— and FE fails to provide an estimate of 􏱬. Apart from providing a synthesis of the FE and RE approaches, are there other reasons to consider the CRE approach even if it simply delivers the usual FE estimate of 􏱬? Yes, at least two. First, the CRE approach provides a simple, formal way of choosing between the FE and RE approaches. As we just discussed, the RE approach sets 􏰸 = 0 while FE estimates 􏰸. Because we have 􏰸ˆCRE and its standard error [obtained from RE estimation of (14.15)], we can construct a t test of H0: 􏰸 = 0 against H1: 􏰸 􏱿 0. [The appendix discusses how to make this test robust to heteroskedasticity and serial correlation in {uit}.] If we reject H0 at a sufficiently small significance level, we reject RE in favor of FE. As usual, especially with a large cross section, it is important to distinguish between a statistical rejection and economically important differences. A second reason to study the CRE approach is that it provides a way to include time- constant explanatory variables in what is effectively a fixed effects analysis. For example, let zi be a variable that does not change over time—it could be gender, say, or an IQ test score determined in childhood. We can easily augment (14.15) to include zi: yit = 􏱮 + 􏱬xit + 􏰸x-i + 􏱛zi + ri + uit, [14.17] where we do not change the notation for the error term (which no longer includes zi). If we estimate this expanded equation by RE, it can still be shown that the estimate of 􏱬 is the FE estimate from (14.1). In fact, once we include x-i, we can include any other time- constant variables in the equation, estimate it by RE, and obtain 􏱬ˆFE as the coefficient on xit. In addition, we obtain an estimate of 􏱛, althought the estimate should be interpreted with caution because it does not necessarily estimate a causal effect of zi on yit. The same CRE strategy can be applied to models with many time-varying explanatory variables (and many time-constant variables). When the equation augmented with the time averages is estimated by RE, the coefficients on the time-varying variables are identi- cal to the FE estimates. As a practical note, when the panel is balanced there is no need to include the time averages of variables that change over time—the leading case being time period dummies. (With T time periods, the time average of a time period is just 1/T, a constant for all i and t; clearly it makes no sense to add a bunch of constants to an equa- tion that already has an intercept.) If the panel data set is unbalanced, then the average of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 499 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods variables such as time dummies can change across i—it will depend on how many periods we have for cross-sectional unit i. In such cases, the time averages of any variable that changes over time must be included. Computer Exercise 14 in this chapter illustrates how the CRE approach can be applied to the balanced panel data set in AIRFARE.RAW, and how one can test RE versus FE in the CRE framework. 14.4 Applying Panel Data Methods to Other Data Structures The various panel data methods can be applied to certain data structures that do not involve time. For example, it is common in demography to use siblings (sometimes twins) to ac- count for unobserved family and background characteristics. Usually we want to allow the unobserved “family effect,” which is common to all siblings within a family, to be corre- lated with observed explanatory variables. If those explanatory variables vary across sib- lings within a family, differencing across sibling pairs—or, more generally, using the within transformation within a family—is preferred as an estimation method. By removing the unobserved effect, we eliminate potential bias caused by confounding family background characteristics. Implementing fixed effects on such data structures is rather straightforward in regression packages that support FE estimation. As an example, Geronimus and Korenman (1992) used pairs of sisters to study the effects of teen childbearing on future economic outcomes. When the outcome is income relative to needs—something that depends on the number of children—the model is log(incneedsfs) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0sister2s 􏱕 􏱬1teenbrthfs 􏱕 􏱬2agefs 􏱕 other factors 􏱕 af 􏱕 ufs, [14.18] where f indexes family and s indexes a sister within the family. The intercept for the first sister is 􏱬0, and the intercept for the second sister is 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0. The variable of interest is teenbrthfs, which is a binary variable equal to one if sister s in family f had a child while a teenager. The variable agefs is the current age of sister s in family f ; Geronimus and Korenman also used some other controls. The unobserved variable af , which changes only across family, is an unobserved family effect or a family fixed effect. The main concern in the analysis is that teenbrth is correlated with the family effect. If so, an OLS analysis that pools across families and sisters gives a biased estimator of the effect of teenage mother- hood on economic outcomes. Solving this problem is simple: within each family, differ- ence (14.18) across sisters to get 􏰧log(incneeds) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧teenbrth 􏱕 􏱬2􏰧age 􏱕 . . . 􏱕 􏰧u; this removes the family effect, af , and the resulting equation can be estimated by OLS. Notice that there is no time element here: the differencing is across sisters within a family. Also, we have allowed for differences in intercepts [14.19] EXPLORING FURTHER 14.4 When using the differencing method, does it make sense to include dummy variables for the mother and father’s race in (14.18)? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 500 PART 3 Advanced Topics across sisters in (14.18), which leads to a nonzero intercept in the differenced equation, (14.19). If in entering the data the order of the sisters within each family is essentially random, the estimated intercept should be close to zero. But even in such cases it does not hurt to include an intercept in (14.19), and having the intercept allows for the fact that, say, the first sister listed might always be the neediest. Using 129 sister pairs from the 1982 National Longitudinal Survey of Young Women, Geronimus and Korenman first estimated 􏱬1 by pooled OLS to obtain 􏱦.33 or 􏱦.26, where the second estimate comes from controlling for family background variables (such as parents’ education); both estimates are very statistically significant [see Table 3 in Geronimus and Korenman (1992)]. Therefore, teenage motherhood has a rather large impact on future family income. However, when the differenced equation is estimated, the coefficient on teenbrth is 􏱦.08, which is small and statistically insignificant. This suggests that it is largely a wom- an’s family background that affects her future income, rather than teenage childbearing. Geronimus and Korenman looked at several other outcomes and two other data sets; in some cases, the within family estimates were economically large and statistically sig- nificant. They also showed how the effects disappear entirely when the sisters’ education levels are controlled for. Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) used the differencing methodology to estimate the re- turn to education. They obtained a sample of 149 identical twins and collected information on earnings, education, and other variables. Identical twins were used because they should have the same underlying ability. This can be differenced away by using twin differences, rather than OLS on the pooled data. Because identical twins are the same in age, gender, and race, these factors all drop out of the differenced equation. Therefore, Ashenfelter and Krueger regressed the difference in log(earnings) on the difference in education and es- timated the return to education to be about 9.2% (t 􏱪 3.83). Interestingly, this is actually larger than the pooled OLS estimate of 8.4% (which controls for gender, age, and race). Ashenfelter and Krueger also estimated the equation by random effects and obtained 8.7% as the return to education. (See Table 5 in their paper.) The random effects analysis is mechanically the same as the panel data case with two time periods. The samples used by Geronimus and Korenman (1992) and Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) are examples of matched pairs samples. Generally, fixed and random effects methods can be applied to a cluster sample. These are cross-sectional data sets, but each observation belongs to a well-defined cluster. In the previous examples, each family is a cluster. As another example, suppose we have participation data on various pension plans, where firms offer more than one plan. We can then view each firm as a cluster, and it is pretty clear that unobserved firm effects would be an important factor in determining participation rates in pension plans within the firm. Educational data on students sampled from many schools form a cluster sample, where each school is a cluster. Because the outcomes within a cluster are likely to be correlated, allowing for an unobserved cluster effect is typically important. Fixed effects estimation is preferred when we think the unobserved cluster effect—an example of which is af in (14.12)—is correlated with one or more of the explanatory variables. Then, we can only include explanatory variables that vary, at least somewhat, within clusters. The cluster sizes are rarely the same, so fixed effects methods for unbalanced panels are usually required. In some cases, the key explanatory variables—often policy variables—change only at the level of the cluster, not within the cluster. In such cases the fixed effects approach is not applicable. For example, we may be interested in the effects of measured teacher quality on student performance, where each cluster is an elementary school classroom. Because Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 501 all students within a cluster have the same teacher, eliminating a “class effect” also elimi- nates any observed measures of teacher quality. If we have good controls in the equation, we may be justified in applying random effects on the unbalanced cluster. As with panel data, the key requirement for RE to produce convincing estimates is that the explanatory variables are uncorrelated with the unobserved cluster effect. Most econometrics packages allow random effects estimation on unbalanced clusters without much effort. Pooled OLS is also commonly applied to cluster samples when eliminating a clus- ter effect via fixed effects is infeasible or undesirable. However, as with panel data, the usual OLS standard errors are incorrect unless there is no cluster effect, and so robust standard errors that allow “cluster correlation” (and heteroskedasticity) should be used. Some regression packages have simple commands to correct standard errors and the usual test statistics for general within cluster correlation (as well as heteroskedasticity). These are the same corrections that work for pooled OLS on panel data sets, which we reported in Example 13.9. As an example, Papke (1999) estimates linear probability models for the continuation of defined benefit pension plans based on whether firms adopted defined con- tribution plans. Because there is likely to be a firm effect that induces correlation across different plans within the same firm, Papke corrects the usual OLS standard errors for cluster sampling, as well as for heteroskedasticity in the linear probability model. Summary In this chapter we have continued our discussion of panel data methods, studying the fixed effects and random effects estimators, and also described the correlated random effects ap- proach as a unifying framework. Compared with first differencing, the fixed effects estimator is efficient when the idiosyncratic errors are serially uncorrelated (as well as homoskedas- tic), and we make no assumptions about correlation between the unobserved effect ai and the explanatory variables. As with first differencing, any time-constant explanatory variables drop out of the analysis. Fixed effects methods apply immediately to unbalanced panels, but we must assume that the reasons some time periods are missing are not systematically related to the idiosyncratic errors. The random effects estimator is appropriate when the unobserved effect is thought to be uncorrelated with all the explanatory variables. Then, ai can be left in the error term, and the resulting serial correlation over time can be handled by generalized least squares estimation. Conveniently, feasible GLS can be obtained by a pooled regression on quasi- demeaned data. The value of the estimated transformation parameter, 􏰩ˆ, indicates whether the estimates are likely to be closer to the pooled OLS or the fixed effects estimates. If the full set of random effects assumptions holds, the random effects estimator is asymptotically— as N gets large with T fixed—more efficient than pooled OLS, first differencing, or fixed effects (which are all unbiased, consistent, and asymptotically normal). The correlated random effects approach to panel data models has become more popular in recent years, primarily because it allows a simple test for choosing between FE and RE, and it allows one to incorporate time-constant variables in an equation that delivers the FE estimates of the time-varying variables. Finally, the panel data methods studied in Chapters 13 and 14 can be used when working with matched pairs or cluster samples. Differencing or the within transformation eliminates the cluster effect. If the cluster effect is uncorrelated with the explanatory variables, pooled OLS can be used, but the standard errors and test statistics should be adjusted for cluster correlation. Random effects estimation is also a possibility. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 502 PART 3 Advanced Topics Key Terms Cluster Effect Cluster Sample Composite Error Term Correlated Random Effects Dummy Variable Regression Fixed Effects Estimator Problems Fixed Effects Transformation Matched Pairs Samples Quasi-Demeaned Data Random Effects Estimator Random Effects Model Time-Demeaned Data Unbalanced Panel Unobserved Effects Model Within Estimator Within Transformation 1 Supposethattheidiosyncraticerrorsin(14.4),{uit:t􏱪1,2,...,T},areseriallyuncorrelated with constant variance, 􏱧 u2. Show that the correlation between adjacent differences, 􏰧uit and 􏰧ui,t􏱕1, is 􏱦.5. Therefore, under the ideal FE assumptions, first differencing induces negative serial correlation of a known value. 2 With a single explanatory variable, the equation used to obtain the between estimator is y- i 􏱪 􏱬 0 􏱕 􏱬 1 x- i 􏱕 a i 􏱕 u- i , where the overbar represents the average over time. We can assume that E(ai) 􏱪 0 because we have included an intercept in the equation. Suppose that u-i is uncorrelated with xˉi, but Cov(xit, ai) 􏱪 􏱧xa for all t (and i because of random sampling in the cross section). (i) Letting 􏱬 ̃1 be the between estimator, that is, the OLS estimator using the time averages, show that plim􏱬 ̃1 􏱪􏱬1 􏱕􏱧xa/Var(x-i), where the probability limit is defined as N 􏱽 􏱵. [Hint: See equations (5.5) and (5.6).] (ii) Assumefurtherthatthexit,forallt􏱪1,2,...,T,areuncorrelatedwithconstantvari- 2 ance 􏱧x2. Show that plim􏱬 ̃1 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 T(􏱧xa/􏱧x). (iii) If the explanatory variables are not very highly correlated across time, what does part (ii) suggest about whether the inconsistency in the between estimator is smaller when there are more time periods? 3 In a random effects model, define the composite error vit 􏱪 ai 􏱕 uit, where ai is uncorrelated with uit and the uit have constant variance 􏱧u2 and are serially uncorrelated. Define eit 􏱪 vit 􏱦 􏰩v-i, where 􏰩 is given in (14.10). (i) Show that E(eit) 􏱪 0. (ii) Show that Var(eit) 􏱪 􏱧u2, t 􏱪 1, ..., T. (iii) Show that for t 􏱻 s, Cov(eit, eis) 􏱪 0. 4 Inordertodeterminetheeffectsofcollegiateathleticperformanceonapplicants,youcollect data on applications for a sample of Division I colleges for 1985, 1990, and 1995. (i) What measures of athletic success would you include in an equation? What are some of the timing issues? (ii) What other factors might you control for in the equation? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 503 (iii) Write an equation that allows you to estimate the effects of athletic success on the percentage change in applications. How would you estimate this equation? Why would you choose this method? 5 Suppose that, for one semester, you can collect the following data on a random sample of college juniors and seniors for each class taken: a standardized final exam score, percentage of lectures attended, a dummy variable indicating whether the class is within the student’s major, cumulative grade point average prior to the start of the semester, and SAT score. (i) Why would you classify this data set as a cluster sample? Roughly, how many obser- vations would you expect for the typical student? (ii) Writeamodel,similartoequation(14.18),thatexplainsfinalexamperformancein terms of attendance and the other characteristics. Use s to subscript student and c to subscript class. Which variables do not change within a student? (iii) If you pool all of the data and use OLS, what are you assuming about unobserved stu- dent characteristics that affect performance and attendance rate? What roles do SAT score and prior GPA play in this regard? (iv) If you think SAT score and prior GPA do not adequately capture student ability, how would you estimate the effect of attendance on final exam performance? 6 Usingthe“cluster”optionintheeconometricspackageStata®11,thefullyrobuststandard errors for the pooled OLS estimates in Table 14.2—that is, robust to serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in the composite errors, {vit: t 􏱪 1, ..., T}—are obtained as se(􏱬ˆeduc) 􏱪 .011, se( ˆ􏱬black) 􏱪 .051, se( ˆ􏱬hispan) 􏱪 .039, se( ˆ􏱬exper) 􏱪 .020, se( ˆ􏱬exper2) 􏱪 .0010, se(􏱬ˆmarried) 􏱪 .026, and se(􏱬ˆunion) 􏱪 .027. (i) How do these standard errors generally compare with the nonrobust ones, and why? (ii) HowdotherobuststandarderrorsforpooledOLScomparewiththestandarderrors for RE? Does it seem to matter whether the explanatory variable is time-constant or time-varying? (iii) When the fully robust standard errors for the RE estimates are computed, Stata® 11 reports the following (where we look at only the coefficients on the time-varying vari- ables): se(􏱬ˆexper) 􏱪 0.16, se(􏱬ˆexpersq) 􏱪 .0008, se(􏱬ˆmarried) 􏱪 0.19, and se(􏱬ˆunion) 􏱪 0.21. [These are robust to any kind of serial correlation or heteroskedasticity in the idiosyncratic errors {uit: t = 1, ..., T} as well as heteroskedasticity in ai.] How do the robust standard errors generally compare with the usual RE standard errors reported in Table 2? What conclusion might you draw? (iv) Comparing the four standard errors in part (iii) with their pooled OLS counterparts, what do you make of the fact that the robust RE standard errors are all below the robust POLS standard errors? Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in RENTAL.RAW for this exercise. The data on rental prices and other variables for college towns are for the years 1980 and 1990. The idea is to see whether a stronger presence of students affects rental rates. The unobserved effects model is log(rentit) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0y90t 􏱕 􏱬1log(popit) 􏱕 􏱬2log(avgincit) 􏱕 􏱬3pctstuit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 504 PART 3 Advanced Topics where pop is city population, avginc is average income, and pctstu is student population as a (i) (ii) (iii) (iv) C2 Use (i) (ii) (iii) percentage of city population (during the school year). Estimate the equation by pooled OLS and report the results in standard form. What do you make of the estimate on the 1990 dummy variable? What do you get for 􏱬ˆpctstu? Are the standard errors you report in part (i) valid? Explain. Now, difference the equation and estimate by OLS. Compare your estimate of 􏱬pctstu with that from part (i). Does the relative size of the student population appear to affect rental prices? Estimate the model by fixed effects to verify that you get identical estimates and standard errors to those in part (iii). CRIME4.RAW for this exercise. Reestimate the unobserved effects model for crime in Example 13.9 but use fixed effects rather than differencing. Are there any notable sign or magnitude changes in the coefficients? What about statistical significance? Add the logs of each wage variable in the data set and estimate the model by fixed effects. How does including these variables affect the coefficients on the criminal justice variables in part (i)? Do the wage variables in part (ii) all have the expected sign? Explain. Are they jointly significant? C3 For on hours of job training per employee. The basic model for the three years is this exercise, we use JTRAIN.RAW to determine the effect of the job training grant hrsempit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1d88t 􏱕 􏱛2d89t 􏱕 􏱬1grantit 􏱕 􏱬2granti,t􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬3log(employit) 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit. (i) Estimate the equation using fixed effects. How many firms are used in the FE estimation? How many total observations would be used if each firm had data on all variables (in particular, hrsemp) for all three years? (ii) Interpret the coefficient on grant and comment on its significance. (iii) Is it surprising that grant􏱦1 is insignificant? Explain. (iv) Do larger firms provide their employees with more or less training, on average? How big are the differences? (For example, if a firm has 10% more employees, what is the change in average hours of training?) C4 In Example 13.8, we used the unemployment claims data from Papke (1994) to estimate the effect of enterprise zones on unemployment claims. Papke also uses a model that allows each city to have its own time trend: log(uclmsit) 􏱪 ai 􏱕 cit 􏱕 􏱬1ezit 􏱕 uit, where ai and ci are both unobserved effects. This allows for more heterogeneity across cities. (i) Show that, when the previous equation is first differenced, we obtain 􏰧log(uclmsit ) 􏱪 ci 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧ezit 􏱕 􏰧uit, t 􏱪 2, ..., T. Notice that the differenced equation contains a fixed effect, ci. (ii) Estimate the differenced equation by fixed effects. What is the estimate of 􏱬1? Is it very different from the estimate obtained in Example 13.8? Is the effect of enterprise zones still statistically significant? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 505 (iii) Add a full set of year dummies to the estimation in part (ii). What happens to the estimate of 􏱬1? C5 (i) In the wage equation in Example 14.4, explain why dummy variables for occupation might be important omitted variables for estimating the union wage premium. (ii) If every man in the sample stayed in the same occupation from 1981 through 1987, would you need to include the occupation dummies in a fixed effects estimation? Explain. (iii) Using the data in WAGEPAN.RAW, include eight of the occupation dummy vari- ables in the equation and estimate the equation using fixed effects. Does the coef- ficient on union change by much? What about its statistical significance? C6 Add the interaction term unionit􏱳t to the equation estimated in Table 14.2 to see if wage growth depends on union status. Estimate the equation by random and fixed effects and compare the results. C7 Use the state-level data on murder rates and executions in MURDER.RAW for the following exercise. (i) Consider the unobserved effects model mrdrteit 􏱪 􏱗t 􏱕 􏱬1execit 􏱕 􏱬2unemit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where 􏱗t simply denotes different year intercepts and ai is the unobserved state effect. If past executions of convicted murderers have a deterrent effect, what should be the sign of 􏱬1? What sign do you think 􏱬2 should have? Explain. (ii) Using just the years 1990 and 1993, estimate the equation from part (i) by pooled OLS. Ignore the serial correlation problem in the composite errors. Do you find any evidence for a deterrent effect? (iii) Now, using 1990 and 1993, estimate the equation by fixed effects. You may use first differencing since you are only using two years of data. Is there evidence of a deterrent effect? How strong? (iv) Compute the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error for the estimation in part (ii). (v) Find the state that has the largest number for the execution variable in 1993. (The variable exec is total executions in 1991, 1992, and 1993.) How much bigger is this value than the next highest value? (vi) Estimate the equation using first differencing, dropping Texas from the analysis. Compute the usual and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. Now, what do you find? What is going on? (vii) Use all three years of data and estimate the model by fixed effects. Include Texas in the analysis. Discuss the size and statistical significance of the deterrent effect compared with only using 1990 and 1993. C8 Use the data in MATHPNL.RAW for this exercise. You will do a fixed effects version of the first differencing done in Computer Exercises 11 in Chapter 13. The model of interest is math4it 􏱪 􏱛1y94t 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱛5y98t 􏱕 􏰸1log(rexppit) 􏱕 􏰸2log(rexppi,t􏱦1) 􏱕 􏰬1log(enrolit) 􏱕 􏰬2lunchit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit , where the first available year (the base year) is 1993 because of the lagged spending variable. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 506 PART 3 Advanced Topics (i) Estimate the model by pooled OLS and report the usual standard errors. You should include an intercept along with the year dummies to allow ai to have a nonzero expected value. What are the estimated effects of the spending variables? Obtain the OLS residuals, vˆit. (ii) Is the sign of the lunchit coefficient what you expected? Interpret the magnitude of the coefficient. Would you say that the district poverty rate has a big effect on test pass rates? (iii) Compute a test for AR(1) serial correlation using the regression vˆit on vˆi,t􏱦1. You should use the years 1994 through 1998 in the regression. Verify that there is strong positive serial correlation and discuss why. (iv) Now, estimate the equation by fixed effects. Is the lagged spending variable still significant? (v) Why do you think, in the fixed effects estimation, the enrollment and lunch program variables are jointly insignificant? (vi) Definethetotal,orlong-run,effectofspendingas􏰩1􏱪􏰸1􏱕􏰸2.Usethesubstitution C10 Use the model 􏰸1 􏱪 􏰩1 􏱦 􏰸2 to obtain a standard error for 􏰩ˆ1. [Hint: Standard fixed effects esti- mation using log(rexppit) and zit 􏱪 log(rexppi,t􏱦1) 􏱦 log(rexppit) as explanatory variables should do it.] C9 The file PENSION.RAW contains information on participant-directed pension plans for U.S. workers. Some of the observations are for couples within the same family, so this data set constitutes a small cluster sample (with cluster sizes of two). (i) Ignoring the clustering by family, use OLS to estimate the model pctstck 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1choice 􏱕 􏱬2 prftshr 􏱕 􏱬3 female 􏱕 􏱬4age 􏱕 􏱬5educ 􏱕 􏱬6 finc25 􏱕 􏱬7 finc35 􏱕 􏱬8 finc50 􏱕 􏱬9 finc75 􏱕 􏱬10 finc100 􏱕 􏱬11 finc101 􏱕 􏱬12wealth89 􏱕 􏱬13stckin89 􏱕 􏱬14irain89 􏱕 u, where the variables are defined in the data set. The variable of most interest is choice, which is a dummy variable equal to one if the worker has a choice in how to allocate pension funds among different investments. What is the estimated effect of choice? Is it statistically significant? (ii) Are the income, wealth, stock holding, and IRA holding control variables impor- tant? Explain. (iii) Determine how many different families there are in the data set. (iv) Now,obtainthestandarderrorsforOLSthatarerobusttoclustercorrelationwithina family. Do they differ much from the usual OLS standard errors? Are you surprised? (v) Estimate the equation by differencing across only the spouses within a family. Why do the explanatory variables asked about in part (ii) drop out in the first-differenced estimation? (vi) Are any of the remaining explanatory variables in part (v) significant? Are you surprised? 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, ..., 4, where 􏱗t means that we allow for different year intercepts. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in AIRFARE.RAW for this exercise. We are interested in estimating log( fareit) 􏱪 􏱗t 􏱕 􏱬1concenit 􏱕 􏱬2log(disti) 􏱕 􏱬3[log(disti)]2 CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 507 (i) Estimate the above equation by pooled OLS, being sure to include year dummies. If 􏰧concen 􏱪 .10, what is the estimated percentage increase in fare? (ii) What is the usual OLS 95% confidence interval for 􏱬1? Why is it probably not reliable? If you have access to a statistical package that computes fully robust standard errors, find the fully robust 95% CI for 􏱬1. Compare it to the usual CI and comment. (iii) Describe what is happening with the quadratic in log(dist). In particular, for what value of dist does the relationship between log( fare) and dist become positive? [Hint: First figure out the turning point value for log(dist), and then exponentiate.] Is the turning point outside the range of the data? (iv) Nowestimatetheequationusingrandomeffects.Howdoestheestimateof􏱬1change? (v) Now estimate the equation using fixed effects. What is the FE estimate of 􏱬1? Why is it fairly similar to the RE estimate? (Hint: What is 􏰩ˆ for RE estimation?) (vi) Name two characteristics of a route (other than distance between stops) that are captured by ai. Might these be correlated with concenit? (vii) Are you convinced that higher concentration on a route increases airfares? What is your best estimate? C11 This question assumes that you have access to a statistical package that computes stan- dard errors robust to arbitrary serial correlation and heteroskedasticity for panel data methods. (i) For the pooled OLS estimates in Table 14.1, obtain the standard errors that allow for arbitrary serial correlation (in the composite errors, vit 􏱪 ai 􏱕 uit) and heteroske- dasticity. How do the robust standard errors for educ, married, and union compare with the nonrobust ones? (ii) Now obtain the robust standard errors for the fixed effects estimates that allow arbitrary serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in the idiosyncratic errors, uit. How do these compare with the nonrobust FE standard errors? (iii) For which method, pooled OLS or FE, is adjusting the standard errors for serial correlation more important? Why? C12 Use the data in ELEM94_95 to answer this question. The data are on elementary schools in Michigan. In this exercise, we view the data as a cluster sample, where each school is part of a district cluster. (i) What are the smallest and largest number of schools in a district? What is the average number of schools per district? (ii) Using pooled OLS (that is, pooling across all 1,848 schools), estimate a model relating lavgsal to bs, lenrol, lstaff, and lunch; see also Computer Exercises 11 from Chapter 9. What are the coefficient and standard error on bs? (iii) Obtain the standard errors that are robust to cluster correlation within district (and also heteroskedasticity). What happens to the t statistic for bs? ˆ (iv) Still using pooled OLS, drop the four observations with bs 􏱰 .5 and obtain 􏱬bs and its cluster-robust standard error. Now is there much evidence for a salary-benefits tradeoff? (v) Estimate the equation by fixed effects, allowing for a common district effect for schools within a district. Again drop the observations with bs 􏱰 .5. Now what do you conclude about the salary-benefits tradeoff? (vi) Inlightofyourestimatesfromparts(iv)and(v),discusstheimportanceofallowing teacher compensation to vary systematically across districts via a district fixed effect. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 508 PART 3 Advanced Topics C13 The data set DRIVING.RAW includes state-level panel data (for the 48 continental U.S. states) from 1980 through 2004, for a total of 25 years. Various driving laws are indi- cated in the data set, including the alcohol level at which drivers are considered legally intoxicated. There are also indicators for “per se” laws—where licenses can be revoked without a trial—and seat belt laws. Some economics and demographic variables are also included. (i) How is the variable totfatrte defined? What is the average of this variable in the years 1980, 1992, and 2004? Run a regression of totfatrte on dummy variables for the years 1981 through 2004, and describe what you find. Did driving become safer over this period? Explain. (ii) Add the variables bac08, bac10, perse, sbprim, sbsecon, sl70plus, gdl, perc14_24, unem, and vehicmilespc to the regression from part (i). Interpret the coefficients on bac8 and bac10. Do per se laws have a negative effect on the fatality rate? What about having a primary seat belt law? (Note that if a law was enacted some- time within a year the fraction of the year is recorded in place of the zero-one indicator.) (iii) Reestimate the model from part (ii) using fixed effects (at the state level). How do the coefficients on bac08, bac10, perse, and sbprim compare with the pooled OLS estimates? Which set of estimates do you think is more reliable? (iv) Suppose that vehicmilespc, the number of miles driven per capita, increases by 1,000. Using the FE estimates, what is the estimated effect on totfatrte? Be sure to interpret the estimate as if explaining to a layperson. (v) If there is serial correlation or heteroskedasticity in the idiosyncratic errors of the model then the standard errors in part (iii) are invalid. If possible, use “cluster” robust standard errors for the fixed effects estimates. What happens to the statisti- cal significance of the policy variables in part (iii)? C14 Use the data set in AIRFARE.RAW to answer this question. The estimates can be com- pared with those in Computer Exercise 10, in this Chapter. (i) Compute the time averages of the variable concen; call these concenbar. How many different time averages can there be? Report the smallest and the largest. (ii) Estimate the equation lfareit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1y98t 􏱕 􏱛2y99t 􏱕 􏱛3y00t 􏱕 􏱬1concenit 􏱕 􏱬2ldisti 􏱕 􏱬3ldistsqi 􏱕 􏰸1concenbari 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit by random effects. Verify that 􏱬ˆ1 is identical to the FE estimate computed in C10. (iii) If you drop ldist and ldistsq from the estimation in part (i) but still include concen- bari, what happens to the estimate of 􏱬ˆ1? What happens to the estimate of 􏰸1? (iv) Using the equation in part (ii) and the usual RE standard error, test H0: 􏰸1 = 0 against the two-sided alternative. Report the p-value. What do you conclude about RE versus FE for estimating 􏱬1 in this application? (v) If possible, for the test in part (iv) obtain a t-statistic (and, therefore, p-value) that is robust to abitrary serial correlation and heteroskedasticity. Does this change the conclusion reached in part (iv)? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 509 APPENDIX 14A 14A.1 Assumptions for Fixed and Random Effects In this appendix, we provide statements of the assumptions for fixed and random effects estimation. We also provide a discussion of the properties of the estimators under different sets of assumptions. Verification of these claims is somewhat involved, but can be found in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10). Assumption FE.1 For each i, the model is yit 􏱪􏱬1xit1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxitk 􏱕ai 􏱕uit,t􏱪1,...,T, where the 􏱬j are the parameters to estimate and ai is the unobserved effect. Assumption FE.2 We have a random sample from the cross section. Assumption FE.3 Each explanatory variable changes over time (for at least some i ), and no perfect linear relationships exist among the explanatory variables. Assumption FE.4 For each t, the expected value of the idiosyncratic error given the explanatory variables in all time periods and the unobserved effect is zero: E(uit􏰫Xi, ai) 􏱪 0. Under these first four assumptions—which are identical to the assumptions for the first-differencing estimator—the fixed effects estimator is unbiased. Again, the key is the strict exogeneity assumption, FE.4. Under these same assumptions, the FE estimator is consistent with a fixed T as N 􏱽 􏱵. Assumption FE.5 Var(uit􏰫Xi, ai) 􏱪 Var(uit) 􏱪 􏱧u2, for all t 􏱪 1,...,T. Assumption FE.6 For all t 􏱻 s, the idiosyncratic errors are uncorrelated (conditional on all explanatory variables and ai): Cov(uit,uis􏰫Xi, ai) 􏱪 0. Under Assumptions FE.1 through FE.6, the fixed effects estimator of the 􏱬j is the best linear unbiased estimator. Since the FD estimator is linear and unbiased, it is necessarily worse than the FE estimator. The assumption that makes FE better than FD is FE.6, which implies that the idiosyncratic errors are serially uncorrelated. Assumption FE.7 Conditional on Xi and ai, the uit are independent and identically distributed as Normal(0, 􏱧u2). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 510 PART 3 Advanced Topics Assumption FE.7 implies FE.4, FE.5, and FE.6, but it is stronger because it assumes a normal distribution for the idiosyncratic errors. If we add FE.7, the FE estimator is nor- mally distributed, and t and F statistics have exact t and F distributions. Without FE.7, we can rely on asymptotic approximations. But, without making special assumptions, these approximations require large N and small T. The ideal random effects assumptions include FE.1, FE.2, FE.4, FE.5, and FE.6. (FE.7 could be added but it gains us little in practice because we have to estimate 􏰩.) Because we are only subtracting a fraction of the time averages, we can now allow time-constant explanatory variables. So, FE.3 is replaced with Assumption RE.1 There are no perfect linear relationships among the explanatory variables. The cost of allowing time-constant regressors is that we must add assumptions about how the unobserved effect, ai, is related to the explanatory variables. Assumption RE.2 In addition to FE.4, the expected value of ai given all explanatory variables is constant: E(ai􏰫Xi) 􏱪 􏱬0. This is the assumption that rules out correlation between the unobserved effect and the explanatory variables, and it is the key distinction between fixed effects and random effects. Because we are assuming ai is uncorrelated with all elements of xit, we can in- clude time-constant explanatory variables. (Technically, the quasi-time-demeaning only removes a fraction of the time average, and not the whole time average.) We allow for a nonzero expectation for ai in stating Assumption RE.4 so that the model under the ran- dom effects assumptions contains an intercept, 􏱬0, as in equation (14.7). Remember, we would typically include a set of time-period intercepts, too, with the first year acting as the base year. We also need to impose homoskedasticity on ai as follows: Assumption RE.3 In addition to FE.5, the variance of ai given all explanatory variables is constant: Var(ai􏰫Xi) 􏱪 􏱧a2. Under the six random effects assumptions (FE.1, FE.2, RE.3, RE.4, RE.5, and FE.6), the RE estimator is consistent and asymptotically normally distributed as N gets large for fixed T. Actually, consistency and asymptotic normality follow under the first four assumptions, but without the last two assumptions the usual RE standard errors and test statistics would not be valid. In addition, under the six RE assumptions, the RE estima- tors are asymptotically efficient. This means that, in large samples, the RE estimators will have smaller standard errors than the corresponding pooled OLS estimators (when the proper, robust standard errors are used for pooled OLS). For coefficients on time-varying explanatory variables (the only ones estimable by FE), the RE estimator is more efficient Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 14 Advanced Panel Data Methods 511 than the FE estimator—often much more efficient. But FE is not meant to be efficient under the RE assumptions; FE is intended to be robust to correlation between ai and the xitj. As often happens in econometrics, there is a tradeoff between robustness and efficiency. See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10) for verification of the claims made here. 14A.2 Inference Robust to Serial Correlation and Heteroskedasticity for Fixed Effects and Random Effects One of the key assumptions for performing inference using the FE, RE, and even the CRE approach to panel data models is the assumption of no serial correlation in the idio- syncratic errors,{uit: t = 1, ..., T}—see Assumption FE.6. Of course, heteroskedasticity can also be an issue, but this is also ruled out for standard inference (see Assumption FE.5). As discussed in the appendix to Chapter 13, the same issues can arise with first differencing estimation when we have T ≥ 3 time periods. Fortunately, as with FD estimation, there are now simple solutions for fully robust inference—inference that is robust to arbitrary violations of Assumptions FE.5 and FE.6 and, when applying the RE or CRE approaches, to Assumption RE.5. As with FD esti- mation, the general approach to obtaining fully robust standard errors and test statistics is known as clustering. Now, however, the clustering is applied to a different equation. For example, for FE estimation, the clustering is applied to the time-demeaned equation (14.5). For RE estimation, the clustering gets applied to the quasi-time-demeaned equa- tion (14.11) [and a similar comment holds for CRE, but there the time averages are in- cluded as separate explanatory variables]. The details, which can be found in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 10) are too advanced for this course. But understanding the purpose of clustering is not: if possible, we should compute standard errors, confidence intervals, and test statistics that are valid in large cross sections under the weakest set of assump- tions. The FE estimator requires only Assumptions FE.1 to FE.4 for unbiasedness and consistency (as N 􏱽 􏱵 with T fixed). Thus, a careful researcher at least checks whether inference made robust to serial correlation and heteroskedasticity in the errors affects inference. Experience shows that it often does. Applying cluster robust inference to account for serial correlation within a panel data context is easily justified when N is substantially larger than T, but cannot be justified when N is small and T is larger. Computing the cluster robust statistics after FE or RE estimation is simple in many econometrics packages, often only requiring a qualification for the form “cluster(id)” appended to the end of FE and RE estimation commands. As in the FD case, “id” refers to a cross-section identifier. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 512 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 15 CHAPTER In this chapter, we further study the problem of endogenous explanatory variables in multiple regression models. In Chapter 3, we derived the bias in the OLS estimators when an important variable is omitted; in Chapter 5, we showed that OLS is generally incon- sistent under omitted variables. Chapter 9 demonstrated that omitted variables bias can be eliminated (or at least mitigated) when a suitable proxy variable is given for an unobserved explanatory variable. Unfortunately, suitable proxy variables are not always available. In the previous two chapters, we explained how fixed effects estimation or first differ- encing can be used with panel data to estimate the effects of time-varying independent vari- ables in the presence of time-constant omitted variables. Although such methods are very useful, we do not always have access to panel data. Even if we can obtain panel data, it does us little good if we are interested in the effect of a variable that does not change over time: first differencing or fixed effects estimation eliminates time-constant explanatory variables. In addition, the panel data methods that we have studied so far do not solve the problem of time-varying omitted variables that are correlated with the explanatory variables. In this chapter, we take a different approach to the endogeneity problem. You will see how the method of instrumental variables (IV) can be used to solve the problem of endogeneity of one or more explanatory variables. The method of two stage least squares (2SLS or TSLS) is second in popularity only to ordinary least squares for estimating linear equations in applied econometrics. We begin by showing how IV methods can be used to obtain consistent estimators in the presence of omitted variables. IV can also be used to solve the errors-in-variables problem, at least under certain assumptions. The next chapter will demonstrate how to estimate simultaneous equations models using IV methods. Our treatment of instrumental variables estimation closely follows our development of ordinary least squares in Part 1, where we assumed that we had a random sample from an underlying population. This is a desirable starting point because, in addition to simplify- ing the notation, it emphasizes that the important assumptions for IV estimation are stated Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 513 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares in terms of the underlying population (just as with OLS). As we showed in Part 2, OLS can be applied to time series data, and the same is true of instrumental variables methods. Section 15.7 discusses some special issues that arise when IV methods are applied to time series data. In Section 15.8, we cover applications to pooled cross sections and panel data. 15.1 Motivation: Omitted Variables in a Simple Regression Model When faced with the prospect of omitted variables bias (or unobserved heterogeneity), we have so far discussed three options: (1) we can ignore the problem and suffer the conse- quences of biased and inconsistent estimators; (2) we can try to find and use a suitable proxy variable for the unobserved variable; or (3) we can assume that the omitted variable does not change over time and use the fixed effects or first-differencing methods from Chapters 13 and 14. The first response can be satisfactory if the estimates are coupled with the direction of the biases for the key parameters. For example, if we can say that the estimator of a posi- tive parameter, say, the effect of job training on subsequent wages, is biased toward zero and we have found a statistically significant positive estimate, we have still learned something: job training has a positive effect on wages, and it is likely that we have underestimated the effect. Unfortunately, the opposite case, where our estimates may be too large in magnitude, often occurs, which makes it very difficult for us to draw any useful conclusions. The proxy variable solution discussed in Section 9.2 can also produce satisfying re- sults, but it is not always possible to find a good proxy. This approach attempts to solve the omitted variable problem by replacing the unobservable with a proxy variable. Another approach leaves the unobserved variable in the error term, but rather than estimating the model by OLS, it uses an estimation method that recognizes the presence of the omitted variable. This is what the method of instrumental variables does. For illustration, consider the problem of unobserved ability in a wage equation for working adults. A simple model is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2abil 􏱕 e, where e is the error term. In Chapter 9, we showed how, under certain assumptions, a proxy variable such as IQ can be substituted for ability, and then a consistent estimator of 􏱬1 is available from the regression of log(wage) on educ, IQ. Suppose, however, that a proxy variable is not available (or does not have the properties needed to produce a consistent estimator of 􏱬1). Then, we put abil into the error term, and we are left with the simple regression model log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u, [15.1] where u contains abil. Of course, if equation (15.1) is estimated by OLS, a biased and inconsistent estimator of 􏱬1 results if educ and abil are correlated. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 514 PART 3 Advanced Topics It turns out that we can still use equation (15.1) as the basis for estimation, provided we can find an instrumental variable for educ. To describe this approach, the simple regression model is written as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x􏱕u, [15.2] where we think that x and u are correlated: Cov(x,u) 􏱻 0. [15.3] The method of instrumental variables works whether or not x and u are correlated, but, for reasons we will see later, OLS should be used if x is uncorrelated with u. In order to obtain consistent estimators of 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 when x and u are correlated, we need some additional information. The information comes by way of a new variable that satisfies certain properties. Suppose that we have an observable variable z that satisfies these two assumptions: (1) z is uncorrelated with u, that is, (2) z is correlated with x, that is, Cov(z,u) 􏱪 0; [15.4] Cov(z,x) 􏱻 0. [15.5] Then, we call z an instrumental variable for x, or sometimes simply an instrument for x. The requirement that the instrument z satisfies (15.4) is summarized by saying “z is exogenous in equation (15.2),” and so we often refer to (15.4) as instrument exogeneity. In the context of omitted variables, instrument exogeneity means that z should have no partial effect on y (after x and omitted variables have been controlled for), and z should be uncor- related with the omitted variables. Equation (15.5) means that z must be related, either posi- tively or negatively, to the endogenous explanatory variable x. This condition is sometimes referred to as instrument relevance (as in “z is relevant for explaining variation in x”). There is a very important difference between the two requirements for an instrumen- tal variable. Because (15.4) involves the covariance between z and the unobserved er- ror u, we cannot generally hope to test this assumption: in the vast majority of cases, we must maintain Cov(z,u) 􏱪 0 by appealing to economic behavior or introspection. (In unusual cases, we might have an observable proxy variable for some factor contained in u, in which case we can check to see if z and the proxy variable are roughly uncorre- lated. Of course, if we have a good proxy for an important element of u, we might just add the proxy as an explanatory variable and estimate the expanded equation by ordinary least squares. See Section 9.2.) By contrast, the condition that z is correlated with x (in the population) can be tested, given a random sample from the population. The easiest way to do this is to estimate a simple regression between x and z. In the population, we have x􏱪􏰵0 􏱕􏰵1z􏱕v. [15.6] Then, because 􏰵1 􏱪 Cov(z,x)/Var(z), assumption (15.5) holds if, and only if, 􏰵1 􏱻 0. Thus, we should be able to reject the null hypothesis H0: 􏰵1 􏱪 0 [15.7] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 515 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares against the two-sided alternative H0: 􏰵1 􏱻 0, at a sufficiently small significance level (say, 5% or 1%). If this is the case, then we can be fairly confident that (15.5) holds. For the log(wage) equation in (15.1), an instrumental variable z for educ must be (1) uncorrelated with ability (and any other unobserved factors affecting wage) and (2) correlated with education. Something such as the last digit of an individual’s Social Security Number almost certainly satisfies the first requirement: it is uncorre- lated with ability because it is determined randomly. However, it is precisely because of the randomness of the last digit of the SSN that it is not correlated with education, either; therefore it makes a poor instrumental variable for educ. What we have called a proxy variable for the omitted variable makes a poor IV for the opposite reason. For example, in the log(wage) example with omitted ability, a proxy variable for abil must be as highly correlated as possible with abil. An instrumental vari- able must be uncorrelated with abil. Therefore, while IQ is a good candidate as a proxy variable for abil, it is not a good instrumental variable for educ. Whether other possible instrumental variable candidates satisfy the exogeneity re- quirement in (15.4) is less clear-cut. In wage equations, labor economists have used family background variables as IVs for education. For example, mother’s education (motheduc) is positively correlated with child’s education, as can be seen by collecting a sample of data on working people and running a simple regression of educ on motheduc. Therefore, motheduc satisfies equation (15.5). The problem is that mother’s education might also be correlated with child’s ability (through mother’s ability and perhaps quality of nurturing at an early age), in which case (15.4) fails. Another IV choice for educ in (15.1) is number of siblings while growing up (sibs). Typically, having more siblings is associated with lower average levels of education. Thus, if number of siblings is uncorrelated with ability, it can act as an instrumental vari- able for educ. As a second example, consider the problem of estimating the causal effect of skipping classes on final exam score. In a simple regression framework, we have score 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1skipped 􏱕 u, [15.8] where score is the final exam score and skipped is the total number of lectures missed dur- ing the semester. We certainly might be worried that skipped is correlated with other fac- tors in u: more able, highly motivated students might miss fewer classes. Thus, a simple regression of score on skipped may not give us a good estimate of the causal effect of missing classes. What might be a good IV for skipped? We need something that has no direct effect on score and is not correlated with student ability and motivation. At the same time, the IV must be correlated with skipped. One option is to use distance between living quarters and campus. Some students at a large university will commute to campus, which may increase the likelihood of missing lectures (due to bad weather, oversleeping, and so on). Thus, skipped may be positively correlated with distance; this can be checked by regressing skipped on distance and doing a t test, as described earlier. Is distance uncorrelated with u? In the simple regression model (15.8), some fac- tors in u may be correlated with distance. For example, students from low-income families may live off campus; if income affects student performance, this could cause distance to be correlated with u. Section 15.2 shows how to use IV in the context of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 516 PART 3 Advanced Topics multiple regression, so that other factors affecting score can be included directly in the model. Then, distance might be a good IV for skipped. An IV approach may not be necessary at all if a good proxy exists for student ability, such as cumulative GPA prior to the semester. There is a final point worth emphasizing before we turn to the mechanics of IV estimation: namely, in using the simple regression in equation (15.6) to test (15.7), it is important to take note of the sign (and even magnitude) of 􏰵ˆ 1 and not just its statistical significance. Arguments for why a variable z makes a good IV candidate for an endog- enous explanatory variable x should include a discussion about the nature of the relation- ship between x and z. For example, due to genetics and background influences it makes sense that child’s education (x) and mother’s education (z) are positively correlated. If in your sample of data you find that they are actually negatively correlated—that is, 􏰵ˆ 1 < 0—then your use of mother’s education as an IV for child’s education is likely to be unconvincing. [And this has nothing to do with whether condition (15.4) is likely to hold.] In the example of measuring whether skipping classes has an effect on test perfor- mance, one should find a positive, statistically significant relationship between skipped and distance in order to justify using distance as an IV for skipped: a negative relationship would be difficult to justify [and would suggest that there are important omitted variables driving a negative correlation—variables that might themselves have to be included in the model (15.8)]. We now demonstrate that the availability of an instrumental variable can be used to estimate consistently the parameters in equation (15.2). In particular, we show that as- sumptions (15.4) and (15.5) serve to identify the parameter 􏱬1. Identification of a param- eter in this context means that we can write 􏱬1 in terms of population moments that can be estimated using a sample of data. To write 􏱬1 in terms of population covariances, we use equation (15.2): the covariance between z and y is Cov(z,y) 􏱪 􏱬1Cov(z,x) 􏱕 Cov(z,u). Now, under assumption (15.4), Cov(z,u) 􏱪 0, and under assumption (15.5), Cov(z,x) 􏱻 0. Thus, we can solve for 􏱬1 as Cov(z,y) 􏱬1 􏱪 ________ . Cov(z,x) [15.9] [Notice how this simple algebra fails if z and x are uncorrelated, that is, if Cov(z, x) 􏱪 0.] Equation (15.9) shows that 􏱬1 is the population covariance between z and y divided by the population covariance between z and x, which shows that 􏱬1 is identified. Given a random sample, we estimate the population quantities by the sample analogs. After canceling the sample sizes in the numerator and denominator, we get the instrumental variables (IV) estimator of 􏱬1: [15.10] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∑n - - (zi 􏱦 z) (yi 􏱦 y) i􏱪_1______________ ˆ _∑ 􏱬1􏱪 n - -. (z 􏱦 z) (x 􏱦 x) ii i􏱪1 Given a sample of data on x, y, and z, it is simple to obtain the IV estimator in (15.10). The IVestimatorof􏱬 issimply􏱬ˆ 􏱪y-􏱦􏱬ˆx-,whichlooksjustliketheOLSinterceptestima- 00ˆ1 tor except that the slope estimator, 􏱬1, is now the IV estimator. 517 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares It is no accident that when z 􏱪 x we obtain the OLS estimator of 􏱬1. In other words, when x is exogenous, it can be used as its own IV, and the IV estimator is then identical to the OLS estimator. A simple application of the law of large numbers shows that the IV estimator is consistent for 􏱬1: plim( 􏱬ˆ 1) 􏱪 􏱬1, provided assumptions (15.4) and (15.5) are satisfied. If either assumption fails, the IV estimators are not consistent (more on this later). One feature of the IV estimator is that, when x and u are in fact correlated—so that instrumental variables estimation is actually needed—it is essentially never unbiased. This means that, in small samples, the IV estimator can have a substantial bias, which is one reason why large samples are preferred. When discussing the application of instrumental variables it is important to be careful with language. Like OLS, IV is an estimation method. It makes little sense to refer to “an instrumental variables model”—just as the phrase “OLS model” makes little sense. As we know, a model is an equation such as (15.8), which is a special case of the generic model in equation (15.2). When we have a model such as (15.2), we can choose to estimate the parameters of that model in many different ways. Prior to this chapter we focused primar- ily on OLS, but, for example, we also know from Chapter 8 that one can use weighted least squares as an alternative estimation method (and there are usually numerous possibilities for the weights). If we have an instrumental variable candidate z for x then we can instead apply instrumental variables estimation. It is certainly true that the estimation method we apply is motivated by the model and assumptions we make about that model. But the estimators are well defined and exist apart from any underlying model or assumptions: remember, an estimator is simply a rule for combining data. The bottom line is that while we probably know what a researcher means when using a phrase such as “I estimated an IV model,” such language betrays a lack of understanding about the difference between a model and an estimation method. Statistical Inference with the IV Estimator Given the similar structure of the IV and OLS estimators, it is not surprising that the IV estimator has an approximate normal distribution in large sample sizes. To perform inference on 􏱬1, we need a standard error that can be used to compute t statistics and confidence intervals. The usual approach is to impose a homoskedasticity assumption, just as in the case of OLS. Now, the homoskedasticity assumption is stated conditional on the instrumental variable, z, not the endogenous explanatory variable, x. Along with the previ- ous assumptions on u, x, and z, we add E(u2􏰫z) 􏱪 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(u). [15.11] It can be shown that, under (15.4), (15.5), and (15.11), the asymptotic variance 2 __􏱧____ , [15.12] n􏱧2x 􏰴2x,z of􏱬ˆ1 is where 􏱧2x is the population variance of x, 􏱧2 is the population variance of u, and 􏰴2x,z is the square of the population correlation between x and z. This tells us how highly correlated x and z are in the population. As with the OLS estimator, the asymptotic variance of the IV estimator decreases to zero at the rate of 1/n, where n is the sample size. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 518 PART 3 Advanced Topics Equation (15.12) is interesting for two reasons. First, it provides a way to obtain a standard error for the IV estimator. All quantities in (15.12) can be consistently estimated given a random sample. To estimate 􏱧2x, we simply compute the sample variance of xi; to estimate 􏰴2x,z, we can run the regression of xi on zi to obtain the R-squared, say, R2x,z. Finally, to estimate 􏱧2, we can use the IV residuals, uˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 􏱬ˆ0 􏱦 􏱬ˆ1xi, i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, where 􏱬ˆ0 and 􏱬ˆ1 are the IV estimates. A consistent estimator of 􏱧2 looks just like the esti- mator of 􏱧2 from a simple OLS regression: 􏱧ˆ2 􏱪 __1___ n 􏱦 2 i􏱪1 where it is standard to use the degrees of freedom correction (even though this has little effect as the sample size grows). ˆ The (asymptotic) standard error of 􏱬1 is the square root of the estimated asymptotic variance, the latter of which is given by ___􏱧ˆ_____ where SSTx is the total sum of squares of the xi . [Recall that the sample variance of xi is SSTx 􏱆n, and so the sample sizes cancel to give us (15.13).] The resulting standard error can be used to construct either t statistics for hypotheses involving 􏱬1 or confidence intervals for 􏱬1. 􏱬ˆ0 also has a standard error that we do not present here. Any modern econometrics package computes the standard error after any IV estimation. A second reason (15.12) is interesting is that it allows us to compare the asymp- totic variances of the IV and the OLS estimators (when x and u are uncorrelated). Under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the variance of the OLS estimator is 􏱧2/SSTx, while the comparable formula for the IV estimator is 􏱧2/(SSTx􏱳R2x,z); they differ only in that R2x,z ap- pears in the denominator of the IV variance. Because an R-squared is always less than one, the IV variance is always larger than the OLS variance (when OLS is valid). If R2x,z is small, then the IV variance can be much larger than the OLS variance. Remember, R2x,z measures the strength of the linear relationship between x and z in the sample. If x and z are only slightly correlated, R2x,z can be small, and this can translate into a very large sam- pling variance for the IV estimator. The more highly correlated z is with x, the closer R2x,z is to one, and the smaller is the variance of the IV estimator. In the case that z 􏱪 x, R2x,z 􏱪 1, and we get the OLS variance, as expected. The previous discussion highlights an important cost of performing IV estimation when x and u are uncorrelated: the asymptotic variance of the IV estimator is always larger, and sometimes much larger, than the asymptotic variance of the OLS estimator. EXAMPLE 15.1 ESTIMATING THE RETURN TO EDUCATION FOR MARRIED WOMEN We use the data on married working women in MROZ.RAW to estimate the return to education in the simple regression model log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 u. [15.14] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∑n uˆ2, i 2 , [15.13] SSTx􏱳R2x,z 519 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares For comparison, we first obtain the OLS estimates: 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 􏱦.185 􏱕 .109 educ (.185) (.014) n 􏱪 428, R2 􏱪 .118. [15.15] The estimate for 􏱬1 implies an almost 11% return for another year of education. Next, we use father’s education ( fatheduc) as an instrumental variable for educ. We have to maintain that fatheduc is uncorrelated with u. The second requirement is that educ and fatheduc are correlated. We can check this very easily using a simple regression of educ on fatheduc (using only the working women in the sample): 􏱾educ 􏱪 10.24 􏱕 .269 fatheduc (.28) (.029) [15.16] n 􏱪 428, R2 􏱪 .173. The t statistic on fatheduc is 9.28, which indicates that educ and fatheduc have a statisti- cally significant positive correlation. (In fact, fatheduc explains about 17% of the variation in educ in the sample.) Using fatheduc as an IV for educ gives 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 .441 􏱕 .059 educ (.446) (.035) [15.17] n 􏱪 428, R2 􏱪 .093. The IV estimate of the return to education is 5.9%, which is barely more than one-half of the OLS estimate. This suggests that the OLS estimate is too high and is consistent with omitted ability bias. But we should remember that these are estimates from just one sample: we can never know whether .109 is above the true return to education, or whether .059 is closer to the true return to education. Further, the standard error of the IV estimate is two and one- half times as large as the OLS standard error (this is expected, for the reasons we gave ear- lier). The 95% confidence interval for 􏱬1 using OLS is much tighter than that using the IV; in fact, the IV confidence interval actually contains the OLS estimate. Therefore, although the differences between (15.15) and (15.17) are practically large, we cannot say whether the difference is statistically significant. We will show how to test this in Section 15.5. In the previous example, the estimated return to education using IV was less than that using OLS, which corresponds to our expectations. But this need not have been the case, as the following example demonstrates. EXAMPLE 15.2 ESTIMATING THE RETURN TO EDUCATION FOR MEN We now use WAGE2.RAW to estimate the return to education for men. We use the vari- able sibs (number of siblings) as an instrument for educ. These are negatively correlated, as we can verify from a simple regression: 􏱾educ 􏱪 14.14 􏱦 .228 sibs (.11) (.030) n 􏱪 935, R2 􏱪 .057. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 520 PART 3 Advanced Topics This equation implies that every sibling is associated with, on average, about .23 less of a year of education. If we assume that sibs is uncorrelated with the error term in (15.14), then the IV estimator is consistent. Estimating equation (15.14) using sibs as an IV for educ gives 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 5.13 􏱕 .122 educ (.36) (.026) n 􏱪 935. (The R-squared is computed to be negative, so we do not report it. A discussion of R-squared in the context of IV estimation follows.) For comparison, the OLS estimate of 􏱬1 is .059 with a standard error of .006. Unlike in the previous example, the IV estimate is now much higher than the OLS estimate. While we do not know whether the difference is statistically significant, this does not mesh with the omitted ability bias from OLS. It could be that sibs is also correlated with ability: more siblings means, on average, less parental attention, which could result in lower ability. Another interpretation is that the OLS estimator is biased toward zero because of measurement error in educ. This is not entirely convincing because, as we discussed in Section 9.3, educ is unlikely to satisfy the classical errors-in-variables model. In the previous examples, the endogenous explanatory variable (educ) and the instrumental variables ( fatheduc, sibs) had quantitative meaning. But nothing prevents the explanatory variable or IV from being binary variables. Angrist and Krueger (1991), in their simplest analysis, came up with a clever binary instrumental variable for educ, using census data on men in the United States. Let frstqrt be equal to one if the man was born in the first quarter of the year, and zero otherwise. It seems that the error term in (15.14)—and, in particular, ability—should be unrelated to quarter of birth. But frstqrt also needs to be correlated with educ. It turns out that years of education do differ systematically in the population based on quarter of birth. Angrist and Krueger argued persuasively that this is due to compulsory school attendance laws in effect in all states. Briefly, students born early in the year typically begin school at an older age. Therefore, they reach the compulsory schooling age (16 in most states) with somewhat less edu- cation than students who begin school at a younger age. For students who finish high school, Angrist and Krueger verified that there is no relationship between years of educa- tion and quarter of birth. Because years of education varies only slightly across quarter of birth—which means R2x,z in (15.13) is very small—Angrist and Krueger needed a very large sample size to get a reasonably precise IV estimate. Using 247,199 men born between 1920 and 1929, the OLS estimate of the return to education was .0801 (standard error .0004), and the IV estimate was .0715 (.0219); these are reported in Table III of Angrist and Krueger’s paper. Note how large the t statistic is for the OLS estimate (about 200), whereas the t statistic for the IV estimate is only 3.26. Thus, the IV estimate is statisti- cally different from zero, but its confidence interval is much wider than that based on the OLS estimate. An interesting finding by Angrist and Krueger is that the IV estimate does not differ much from the OLS estimate. In fact, using men born in the next decade, the IV estimate is somewhat higher than the OLS estimate. One could interpret this as showing that Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 521 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares there is no omitted ability bias when wage equations are estimated by OLS. However, the Angrist and Krueger paper has been criticized on econometric grounds. As discussed by Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995), it is not obvious that season of birth is unrelated to unobserved factors that affect wage. As we will explain in the next subsection, even a small amount of correlation between z and u can cause serious problems for the IV estimator. For policy analysis, the endogenous explanatory variable is often a binary variable. For example, Angrist (1990) studied the effect that being a veteran of the Vietnam War had on lifetime earnings. A simple model is log(earns) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1veteran 􏱕 u, [15.18] where veteran is a binary variable. The problem with estimating this equation by OLS is that there may be a self-selection problem, as we mentioned in Chapter 7: perhaps people who get the most out of the military choose to join, or the decision to join is cor- related with other characteristics that affect earnings. These will cause veteran and u to be correlated. Angrist pointed out that the Vietnam draft lottery provided a natural experi- ment (see also Chapter 13) that created an instrumental variable for veteran. Young men were given lottery numbers that determined whether they would be called to serve in Vietnam. Because the numbers given were (eventually) randomly assigned, it seems plausible that draft lottery number is uncorrelated with the error term u. But those with a low enough number had to serve in Vietnam, so that the probability of being a veteran is correlated with lottery number. If both of these asser- tions are true, draft lottery number is a good IV candidate for veteran. It is also possible to have a binary endogenous explanatory variable and a binary instrumental variable. See Problem 1 for an example. Properties of IV with a Poor Instrumental Variable We have already seen that, though IV is consistent when z and u are uncorrelated and z and x have any positive or negative correlation, IV estimates can have large standard errors, especially if z and x are only weakly correlated. Weak correlation between z and x can have even more serious consequences: the IV estimator can have a large asymptotic bias even if z and u are only moderately correlated. We can see this by studying the probability limit of the IV estimator when z and u are possibly correlated. Letting 􏱬ˆ 1, IV denote the IV estimator, we can write EXPLORING FURTHER 15.1 If some men who were assigned low draft lottery numbers obtained additional schooling to reduce the probability of being drafted, is lottery number a good instrument for veteran in (15.18)? ˆ Corr(z,u) 􏱧u plim 􏱬 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 ________ 􏱳 __ , [15.19] where 􏱧u and 􏱧x are the standard deviations of u and x in the population, respectively. The interesting part of this equation involves the correlation terms. It shows that, even if Corr(z,u) is small, the inconsistency in the IV estimator can be very large if Corr(z,x) is also small. Thus, even if we focus only on consistency, it is not necessarily better to use IV than OLS if the correlation between z and u is smaller than that between x and u. Using Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 1, IV 1 Corr(z,x) 􏱧x 522 PART 3 Advanced Topics the fact that Corr(x,u) 􏱪 Cov(x,u)/(􏱧x􏱧u) along with equation (5.3), we can write the plim 􏱧 x Comparing these formulas shows that it is possible for the directions of the asymptotic biases to be different for IV and OLS. For example, suppose Corr(x,u) 􏱰 0, Corr(z,x) 􏱰 0, and Corr(z,u) 􏱷 0. Then the IV estimator has a downward bias, whereas the OLS estimator has an upward bias (asymptotically). In practice, this situation is probably rare. More prob- lematic is when the direction of the bias is the same and the correlation between z and x is small. For concreteness, suppose x and z are both positively correlated with u and Corr(z,x) 􏱰 0. Then the asymptotic bias in the IV estimator is less than that for OLS only if Corr(z,u)/ Corr(z,x) 􏱷 Corr(x,u). If Corr(z,x) is small, then a seemingly small correlation between z and u can be magnified and make IV worse than OLS, even if we restrict attention to bias. For example, if Corr(z,x) 􏱪 .2, Corr(z,u) must be less than one-fifth of Corr(x,u) before IV has less asymptotic bias than OLS. In many applications, the correlation between the instrument and x is less than .2. Unfortunately, because we rarely have an idea about the relative magnitudes of Corr(z,u) and Corr(x,u), we can never know for sure which estima- tor has the largest asymptotic bias [unless, of course, we assume Corr(z,u) 􏱪 0]. In the Angrist and Krueger (1991) example mentioned earlier, where x is years of schooling and z is a binary variable indicating quarter of birth, the correlation between z and x is very small. Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995) discussed reasons why quarter of birth and u might be somewhat correlated. From equation (15.19), we see that this can lead to a substantial bias in the IV estimator. When z and x are not correlated at all, things are especially bad, whether or not z is uncorrelated with u. The following example illustrates why we should always check to see if the endogenous explanatory variable is correlated with the IV candidate. EXAMPLE 15.3 ESTIMATING THE EFFECT OF SMOKING ON BIRTH WEIGHT In Chapter 6, we estimated the effect of cigarette smoking on child birth weight. Without other explanatory variables, the model is log(bwght) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 packs 􏱕 u, [15.21] where packs is the number of packs smoked by the mother per day. We might worry that packs is correlated with other health factors or the availability of good prenatal care, so that packs and u might be correlated. A possible instrumental variable for packs is the average price of cigarettes in the state of residence, cigprice. We will assume that cigprice and u are uncorrelated (even though state support for health care could be correlated with cigarette taxes). If cigarettes are a typical consumption good, basic economic theory suggests that packs and cigprice are negatively correlated, so that cigprice can be used as an IV for packs. To check this, we regress packs on cigprice, using the data in BWGHT.RAW: n 􏱪 1,388, R2 􏱪 .0000, R2 􏱪 􏱦.0006. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. of the OLS estimator—call it 􏱬ˆ1,OLS—as ˆ __ plim 􏱬1,OLS 􏱪 􏱬1 􏱕 Corr(x,u) 􏱳 􏱧u . [15.20] 􏱾 packs 􏱪 .067 􏱕 .0003 cigprice (.103) (.0008) - 523 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares This indicates no relationship between smoking during pregnancy and cigarette prices, which is perhaps not too surprising given the addictive nature of cigarette smoking. Because packs and cigprice are not correlated, we should not use cigprice as an IV for packs in (15.21). But what happens if we do? The IV results would be 􏱾log(bwght) 􏱪 4.45 􏱕 2.99 packs (.91) (8.70) n 􏱪 1,388 (the reported R-squared is negative). The coefficient on packs is huge and of an unex- pected sign. The standard error is also very large, so packs is not significant. But the es- timates are meaningless because cigprice fails the one requirement of an IV that we can always test: assumption (15.5). The previous example shows that IV estimation can produce strange results when the instrument relevance condition, Corr(z,x) 􏱻 0, fails. Of practically greater interest is the so-called problem of weak instruments, which is loosely defined as the problem of “low” (but not zero) correlation between z and x. In a particular application, it is difficult to define how low is too low, but recent theoretical research, supplemented by simulation studies, has shed considerable light on the issue. Staiger and Stock (1997) formalized the problem of weak instruments by modeling the correlation between z and Computing R-Squared after IV Estimation Most regression packages compute an R-squared after IV estimation, using the standard formula: R2 􏱪 1 􏱦 SSR/SST, where SSR is the sum of squared IV residuals, and SST is the total sum of squares of y. Unlike in the case of OLS, the R-squared from IV estima- tion can be negative because SSR for IV can actually be larger than SST. Although it does not really hurt to report the R-squared for IV estimation, it is not very useful, either. When x and u are correlated, we cannot decompose the variance of y into 􏱬21Var(x) 􏱕 Var(u), and so the R-squared has no natural interpretation. In addition, as we will discuss in Section 15.3, these R-squareds cannot be used in the usual way to compute F tests of joint restrictions. If our goal was to produce the largest R-squared, we would always use OLS. IV meth- ods are intended to provide better estimates of the ceteris paribus effect of x on y when x and u are correlated; goodness-of-fit is not a factor. A high R-squared resulting from OLS is of little comfort if we cannot consistently estimate 􏱬1. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. x as a function of the sample size; in particular, the correlation is assumed to shrink to __ zero at the rate 1/􏱯 n . Not surprisingly, the asymptotic distribution of the instrumental variables estimator is different compared with the usual asymptotics, where the correla- tion is assumed to be fixed and nonzero. One of the implications of the Stock-Staiger work is that the usual statistical inference, based on t statistics and the standard nor- mal distribution, can be seriously misleading. [See Imbens and Wooldridge (2007) for further discussion.] 524 PART 3 Advanced Topics 15.2 IV Estimation of the Multiple Regression Model The IV estimator for the simple regression model is easily extended to the multiple regres- sion case. We begin with the case where only one of the explanatory variables is correlated with the error. In fact, consider a standard linear model with two explanatory variables: y1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1y2 􏱕􏱬2z1 􏱕u1. [15.22] We call this a structural equation to emphasize that we are interested in the 􏱬j, which simply means that the equation is supposed to measure a causal relationship. We use a new notation here to distinguish endogenous from exogenous variables. The dependent variable y1 is clearly endogenous, as it is correlated with u1. The variables y2 and z1 are the explanatory variables, and u1 is the error. As usual, we assume that the expected value of u1 is zero: E(u1) 􏱪 0. We use z1 to indicate that this variable is exogenous in (15.22) (z1 is uncorrelated with u1). We use y2 to indicate that this variable is suspected of being corre- lated with u1. We do not specify why y2 and u1 are correlated, but for now it is best to think of u1 as containing an omitted variable correlated with y2. The notation in equation (15.22) originates in simultaneous equations models (which we cover in Chapter 16), but we use it more generally to easily distinguish exogenous from endogenous explanatory variables in a multiple regression model. An example of (15.22) is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 u1, [15.23] where y1 􏱪 log(wage), y2 􏱪 educ, and z1 􏱪 exper. In other words, we assume that exper is exogenous in (15.23), but we allow that educ—for the usual reasons—is correlated with u1. We know that if (15.22) is estimated by OLS, all of the estimators will be biased and inconsistent. Thus, we follow the strategy suggested in the previous section and seek an instrumental variable for y2. Since z1 is assumed to be uncorrelated with u1, can we use z1 as an instrument for y2, assuming y2 and z1 are correlated? The answer is no. Since z1 itself ap- pears as an explanatory variable in (15.22), it cannot serve as an instrumental variable for y2. We need another exogenous variable—call it z2—that does not appear in (15.22). Therefore, key assumptions are that z1 and z2 are uncorrelated with u1; we also assume that u1 has zero expected value, which is without loss of generality when the equation contains an intercept: E(u1) 􏱪 0, Cov(z1,u1) 􏱪 0, and Cov(z2,u1) 􏱪 0. [15.24] Given the zero mean assumption, the latter two assumptions are equivalent to E(z1u1) 􏱪 E(z2u1) 􏱪 0, and so the method of moments approach suggests obtaining estimators 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, and 􏱬ˆ2 by solving the sample counterparts of (15.24): ∑n ˆˆˆ (yi1 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1yi2 􏱦􏱬2zi1)􏱪0 i􏱪1 ∑n ˆˆˆ [15.25] zi1(yi1 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1yi2 􏱦 􏱬2zi1) 􏱪 0 ∑n ˆˆˆ i􏱪1 zi2(yi1 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1yi2 􏱦 􏱬2zi1) 􏱪 0. i􏱪1 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 525 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares This is a set of three linear equations in the three unknowns 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, and 􏱬ˆ2, and it is easily solved given the data on y1, y2, z1, and z2. The estimators are called instrumental variables estimators. If we think y2 is exogenous and we choose z2 􏱪 y2, equations (15.25) are ex- actly the first order conditions for the OLS estimators; see equations (3.13). We still need the instrumental variable z2 to be correlated with y2, but the sense in which these two variables must be correlated is complicated by the presence of z1 in equa- tion (15.22). We now need to state the assumption in terms of partial correlation. The easiest way to state the condition is to write the endogenous explanatory variable as a linear function of the exogenous variables and an error term: y2 􏱪􏰵0 􏱕􏰵1z1 􏱕􏰵2z2 􏱕v2, [15.26] where, by construction, E(v2) 􏱪 0, Cov(z1,v2) 􏱪 0, and Cov(z2,v2) 􏱪 0, and the 􏰵j are unknown parameters. The key identification condition [along with (15.24)] is that 􏰵2 􏱻 0. In other words, after partialling out z1, y2 and z2 are still correlated. This correlation can be positive or negative, but it cannot be zero. Testing (15.27) is easy: we es- timate (15.26) by OLS and use a t test (possibly making it robust to heteroske- dasticity). We should always test this as- sumption. Unfortunately, we cannot test that z1 and z2 are uncorrelated with u1; hopefully, we can make the case based on economic reasoning or introspection. Equation (15.26) is an example of a reduced form equation, which means that we have written an endogenous vari- able in terms of exogenous variables. This name comes from simultaneous equations models—which we study in the next chapter—but it is a useful concept when- ever we have an endogenous explanatory variable. The name helps distinguish it from the structural equation (15.22). [15.27] EXPLORING FURTHER 15.2 Suppose we wish to estimate the effect of marijuana usage on college grade point av- erage. For the population of college seniors at a university, let daysused denote the number of days in the past month on which a student smoked marijuana and consider the structural equation colGPA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1daysused 􏱕 􏱬2 SAT 􏱕 u. (i) Let percHS denote the percentage of a students’s high school graduating class that reported regular use of marijuana. If this is an IV candidate for daysused, write the reduced form for daysused. Do you think (15.27) is likely to be true? (ii) Do you think percHS is truly exogenous in the structural equation? What problems might there be? Adding more exogenous explanatory variables to the model is straightforward. Write the structural model as y1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1y2 􏱕􏱬2z1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kzk􏱦1 􏱕u1, [15.28] where y2 is thought to be correlated with u1. Let zk be a variable not in (15.28) that is also exogenous. Therefore, we assume that E(u1) 􏱪 0, Cov(zj,u1) 􏱪 0, j 􏱪 1, ..., k. [15.29] Under (15.29), z1, ..., zk􏱦1 are the exogenous variables appearing in (15.28). In effect, these act as their own instrumental variables in estimating the 􏱬j in (15.28). The special case of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 526 PART 3 Advanced Topics k 􏱪 2 is given in the equations in (15.25); along with z2, z1 appears in the set of moment conditions used to obtain the IV estimates. More generally, z1, ..., zk􏱦1 are used in the mo- ment conditions along with the instrumental variable for y2, zk. The reduced form for y2 is y2 􏱪􏰵0 􏱕􏰵1z1 􏱕...􏱕􏰵k􏱦1zk􏱦1 􏱕􏰵kzk 􏱕v2, [15.30] and we need some partial correlation between zk and y2: 􏰵k 􏱻 0. [15.31] Under (15.29) and (15.31), zk is a valid IV for y2. [We do not care about the remaining 􏰵j in (15.30); some or all of them could be zero.] A minor additional assumption is that there are no perfect linear relationships among the exogenous variables; this is analogous to the assumption of no perfect collinearity in the context of OLS. For standard statistical inference, we need to assume homoskedasticity of u1. We give a careful statement of these assumptions in a more general setting in Section 15.3. EXAMPLE 15.4 USING COLLEGE PROXIMITY AS AN IV FOR EDUCATION Card (1995) used wage and education data for a sample of men in 1976 to estimate the return to education. He used a dummy variable for whether someone grew up near a four- year college (nearc4) as an instrumental variable for education. In a log(wage) equation, he included other standard controls: experience, a black dummy variable, dummy variables for living in an SMSA and living in the South, and a full set of regional dummy variables and an SMSA dummy for where the man was living in 1966. In order for nearc4 to be a valid instrument, it must be uncorrelated with the error term in the wage equation—we assume this—and it must be partially correlated with educ. To check the latter require- ment, we regress educ on nearc4 and all of the exogenous variables appearing in the equa- tion. (That is, we estimate the reduced form for educ.) Using the data in CARD.RAW, we obtain, in condensed form, educ 􏱪 16.64 􏱕 .320 nearc4 􏱦 .413 exper 􏱕 ... (.24) (.088) (.034) n 􏱪 3,010, R2 􏱪 .477. We are interested in the coefficient and t statistic on nearc4. The coefficient implies that in 1976, other things being fixed (experience, race, region, and so on), people who lived near a college in 1966 had, on average, about one-third of a year more education than those who did not grow up near a college. The t statistic on nearc4 is 3.64, which gives a p-value that is zero in the first three decimals. Therefore, if nearc4 is uncorrelated with unobserved factors in the error term, we can use nearc4 as an IV for educ. The OLS and IV estimates are given in Table 15.1. Interestingly, the IV estimate of the return to education is almost twice as large as the OLS estimate, but the standard error of the IV estimate is over 18 times larger than the OLS standard error. The 95% confidence interval for the IV estimate is between .024 and .239, which is a very wide range. The presence of larger confidence intervals is a price we must pay to get a consis- tent estimator of the return to education when we think educ is endogenous. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 527 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares T A B L E 1 5 . 1 Dependent Variable: log(wage) Explanatory Variables OLS IV educ .075 (.003) .132 (.055) exper .085 (.007) .108 (.024) exper2 􏱦.0023 (.0003) 􏱦.0023 (.0003) black 􏱦.199 (.018) 􏱦.147 (.054) smsa .136 (.020) .112 (.032) south 􏱦.148 (.026) 􏱦.145 (.027) Observations R-squared 3,010 .300 3,010 .238 Other controls: smsa66, reg662, ..., reg669 As discussed earlier, we should not make anything of the smaller R-squared in the IV estimation: by definition, the OLS R-squared will always be larger because OLS mini- mizes the sum of squared residuals. It is worth noting, especially for studying the effects of policy interventions, that a reduced form equation exists for y1, too. In the context of equation (15.28) with zk an IV for y2, the reduced form for y1 always has the form y1 = 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1z1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰸kzk + e1, [15.32] where􏰸j 􏱪􏱬j 􏱕􏱬1πj 􏱕forj<1,􏰸k 􏱪􏱬1πk,ande1 􏱪u1 􏱕􏱬1v2—ascanbeverifiedby plugging (15.30) into (15.28) and rearranging. Because the zj are exogenous in (15.32), the 􏰸j can be consistently estimated by OLS. In other words, we regress y1 on all of the exogenous variables, including zk, the IV for y2. Only if we want to estimate 􏱬1 in (15.28) do we need to apply IV. When y2 is a zero-one variable denoting participation, and zk is a zero-one variable representing eligibility for program participation—which is, hopefully, either randomized across individuals or, at most, a function of the other exogenous variables z1, ..., zk−1 (such as income)—the coefficient 􏰸k has an interesting intepretation. Rather than an estimate of the effect of the program itself, it is an estimate of the effect of offering the program. Unlike 􏱬1 in (15.28)—which measures the effect of the program itself—􏰸k accounts for the pos- sibility that some units made eligible will choose not to participate. In the program evalu- ation literature, 􏰸k is an example of an intention-to-treat parameter: it measures the effect of being made eligible and not the effect of actual participation. The intention-to-treat coefficient, 􏰸k 􏱪 􏱬1πk, depends on the effect of participating, 􏱬1, and the change (typi- cally, increase) in the probability of participating due to being eligible, πk. [When y2 is binary, equation (15.30) is a linear probability model, and therefore πk measures the ceteris paribus change in probability that y2 􏱪 1 as zk switches from zero to one.] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 528 PART 3 Advanced Topics 15.3 Two Stage Least Squares In the previous section, we assumed that we had a single endogenous explanatory variable (y2), along with one instrumental variable for y2. It often happens that we have more than one exogenous variable that is excluded from the structural model and might be correlated with y2, which means they are valid IVs for y2. In this section, we discuss how to use multiple instrumental variables. A Single Endogenous Explanatory Variable Consider again the structural model (15.22), which has one endogenous and one exoge- nous explanatory variable. Suppose now that we have two exogenous variables excluded from (15.22): z2 and z3. Our assumptions that z2 and z3 do not appear in (15.22) and are uncorrelated with the error u1 are known as exclusion restrictions. If z2 and z3 are both correlated with y2, we could just use each as an IV, as in the previ- ous section. But then we would have two IV estimators, and neither of these would, in gen- eral, be efficient. Since each of z1, z2, and z3 is uncorrelated with u1, any linear combination is also uncorrelated with u1, and therefore any linear combination of the exogenous vari- ables is a valid IV. To find the best IV, we choose the linear combination that is most highly correlated with y2. This turns out to be given by the reduced form equation for y2. Write y2 􏱪􏰵0 􏱕􏰵1z1 􏱕􏰵2z2 􏱕􏰵3z3 􏱕v2, [15.33] E(v2) 􏱪 0, Cov(z1,v2) 􏱪 0, Cov(z2,v2) 􏱪 0, and Cov(z3,v2) 􏱪 0. where Then, the best IV for y2 (under the assumptions given in the chapter appendix) is the linear combination of the zj in (15.33), which we call y*2: y*2 􏱪 􏰵0 􏱕 􏰵1z1 􏱕 􏰵2z2 􏱕 􏰵3z3. [15.34] For this IV not to be perfectly correlated with z1 we need at least one of 􏰵2 or 􏰵3 to be dif- ferent from zero: 􏰵2 􏱻0or􏰵3 􏱻0. [15.35] This is the key identification assumption, once we assume the zj are all exogenous. (The value of 􏰵1 is irrelevant.) The structural equation (15.22) is not identified if 􏰵2 􏱪 0 and 􏰵3 􏱪 0. We can test H0: 􏰵2 􏱪 0 and 􏰵3 􏱪 0 against (15.35) using an F statistic. A useful way to think of (15.33) is that it breaks y2 into two pieces. The first is y*2; this is the part of y2 that is uncorrelated with the error term, u1. The second piece is v2, and this part is possibly correlated with u1—which is why y2 is possibly endogenous. Given data on the zj, we can compute y*2 for each observation, provided we know the population parameters 􏰵j. This is never true in practice. Nevertheless, as we saw in the previous section, we can always estimate the reduced form by OLS. Thus, using the sample, we regress y2 on z1, z2, and z3 and obtain the fitted values: yˆ2 􏱪 􏰵ˆ0 􏱕 􏰵ˆ1z1 􏱕 􏰵ˆ2z2 􏱕 􏰵ˆ3z3 [15.36] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 529 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares (that is, we have yˆi2 for each i). At this point, we should verify that z2 and z3 are jointly significant in (15.33) at a reasonably small significance level (no larger than 5%). If z2 and z3 are not jointly significant in (15.33) then we are wasting our time with IV estimation. Once we have yˆ2, we can use it as the IV for y2. The three equations for estimating 􏱬0, 􏱬1, and 􏱬2 are the first two equations of (15.25), with the third replaced by ∑n ˆˆˆ yˆi2(yi1 􏱦 􏱬0 􏱦 􏱬1yi2 􏱦 􏱬2zi1) 􏱪 0. [15.37] i􏱪1 Solving the three equations in three unknowns gives us the IV estimators. With multiple instruments, the IV estimator using yˆi2 as the instrument is also called the two stage least squares (2SLS) estimator. The reason is simple. Using the algebra of OLS, it can be shown that when we use yˆ2 as the IV for y2, the IV estimates 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, and 􏱬ˆ2 are identical to the OLS estimates from the regression of y1 on yˆ2 and z1. [15.38] In other words, we can obtain the 2SLS estimator in two stages. The first stage is to run the regression in (15.36), where we obtain the fitted values yˆ2. The second stage is the OLS regression (15.38). Because we use yˆ2 in place of y2, the 2SLS estimates can differ substantially from the OLS estimates. Some economists like to interpret the regression in (15.38) as follows. The fitted value, yˆ2, is the estimated version of y*2, and y*2 is uncorrelated with u1. Therefore, 2SLS first “purges” y2 of its correlation with u1 before doing the OLS regression in (15.38). We can show this by plugging y2 􏱪 y*2 􏱕 v2 into (15.22): y1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1y*2 􏱕􏱬2z1 􏱕u1 􏱕􏱬1v2. [15.39] Now, the composite error u1 􏱕 􏱬1v2 has zero mean and is uncorrelated with y*2 and z1, which is why the OLS regression in (15.38) works. Most econometrics packages have special commands for 2SLS, so there is no need to per- form the two stages explicitly. In fact, in most cases you should avoid doing the second stage manually, as the standard errors and test statistics obtained in this way are not valid. [The rea- son is that the error term in (15.39) includes v2, but the standard errors involve the variance of u1 only.] Any regression software that supports 2SLS asks for the dependent variable, the list of explanatory variables (both exogenous and endogenous), and the entire list of instrumental vari- ables (that is, all exogenous variables). The output is typically quite similar to that for OLS. In model (15.28) with a single IV for y2, the IV estimator from Section 15.2 is identi- cal to the 2SLS estimator. Therefore, when we have one IV for each endogenous explana- tory variable, we can call the estimation method IV or 2SLS. Adding more exogenous variables changes very little. For example, suppose the wage equation is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 u1, [15.40] where u1 is uncorrelated with both exper and exper2. Suppose that we also think mother’s and father’s educations are uncorrelated with u1. Then, we can use both of these as IVs for educ. The reduced form equation for educ is educ 􏱪 􏰵0 􏱕 􏰵1exper 􏱕 􏰵2exper2 􏱕 􏰵3motheduc 􏱕 􏰵4 fatheduc 􏱕 v2, [15.41] and identification requires that 􏰵3 􏱻 0 or 􏰵4 􏱻 0 (or both, of course). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 530 PART 3 Advanced Topics EXAMPLE 15.5 RETURN TO EDUCATION FOR WORKING WOMEN We estimate equation (15.40) using the data in MROZ.RAW. First, we test H0: 􏰵3 􏱪 0, 􏰵4 􏱪 0 in (15.41) using an F test. The result is F 􏱪 55.40, and p-value 􏱪 .0000. As ex- pected, educ is (partially) correlated with parents’ education. When we estimate (15.40) by 2SLS, we obtain, in equation form, 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 .048 􏱕 .061 educ 􏱕 .044 exper 􏱦 .0009 exper2 (.400) (.031) (.013) (.0004) n 􏱪 428, R2 􏱪 .136. The estimated return to education is about 6.1%, compared with an OLS estimate of about 10.8%. Because of its relatively large standard error, the 2SLS estimate is barely statisti- cally significant at the 5% level against a two-sided alternative. The assumptions needed for 2SLS to have the desired large sample properties are given in the chapter appendix, but it is useful to briefly summarize them here. If we write the structural equation as in (15.28), y1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1y2 􏱕􏱬2z1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kzk􏱦1 􏱕u1, [15.42] then we assume each zj to be uncorrelated with u1. In addition, we need at least one exogenous variable not in (15.42) that is partially correlated with y2. This ensures consis- tency. For the usual 2SLS standard errors and t statistics to be asymptotically valid, we also need a homoskedasticity assumption: the variance of the structural error, u1, cannot depend on any of the exogenous variables. For time series applications, we need more assumptions, as we will see in Section 15.7. Multicollinearity and 2SLS In Chapter 3, we introduced the problem of multicollinearity and showed how correlation among regressors can lead to large standard errors for the OLS estimates. Multicollinear- ity can be even more serious with 2SLS. To see why, the (asymptotic) variance of the 2SLS estimator of 􏱬1 can be approximated as 􏱧2/[􏱾SST2(1 􏱦 Rˆ2)], [15.43] where 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(u1), 􏱾SST2 is the total variation in yˆ2, and Rˆ2 is the R-squared from a regres- sion of yˆ2 on all other exogenous variables appearing in the structural equation. There are two reasons why the variance of the 2SLS estimator is larger than that for OLS. First, yˆ2, by construction, has less variation than y2. (Remember: Total sum of squares 􏱪 explained sum of squares 􏱕 residual sum of squares; the variation in y2 is the total sum of squares, while the variation in yˆ2 is the explained sum of squares from the first stage regression.) Second, the correlation between yˆ2 and the exogenous variables in (15.42) is often much higher than the correlation between y2 and these variables. This essentially defines the multicollinearity problem in 2SLS. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 531 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares As an illustration, consider Example 15.4. When educ is regressed on the exogenous variables in Table 15.1 (not including nearc4), R-squared 􏱪 .475; this is a moderate degree of multicollinearity, but the important thing is that the OLS standard error on 􏱬ˆeduc is quite small. When we obtain the first stage fitted values, 􏱾educ, and regress these on the exog- enous variables in Table 15.1, R-squared 􏱪 .995, which indicates a very high degree of multicollinearity between 􏱾educ and the remaining exogenous variables in the table. (This high R-squared is not too surprising because 􏱾educ is a function of all the exogenous vari- ables in Table 15.1, plus nearc4.) Equation (15.43) shows that an Rˆ2 close to one can result in a very large standard error for the 2SLS estimator. But as with OLS, a large sample size can help offset a large Rˆ2. Multiple Endogenous Explanatory Variables Two stage least squares can also be used in models with more than one endogenous explanatory variable. For example, consider the model y1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1y2 􏱕􏱬2y3 􏱕􏱬3z1 􏱕􏱬4z2 􏱕􏱬5z3 􏱕u1, [15.44] where E(u1) 􏱪 0 and u1 is uncorrelated with z1, z2, and z3. The variables y2 and y3 are endogenous explanatory variables: each may be correlated with u1. To estimate (15.44) by 2SLS, we need at least two exogenous variables that do not ap- pear in (15.44) but that are correlated with y2 and y3. Suppose we have two excluded exog- enous variables, say z4 and z5. Then, from our analysis of a single endogenous explanatory variable, we need either z4 or z5 to appear in each reduced form for y2 and y3. (As before, we can use F statistics to test this.) Although this is necessary for identification, unfortu- nately, it is not sufficient. Suppose that z4 appears in each reduced form, but z5 appears in neither. Then, we do not really have two exogenous variables partially correlated with y2 and y3. Two stage least squares will not produce consistent estimators of the 􏱬j. Generally, when we have more than one endogenous explanatory variable in a regression model, identification can fail in several complicated ways. But we can easily state a necessary condition for identification, which is called the order condition. Order Condition for Identification of an Equation. We need at least as many excluded exogenous variables as there are included endogenous explana- tory variables in the structural equation. The order condition is simple to check, as it only involves counting endogenous and exogenous variables. The sufficient condition for identification is called the rank condition. We have seen special cases of the rank condition before—for example, in the discussion surrounding equation (15.35). A general statement of the rank condition requires matrix alge- bra and is beyond the scope of this text. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 15.3 The following model explains violent crime rates, at the city level, in terms of a binary variable for whether gun control laws exist and other controls: violent 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1guncontrol 􏱕 􏱬2unem 􏱕 􏱬3popul 􏱕 􏱬4percblck 􏱕 􏱬5age18_21 􏱕 .... Some researchers have estimated similar equations using variables such as the num- ber of National Rifle Association members in the city and the number of subscribers to gun magazines as instrumental variables for guncontrol [see, for example, Kleck and Patterson (1993)]. Are these convincing instruments? 532 PART 3 Advanced Topics Testing Multiple Hypotheses after 2SLS Estimation We must be careful when testing multiple hypotheses in a model estimated by 2SLS. It is tempting to use either the sum of squared residuals or the R-squared form of the F statistic, as we learned with OLS in Chapter 4. The fact that the R-squared in 2SLS can be negative suggests that the usual way of computing F statistics might not be appropriate; this is the case. In fact, if we use the 2SLS residuals to compute the SSRs for both the restricted and unrestricted models, there is no guarantee that SSRr 􏱸 SSRur; if the reverse is true, the F statistic would be negative. It is possible to combine the sum of squared residuals from the second stage regres- sion [such as (15.38)] with SSRur to obtain a statistic with an approximate F distribution in large samples. Because many econometrics packages have simple-to-use test commands that can be used to test multiple hypotheses after 2SLS estimation, we omit the details. Davidson and MacKinnon (1993) and Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5) contain discussions of how to compute F-type statistics for 2SLS. 15.4 IV Solutions to Errors-in-Variables Problems In the previous sections, we presented the use of instrumental variables as a way to solve the omitted variables problem, but they can also be used to deal with the measurement error problem. As an illustration, consider the model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x*1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕u, [15.45] where y and x2 are observed but x*1 is not. Let x1 be an observed measurement of x*1: x1 􏱪 x*1 􏱕 e1, where e1 is the measurement error. In Chapter 9, we showed that correlation be- tween x1 and e1 causes OLS, where x1 is used in place of x*1, to be biased and inconsistent. We can see this by writing y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕(u􏱦􏱬1e1). [15.46] If the classical errors-in-variables (CEV) assumptions hold, the bias in the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 is toward zero. Without further assumptions, we can do nothing about this. In some cases, we can use an IV procedure to solve the measurement error problem. In (15.45), we assume that u is uncorrelated with x*1, x1, and x2; in the CEV case, we as- sume that e1 is uncorrelated with x*1 and x2. These imply that x2 is exogenous in (15.46), but that x1 is correlated with e1. What we need is an IV for x1. Such an IV must be cor- related with x1, uncorrelated with u—so that it can be excluded from (15.45)—and uncor- related with the measurement error, e1. One possibility is to obtain a second measurement on x*1, say, z1. Because it is x*1 that affects y, it is only natural to assume that z1 is uncorrelated with u. If we write z1 􏱪 x*1 􏱕 a1, where a1 is the measurement error in z1, then we must assume that a1 and e1 are uncor- related. In other words, x1 and z1 both mismeasure x*1, but their measurement errors are uncorrelated. Certainly, x1 and z1 are correlated through their dependence on x*1, so we can use z1 as an IV for x1. Where might we get two measurements on a variable? Sometimes, when a group of workers is asked for their annual salary, their employers can provide a second measure. For married couples, each spouse can independently report the level of savings or family Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 533 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares income. In the Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) study cited in Section 14.3, each twin was asked about his or her sibling’s years of education; this gives a second measure that can be used as an IV for self-reported education in a wage equation. (Ashenfelter and Krue- ger combined differencing and IV to account for the omitted ability problem as well; more on this in Section 15.8.) Generally, though, having two measures of an explanatory variable is rare. An alternative is to use other exogenous variables as IVs for a potentially mis- measured variable. For example, our use of motheduc and fatheduc as IVs for educ in Example 15.5 can serve this purpose. If we think that educ 􏱪 educ* 􏱕 e1, then the IV estimates in Example 15.5 do not suffer from measurement error if motheduc and fathe- duc are uncorrelated with the measurement error, e1. This is probably more reasonable than assuming motheduc and fatheduc are uncorrelated with ability, which is contained in u in (15.45). IV methods can also be adopted when using things like test scores to control for unobserved characteristics. In Section 9.2, we showed that, under certain assumptions, proxy variables can be used to solve the omitted variables problem. In Example 9.3, we used IQ as a proxy variable for unobserved ability. This simply entails adding IQ to the model and performing an OLS regression. But there is an alternative that works when IQ does not fully satisfy the proxy variable assumptions. To illustrate, write a wage equation as log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 abil 􏱕 u, [15.47] where we again have the omitted ability problem. But we have two test scores that are indicators of ability. We assume that the scores can be written as test1 􏱪 􏰸1abil 􏱕 e1 and test2 􏱪 􏱛1abil 􏱕 e2, where 􏰸1 􏱰 0, 􏱛1 􏱰 0. Since it is ability that affects wage, we can assume that test1 and test2 are uncorrelated with u. If we write abil in terms of the first test score and plug the result into (15.47), we get log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 􏱮1test1 􏱕 (u 􏱦 􏱮1e1), [15.48] where 􏱮1 􏱪 1/􏰸1. Now, if we assume that e1 is uncorrelated with all the explanatory vari- ables in (15.47), including abil, then e1 and test1 must be correlated. [Notice that educ is not endogenous in (15.48); however, test1 is.] This means that estimating (15.48) by OLS will produce inconsistent estimators of the 􏱬j (and 􏱮1). Under the assumptions we have made, test1 does not satisfy the proxy variable assumptions. If we assume that e2 is also uncorrelated with all the explanatory variables in (15.47) and that e1 and e2 are uncorrelated, then e1 is uncorrelated with the second test score, test2. Therefore, test2 can be used as an IV for test1. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 534 PART 3 Advanced Topics EXAMPLE 15.6 USING TWO TEST SCORES AS INDICATORS OF ABILITY We use the data in WAGE2.RAW to implement the preceding procedure, where IQ plays the role of the first test score, and KWW (knowledge of the world of work) is the second test score. The explanatory variables are the same as in Example 9.3: educ, exper, tenure, married, south, urban, and black. Rather than adding IQ and doing OLS, as in column (2) of Table 9.2, we add IQ and use KWW as its instrument. The coefficient on educ is .025 (se 􏱪 .017). This is a low estimate, and it is not statistically different from zero. This is a puzzling finding, and it suggests that one of our assumptions fails; perhaps e1 and e2 are correlated. 15.5 Testing for Endogeneity and Testing Overidentifying Restrictions In this section, we describe two important tests in the context of instrumental variables estimation. Testing for Endogeneity The 2SLS estimator is less efficient than OLS when the explanatory variables are exoge- nous; as we have seen, the 2SLS estimates can have very large standard errors. Therefore, it is useful to have a test for endogeneity of an explanatory variable that shows whether 2SLS is even necessary. Obtaining such a test is rather simple. To illustrate, suppose we have a single suspected endogenous variable, y1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1y2 􏱕􏱬2z1 􏱕􏱬3z2 􏱕u1, [15.49] where z1 and z2 are exogenous. We have two additional exogenous variables, z3 and z4, which do not appear in (15.49). If y2 is uncorrelated with u1, we should estimate (15.49) by OLS. How can we test this? Hausman (1978) suggested directly comparing the OLS and 2SLS estimates and determining whether the differences are statistically significant. After all, both OLS and 2SLS are consistent if all variables are exogenous. If 2SLS and OLS differ signifi- cantly, we conclude that y2 must be endogenous (maintaining that the zj are exogenous). It is a good idea to compute OLS and 2SLS to see if the estimates are practically dif- ferent. To determine whether the differences are statistically significant, it is easier to use a regression test. This is based on estimating the reduced form for y2, which in this case is y2 􏱪􏰵0 􏱕􏰵1z1 􏱕􏰵2z2 􏱕􏰵3z3 􏱕􏰵4z4 􏱕v2. [15.50] Now, since each zj is uncorrelated with u1, y2 is uncorrelated with u1 if, and only if, v2 is un- correlated with u1; this is what we wish to test. Write u1 􏱪 􏱛1v2 􏱕 e1, where e1 is uncorrelated with v2 and has zero mean. Then, u1 and v2 are uncorrelated if, and only if, 􏱛1 􏱪 0. The easiest way to test this is to include v2 as an additional regressor in (15.49) and to do a t test. There is only one problem with implementing this: v2 is not observed, because it is the error term in (15.50). Because we can estimate the reduced form for y2 by OLS, we can obtain the reduced form residuals, vˆ2. Therefore, we estimate y1 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1y2 􏱕 􏱬2z1 􏱕 􏱬3z2 􏱕 􏱛1vˆ2 􏱕 error [15.51] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 535 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares by OLS and test H0: 􏱛1 􏱪 0 using a t statistic. If we reject H0 at a small significance level, we conclude that y2 is endogenous because v2 and u1 are correlated. Testing for Endogeneity of a Single Explanatory Variable: (i) Estimate the reduced form for y2 by regressing it on all exogenous variables (including those in the structural equation and the additional IVs). Obtain the residuals, vˆ2. (ii) Add vˆ2 to the structural equation (which includes y2) and test for significance of vˆ2 using an OLS regression. If the coefficient on vˆ2 is statistically different from zero, we conclude that y2 is indeed endogenous. We might want to use a heteroskedasticity-robust t test. EXAMPLE 15.7 RETURN TO EDUCATION FOR WORKING WOMEN We can test for endogeneity of educ in (15.40) by obtaining the residuals vˆ2 from esti- mating the reduced form (15.41)—using only working women—and including these in (15.40). When we do this, the coefficient on vˆ2 is 􏱛ˆ1 􏱪 .058, and t 􏱪 1.67. This is moderate evidence of positive correlation between u1 and v2. It is probably a good idea to report both estimates because the 2SLS estimate of the return to education (6.1%) is well below the OLS estimate (10.8%). An interesting feature of the regression from step (ii) of the test for endogeneity is that the coefficient estimates on all explanatory variables (except, of course, vˆ2) are identi- cal to the 2SLS estimates. For example, estimating (15.51) by OLS produces the same 􏱬ˆj as estimating (15.49) by 2SLS. One benefit of this equivalence is that it provides an easy check on whether you have done the proper regression in testing for endogeneity. But it also gives a different, useful interpretation of 2SLS: adding vˆ2 to the original equation as an explanatory variable, and applying OLS, clears up the endogeneity of y2. So, when we start by estimating (15.49) by OLS, we can quantify the importance of allowing y2 to be endogenous by seeing how much 􏱬ˆ1 changes when vˆ2 is added to the equation. Irrespec- tive of the outcome of the statistical tests, we can see whether the change in 􏱬ˆ1 is expected and is practically significant. We can also test for endogeneity of multiple explanatory variables. For each suspected endogenous variable, we obtain the reduced form residuals, as in part (i). Then, we test for joint significance of these residuals in the structural equation, using an F test. Joint signifi- cance indicates that at least one suspected explanatory variable is endogenous. The number of exclusion restrictions tested is the number of suspected endogenous explanatory variables. Testing Overidentification Restrictions When we introduced the simple instrumental variables estimator in Section 15.1, we emphasized that the instrument must satisfy two requirements: it must be uncorrelated with the error (exogeneity) and correlated with the endogenous explanatory variable (relevance). We have now seen that, even in models with additional explanatory variables, the second requirement can be tested using a t test (with just one instrument) or an F test (when there are multiple instruments). In the context of the simple IV estimator, we noted that the exo- geneity requirement cannot be tested. However, if we have more instruments than we need, we can effectively test whether some of them are uncorrelated with the structural error. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 536 PART 3 Advanced Topics As a specific example, again consider equation (15.49) with two instrumental variables for y2, z3, and z4. Remember, z1 and z2 essentially act as their own instruments. Because we have two instruments for y2, we can estimate (15.49) using, say, only z3 as an IV for y2; let 􏱬ˇ1 be the resulting IV estimator of 􏱬1. Then, we can estimate (15.49) using only z4 as an IV for y2; call this IV estimator 􏱬 ̃1. If all zj are exogenous, and if z3 and z4 are each partially correlated with y2, then 􏱬ˇ1 and 􏱬 ̃1 are both consistent for 􏱬1. Therefore, if our logic for choosing the instruments is sound, 􏱬ˇ1 and 􏱬 ̃ 1 should differ only by sampling error. Hausman (1978) proposed basing a test of whether z3 and z4 are both exogenous on the difference, 􏱬ˇ1 􏱦 􏱬 ̃1. Shortly, we will provide a simpler way to obtain a valid test, but, before doing so, we should understand how to interpret the outcome of the test. If we conclude that 􏱬ˇ1 and 􏱬 ̃1 are statistically different from one another, then we have no choice but to conclude that either z3, z4, or both fail the exogeneity requirement. Unfor- tunately, we cannot know which is the case (unless we simply assert from the beginning that, say, z3 is exogenous). For example, if y2 denotes years of schooling in a log wage equation, z3 is mother’s education, and z4 is father’s education, a statistically significant difference in the two IV estimators implies that one or both of the parents’ education vari- ables are correlated with u1 in (15.54). Certainly, rejecting one’s instruments as being exogenous is serious and requires a new approach. But the more serious, and subtle, problem in comparing IV estimates is that they may be similar even though both instruments fail the exogeneity requirement. In the previous example, it seems likely that if mother’s education is positively correlated with u1, then so is father’s education. Therefore, the two IV estimates may be similar even though each is inconsistent. In effect, because the IVs in this example are chosen using similar reasoning, their separate use in IV procedures may very well lead to similar estimates that are nevertheless both inconsistent. The point is that we should not feel espe- cially comfortable if our IV procedures pass the Hausman test. Another problem with comparing two IV estimates is that often they may seem practi- cally different yet, statistically, we cannot reject the null hypothesis that they are consis- tent for the same population parameter. For example, in estimating (15.40) by IV using motheduc as the only instrument, the coefficient on educ is .049 (.037). If we use only fatheduc as the IV for educ, the coefficient on educ is .070 (.034). [Perhaps not surpris- ingly, the estimate using both parents’ education as IVs is in between these two, .061 (.031).] For policy purposes, the difference between 5% and 7% for the estimated return to a year of schooling is substantial. Yet, as shown in Example 15.8, the difference is not statistically significant. The procedure of comparing different IV estimates of the same parameter is an example of testing overidentifying restrictions. The general idea is that we have more instruments than we need to estimate the parameters consistently. In the previous example, we had one more instrument than we need, and this results in one overidentifying restriction that can be tested. In the general case, suppose that we have q more instruments than we need. For example, with one endogenous explanatory variable, y2, and three proposed instruments for y2, we have q 􏱪 3 􏱦 1 􏱪 2 overidentifying restrictions. When q is two or more, com- paring several IV estimates is cumbersome. Instead, we can easily compute a test statistic based on the 2SLS residuals. The idea is that, if all instruments are exogenous, the 2SLS residuals should be uncorrelated with the instruments, up to sampling error. But if there are k 􏱕 1 parameters and k 􏱕 1 􏱕 q instruments, the 2SLS residuals have a zero mean and are identically uncorrelated with k linear combinations of the instruments. (This algebraic fact contains, as a special case, the fact that the OLS residuals have a zero mean and Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 537 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares are uncorrelated with the k explanatory variables.) Therefore, the test checks whether the 2SLS residuals are correlated with q linear functions of the instruments, and we need not decide on the functions; the test does that for us automatically. The following regression-based test is valid when the homoskedasticity assumption, listed as Assumption 2SLS.5 in the chapter appendix, holds. Testing Overidentifying Restrictions: (i) Estimate the structural equation by 2SLS and obtain the 2SLS residuals, uˆ1. (ii) Regress uˆ1 on all exogenous variables. Obtain the R-squared, say, R21. (iii) Under the null hypothesis that all IVs are uncorrelated with u1, nR21 ~a 􏱚2q, where q is the number of instrumental variables from outside the model minus the total num- ber of endogenous explanatory variables. If nR21 exceeds (say) the 5% critical value in the 􏱚2q distribution, we reject H0 and conclude that at least some of the IVs are not exogenous. EXAMPLE 15.8 RETURN TO EDUCATION FOR WORKING WOMEN When we use motheduc and fatheduc as IVs for educ in (15.40), we have a single overidentifying restriction. Regressing the 2SLS residuals uˆ1 on exper, exper2, mothe- duc, and fatheduc produces R21 􏱪 .0009. Therefore, nR21 􏱪 428(.0009) 􏱪 .3852, which is a very small value in a 􏱚21 distribution ( p-value 􏱪 .535). Therefore, the parents’ edu- cation variables pass the overidentification test. When we add husband’s education to the IV list, we get two overidentifying restrictions, and nR21 􏱪 1.11 (p-value 􏱪 .574). Subject to the preceding cautions, it seems reasonable to add huseduc to the IV list, as this reduces the standard error of the 2SLS estimate: the 2SLS estimate on educ using all three instruments is .080 (se 􏱪 .022), so this makes educ much more significant than when huseduc is not used as an IV (􏱬ˆeduc 􏱪 .061, se 􏱪 .031). When q 􏱪 1, a natural question is: How does the test obtained from the regression- based procedure compare with a test based on directly comparing the estimates? In fact, the two procedures are asymptotically the same. As a practical matter, it makes sense to compute the two IV estimates to see how they differ. More generally, when q 􏱸 2, one can compare the 2SLS estimates using all IVs to the IV estimates using single instruments. By doing so, one can see if the various IV estimates are practically different, whether or not the overidentification test rejects or fails to reject. In the previous example, we alluded to a general fact about 2SLS: under the standard 2SLS assumptions, adding instruments to the list improves the asymptotic efficiency of the 2SLS. But this requires that any new instruments are in fact exogenous—otherwise, 2SLS will not even be consistent—and it is only an asymptotic result. With the typical sample sizes available, adding too many instruments—that is, increasing the number of overiden- tifying restrictions—can cause severe biases in 2SLS. A detailed discussion would take us too far afield. A nice illustration is given by Bound, Jaeger, and Baker (1995) who argue that the 2SLS estimates of the return to education obtained by Angrist and Krueger (1991), using many instrumental variables, are likely to be seriously biased (even with hundreds of thousands of observations!). The overidentification test can be used whenever we have more instruments than we need. If we have just enough instruments, the model is said to be just identified, and the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 538 PART 3 Advanced Topics R-squared in part (ii) will be identically zero. As we mentioned earlier, we cannot test exogeneity of the instruments in the just identified case. The test can be made robust to heteroskedasticity of arbitrary form; for details, see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5). 15.6 2SLS with Heteroskedasticity Heteroskedasticity in the context of 2SLS raises essentially the same issues as with OLS. Most importantly, it is possible to obtain standard errors and test statistics that are (asymptotically) robust to heteroskedasticity of arbitrary and unknown form. In fact, expression (8.4) continues to be valid if the rˆij are obtained as the residuals from regressing xˆij on the other xˆih, where the “ˆ” denotes fitted values from the first stage regressions (for endogenous explanatory variables). Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5) contains more details. Some software packages do this routinely. We can also test for heteroskedasticity, using an analog of the Breusch-Pagan test that we covered in Chapter 8. Let uˆ denote the 2SLS residuals and let z1, z2, ..., zm denote all the exogenous variables (including those used as IVs for the endogenous explanatory variables). Then, under reasonable assumptions [spelled out, for example, in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5)], an asymptotically valid statistic is the usual F statistic for joint sig- nificance in a regression of uˆ2 on z1, z2, ..., zm. The null hypothesis of homoskedasticity is rejected if the zj are jointly significant. If we apply this test to Example 15.8, using motheduc, fatheduc, and huseduc as instruments for educ, we obtain F5,422 􏱪 2.53, and p-value 􏱪 .029. This is evidence of heteroskedasticity at the 5% level. We might want to compute heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors to account for this. If we know how the error variance depends on the exogenous variables, we can use a weighted 2SLS procedure, essentially the same as in Section 8.4. After estimating a model for Var(u􏰫z1, z2, ..., zm), we divide the dependen_t_variable, the explanatory variables, and all the instrumental variables for observation i by √hˆi, where hˆi denotes the estim_a_ted variance. (The constant, which is both an explanatory variable and an IV, is divided by √hˆi ; see Section 8.4.) Then, we apply 2SLS on the transformed equation using the transformed instruments. 15.7 Applying 2SLS to Time Series Equations When we apply 2SLS to time series data, many of the considerations that arose for OLS in Chapters 10, 11, and 12 are relevant. Write the structural equation for each time period as yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕ut, [15.52] where one or more of the explanatory variables xtj might be correlated with ut. Denote the set of exogenous variables by zt1, ..., ztm: E(ut) 􏱪 0, Cov(ztj,ut) 􏱪 0, j 􏱪 1, ..., m. Any exogenous explanatory variable is also a ztj. For identification, it is necessary that m 􏱸 k (we have as many exogenous variables as explanatory variables). The mechanics of 2SLS are identical for time series or cross-sectional data, but for time series data the statistical properties of 2SLS depend on the trending and correlation Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 539 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares properties of the underlying sequences. In particular, we must be careful to include trends if we have trending dependent or explanatory variables. Since a time trend is exogenous, it can always serve as its own instrumental variable. The same is true of seasonal dummy variables, if monthly or quarterly data are used. Series that have strong persistence (have unit roots) must be used with care, just as with OLS. Often, differencing the equation is warranted before estima- tion, and this applies to the instruments as well. Under analogs of the assumptions in Chapter 11 for the asymptotic properties of OLS, 2SLS using time series data is consistent and asymptotically normally distributed. In fact, if we replace the explanatory variables with the instrumental variables in stating the assumptions, we only need to add the identification assumptions for 2SLS. For ex- ample, the homoskedasticity assumption is stated as E(u2t 􏰫zt1, ..., ztm) 􏱪 􏱧2, [15.53] and the no serial correlation assumption is stated as E(utus􏰫zt, zs) 􏱪 0, for all t 􏱻 s, [15.54] where zt denotes all exogenous variables at time t. A full statement of the assumptions is given in the chapter appendix. We will provide examples of 2SLS for time series prob- lems in Chapter 16; see also Computer Exercise C4. As in the case of OLS, the no serial correlation assumption can often be violated with time series data. Fortunately, it is very easy to test for AR(1) serial correlation. If we write ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et and plug this into equation (15.52), we get yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xt1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxtk 􏱕􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕et,t􏱸2. [15.55] To test H0: 􏰴1 􏱪 0, we must replace ut􏱦1 with the 2SLS residuals, uˆt􏱦1. Further, if xtj is endogenous in (15.52), then it is endogenous in (15.55), so we still need to use an IV. Because et is uncorrelated with all past values of ut, ˆut􏱦1 can be used as its own instrument. Testing for AR(1) Serial Correlation after 2SLS: (i) Estimate (15.52) by 2SLS and obtain the 2SLS residuals, uˆt. (ii) Estimate yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxtk 􏱕 􏰴uˆt􏱦1 􏱕 errort, t 􏱪 2, ..., n by 2SLS, using the same instruments from part (i), in addition to uˆt􏱦1. Use the t statistic on 􏰴ˆ to test H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 15.4 A model to test the effect of growth in gov- ernment spending on growth in output is gGDPt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gGOVt 􏱕 􏱬2INVRATt 􏱕 􏱬3gLABt 􏱕 ut, where g indicates growth, GDP is real gross domestic product, GOV is real govern- ment spending, INVRAT is the ratio of gross domestic investment to GDP, and LAB is the size of the labor force. [See equation (6) in Ram (1986).] Under what assump- tions would a dummy variable indicating whether the president in year t 􏱦 1 is a Republican be a suitable IV for gGOVt? 540 PART 3 Advanced Topics As with the OLS version of this test from Chapter 12, the t statistic only has asymp- totic justification, but it tends to work well in practice. A heteroskedasticity-robust version can be used to guard against heteroskedasticity. Further, lagged residuals can be added to the equation to test for higher forms of serial correlation using a joint F test. What happens if we detect serial correlation? Some econometrics packages will com- pute standard errors that are robust to fairly general forms of serial correlation and hetero- skedasticity. This is a nice, simple way to go if your econometrics package does this. The computations are very similar to those in Section 12.5 for OLS. [See Wooldridge (1995) for formulas and other computational methods.] An alternative is to use the AR(1) model and correct for serial correlation. The pro- cedure is similar to that for OLS and places additional restrictions on the instrumental variables. The quasi-differenced equation is the same as in equation (12.32): y ̃t 􏱪􏱬0(1􏱦􏰴)􏱕􏱬1x ̃t1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kx ̃tk 􏱕et, t􏱸2, [15.56] where x ̃tj 􏱪 xtj 􏱦 􏰴xt􏱦1, j. (We can use the t 􏱪 1 observation just as in Section 12.3, but we omit that for simplicity here.) The question is: What can we use as instrumental variables? It seems natural to use the quasi-differenced instruments, z ̃tj 􏱪 ztj 􏱦 􏰴zt􏱦1, j. This only works, however, if in (15.52) the original error ut is uncorrelated with the in- struments at times t, t 􏱦 1, and t 􏱕 1. That is, the instrumental variables must be strictly exogenous in (15.52). This rules out lagged dependent variables as IVs, for example. It also eliminates cases where future movements in the IVs react to current and past changes in the error, ut. 2SLS with AR(1) Errors: (i) Estimate (15.52) by 2SLS and obtain the 2SLS residuals, uˆt, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. (ii) Obtain 􏰴ˆ from the regression of uˆt on uˆt􏱦1, t 􏱪 2, ..., n and construct the quasi- differenced variables y ̃t 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏰴ˆyt􏱦1, x ̃tj 􏱪 xtj 􏱦 􏰴ˆxt􏱦1, j, and z ̃tj 􏱪 ztj 􏱦 􏰴ˆzt􏱦1, j for t 􏱸 2. (Remember, in most cases, some of the IVs will also be explanatory variables.) (iii) Estimate (15.56) (where 􏰴 is replaced with 􏰴ˆ) by 2SLS, using the z ̃tj as the instru- ments. Assuming that (15.56) satisfies the 2SLS assumptions in the chapter appendix, the usual 2SLS test statistics are asymptotically valid. We can also use the first time period as in Prais-Winsten estimation of the model with exogenous explanatory variables. The transformed variables in the first time period—the dependent variable, explanatory variables, and instrumental variables—are obtained sim- ply by multiplying all first-period values by (1 􏱦 􏰴ˆ)1/2. (See also Section 12.3.) 15.8 Applying 2SLS to Pooled Cross Sections and Panel Data Applying instrumental variables methods to independently pooled cross sections raises no new difficulties. As with models estimated by OLS, we should often include time period dummy variables to allow for aggregate time effects. These dummy variables are exogenous—because the passage of time is exogenous—and so they act as their own instruments. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 541 CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares EXAMPLE 15.9 EFFECT OF EDUCATION ON FERTILITY In Example 13.1, we used the pooled cross section in FERTIL1.RAW to estimate the effect of education on women’s fertility, controlling for various other factors. As in Sander (1992), we allow for the possibility that educ is endogenous in the equation. As instrumental vari- ables for educ, we use mother’s and father’s education levels (meduc, feduc). The 2SLS estimate of 􏱬educ is 􏱦.153 (se 􏱪 .039), compared with the OLS estimate 􏱦.128 (se 􏱪 .018). The 2SLS estimate shows a somewhat larger effect of education on fertility, but the 2SLS standard error is over twice as large as the OLS standard error. (In fact, the 95% con- fidence interval based on 2SLS easily contains the OLS estimate.) The OLS and 2SLS estimates of 􏱬educ are not statistically different, as can be seen by testing for endogeneity of educ as in Section 15.5: when the reduced form residual, vˆ2, is included with the other regressors in Table 13.1 (including educ), its t statistic is .702, which is not significant at any reasonable level. Therefore, in this case, we conclude that the difference between 2SLS and OLS could be entirely due to sampling error. Instrumental variables estimation can be combined with panel data methods, particu- larly first differencing, to estimate parameters consistently in the presence of unobserved effects and endogeneity in one or more time-varying explanatory variables. The following simple example illustrates this combination of methods. EXAMPLE 15.10 JOB TRAINING AND WORKER PRODUCTIVITY Suppose we want to estimate the effect of another hour of job training on worker produc- tivity. For the two years 1987 and 1988, consider the simple panel data model log(scrapit) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛0d88t 􏱕 􏱬1hrsempit 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, t 􏱪 1, 2, where scrapit is firm i’s scrap rate in year t, and hrsempit is hours of job training per employee. As usual, we allow different year intercepts and a constant, unobserved firm effect, ai. For the reasons discussed in Section 13.2, we might be concerned that hrsempit is correlated with ai, the latter of which contains unmeasured worker ability. As before, we difference to remove ai: 􏰧log(scrapi) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧hrsempi 􏱕 􏰧ui. [15.57] Normally, we would estimate this equation by OLS. But what if 􏰧ui is correlated with 􏰧hrsempi? For example, a firm might hire more skilled workers, while at the same time reducing the level of job training. In this case, we need an instrumental variable for 􏰧hrsempi. Generally, such an IV would be hard to find, but we can exploit the fact that some firms received job training grants in 1988. If we assume that grant designation is uncorrelated with 􏰧ui—something that is reasonable, because the grants were given at the beginning of 1988—then 􏰧granti is valid as an IV, provided 􏰧hrsemp and 􏰧grant are correlated. Using the data in JTRAIN.RAW differenced between 1987 and 1988, the first stage regression is Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 542 PART 3 Advanced Topics 􏰧􏱾hrsemp 􏱪 .51 􏱕 27.88 􏰧grant (1.56) (3.13) n􏱪45,R2 􏱪.392. This confirms that the change in hours of job training per employee is strongly positively related to receiving a job training grant in 1988. In fact, receiving a job training grant increased per-employee training by almost 28 hours, and grant designation accounted for almost 40% of the variation in 􏰧hrsemp. Two stage least squares estimation of (15.57) gives 􏰧log(scrap) 􏱪 􏱦.033 􏱦 .014 􏰧hrsemp (.127) (.008) n􏱪45,R2 􏱪.016. This means that 10 more hours of job training per worker are estimated to reduce the scrap rate by about 14%. For the firms in the sample, the average amount of job training in 1988 was about 17 hours per worker, with a minimum of zero and a maximum of 88. For comparison, OLS estimation of (15.57) gives 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 􏱦.0076 (se 􏱪 .0045), so the 2SLS estimate of 􏱬1 is almost twice as large in magnitude and is slightly more statistically significant. When T 􏱸 3, the differenced equation may contain serial correlation. The same test and correction for AR(1) serial correlation from Section 15.7 can be used, where all regressions are pooled across i as well as t. Because we do not want to lose an entire time period, the Prais-Winsten transformation should be used for the initial time period. Unobserved effects models containing lagged dependent variables also require IV methods for consistent estimation. The reason is that, after differencing, 􏰧yi,t􏱦1 is cor- related with 􏰧uit because yi,t􏱦1 and ui,t􏱦1 are correlated. We can use two or more lags of y as IVs for 􏰧yi,t􏱦1. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 11) for details.] Instrumental variables after differencing can be used on matched pairs samples as well. Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994) differenced the wage equation across twins to elimi- nate unobserved ability: log(wage2) 􏱦 log(wage1) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1(educ2,2 􏱦 educ1,1) 􏱕 (u2 􏱦 u1), where educ1,1 is years of schooling for the first twin as reported by the first twin, and educ2,2 is years of schooling for the second twin as reported by the second twin. To account for possible measurement error in the self-reported schooling measures, Ashen- felter and Krueger used (educ2,1 􏱦 educ1,2) as an IV for (educ2,2 􏱦 educ1,1), where educ2,1 is years of schooling for the second twin as reported by the first twin, and educ1,2 is years of schooling for the first twin as reported by the second twin. The IV estimate of 􏱬1 is .167 (t 􏱪 3.88), compared with the OLS estimate on the first differences of .092 (t 􏱪 3.83) [see Ashenfelter and Krueger (1994, Table 3)]. Summary In Chapter 15, we have introduced the method of instrumental variables as a way to estimate the parameters in a linear model consistently when one or more explanatory vari- ables are endogenous. An instrumental variable must have two properties: (1) it must be Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 543 exogenous, that is, uncorrelated with the error term of the structural equation; (2) it must be partially correlated with the endogenous explanatory variable. Finding a variable with these two properties is usually challenging. The method of two stage least squares, which allows for more instrumental variables than we have explanatory variables, is used routinely in the empirical social sciences. When used properly, it can allow us to estimate ceteris paribus effects in the presence of endogenous explanatory variables. This is true in cross-sectional, time series, and panel data applications. But when instruments are poor—which means they are correlated with the error term, only weakly correlated with the endogenous explanatory variable, or both— then 2SLS can be worse than OLS. When we have valid instrumental variables, we can test whether an explanatory vari- able is endogenous, using the test in Section 15.5. In addition, though we can never test whether all IVs are exogenous, we can test that at least some of them are—assuming that we have more instruments than we need for consistent estimation (that is, the model is overidentified). Heteroskedasticity and serial correlation can be tested for and dealt with using methods similar to the case of models with exogenous explanatory variables. In this chapter, we used omitted variables and measurement error to illustrate the method of instrumental variables. IV methods are also indispensable for simultaneous equations models, which we will cover in Chapter 16. Key Terms Endogenous Explanatory Variables Errors-in-Variables Exclusion Restrictions Exogenous Explanatory Variables Exogenous Variables Identification Problems Instrumental Variable Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimator Instrument Exogeneity Instrument Relevance Natural Experiment Omitted Variables Order Condition Overidentifying Restrictions Rank Condition Reduced Form Equation Structural Equation Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS) Estimator Weak Instruments 1 Consider a simple model to estimate the effect of personal computer (PC) ownership on college grade point average for graduating seniors at a large public university: GPA􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1PC􏱕u, where PC is a binary variable indicating PC ownership. (i) Why might PC ownership be correlated with u? (ii) Explain why PC is likely to be related to parents’ annual income. Does this mean parental income is a good IV for PC? Why or why not? (iii) Suppose that, four years ago, the university gave grants to buy computers to roughly one-half of the incoming students, and the students who received grants were randomly chosen. Carefully explain how you would use this information to construct an instrumental variable for PC. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 544 PART 3 Advanced Topics 2 Supposethatyouwishtoestimatetheeffectofclassattendanceonstudentperformance,as in Example 6.3. A basic model is stndfnl 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1atndrte 􏱕 􏱬2 priGPA 􏱕 􏱬3 ACT 􏱕 u, where the variables are defined as in Chapter 6. (i) Let dist be the distance from the students’ living quarters to the lecture hall. Do you think dist is uncorrelated with u? (ii) Assuming that dist and u are uncorrelated, what other assumption must dist satisfy to be a valid IV for atndrte? (iii) Suppose, as in equation (6.18), we add the interaction term priGPA􏱳atndrte: stndfnl 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1atndrte 􏱕 􏱬2 priGPA 􏱕 􏱬3 ACT 􏱕 􏱬4 priGPA􏱳atndrte 􏱕 u. If atndrte is correlated with u, then, in general, so is priGPA􏱳atndrte. What might be a good IV for priGPA􏱳atndrte? [Hint: If E(u􏰫priGPA, ACT, dist) 􏱪 0, as happens when priGPA, ACT, and dist are all exogenous, then any function of priGPA and dist is uncor- related with u.] 3 Consider the simple regression model y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x􏱕u and let z be a binary instrumental variable for x. Use (15.10) to show that the IV estimator 􏱬ˆ1 can be written as 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 (y-1 􏱦 y-0)/(x-1 􏱦 x-0), where y-0 and x-0 are the sample averages of yi and xi over the part of the sample with zi 􏱪 0, and where y-1 and x-1 are the sample averages of yi and xi over the part of the sample with zi 􏱪 1. This estimator, known as a grouping estimator, was first suggested by Wald (1940). 4 Suppose that, for a given state in the United States, you wish to use annual time series data to estimate the effect of the state-level minimum wage on the employment of those 18 to 25 years old (EMP). A simple model is gEMPt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gMINt 􏱕 􏱬2gPOPt 􏱕 􏱬3gGSPt 􏱕 􏱬4gGDPt 􏱕 ut, where MINt is the minimum wage, in real dollars, POPt is the population from 18 to 25 years old, GSPt is gross state product, and GDPt is U.S. gross domestic product. The g prefix indicates the growth rate from year t 􏱦 1 to year t, which would typically be approximated by the difference in the logs. (i) If we are worried that the state chooses its minimum wage partly based on unob- served (to us) factors that affect youth employment, what is the problem with OLS estimation? (ii) Let USMINt be the U.S. minimum wage, which is also measured in real terms. Do you think gUSMINt is uncorrelated with ut? (iii) By law, any state’s minimum wage must be at least as large as the U.S. minimum. Explain why this makes gUSMINt a potential IV candidate for gMINt. 5 Refer to equations (15.19) and (15.20). Assume that 􏱧u 􏱪 􏱧x, so that the population varia- tion in the error term is the same as it is in x. Suppose that the instrumental variable, z, is slightly correlated with u: Corr(z,u) 􏱪 .1. Suppose also that z and x have a somewhat stron- ger correlation: Corr(z,x) 􏱪 .2. (i) What is the asymptotic bias in the IV estimator? (ii) How much correlation would have to exist between x and u before OLS has more asymptotic bias than 2SLS? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 545 6 (i) In the model with one endogenous explanatory variable, one exogenous explanatory variable, and one extra exogenous variable, take the reduced form for y2 (15.26), and plug it into the structural equation (15.22). This gives the reduced form for y1: y1 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏱮1z1 􏱕􏱮2z2 􏱕v1. Find the 􏱮j in terms of the 􏱬j and the 􏰵j. (ii) Find the reduced form error, v1, in terms of u1, v2, and the parameters. (iii) How would you consistently estimate the aj? 7 The following is a simple model to measure the effect of a school choice program on stan- dardized test performance [see Rouse (1998) for motivation and Computer Exercise C11 for an analysis of a subset of Rouse’s data]: score 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1choice 􏱕 􏱬2 faminc 􏱕 u1, where score is the score on a statewide test, choice is a binary variable indicating whether a student attended a choice school in the last year, and faminc is family income. The IV for choice is grant, the dollar amount granted to students to use for tuition at choice schools. The grant amount differed by family income level, which is why we control for faminc in the equation. (i) Even with faminc in the equation, why might choice be correlated with u1? (ii) If within each income class, the grant amounts were assigned randomly, is grant uncorrelated with u1? (iii) Write the reduced form equation for choice. What is needed for grant to be partially correlated with choice? (iv) Write the reduced form equation for score. Explain why this is useful. (Hint: How do you interpret the coefficient on grant?) 8 Suppose you want to test whether girls who attend a girls’ high school do better in math than girls who attend coed schools. You have a random sample of senior high school girls from a state in the United States, and score is the score on a standardized math test. Let girlhs be a dummy variable indicating whether a student attends a girls’ high school. (i) What other factors would you control for in the equation? (You should be able to rea- sonably collect data on these factors.) (ii) Write an equation relating score to girlhs and the other factors you listed in part (i). (iii) Suppose that parental support and motivation are unmeasured factors in the error term in part (ii). Are these likely to be correlated with girlhs? Explain. (iv) Discuss the assumptions needed for the number of girls’ high schools within a 20-mile radius of a girl’s home to be a valid IV for girlhs. (v) Suppose that, when you estimate the reduced form for girlshs, you find that the coefficient on numghs (the number of girls’ high schools within a 20-mile radius) is negative and statistically significant. Would you feel comfortable proceeding with IV estimation where numghs is used as an IV for girlshs? Explain. 9 Supposethat,inequation(15.8),youdonothaveagoodinstrumentalvariablecandidatefor skipped. But you have two other pieces of information on students: combined SAT score and cumulative GPA prior to the semester. What would you do instead of IV estimation? 10 In a recent article, Evans and Schwab (1995) studied the effects of attending a Catholic high school on the probability of attending college. For concreteness, let college be a binary variable equal to unity if a student attends college, and zero otherwise. Let CathHS Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 546 PART 3 Advanced Topics be a binary variable equal to one if the student attends a Catholic high school. A linear probability model is college 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1CathHS 􏱕 other factors 􏱕 u, where the other factors include gender, race, family income, and parental education. (i) Why might CathHS be correlated with u? (ii) Evans and Schwab have data on a standardized test score taken when each student was a sophomore. What can be done with this variable to improve the ceteris paribus estimate of attending a Catholic high school? (iii) Let CathRel be a binary variable equal to one if the student is Catholic. Discuss the two requirements needed for this to be a valid IV for CathHS in the preceding equation. Which of these can be tested? (iv) Not surprisingly, being Catholic has a significant positive effect on attending a Catholic high school. Do you think CathRel is a convincing instrument for CathHS? 11 Consider a simple time series model where the explanatory variable has classical measurement error: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x*t 􏱕 ut [15.58] x t 􏱪 x *t 􏱕 e t , where ut has zero mean and is uncorrelated with x*t and et. We observe yt and xt only. Assume that et has zero mean and is uncorrelated with x*t and that x*t also has a zero mean (this last assumption is only to simplify the algebra). (i) Write x*t 􏱪 xt 􏱦 et and plug this into (15.58). Show that the error term in the new equation, say, vt, is negatively correlated with xt if 􏱬1 􏱰 0. What does this imply about the OLS estimator of 􏱬1 from the regression of yt on xt? (ii) In addition to the previous assumptions, assume that ut and et are uncorrelated with all past values of x*t and et; in particular, with x*t 􏱦1 and et􏱦1. Show that E(xt􏱦1vt) 􏱪 0, where vt is the error term in the model from part (i). (iii) Are xt and xt􏱦1 likely to be correlated? Explain. (iv) What do parts (ii) and (iii) suggest as a useful strategy for consistently estimating 􏱬0 and 􏱬1? Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in WAGE2.RAW for this exercise. (i) In Example 15.2, if sibs is used as an instrument for educ, the IV estimate of the return to education is .122. To convince yourself that using sibs as an IV for educ is not the same as just plugging sibs in for educ and running an OLS regression, run the regression of log(wage) on sibs and explain your findings. (ii) The variable brthord is birth order (brthord is one for a first-born child, two for a second-born child, and so on). Explain why educ and brthord might be negatively correlated. Regress educ on brthord to determine whether there is a statistically significant negative correlation. (iii) Use brthord as an IV for educ in equation (15.1). Report and interpret the results. (iv) Now, suppose that we include number of siblings as an explanatory variable in the wage equation; this controls for family background, to some extent: log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2sibs 􏱕 u. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 547 Suppose that we want to use brthord as an IV for educ, assuming that sibs is exog- enous. The reduced form for educ is educ 􏱪 􏰵0 􏱕 􏰵1sibs 􏱕 􏰵2brthord 􏱕 v. State and test the identification assumption. (v) Estimate the equation from part (iv) using brthord as an IV for educ (and sibs as its own IV). Comment on the standard errors for 􏱬ˆeduc and 􏱬ˆsibs. (vi) Using the fitted values from part (iv), 􏱾educ, compute the correlation between 􏱾educ and sibs. Use this result to explain your findings from part (v). C2 The data in FERTIL2.RAW include, for women in Botswana during 1988, informa- tion on number of children, years of education, age, and religious and economic status variables. (i) Estimate the model children 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2age 􏱕 􏱬3age2 􏱕 u by OLS, and interpret the estimates. In particular, holding age fixed, what is the estimated effect of another year of education on fertility? If 100 women receive another year of education, how many fewer children are they expected to have? (ii) The variable frsthalf is a dummy variable equal to one if the woman was born dur- ing the first six months of the year. Assuming that frsthalf is uncorrelated with the error term from part (i), show that frsthalf is a reasonable IV candidate for educ. (Hint: You need to do a regression.) (iii) Estimate the model from part (i) by using frsthalf as an IV for educ. Compare the estimated effect of education with the OLS estimate from part (i). (iv) Add the binary variables electric, tv, and bicycle to the model and assume these are exogenous. Estimate the equation by OLS and 2SLS and compare the esti- mated coefficients on educ. Interpret the coefficient on tv and explain why televi- sion ownership has a negative effect on fertility. C3 Use (i) The equation we estimated in Example 15.4 can be written as the data in CARD.RAW for this exercise. log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 ... 􏱕 u, where the other explanatory variables are listed in Table 15.1. In order for IV to be consistent, the IV for educ, nearc4, must be uncorrelated with u. Could nearc4 be correlated with things in the error term, such as unobserved ability? Explain. (ii) For a subsample of the men in the data set, an IQ score is available. Regress IQ on nearc4 to check whether average IQ scores vary by whether the man grew up near a four-year college. What do you conclude? (iii) Now, regress IQ on nearc4, smsa66, and the 1966 regional dummy variables reg662, ..., reg669. Are IQ and nearc4 related after the geographic dummy vari- ables have been partialled out? Reconcile this with your findings from part (ii). (iv) From parts (ii) and (iii), what do you conclude about the importance of controlling for smsa66 and the 1966 regional dummies in the log(wage) equation? C4 Use month T-bill rate to the inflation rate (constructed from the Consumer Price Index) is the data in INTDEF.RAW for this exercise. A simple equation relating the three- i3t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inft 􏱕 ut. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 548 PART 3 Advanced Topics (i) Estimate this equation by OLS, omitting the first time period for later compari- sons. Report the results in the usual form. (ii) Some economists feel that the Consumer Price Index mismeasures the true rate of inflation, so that the OLS from part (i) suffers from measurement error bias. Re- estimate the equation from part (i), using inft􏱦1 as an IV for inft. How does the IV estimate of 􏱬1 compare with the OLS estimate? (iii) Now, first difference the equation: 􏰧i3t 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧inft 􏱕 􏰧ut. Estimate this by OLS and compare the estimate of 􏱬1 with the previous estimates. (iv) Can you use 􏰧inft􏱦1 as an IV for 􏰧inft in the differenced equation in part (iii)? Ex- plain. (Hint: Are 􏰧inft and 􏰧inft􏱦1 sufficiently correlated?) C5 Use the data in CARD.RAW for this exercise. (i) In Table 15.1, the difference between the IV and OLS estimates of the return to education is economically important. Obtain the reduced form residuals, vˆ2, from the reduced form regression educ on nearc4, exper, exper2, black, smsa, south, smsa66, reg662, ..., reg669—see Table15.1. Use these to test whether educ is exogenous; that is, determine if the difference between OLS and IV is statistically significant. (ii) Estimate the equation by 2SLS, adding nearc2 as an instrument. Does the coeffi- cient on educ change much? (iii) Test the single overidentifying restriction from part (ii). C6 Use the data in MURDER.RAW for this exercise. The variable mrdrte is the murder rate, that is, the number of murders per 100,000 people. The variable exec is the total number of prisoners executed for the current and prior two years; unem is the state un- employment rate. (i) How many states executed at least one prisoner in 1991, 1992, or 1993? Which state had the most executions? (ii) Using the two years 1990 and 1993, do a pooled regression of mrdrte on d93, exec, and unem. What do you make of the coefficient on exec? (iii) Using the changes from 1990 to 1993 only (for a total of 51 observations), esti- mate the equation 􏰧mrdrte 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱬1􏰧exec 􏱕 􏱬2􏰧unem 􏱕 􏰧u by OLS and report the results in the usual form. Now, does capital punishment ap- pear to have a deterrent effect? (iv) Thechangeinexecutionsmaybeatleastpartlyrelatedtochangesintheexpected murder rate, so that 􏰧exec is correlated with 􏰧u in part (iii). It might be reasonable to assume that 􏰧exec􏱦1 is uncorrelated with 􏰧u. (After all, 􏰧exec􏱦1 depends on ex- ecutions that occurred three or more years ago.) Regress 􏰧exec on 􏰧exec􏱦1 to see if they are sufficiently correlated; interpret the coefficient on 􏰧exec􏱦1. (v) Reestimate the equation from part (iii), using 􏰧exec􏱦1 as an IV for 􏰧exec. Assume that 􏰧unem is exogenous. How do your conclusions change from part (iii)? C7 Use the data in PHILLIPS.RAW for this exercise. (i) In Example 11.5, we estimated an expectations augmented Phillips curve of the form 􏰧inft 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unemt 􏱕 et, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 549 where 􏰧inft 􏱪 inft 􏱦 inft􏱦1. In estimating this equation by OLS, we assumed that the supply shock, et, was uncorrelated with unemt. If this is false, what can be said about the OLS estimator of 􏱬1? (ii) Suppose that et is unpredictable given all past information: E(et􏰫inft􏱦1, unemt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 0. Explain why this makes unemt􏱦1 a good IV candidate for unemt. (iii) Regress unemt on unemt􏱦1. Are unemt and unemt􏱦1 significantly correlated? (iv) Estimate the expectations augmented Phillips curve by IV. Report the results in the usual form and compare them with the OLS estimates from Example 11.5. C8 Use the data in 401KSUBS.RAW for this exercise. The equation of interest is a linear probability model: pira 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1p401k 􏱕 􏱬2inc 􏱕 􏱬3inc2 􏱕 􏱬4age 􏱕 􏱬5age2 􏱕 u. The goal is to test whether there is a tradeoff between participating in a 401(k) plan and having an individual retirement account (IRA). Therefore, we want to estimate 􏱬1. (i) Estimate the equation by OLS and discuss the estimated effect of p401k. (ii) For the purposes of estimating the ceteris paribus tradeoff between participation in two different types of retirement savings plans, what might be a problem with ordinary least squares? (iii) The variable e401k is a binary variable equal to one if a worker is eligible to par- ticipate in a 401(k) plan. Explain what is required for e401k to be a valid IV for p401k. Do these assumptions seem reasonable? (iv) Estimate the reduced form for p401k and verify that e401k has significant partial correlation with p401k. Since the reduced form is also a linear probability model, use a heteroskedasticity-robust standard error. (v) Now, estimate the structural equation by IV and compare the estimate of 􏱬1 with the OLS estimate. Again, you should obtain heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. (vi) Testthenullhypothesisthatp401kisinfactexogenous,usingaheteroskedasticity- robust test. C9 The correctly using 2SLS with those obtained using inappropriate procedures. Use the data file WAGE2.RAW. (i) Use a 2SLS routine to estimate the equation log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3tenure 􏱕 􏱬4black 􏱕 u, where sibs is the IV for educ. Report the results in the usual form. (ii) Now, manually carry out 2SLS. That is, first regress educi on sibsi, experi, tenurei, purpose of this exercise is to compare the estimates and standard errors obtained by and blacki and obtain the fitted values, 􏱾educi, i 􏱪 1, ..., n. Then, run the second 􏱾 stage regression log(wagei) on educi, experi, tenurei, and blacki, i 􏱪 1, ..., n. Verify that the 􏱬ˆj are identical to those obtained from part (i), but that the standard errors are somewhat different. The standard errors obtained from the second stage regres- sion when manually carrying out 2SLS are generally inappropriate. (iii) Now, use the following two-step procedure, which generally yields inconsistent parameter estimates of the 􏱬j, and not just inconsistent standard 􏱷errors. In step one, regress educi on sibsi only and obtain the fitted values, say educi. (Note that this is an incorrect firs􏱷t stage regression.) Then, in the second step, run the regres- sion of log(wagei) on educi, experi, tenurei, and blacki, i 􏱪 1, ..., n. How does the estimate from this incorrect, two-step procedure compare with the correct 2SLS estimate of the return to education? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 550 PART 3 Advanced Topics C10 Use (i) Run a simple OLS regression of log(wage) on educ. Without controlling for other factors, what is the 95% confidence interval for the return to another year of education? (ii) The variable ctuit, in thousands of dollars, is the change in college tuition facing students from age 17 to age 18. Show that educ and ctuit are essentially uncorre- lated. What does this say about ctuit as a possible IV for educ in a simple regres- sion analysis? (iii) Now, add to the simple regression model in part (i) a quadratic in experience and a full set of regional dummy variables for current residence and residence at age 18. Also include the urban indicators for current and age 18 residences. What is the estimated return to a year of education? (iv) Again using ctuit as a potential IV for educ, estimate the reduced form for educ. [Naturally, the reduced form for educ now includes the explanatory variables in part (iii).] Show that ctuit is now statistically significant in the reduced form for educ. (v) Estimate the model from part (iii) by IV, using ctuit as an IV for educ. How does the confidence interval for the return to education compare with the OLS CI from part (iii)? (vi) Do you think the IV procedure from part (v) is convincing? the data in HTV.RAW for this exercise. C11 The can be used to estimate the effect of school choice on academic achievement. Atten- dance at a choice school was paid for by a voucher, which was determined by a lottery among those who applied. The data subset was chosen so that any student in the sample has a valid 1994 math test score (the last year available in Rouse’s sample). Unfortu- nately, as pointed out by Rouse, many students have missing test scores, possibly due to attrition (that is, leaving the Milwaukee public school district). These data include stu- dents who applied to the voucher program and were accepted, students who applied and were not accepted, and students who did not apply. Therefore, even though the vouchers were chosen by lottery among those who applied, we do not necessarily have a random sample from a population where being selected for a voucher has been randomly deter- mined. (An important consideration is that students who never applied to the program may be systematically different from those who did—and in ways that we cannot know based on the data.) Rouse (1998) uses panel data methods of the kind we discussed in Chapter 14 to allow student fixed effects; she also uses instrumental variables methods. This problem asks you to do a cross-sectional analysis where winning the lottery for a voucher acts as an instrumental variable for attending a choice school. Actually, because we have multi- ple years of data on each student, we construct two variables. The first, choiceyrs, is the number of years from 1991 to 1994 that a student attended a choice school; this variable ranges from zero to four. The variable selectyrs indicates the number of years a student was selected for a voucher. If the student applied for the program in 1990 and received a voucher then selectyrs = 4; if he or she applied in 1991 and received a voucher then selectyrs = 3; and so on. The outcome of interest is mnce, the student’s percentile score on a math test administered in 1994. (i) Of the 990 students in the sample, how many were never awarded a voucher? How many had a voucher available for four years? How many students actually attended a choice school for four years? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. data set in VOUCHER.DTA, which is a subset of the data used in Rouse (1998), CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 551 (ii) Run a simple regression of choiceyrs on selectyrs. Are these variables related in the direction you expected? How strong is the relationship? Is selectyrs a sensible IV candidate for choiceyrs? (iii) Run a simple regression of mnce on choiceyrs. What do you find? Is this what you expected? What happens if you add the variables black, hispanic, and female? (iv) Why might choiceyrs be endogenous in an equation such as mnce 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1choiceyrs 􏱕 􏱬2black 􏱕 􏱬3hispanic 􏱕 􏱬4female 􏱕 u1? (v) Estimate the equation in part (iv) by instrumental variables, using selectyrs as the IV for choiceyrs. Does using IV produce a positive effect of attending a choice school? What do you make of the coefficients on the other explanatory vairables? (vi) To control for the possibility that prior achievement affects participating in the lottery (as well as predicting attrition), add mnce90—the math score in 1990—to the equation in part (iv). Estimate the equation by OLS and IV, and compare the results for 􏱬1. For the IV estimate, how much is each year in a choice school worth on the math percentile score? Is this a practically large effect? (vii) Why is the analysis from part (vi) not entirely convincing? [Hint: Compared with part (v), what happens to the number of observations, and why?] (viii) The variables choiceyrs1, choiceyrs2, and so on are dummy variables indicating the different number of years a student could have been in a choice school (from 1991 to 1994). The dummy variables selectyrs1, selectyrs2, and so on have a similar definition, but for being selected from the lottery. Estimate the equation mnce 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 choiceyrs1 􏱕 􏱬2choiceyrs2 􏱕 􏱬3choiceyrs3 􏱕 􏱬4 choiceyrs4 􏱕 􏱬5 black 􏱕 􏱬6hispanic 􏱕 􏱬7female by IV, using as instruments the four selectyrs dummy variables. (As before, the variables black, hispanic, and female act as their own IVs.) Describe your findings. Do they make sense? APPENDIX 15A 15A.1 Assumptions for Two Stage Least Squares This appendix covers the assumptions under which 2SLS has desirable large sample properties. We first state the assumptions for cross-sectional applications under random sampling. Then, we discuss what needs to be added for them to apply to time series and panel data. 15A.2 Assumption 2SLS.1 (Linear in Parameters) The model in the population can be written as y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk 􏱕u, where 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k are the unknown parameters (constants) of interest, and u is an unobserved random error or random disturbance term. The instrumental variables are denoted as zj. It is worth emphasizing that Assumption 2SLS.1 is virtually identical to MLR.1 (with the minor exception that 2SLS.1 mentions the notation for the instrumental variables, zj). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 552 PART 3 Advanced Topics In other words, the model we are interested in is the same as that for OLS estimation of the 􏱬j. Sometimes it is easy to lose sight of the fact that we can apply different estimation methods to the same model. Unfortunately, it is not uncommon to hear researchers say “I estimated an OLS model” or “I used a 2SLS model.” Such statements are meaningless. OLS and 2SLS are different estimation methods that are applied to the same model. It is true that they have desirable statistical properties under different sets of assumptions on the model, but the relationship they are estimating is given by the equation in 2SLS.1 (or MLR.1). The point is similar to that made for the unobserved effects panel data model covered in Chapters 13 and 14: pooled OLS, first differencing, fixed effects, and random effects are different estimation methods for the same model. 15A.3 Assumption 2SLS.2 (Random Sampling) We have a random sample on y, the xj, and the zj. 15A.4 Assumption 2SLS.3 (Rank Condition) (i) There are no perfect linear relationships among the instrumental variables. (ii) The rank condition for identification holds. With a single endogenous explanatory variable, as in equation (15.42), the rank con- dition is easily described. Let z1, ..., zm denote the exogenous variables, where zk, ..., zm do not appear in the structural model (15.42). The reduced form of y2 is y2 􏱪􏰵0 􏱕􏰵1z1 􏱕􏰵2z2 􏱕...􏱕􏰵k–1zk–1 􏱕􏰵kzk 􏱕...􏱕􏰵mzm 􏱕v2. Then, we need at least one of 􏰵k, ..., 􏰵m to be nonzero. This requires at least one exogenous variable that does not appear in (15.42) (the order condition). Stating the rank condition with two or more endogenous explanatory variables requires matrix algebra. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5).] 15A.5 Assumption 2SLS.4 (Exogenous Instrumental Variables) The error term u has zero mean, and each IV is uncorrelated with u. Remember that any xj that is uncorrelated with u also acts as an IV. 15A.6 Theorem 15A.1 Under Assumptions 2SLS.1 through 2SLS.4, the 2SLS estimator is consistent. 15A.7 Assumption 2SLS.5 (Homoskedasticity) Let z denote the collection of all instrumental variables. Then, E(u2􏱜z) 􏱪 􏰴2. 15A.8 Theorem 15A.2 Under Assumptions 2SLS.1 through 2SLS.5, the 2SLS estimators are asymptoti- cally normally distributed. Consistent estimators of the asymptotic∑variance are given as in equation (15.43), where 􏰴2 is replaced with 􏰴ˆ2 􏱪 (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)􏱦1 n uˆ2, and the uˆ are the 2SLS residuals. i􏱪1i i Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 15 Instrumental Variables Estimation and Two Stage Least Squares 553 The 2SLS estimator is also the best IV estimator under the five assumptions given. We state the result here. A proof can be found in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 5). 15A.9 Theorem 15A.3 Under Assumptions 2SLS.1 through 2SLS.5, the 2SLS estimator is asymptotically efficient in the class of IV estimators that uses linear combinations of the exogenous variables as instruments. If the homoskedasticity assumption does not hold, the 2SLS estimators are still as- ymptotically normal, but the standard errors (and t and F statistics) need to be adjusted; many econometrics packages do this routinely. Moreover, the 2SLS estimator is no lon- ger the asymptotically efficient IV estimator, in general. We will not study more efficient estimators here [see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 8)]. For time series applications, we must add some assumptions. First, as with OLS, we must assume that all series (including the IVs) are weakly dependent: this ensures that the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem hold. For the usual standard errors and test statistics to be valid, as well as for asymptotic efficiency, we must add a no serial correlation assumption. 15A.10 Assumption 2SLS.6 (No Serial Correlation) Equation (15.54) holds. A similar no serial correlation assumption is needed in panel data applications. Tests and corrections for serial correlation were discussed in Section 15.7. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 554 Simultaneous Equations Models 16 CHAPTER In the previous chapter, we showed how the method of instrumental variables can solve two kinds of endogeneity problems: omitted variables and measurement error. Conceptually, these problems are straightforward. In the omitted variables case, there is a variable (or more than one) that we would like to hold fixed when estimating the ceteris paribus effect of one or more of the observed explanatory variables. In the measurement error case, we would like to estimate the effect of certain explanatory variables on y, but we have mismeasured one or more variables. In both cases, we could estimate the parameters of interest by OLS if we could collect better data. Another important form of endogeneity of explanatory variables is simultaneity. This arises when one or more of the explanatory variables is jointly determined with the depen- dent variable, typically through an equilibrium mechanism (as we will see later). In this chapter, we study methods for estimating simple simultaneous equations models (SEMs). Although a complete treatment of SEMs is beyond the scope of this text, we are able to cover models that are widely used. The leading method for estimating simultaneous equations models is the method of instrumental variables. Therefore, the solution to the simultaneity problem is essentially the same as the IV solutions to the omitted variables and measurement error problems. However, crafting and interpreting SEMs is challenging. Therefore, we begin by discussing the nature and scope of simultaneous equations models in Section 16.1. In Section 16.2, we confirm that OLS applied to an equation in a simultaneous system is generally biased and inconsistent. Section 16.3 provides a general description of identification and estimation in a two- equation system, while Section 16.4 briefly covers models with more than two equations. Simultaneous equations models are used to model aggregate time series, and in Section 16.5 we include a discussion of some special issues that arise in such models. Section 16.6 touches on simultaneous equations models with panel data. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 555 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 16.1 The Nature of Simultaneous Equations Models The most important point to remember in using simultaneous equations models is that each equation in the system should have a ceteris paribus, causal interpretation. Because we only observe the outcomes in equilibrium, we are required to use counterfactual reasoning in constructing the equations of a simultaneous equations model. We must think in terms of potential as well as actual outcomes. The classic example of an SEM is a supply and demand equation for some commodity or input to production (such as labor). For concreteness, let hs denote the annual labor hours supplied by workers in agriculture, measured at the county level, and let w denote the aver- age hourly wage offered to such workers. A simple labor supply function is hs 􏱪 􏱮1w 􏱕 􏱬1z1 􏱕 u1, [16.1] where z1 is some observed variable affecting labor supply—say, the average manufacturing wage in the county. The error term, u1, contains other factors that affect labor supply. [Many of these factors are observed and could be included in equation (16.1); to illustrate the basic concepts, we include only one such factor, z1.] Equation (16.1) is an example of a structural equation. This name comes from the fact that the labor supply function is derivable from economic theory and has a causal interpretation. The coefficient 􏱮1 measures how labor sup- ply changes when the wage changes; if hs and w are in logarithmic form, 􏱮1 is the labor supply elasticity. Typically, we expect 􏱮1 to be positive (although economic theory does not rule out 􏱮1 􏰯 0). Labor supply elasticities are important for determining how workers will change the number of hours they desire to work when tax rates on wage income change. If z1 is the manufacturing wage, we expect 􏱬1 􏰯 0: other factors equal, if the manufacturing wage increases, more workers will go into manufacturing than into agriculture. When we graph labor supply, we sketch hours as a function of wage, with z1 and u1 held fixed. A change in z1 shifts the labor supply function, as does a change in u1. The difference is that z1 is observed while u1 is not. Sometimes, z1 is called an observed supply shifter, and u1 is called an unobserved supply shifter. How does equation (16.1) differ from those we have studied previously? The dif- ference is subtle. Although equation (16.1) is supposed to hold for all possible values of wage, we cannot generally view wage as varying exogenously for a cross section of coun- ties. If we could run an experiment where we vary the level of agricultural and manufac- turing wages across a sample of counties and survey workers to obtain the labor supply hs for each county, then we could estimate (16.1) by OLS. Unfortunately, this is not a man- ageable experiment. Instead, we must collect data on average wages in these two sectors along with how many person hours were spent in agricultural production. In deciding how to analyze these data, we must understand that they are best described by the interaction of labor supply and demand. Under the assumption that labor markets clear, we actually observe equilibrium values of wages and hours worked. To describe how equilibrium wages and hours are determined, we need to bring in the demand for labor, which we suppose is given by hd 􏱪 􏱮2w 􏱕 􏱬2z2 􏱕 u2, [16.2] where hd is hours demanded. As with the supply function, we graph hours demanded as a function of wage, w, keeping z2 and u2 fixed. The variable z2—say, agricultural land area—is an observable demand shifter, while u2 is an unobservable demand shifter. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 556 PART 3 Advanced Topics Just as with the labor supply equation, the labor demand equation is a structural equation: it can be obtained from the profit maximization considerations of farmers. If hd and w are in logarithmic form, 􏱮2 is the labor demand elasticity. Economic theory tells us that 􏱮2 􏱷 0. Because labor and land are complements in production, we expect 􏱬2 􏱰 0. Notice how equations (16.1) and (16.2) describe entirely different relationships. Labor supply is a behavioral equation for workers, and labor demand is a behavioral relationship for farmers. Each equation has a ceteris paribus interpretation and stands on its own. They become linked in an econometric analysis only because observed wage and hours are determined by the intersection of supply and demand. In other words, for each county i, observed hours hi and observed wage wi are determined by the equilibrium condition his 􏱪 hid. [16.3] Because we observe only equilibrium hours for each county i, we denote observed hours by hi. When we combine the equilibrium condition in (16.3) with the labor supply and demand equations, we get and hi 􏱪 􏱮1wi 􏱕 􏱬1zi1 􏱕 ui1 [16.4] hi 􏱪 􏱮2wi 􏱕 􏱬2zi2 􏱕 ui2, [16.5] where we explicitly include the i subscript to emphasize that hi and wi are the equilibrium observed values for county i. These two equations constitute a simultaneous equations model (SEM), which has several important features. First, given zi1, zi2, ui1, and ui2, these two equations determine hi and wi. (Actually, we must assume that 􏱮1 􏱻 􏱮2, which means that the slopes of the supply and demand functions differ; see Problem 1.) For this rea- son, hi and wi are the endogenous variables in this SEM. What about zi1 and zi2? Because they are determined outside of the model, we view them as exogenous variables. From a statistical standpoint, the key assumption concerning zi1 and zi2 is that they are both uncorrelated with the supply and demand errors, ui1 and ui2, respectively. These are examples of structural errors because they appear in the structural equations. A second important point is that, without including z1 and z2 in the model, there is no way to tell which equation is the supply function and which is the demand function. When z1 represents manufacturing wage, economic reasoning tells us that it is a factor in agricul- tural labor supply because it is a measure of the opportunity cost of working in agriculture; when z2 stands for agricultural land area, production theory implies that it appears in the labor demand function. Therefore, we know that (16.4) represents labor supply and (16.5) represents labor demand. If z1 and z2 are the same—for example, average education level of adults in the county, which can affect both supply and demand—then the equations look identical, and there is no hope of estimating either one. In a nutshell, this illustrates the identification problem in simultaneous equations models, which we will discuss more generally in Section 16.3. The most convincing examples of SEMs have the same flavor as supply and demand examples. Each equation should have a behavioral, ceteris paribus interpretation on its own. Because we only observe equilibrium outcomes, specifying an SEM requires us to ask such counterfactual questions as: How much labor would workers provide if the wage were different from its equilibrium value? Example 16.1 provides another illustration of an SEM where each equation has a ceteris paribus interpretation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 557 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models EXAMPLE 16.1 MURDER RATES AND SIZE OF THE POLICE FORCE Cities often want to determine how much additional law enforcement will decrease their murder rates. A simple cross-sectional model to address this question is murdpc 􏱪 􏱮1 polpc 􏱕 􏱬10 􏱕 􏱬11incpc 􏱕 u1, [16.6] where murdpc is murders per capita, polpc is number of police officers per capita, and incpc is income per capita. (Henceforth, we do not include an i subscript.) We take income per capita as exogenous in this equation. In practice, we would include other factors, such as age and gender distributions, education levels, perhaps geographic variables, and variables that measure severity of punishment. To fix ideas, we consider equation (16.6). The question we hope to answer is: If a city exogenously increases its police force, will that increase, on average, lower the murder rate? If we could exogenously choose police force sizes for a random sample of cities, we could estimate (16.6) by OLS. Certainly, we cannot run such an experiment. But can we think of police force size as being exogenously determined, anyway? Probably not. A city’s spending on law enforcement is at least partly determined by its expected murder rate. To reflect this, we postulate a second relationship: polpc 􏱪 􏱮2murdpc 􏱕 􏱬20 􏱕 other factors. [16.7] We expect that 􏱮2 􏱰 0: other factors being equal, cities with higher (expected) murder rates will have more police officers per capita. Once we specify the other factors in (16.7), we have a two-equation simultaneous equations model. We are really only interested in equation (16.6), but, as we will see in Section 16.3, we need to know precisely how the second equation is specified in order to estimate the first. An important point is that (16.7) describes behavior by city officials, while (16.6) describes the actions of potential murderers. This gives each equation a clear ceteris pari- bus interpretation, which makes equations (16.6) and (16.7) an appropriate simultaneous equations model. We next give an example of an inappropriate use of SEMs. EXAMPLE 16.2 HOUSING EXPENDITURES AND SAVING Suppose that, for a random household in the population, we assume that annual housing expenditures and saving are jointly determined by housing 􏱪 􏱮1saving 􏱕 􏱬10 􏱕 􏱬11inc 􏱕 􏱬12educ 􏱕 􏱬13age 􏱕 u1 [16.8] and saving 􏱪 􏱮2housing 􏱕 􏱬20 􏱕 􏱬21inc 􏱕 􏱬22educ 􏱕 􏱬23age 􏱕 u2, [16.9] where inc is annual income and educ and age are measured in years. Initially, it may seem that these equations are a sensible way to view how housing and saving expenditures are determined. But we have to ask: What value would one of these equations be without the other? Neither has a ceteris paribus interpretation because housing and saving are chosen by Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 558 PART 3 Advanced Topics the same household. For example, it makes no sense to ask this question: If annual income increases by $10,000, how would housing expenditures change, holding saving fixed? If family income increases, a household will generally change the optimal mix of housing expenditures and saving. But equation (16.8) makes it seem as if we want to know the effect of changing inc, educ, or age while keeping saving fixed. Such a thought experiment is not interesting. Any model based on economic principles, particularly utility maximi- zation, would have households optimally choosing housing and saving as functions of inc and the relative prices of housing and saving. The variables educ and age would affect preferences for consumption, saving, and risk. Therefore, housing and saving would each be functions of income, education, age, and other variables that affect the utility maximi- zation problem (such as different rates of return on housing and other saving). Even if we decided that the SEM in (16.8) and (16.9) made sense, there is no way to estimate the parameters. (We discuss this problem more generally in Section 16.3.) The two equations are indistinguishable, unless we assume that income, education, or age appears in one equation but not the other, which would make no sense. Though this makes a poor SEM example, we might be interested in testing whether, other factors being fixed, there is a tradeoff between housing expenditures and saving. But then we would just estimate, say, (16.8) by OLS, unless there is an omitted variable or measurement error problem. Example 16.2 has the characteristics of all too many SEM applications. The problem is that the two endogenous variables are chosen by the same economic agent. Therefore, neither equation can stand on its own. Another example of an inappropriate use of an SEM would be to model weekly hours spent studying and weekly hours working. Each student will choose these variables simultaneously—presumably as a function of the wage that can be earned working, ability as a student, enthusiasm for college, and so on. Just as in Example 16.2, it makes no sense to specify two equations where each is a function of the other. The important lesson is this: just because two variables are determined simultane- ously does not mean that a simultaneous equations model is suitable. For an SEM to make sense, each equation in the SEM should have a ceteris paribus interpretation in isolation from the other equation. As we discussed earlier, supply and demand examples, and Example 16.1, have this feature. Usually, basic economic reason- ing, supported in some cases by simple economic models, can help us use SEMs intelligently (including knowing when not to use an SEM). 16.2 Simultaneity Bias in OLS It is useful to see, in a simple model, that an explanatory variable that is determined simultaneously with the dependent variable is generally correlated with the error term, which leads to bias and inconsistency in OLS. We consider the two-equation structural model Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 16.1 Pindyck and Rubinfeld (1992, Section 11.6) describe a model of advertising where mo- nopolistic firms choose profit maximizing levels of price and advertising expenditures. Does this mean we should use an SEM to model these variables at the firm level? 559 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models y1 􏱪 􏱮1y2 􏱕 􏱬1z1 􏱕 u1 [16.10] y2 􏱪 􏱮2y1 􏱕 􏱬2z2 􏱕 u2 [16.11] and focus on estimating the first equation. The variables z1 and z2 are exogenous, so that each is uncorrelated with u1 and u2. For simplicity, we suppress the intercept in each equation. To show that y2 is generally correlated with u1, we solve the two equations for y2 in terms of the exogenous variables and the error term. If we plug the right-hand side of (16.10) in for y1 in (16.11), we get or y2 􏱪􏱮2(􏱮1y2 􏱕􏱬1z1 􏱕u1)􏱕􏱬2z2 􏱕u2 (1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1)y2 􏱪 􏱮2􏱬1z1 􏱕 􏱬2z2 􏱕 􏱮2u1 􏱕 u2. Now, we must make an assumption about the parameters in order to solve for y2: 􏱮2􏱮1 􏱻 1. [16.12] [16.13] Whether this assumption is restrictive depends on the application. In Example 16.1, we think that 􏱮1 􏰯 0 and 􏱮2 􏱸 0, which implies 􏱮1􏱮2 􏰯 0; therefore, (16.13) is very reasonable for Example 16.1. Provided condition (16.13) holds, we can divide (16.12) by (1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1) and write y2 as y2 􏱪 􏰵21z1 􏱕 􏰵22z2 􏱕 v2, [16.14] where 􏰵21 􏱪 􏱮2 􏱬1/(1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1), 􏰵22 􏱪 􏱬2/(1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1), and v2 􏱪 (􏱮2u1 􏱕 u2)/(1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1). Equation (16.14), which expresses y2 in terms of the exogenous variables and the error terms, is the reduced form equation for y2, a concept we introduced in Chapter 15 in the context of instrumental variables estimation. The parameters 􏰵21 and 􏰵22 are called reduced form parameters; notice how they are nonlinear functions of the structural parameters, which appear in the structural equations, (16.10) and (16.11). The reduced form error, v2, is a linear function of the structural error terms, u1 and u2. Because u1 and u2 are each uncorrelated with z1 and z2, v2 is also uncorrelated with z1 and z2. Therefore, we can consistently estimate 􏰵21 and 􏰵22 by OLS, something that is used for two stage least squares estimation (which we return to in the next section). In addition, the reduced form parameters are sometimes of direct interest, although we are focusing here on estimating equation (16.10). A reduced form also exists for y1 under assumption (16.13); the algebra is similar to that used to obtain (16.14). It has the same properties as the reduced form equation for y2. We can use equation (16.14) to show that, except under special assumptions, OLS es- timation of equation (16.10) will produce biased and inconsistent estimators of 􏱮1 and 􏱬1 in equation (16.10). Because z1 and u1 are uncorrelated by assumption, the issue is whether y2 and u1 are uncorrelated. From the reduced form in (16.14), we see that y2 and u1 are corre- lated if and only if v2 and u1 are correlated (because z1 and z2 are assumed exogenous). But v2 is a linear function of u1 and u2, so it is generally correlated with u1. In fact, if we assume that u1 and u2 are uncorrelated, then v2 and u1 must be correlated whenever 􏱮2 􏱻 0. Even if 􏱮2 equals zero—which means that y1 does not appear in equation (16.11)—v2 and u1 will be correlated if u1 and u2 are correlated. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 560 PART 3 Advanced Topics When 􏱮2 􏱪 0 and u1 and u2 are uncorrelated, y2 and u1 are also uncorrelated. These are fairly strong requirements: if 􏱮2 􏱪 0, y2 is not simultaneously determined with y1. If we add zero correlation between u1 and u2, this rules out omitted variables or measurement errors in u1 that are correlated with y2. We should not be surprised that OLS estimation of equation (16.10) works in this case. When y2 is correlated with u1 because of simultaneity, we say that OLS suffers from simultaneity bias. Obtaining the direction of the bias in the coefficients is generally com- plicated, as we saw with omitted variables bias in Chapters 3 and 5. But in simple models, we can determine the direction of the bias. For example, suppose that we simplify equation (16.10) by dropping z1 from the equation, and we assume that u1 and u2 are uncorrelated. Then, the covariance between y2 and u1 is Cov(y2,u1) 􏱪 Cov(v2,u1) 􏱪 [􏱮2/(1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1)]E(u21) 􏱪 [􏱮2/(1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1)]􏱧21, where 􏱧12 􏱪 Var(u1) 􏱰 0. Therefore, the asymptotic bias (or inconsistency) in the OLS estimator of 􏱮1 has the same sign as 􏱮2/(1 􏱦 􏱮2􏱮1). If 􏱮2 􏱰 0 and 􏱮2􏱮1 􏱷 1, the asymptotic bias is positive. (Unfortunately, just as in our calculation of omitted variables bias from Section 3.3, the conclusions do not carry over to more general models. But they do serve as a useful guide.) For example, in Example 16.1, we think 􏱮2 􏱰 0 and 􏱮2􏱮1 􏰯 0, which means that the OLS estimator of 􏱮1 would have a positive bias. If 􏱮1 􏱪 0, OLS would, on average, estimate a positive impact of more police on the murder rate; generally, the estima- tor of 􏱮1 is biased upward. Because we expect an increase in the size of the police force to reduce murder rates (ceteris paribus), the upward bias means that OLS will underestimate the effectiveness of a larger police force. 16.3 Identifying and Estimating a Structural Equation As we saw in the previous section, OLS is biased and inconsistent when applied to a structural equation in a simultaneous equations system. In Chapter 15, we learned that the method of two stage least squares can be used to solve the problem of endogenous explanatory variables. We now show how 2SLS can be applied to SEMs. The mechanics of 2SLS are similar to those in Chapter 15. The difference is that, be- cause we specify a structural equation for each endogenous variable, we can immediately see whether sufficient IVs are available to estimate either equation. We begin by discuss- ing the identification problem. Identification in a Two-Equation System We mentioned the notion of identification in Chapter 15. When we estimate a model by OLS, the key identification condition is that each explanatory variable is uncorrelated with the error term. As we demonstrated in Section 16.2, this fundamental condition no longer holds, in general, for SEMs. However, if we have some instrumental variables, we can still identify (or consistently estimate) the parameters in an SEM equation, just as with omitted variables or measurement error. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 561 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models Before we consider a general two-equation SEM, it is useful to gain intuition by con- sidering a simple supply and demand example. Write the system in equilibrium form (that is, with qs 􏱪 qd 􏱪 q imposed) as and q 􏱪 􏱮1p 􏱕 􏱬1z1 􏱕 u1 [16.15] q 􏱪 􏱮2 p 􏱕 u2. [16.16] For concreteness, let q be per capita milk consumption at the county level, let p be the average price per gallon of milk in the county, and let z1 be the price of cattle feed, which we assume is exogenous to the supply and demand equations for milk. This means that (16.15) must be the supply function, as the price of cattle feed would shift supply (􏱬1 􏱷 0) but not demand. The demand function contains no observed demand shifters. Given a random sample on (q, p, z1), which of these equations can be estimated? That is, which is an identified equation? It turns out that the demand equation, (16.16), is identified, but the supply equation is not. This is easy to see by using our rules for IV estimation from Chapter 15: we can use z1 as an IV for price in equation (16.16). However, because z1 appears in equation (16.15), we have no IV for price in the supply equation. Intuitively, the fact that the demand equation is identified follows because we have an observed variable, z1, that shifts the supply equation while not affecting the demand equation. Given variation in z1 and no errors, we can trace out the demand curve, as shown in Figure 16.1. The presence of the unobserved demand shifter u2 causes us to estimate the demand equation with error, but the estimators will be consistent, provided z1 is uncorrelated with u2. F I G U R E 1 6 . 1 Shifting supply equations trace out the demand equation. Each supply equation is drawn for a different value of the exogenous variable, z1. price demand equation supply equations quantity Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 562 PART 3 Advanced Topics The supply equation cannot be traced out because there are no exogenous observed factors shifting the demand curve. It does not help that there are unobserved factors shifting the demand function; we need something observed. If, as in the labor demand function (16.2), we have an observed exogenous demand shifter—such as income in the milk demand function—then the supply function would also be identified. To summarize: In the system of (16.15) and (16.16), it is the presence of an exog- enous variable in the supply equation that allows us to estimate the demand equation. Extending the identification discussion to a general two-equation model is not dif- ficult. Write the two equations as and y1 􏱪􏱬10 􏱕􏱮1y2 􏱕z1􏱬1 􏱕u1 [16.17] y2 􏱪 􏱬20 􏱕 􏱮2y1 􏱕 z2􏱬2 􏱕 u2, [16.18] where y1 and y2 are the endogenous variables, and u1 and u2 are the structural error terms. The intercept in the first equation is 􏱬10, and the intercept in the second equation is 􏱬20. The variable z1 denotes a set of k1 exogenous variables appearing in the first equation: z1 􏱪 (z11, z12, ..., z1k1). Similarly, z2 is the set of k2 exogenous variables in the second equation: z2 􏱪 (z21, z22, ..., z2k2). In many cases, z1 and z2 will overlap. As a shorthand form, we use the notation and z1􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬11z11 􏱕 􏱬12z12 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬1k1z1k1 z2􏱬2 􏱪 􏱬21z21 􏱕 􏱬22z22 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬2k2z2k2; that is, z1􏱬1 stands for all exogenous variables in the first equation, with each multi- plied by a coefficient, and similarly for z2􏱬2. (Some authors use the notation z􏲃1􏱬1 and z􏲃2􏱬2 instead. If you have an interest in the matrix algebra approach to econometrics, see Appendix E.) The fact that z1 and z2 generally contain different exogenous variables means that we have imposed exclusion restrictions on the model. In other words, we assume that certain exogenous variables do not appear in the first equation and others are absent from the sec- ond equation. As we saw with the previous supply and demand examples, this allows us to distinguish between the two structural equations. When can we solve equations (16.17) and (16.18) for y1 and y2 (as linear functions of all exogenous variables and the structural errors, u1 and u2)? The condition is the same as that in (16.13), namely, 􏱮2􏱮1 􏱻 1. The proof is virtually identical to the simple model in Section 16.2. Under this assumption, reduced forms exist for y1 and y2. The key question is: Under what assumptions can we estimate the parameters in, say, (16.17)? This is the identification issue. The rank condition for identification of equation (16.17) is easy to state. Rank Condition for Identification of a Structural Equation. The first equation in a two-equation simultaneous equations model is identified if, and only if, the second equa- tion contains at least one exogenous variable (with a nonzero coefficient) that is excluded from the first equation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 563 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models This is the necessary and sufficient condition for equation (16.17) to be identified. The order condition, which we discussed in Chapter 15, is necessary for the rank condition. The order condition for identifying the first equation states that at least one exogenous variable is excluded from this equation. The order condition is trivial to check once both equations have been specified. The rank condition requires more: at least one of the exogenous variables excluded from the first equation must have a nonzero population coefficient in the second equation. This ensures that at least one of the exogenous vari- ables omitted from the first equation actually appears in the reduced form of y2, so that we can use these variables as instruments for y2. We can test this using a t or an F test, as in Chapter 15; some examples follow. Identification of the second equation is, naturally, just the mirror image of the state- ment for the first equation. Also, if we write the equations as in the labor supply and demand example in Section 16.1—so that y1 appears on the left-hand side in both equa- tions, with y2 on the right-hand side—the identification condition is identical. EXAMPLE 16.3 LABOR SUPPLY OF MARRIED, WORKING WOMEN To illustrate the identification issue, consider labor supply for married women already in the workforce. In place of the demand function, we write the wage offer as a function of hours and the usual productivity variables. With the equilibrium condition imposed, the two structural equations are and hours 􏱪 􏱮1log(wage) 􏱕 􏱬10 􏱕 􏱬11educ 􏱕 􏱬12age 􏱕 􏱬13kidslt6 􏱕 􏱬14nwifeinc 􏱕 u1 log(wage) 􏱪 􏱮2hours 􏱕 􏱬20 􏱕 􏱬21educ 􏱕 􏱬22exper 􏱕 􏱬23exper2 􏱕 u2. [16.19] [16.20] The variable age is the woman’s age, in years, kidslt6 is the number of children less than six years old, nwifeinc is the woman’s nonwage income (which includes husband’s earn- ings), and educ and exper are years of education and prior experience, respectively. All variables except hours and log(wage) are assumed to be exogenous. (This is a tenuous assumption, as educ might be correlated with omitted ability in either equation. But for illustration purposes, we ignore the omitted ability problem.) The functional form in this system—where hours appears in level form but wage is in logarithmic form—is popular in labor economics. We can write this system as in equations (16.17) and (16.18) by defining y1 􏱪 hours and y2 􏱪 log(wage). The first equation is the supply function. It satisfies the order condition because two exogenous variables, exper and exper2, are omitted from the labor supply equation. These exclusion restrictions are crucial assumptions: we are assuming that, once wage, education, age, number of small children, and other income are controlled for, past experience has no effect on current labor supply. One could certainly question this assumption, but we use it for illustration. Given equations (16.19) and (16.20), the rank condition for identifying the first equation is that at least one of exper and exper2 has a nonzero coefficient in equation (16.20). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 564 PART 3 Advanced Topics If 􏱬22 􏱪 0 and 􏱬23 􏱪 0, there are no exogenous variables appearing in the second equation that do not also appear in the first (educ appears in both). We can state the rank condi- tion for identification of (16.19) equivalently in terms of the reduced form for log(wage), which is log(wage) 􏱪 􏰵20 􏱕 􏰵21educ 􏱕 􏰵22age 􏱕 􏰵23kidslt6 􏱕 􏰵24nwifeinc 􏱕 􏰵25exper 􏱕 􏰵26exper2 􏱕 v2. [16.21] For identification, we need 􏰵25 􏱻 0 or 􏰵26 􏱻 0, something we can test using a standard F statistic, as we discussed in Chapter 15. The wage offer equation, (16.20), is identified if at least one of age, kidslt6, or nwifeinc has a nonzero coefficient in (16.19). This is identical to assuming that the reduced form for hours—which has the same form as the right-hand side of (16.21)—depends on at least one of age, kidslt6, or nwifeinc. In specifying the wage offer equation, we are assuming that age, kidslt6, and nwifeinc have no effect on the offered wage, once hours, education, and experience are accounted for. These would be poor assumptions if these variables somehow have direct effects on productivity, or if women are discriminated against based on their age or number of small children. In Example 16.3, we take the population of interest to be married women who are in the workforce (so that equilibrium hours are positive). This excludes the group of married women who choose not to work outside the home. Including such women in the model raises some difficult problems. For instance, if a woman does not work, we cannot observe her wage offer. We touch on these issues in Chapter 17; but for now, we must think of equations (16.19) and (16.20) as holding only for women who have hours 􏱰 0. EXAMPLE 16.4 INFLATION AND OPENNESS Romer (1993) proposes theoretical models of inflation that imply that more “open” coun- tries should have lower inflation rates. His empirical analysis explains average annual inflation rates (since 1973) in terms of the average share of imports in gross domestic (or national) product since 1973—which is his measure of openness. In addition to estimating the key equation by OLS, he uses instrumental variables. While Romer does not specify both equations in a simultaneous system, he has in mind a two-equation system: inf 􏱪 􏱬10 􏱕 􏱮1open 􏱕 􏱬11log( pcinc) 􏱕 u1 [16.22] open 􏱪 􏱬20 􏱕 􏱮2inf 􏱕 􏱬21log( pcinc) 􏱕 􏱬22log(land ) 􏱕 u2, [16.23] where pcinc is 1980 per capita income, in U.S. dollars (assumed to be exogenous), and land is the land area of the country, in square miles (also assumed to be exogenous). Equa- tion (16.22) is the one of interest, with the hypothesis that 􏱮1 􏱷 0. (More open economies have lower inflation rates.) The second equation reflects the fact that the degree of openness might depend on the average inflation rate, as well as other factors. The variable log(pcinc) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 16.2 If we have money supply growth since 1973 for each country, which we assume is exogenous, does this help identify equation (16.23)? 565 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models appears in both equations, but log(land ) is assumed to appear only in the second equation. The idea is that, ceteris paribus, a smaller country is likely to be more open (so 􏱬22 􏱷 0). Using the identification rule that was stated earlier, equation (16.22) is identified, provided 􏱬22 􏱻 0. Equation (16.23) is not identified because it contains both exogenous vari- ables. But we are interested in (16.22). Estimation by 2SLS Once we have determined that an equation is identified, we can estimate it by two stage least squares. The instrumental variables consist of the exogenous variables appearing in either equation. EXAMPLE 16.5 LABOR SUPPLY OF MARRIED, WORKING WOMEN We use the data on working, married women in MROZ.RAW to estimate the labor supply equation (16.19) by 2SLS. The full set of instruments includes educ, age, kidslt6, nwifeinc, exper, and exper2. The estimated labor supply curve is 􏱾hours 􏱪 2,225.66 􏱕 1,639.56 log(wage) 􏱦 183.75 educ (574.56) (470.58) (59.10) 􏱦 7.81 age 􏱦 198.15 kidslt6 􏱦 10.17 nwifeinc (9.38) (182.93) (6.61) n 􏱪 428, [16.24] which shows that the labor supply curve slopes upward. The estimated coefficient on log(wage) has the following interpretation: holding other factors fixed, 􏰧􏱾hours 􏱴 16.4(%􏰧wage). We can calculate labor supply elasticities by multiplying both sides of this last equation by 100/hours: or 100􏱳(􏰧􏱾hours/hours) 􏱴 (1,640/hours)(%􏰧wage) %􏰧􏱾hours 􏱴 (1,640/hours)(%􏰧wage), which implies that the labor supply elasticity (with respect to wage) is simply 1,640/hours. [The elasticity is not constant in this model because hours, not log(hours), is the depen- dent variable in (16.24).] At the average hours worked, 1,303, the estimated elasticity is 1,640/1,303 􏱴 1.26, which implies a greater than 1% increase in hours worked given a 1% increase in wage. This is a large estimated elasticity. At higher hours, the elasticity will be smaller; at lower hours, such as hours 􏱪 800, the elasticity is over two. For comparison, when (16.19) is estimated by OLS, the coefficient on log(wage) is 􏱦2.05 (se 􏱪 54.88), which implies no wage effect on hours worked. To confirm that log(wage) is in fact endogenous in (16.19), we can carry out the test from Section 15.5. When we add the reduced form residuals vˆ2 to the equation and estimate by OLS, the t statistic on vˆ2 is 􏱦6.61, which is very significant, and so log(wage) appears to be endogenous. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 566 PART 3 Advanced Topics The wage offer equation (16.20) can also be estimated by 2SLS. The result is 􏱾log(wage) 􏱪 􏱦.656 􏱕 .00013 hours 􏱕 .110 educ (.338) (.00025) (.016) 􏱕 .035 exper 􏱦 .00071 exper2 (.019) (.00045) n 􏱪 428. [16.25] This differs from previous wage equations in that hours is included as an explanatory vari- able and 2SLS is used to account for endogeneity of hours (and we assume that educ and exper are exogenous). The coefficient on hours is statistically insignificant, which means that there is no evidence that the wage offer increases with hours worked. The other coef- ficients are similar to what we get by dropping hours and estimating the equation by OLS. Estimating the effect of openness on inflation by instrumental variables is also straightforward. EXAMPLE 16.6 INFLATION AND OPENNESS Before we estimate (16.22) using the data in OPENNESS.RAW, we check to see whether open has sufficient partial correlation with the proposed IV, log(land). The reduced form regression is o􏱾pen 􏱪 117.08 􏱕 .546 log( pcinc) 􏱦 7.57 log(land ) (15.85) (1.493) (.81) n 􏱪 114, R2 􏱪 .449. The t statistic on log(land ) is over nine in absolute value, which verifies Romer’s assertion that smaller countries are more open. The fact that log(pcinc) is so insignificant in this regression is irrelevant. Estimating (16.22) using log(land ) as an IV for open gives 􏱾inf 􏱪 26.90 􏱦 .337 open 􏱕 .376 log(pcinc) (15.40) (.144) n 􏱪 114. (2.015) [16.26] The coefficient on open is statistically significant at about the 1% level against a one-sided alternative (􏱮1 􏱷 0). The effect is economically important as well: for every percentage point increase in the import share of GDP, annual infla- EXPLORING FURTHER 16.3 How would you test whether the difference between the OLS and IV estimates on open are statistically different? tion is about one-third of a percentage point lower. For comparison, the OLS estimate is 􏱦.215 (se 􏱪 .095). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 567 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 16.4 Systems with More Than Two Equations Simultaneous equations models can consist of more than two equations. Studying general identification of these models is difficult and requires matrix algebra. Once an equation in a general system has been shown to be identified, it can be estimated by 2SLS. Identification in Systems with Three or More Equations We will use a three-equation system to illustrate the issues that arise in the identification of complicated SEMs. With intercepts suppressed, write the model as y1 􏱪 􏱮12y2 􏱕 􏱮13y3 􏱕 􏱬11z1 􏱕 u1 y2 􏱪 􏱮21y1 􏱕 􏱬21z1 􏱕 􏱬22z2 􏱕 􏱬23z3 􏱕 u2 y3 􏱪 􏱮32y2 􏱕 􏱬31z1 􏱕 􏱬32z2 􏱕 􏱬33z3 􏱕 􏱬34z4 􏱕 u3, [16.27] [16.28] [16.29] where the yg are the endogenous variables and the zj are exogenous. The first subscript on the parameters indicates the equation number, and the second indicates the variable num- ber; we use 􏱮 for parameters on endogenous variables and 􏱬 for parameters on exogenous variables. Which of these equations can be estimated? It is generally difficult to show that an equa- tion in an SEM with more than two equations is identified, but it is easy to see when certain equations are not identified. In system (16.27) through (16.29), we can easily see that (16.29) falls into this category. Because every exogenous variable appears in this equation, we have no IVs for y2. Therefore, we cannot consistently estimate the parameters of this equation. For the reasons we discussed in Section 16.2, OLS estimation will not usually be consistent. What about equation (16.27)? Things look promising because z2, z3, and z4 are all excluded from the equation—this is another example of exclusion restrictions. Although there are two endogenous variables in this equation, we have three potential IVs for y2 and y3. Therefore, equation (16.27) passes the order condition. For completeness, we state the order condition for general SEMs. Order Condition for Identification. An equation in any SEM satisfies the order condi- tion for identification if the number of excluded exogenous variables from the equation is at least as large as the number of right-hand side endogenous variables. The second equation, (16.28), also passes the order condition because there is one excluded exogenous variable, z4, and one right-hand side endogenous variable, y1. As we discussed in Chapter 15 and in the previous section, the order condition is only necessary, not sufficient, for identification. For example, if 􏱬34 􏱪 0, z4 appears nowhere in the system, which means it is not correlated with y1, y2, or y3. If 􏱬34 􏱪 0, then the second equation is not identified, because z4 is useless as an IV for y1. This again illustrates that identification of an equation depends on the values of the parameters (which we can never know for sure) in the other equations. There are many subtle ways that identification can fail in complicated SEMs. To obtain sufficient conditions, we need to extend the rank condition for identification in two-equation systems. This is possible, but it requires matrix algebra [see, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 9)]. In many applications, one assumes that, unless there is obviously failure of identification, an equation that satisfies the order condition is identified. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 568 PART 3 Advanced Topics The nomenclature on overidentified and just identified equations from Chapter 15 originated with SEMs. In terms of the order condition, (16.27) is an overidentified equa- tion because we need only two IVs (for y2 and y3) but we have three available (z2, z3, and z4); there is one overidentifying restriction in this equation. In general, the number of over- identifying restrictions equals the total number of exogenous variables in the system, mi- nus the total number of explanatory variables in the equation. These can be tested using the overidentification test from Section 15.5. Equation (16.28) is a just identified equa- tion, and the third equation is an unidentified equation. Estimation Regardless of the number of equations in an SEM, each identified equation can be esti- mated by 2SLS. The instruments for a particular equation consist of the exogenous vari- ables appearing anywhere in the system. Tests for endogeneity, heteroskedasticity, serial correlation, and overidentifying restrictions can be obtained, just as in Chapter 15. It turns out that, when any system with two or more equations is correctly specified and certain additional assumptions hold, system estimation methods are generally more efficient than estimating each equation by 2SLS. The most common system estimation method in the context of SEMs is three stage least squares. These methods, with or with- out endogenous explanatory variables, are beyond the scope of this text. [See, for example, Wooldridge (2010, Chapters 7 and 8).] 16.5 Simultaneous Equations Models with Time Series Among the earliest applications of SEMs was estimation of large systems of simultaneous equations that were used to describe a country’s economy. A simple Keynesian model of aggregate demand (that ignores exports and imports) is where Ct 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1(Yt 􏱦Tt)􏱕􏱬2rt 􏱕ut1 It 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1rt 􏱕 ut2 Yt􏱲Ct 􏱕It 􏱕Gt, Ct 􏱪 consumption Yt 􏱪income Tt 􏱪 tax receipts rt 􏱪 the interest rate It 􏱪 investment Gt 􏱪 government spending [16.30] [16.31] [16.32] [See, for example, Mankiw (1994, Chapter 9).] For concreteness, assume t represents year. The first equation is an aggregate consumption function, where consumption depends on disposable income, the interest rate, and the unobserved structural error ut1. The second equation is a very simple investment function. Equation (16.32) is an identity that is a result of national income accounting: it holds by definition, without error. Thus, there is no sense in which we estimate (16.32), but we need this equation to round out the model. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 569 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models Because there are three equations in the system, there must also be three endogenous variables. Given the first two equations, it is clear that we intend for Ct and It to be en- dogenous. In addition, because of the accounting identity, Yt is endogenous. We would as- sume, at least in this model, that Tt, rt, and Gt are exogenous, so that they are uncorrelated with ut1 and ut2. (We will discuss problems with this kind of assumption later.) If rt is exogenous, then OLS estimation of equation (16.31) is natural. The consump- tion function, however, depends on disposable income, which is endogenous because Yt is. We have two instruments available under the maintained exogeneity assumptions: Tt and Gt. Therefore, if we follow our prescription for estimating cross-sectional equations, we would estimate (16.30) by 2SLS using instruments (Tt,Gt,rt). Models such as (16.30) through (16.32) are seldom estimated now, for several good reasons. First, it is very difficult to justify, at an aggregate level, the assumption that taxes, interest rates, and government spending are exogenous. Taxes clearly depend directly on income; for example, with a single marginal income tax rate 􏰫t in year t, Tt 􏱪 􏰫tYt. We can easily allow this by replacing (Yt 􏱦 Tt) with (1 􏱦 􏰫t)Yt in (16.30), and we can still estimate the equation by 2SLS if we assume that government spending is exogenous. We could also add the tax rate to the instrument list, if it is exogenous. But are government spending and tax rates really exogenous? They certainly could be in principle, if the government sets spending and tax rates independently of what is hap- pening in the economy. But it is a difficult case to make in reality: government spending generally depends on the level of income, and at high levels of income, the same tax re- ceipts are collected for lower marginal tax rates. In addition, assuming that interest rates are exogenous is extremely questionable. We could specify a more realistic model that includes money demand and supply, and then interest rates could be jointly determined with Ct, It, and Yt. But then finding enough exogenous variables to identify the equations becomes quite difficult (and the following problems with these models still pertain). Some have argued that certain components of government spending, such as defense spending—see, for example, Hall (1988) and Ramey (1991)—are exogenous in a variety of simultaneous equations applications. But this is not universally agreed upon, and, in any case, defense spending is not always appropriately correlated with the endogenous explanatory variables [see Shea (1993) for discussion and Computer Exercise C6 for an example]. A second problem with a model such as (16.30) through (16.32) is that it is com- pletely static. Especially with monthly or quarterly data, but even with annual data, we often expect adjustment lags. (One argument in favor of static Keynesian-type models is that they are intended to describe the long run without worrying about short-run dynam- ics.) Allowing dynamics is not very difficult. For example, we could add lagged income to equation (16.31): It 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1rt 􏱕 􏰸2Yt􏱦1 􏱕 ut2. [16.33] In other words, we add a lagged endogenous variable (but not It􏱦1) to the investment equation. Can we treat Yt􏱦1 as exogenous in this equation? Under certain assumptions on ut2, the answer is yes. But we typically call a lagged endogenous variable in an SEM a predetermined variable. Lags of exogenous variables are also predetermined. If we as- sume that ut2 is uncorrelated with current exogenous variables (which is standard) and all past endogenous and exogenous variables, then Yt􏱦1 is uncorrelated with ut2. Given exoge- neity of rt, we can estimate (16.33) by OLS. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 570 PART 3 Advanced Topics If we add lagged consumption to (16.30), we can treat Ct􏱦1 as exogenous in this equa- tion under the same assumptions on ut1 that we made for ut2 in the previous paragraph. Current disposable income is still endogenous in Ct 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1(Yt 􏱦 Tt) 􏱕 􏱬2rt 􏱕 􏱬3Ct􏱦1 􏱕 ut1, [16.34] so we could estimate this equation by 2SLS using instruments (Tt,Gt,rt,Ct􏱦1); if invest- ment is determined by (16.33), Yt􏱦1 should be added to the instrument list. [To see why, use (16.32), (16.33), and (16.34) to find the reduced form for Yt in terms of the exogenous and predetermined variables: Tt, rt, Gt, Ct􏱦1, and Yt􏱦1. Because Yt􏱦1 shows up in this re- duced form, it should be used as an IV.] The presence of dynamics in aggregate SEMs is, at least for the purposes of forecast- ing, a clear improvement over static SEMs. But there are still some important problems with estimating SEMs using aggregate time series data, some of which we discussed in Chapters 11 and 15. Recall that the validity of the usual OLS or 2SLS inference pro- cedures in time series applications hinges on the notion of weak dependence. Unfortu- nately, series such as aggregrate consumption, income, investment, and even interest rates seem to violate the weak dependence requirements. (In the terminology of Chapter 11, they have unit roots.) These series also tend to have exponential trends, although this can be partly overcome by using the logarithmic transformation and assuming different functional forms. Generally, even the large sample, let alone the small sample, properties of OLS and 2SLS are complicated and dependent on various assumptions when they are applied to equations with I(1) variables. We will briefly touch on these issues in Chapter 18. An advanced, general treatment is given by Hamilton (1994). Does the previous discussion mean that SEMs are not usefully applied to time series data? Not at all. The problems with trends and high persistence can be avoided by speci- fying systems in first differences or growth rates. But one should recognize that this is a different SEM than one specified in levels. [For example, if we specify consumption growth as a function of disposable income growth and interest rate changes, this is different from (16.30).] Also, as we discussed earlier, incorporating dynamics is not especially dif- ficult. Finally, the problem of finding truly exogenous variables to include in SEMs is of- ten easier with disaggregated data. For example, for manufacturing industries, Shea (1993) describes how output (or, more precisely, growth in output) in other industries can be used as an instrument in estimating supply functions. Ramey (1991) also has a convincing analy- sis of estimating industry cost functions by instrumental variables using time series data. The next example shows how aggregate data can be used to test an important eco- nomic theory, the permanent income theory of consumption, usually called the perma- nent income hypothesis (PIH). The approach used in this example is not, strictly speaking, based on a simultaneous equations model, but we can think of consumption and income growth (as well as interest rates) as being jointly determined. EXAMPLE 16.7 TESTING THE PERMANENT INCOME HYPOTHESIS Campbell and Mankiw (1990) used instrumental variables methods to test vari- ous versions of the permanent income hypothesis. We will use the annual data from 1959 through 1995 in CONSUMP.RAW to mimic one of their analyses. Campbell and Mankiw used quarterly data running through 1985. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 571 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models One equation estimated by Campbell and Mankiw (using our notation) is gct 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gyt 􏱕 􏱬2r3t 􏱕 ut, [16.35] where gct 􏱪 􏰧log(ct) 􏱪 annual growth in real per capita consumption (excluding durables). gyt 􏱪 growth in real disposable income. r3t 􏱪the(expost)realinterestrateasmeasuredbythereturnonthree-monthT-bill rates: r3t 􏱪 i3t 􏱦 inft, where the inflation rate is based on the Consumer Price Index. The growth rates of consumption and disposable income are not trending, and they are weakly dependent; we will assume this is the case for r3t as well, so that we can apply standard asymptotic theory. The key feature of equation (16.35) is that the PIH implies that the error term ut has a zero mean conditional on all information observed at time t 􏱦 1 or earlier: E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0. However, ut is not necessarily uncorrelated with gyt or r3t; a traditional way to think about this is that these variables are jointly determined, but we are not writing down a full three- equation system. Because ut is uncorrelated with all variables dated t 􏱦 1 or earlier, valid instruments for estimating (16.35) are lagged values of gc, gy, and r3 (and lags of other observable variables, but we will not use those here). What are the hypotheses of interest? The pure form of the PIH has 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2 􏱪 0. Campbell and Mankiw argue that 􏱬1 is positive if some fraction of the population consumes current income, rather than permanent income. The PIH with a nonconstant real interest rate implies that 􏱬2 􏱰 0. When we estimate (16.35) by 2SLS, using instruments gc􏱦1, gy􏱦1, and r3􏱦1 for the endogenous variables gyt and r3t, we obtain g􏱾ct 􏱪 .0081 􏱕 .586 gyt 􏱦 .00027 r3t (.0032) (.135) (.00076) [16.36] n􏱪35,R2 􏱪.678. Therefore, the pure form of the PIH is strongly rejected because the coefficient on gy is economically large (a 1% increase in disposable income increases consumption by over .5%) and statistically significant (t 􏱪 4.34). By contrast, the real interest rate coefficient is very small and statistically insignificant. These findings are qualitatively the same as Campbell and Mankiw’s. The PIH also implies that the errors {ut} are serially uncorrelated. After 2SLS esti- mation, we obtain the residuals, ˆut, and include ˆut􏱦1 as an additional explanatory variable in (16.36); we still use instruments gct􏱦1, gyt􏱦1, r3t􏱦1, and uˆt􏱦1 acts as its own instrument (see Section 15.7). The coefficient on ˆut􏱦1 is 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .187 (se 􏱪 .133), so there is some evi- dence of positive serial correlation, although not at the 5% significance level. Campbell and Mankiw discuss why, with the available quarterly data, positive serial correlation might be found in the errors even if the PIH holds; some of those concerns carry over to annual data. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 572 PART 3 Advanced Topics Using growth rates of trending or I(1) variables in SEMs is fairly com- mon in time series applications. For example, Shea (1993) estimates indus- try supply curves specified in terms of growth rates. If a structural model contains a time trend—which may capture exog- enous, trending factors that are not di- rectly modeled—then the trend acts as its own IV. 16.6 Simultaneous Equations Models with Panel Data Simultaneous equations models also arise in panel data contexts. For example, we can imagine estimating labor supply and wage offer equations, as in Example 16.3, for a group of people working over a given period of time. In addition to allowing for simultaneous determination of variables within each time period, we can allow for unobserved effects in each equation. In a labor supply function, it would be useful to allow an unobserved taste for leisure that does not change over time. The basic approach to estimating SEMs with panel data involves two steps: (1) elimi- nate the unobserved effects from the equations of interest using the fixed effects transformation or first differencing and (2) find instrumental variables for the endogenous variables in the transformed equation. This can be very challenging because, for a convincing analysis, we need to find instruments that change over time. To see why, write an SEM for panel data as yit1 􏱪 􏱮1yit2 􏱕 zit1􏱬1 􏱕 ai1 􏱕 uit1 [16.37] yit2 􏱪 􏱮2yit1 􏱕 zit2􏱬2 􏱕 ai2 􏱕 uit2, [16.38] where i denotes cross section, t denotes time period, and zit1􏱬1 or zit2􏱬2 denotes linear functions of a set of exogenous explanatory variables in each equation. The most general analysis allows the unobserved effects, ai1 and ai2, to be correlated with all explanatory variables, even the elements in z. However, we assume that the idiosyncratic structural errors, uit1 and uit2, are uncorrelated with the z in both equations and across all time periods; this is the sense in which the z are exogenous. Except under special circumstances, yit2 is correlated with uit1, and yit1 is correlated with uit2. Suppose we are interested in equation (16.37). We cannot estimate it by OLS, as the composite error ai1 􏱕 uit1 is potentially correlated with all explanatory variables. Suppose we difference over time to remove the unobserved effect, ai1: 􏰧yit1 􏱪 􏱮1􏰧yit2 􏱕 􏰧zit1􏱬1 􏱕 􏰧uit1. [16.39] (As usual with differencing or time-demeaning, we can only estimate the effects of variables that change over time for at least some cross-sectional units.) Now, the error Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 16.4 Suppose that for a particular city you have monthly data on per capita consumption of fish, per capita income, the price of fish, and the prices of chicken and beef; income and chicken and beef prices are exog- enous. Assume that there is no seasonality in the demand function for fish, but there is in the supply of fish. How can you use this information to estimate a constant elasticity demand-for-fish equation? Specify an equa- tion and discuss identification. (Hint: You should have 11 instrumental variables for the price of fish.) 573 CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models term in this equation is uncorrelated with 􏰧zit1 by assumption. But 􏰧yit2 and 􏰧uit1 are pos- sibly correlated. Therefore, we need an IV for 􏰧yit 2. As with the case of pure cross-sectional or pure time series data, possible IVs come from the other equation: elements in zit2 that are not also in zit1. In practice, we need time- varying elements in zit2 that are not also in zit1. This is because we need an instrument for 􏰧yit2, and a change in a variable from one period to the next is unlikely to be highly cor- related with the level of exogenous variables. In fact, if we difference (16.38), we see that the natural IVs for 􏰧yit2 are those elements in 􏰧zit2 that are not also in 􏰧zit1. As an example of the problems that can arise, consider a panel data version of the labor supply function in Example 16.3. After differencing, suppose we have the equation 􏰧hoursit 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱮1􏰧log(wageit) 􏱕 􏰧(other factorsit), and we wish to use 􏰧experit as an instrument for 􏰧log(wageit). The problem is that, be- cause we are looking at people who work in every time period, 􏰧experit 􏱪 1 for all i and t. (Each person gets another year of experience after a year passes.) We cannot use an IV that is the same value for all i and t, and so we must look elsewhere. Often, participation in an experimental program can be used to obtain IVs in panel data contexts. In Example 15.10, we used receipt of job training grants as an IV for the change in hours of training in determining the effects of job training on worker productivity. In fact, we could view that in an SEM context: job training and worker productivity are jointly deter- mined, but receiving a job training grant is exogenous in equation (15.57). We can sometimes come up with clever, convincing instrumental variables in panel data applications, as the following example illustrates. EXAMPLE 16.8 EFFECT OF PRISON POPULATION ON VIOLENT CRIME RATES In order to estimate the causal effect of prison population increases on crime rates at the state level, Levitt (1996) used instances of prison overcrowding litigation as instruments for the growth in prison population. The equation Levitt estimated is in first differences; we can write an underlying fixed effects model as log(crimeit) 􏱪 􏰩t 􏱕 􏱮1log(prisonit) 􏱕 zit1􏱬1 􏱕 ai1 􏱕 uit1, [16.40] where 􏰩t denotes different time intercepts, and crime and prison are measured per 100,000 people. (The prison population variable is measured on the last day of the previous year.) The vector zit1 contains log of police per capita, log of income per capita, the unemploy- ment rate, proportions of black and those living in metropolitan areas, and age distribution proportions. Differencing (16.40) gives the equation estimated by Levitt: 􏰧log(crimeit) 􏱪 􏰽t 􏱕 􏱮1􏰧log(prisonit) 􏱕 􏰧zit1􏱬1 􏱕 􏰧uit1. [16.41] Simultaneity between crime rates and prison population, or more precisely in the growth rates, makes OLS estimation of (16.41) generally inconsistent. Using the violent crime rate and a subset of the data from Levitt (in PRISON.RAW, for the years 1980 through 1993, for 51􏱳14 􏱪 714 total observations), we obtain the pooled OLS estimate of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 574 PART 3 Advanced Topics 􏱮1, which is 􏱦.181 (se 􏱪 .048). We also estimate (16.41) by pooled 2SLS, where the instruments for 􏰧log(prison) are two binary variables, one each for whether a final deci- sion was reached on overcrowding litigation in the current year or in the previous two years. The pooled 2SLS estimate of 􏱮1 is 􏱦1.032 (se 􏱪 .370). Therefore, the 2SLS es- timated effect is much larger; not surprisingly, it is much less precise, too. Levitt found similar results when using a longer time period (but with early observations missing for some states) and more instruments. Testing for AR(1) serial correlation in rit1 􏱪 􏰧uit1 is easy. After the pooled 2SLS estimation, obtain the residuals, rˆit1. Then, include one lag of these residuals in the original equation, and estimate the equation by 2SLS, where rˆit1 acts as its own instrument. The first year is lost because of the lagging. Then, the usual 2SLS t statistic on the lagged re- sidual is a valid test for serial correlation. In Example 16.8, the coefficient on rˆit1 is only about .076 with t 􏱪 1.67. With such a small coefficient and modest t statistic, we can safely assume serial independence. An alternative approach to estimating SEMs with panel data is to use the fixed effects transformation and then to apply an IV technique such as pooled 2SLS. A simple procedure is to estimate the time-demeaned equation by pooled 2SLS, which would look like ÿit1 􏱪 􏱮1ÿt2 􏱕 z ̈it1􏱬1 􏱕 üit1, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., T, [16.42] where z ̈it1 and z ̈it2 are IVs. This is equivalent to using 2SLS in the dummy variable formu- lation, where the unit-specific dummy variables act as their own instruments. Ayres and Levitt (1998) applied 2SLS to a time-demeaned equation to estimate the effect of LoJack electronic theft prevention devices on car theft rates in cities. If (16.42) is estimated di- rectly, then the df needs to be corrected to N(T 􏱦 1) 􏱦 k1, where k1 is the total number of elements in 􏱮1 and 􏱬1. Including unit-specific dummy variables and applying pooled 2SLS to the original data produces the correct df. A detailed treatment of 2SLS with panel data is given in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 11). Summary Simultaneous equations models are appropriate when each equation in the system has a ceteris paribus interpretation. Good examples are when separate equations describe different sides of a market or the behavioral relationships of different economic agents. Supply and demand examples are leading cases, but there are many other applications of SEMs in economics and the social sciences. An important feature of SEMs is that, by fully specifying the system, it is clear which variables are assumed to be exogenous and which ones appear in each equation. Given a full system, we are able to determine which equations can be identified (that is, can be estimated). In the important case of a two-equation system, identification of (say) the first equation is easy to state: at least one exogenous variable must be excluded from the first equation that appears with a nonzero coefficient in the second equation. As we know from previous chapters, OLS estimation of an equation that contains an endogenous explanatory variable generally produces biased and inconsistent estimators. Instead, 2SLS can be used to estimate any identified equation in a system. More advanced system methods are available, but they are beyond the scope of our treatment. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 575 The distinction between omitted variables and simultaneity in applications is not always sharp. Both problems, not to mention measurement error, can appear in the same equation. A good example is the labor supply of married women. Years of education (educ) appears in both the labor supply and the wage offer functions [see equations (16.19) and (16.20)]. If omit- ted ability is in the error term of the labor supply function, then wage and education are both endogenous. The important thing is that an equation estimated by 2SLS can stand on its own. SEMs can be applied to time series data as well. As with OLS estimation, we must be aware of trending, integrated processes in applying 2SLS. Problems such as serial cor- relation can be handled as in Section 15.7. We also gave an example of how to estimate an SEM using panel data, where the equation is first differenced to remove the unobserved effect. Then, we can estimate the differenced equation by pooled 2SLS, just as in Chapter 15. Alternatively, in some cases, we can use time-demeaning of all variables, including the IVs, and then apply pooled 2SLS; this is identical to putting in dummies for each cross- sectional observation and using 2SLS, where the dummies act as their own instruments. SEM applications with panel data are very powerful, as they allow us to control for unob- served heterogeneity while dealing with simultaneity. They are becoming more and more common and are not especially difficult to estimate. Key Terms Endogenous Variables Exclusion Restrictions Exogenous Variables Identified Equation Just Identified Equation Lagged Endogenous Variable Order Condition Problems Overidentified Equation Predetermined Variable Rank Condition Reduced Form Equation Reduced Form Error Reduced Form Parameters Simultaneity Simultaneity Bias Simultaneous Equations Model (SEM) Structural Equation Structural Errors Structural Parameters Unidentified Equation 1 Write a two-equation system in “supply and demand form,” that is, with the same variable y1 (typically, “quantity”) appearing on the left-hand side: y1 􏱪􏱮1y2 􏱕􏱬1z1 􏱕u1 y1 􏱪􏱮2y2 􏱕􏱬2z2 􏱕u2. (i) If 􏱮1 􏱪 0 or 􏱮2 􏱪 0, explain why a reduced form exists for y1. (Remember, a reduced form expresses y1 as a linear function of the exogenous variables and the structural errors.) If 􏱮1 􏱻 0 and 􏱮2 􏱪 0, find the reduced form for y2. (ii) If 􏱮1 􏱻 0, 􏱮2 􏱻 0, and 􏱮1 􏱻 􏱮2, find the reduced form for y1. Does y2 have a reduced form in this case? (iii) Is the condition 􏱮1 􏱻 􏱮2 likely to be met in supply and demand examples? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 576 PART 3 Advanced Topics 2 Let corn denote per capita consumption of corn in bushels at the county level, let price be the price per bushel of corn, let income denote per capita county income, and let rainfall be inches of rainfall during the last corn-growing season. The following simultaneous equa- tions model imposes the equilibrium condition that supply equals demand: corn 􏱪 􏱮1 price 􏱕 􏱬1income 􏱕 u1 corn 􏱪 􏱮2 price 􏱕 􏱬2rainfall 􏱕 􏰸2rainfall2 􏱕 u2. Which is the supply equation, and which is the demand equation? Explain. 3 In Problem 3 of Chapter 3, we estimated an equation to test for a tradeoff between minutes per week spent sleeping (sleep) and minutes per week spent working (totwrk) for a random sample of individuals. We also included education and age in the equation. Because sleep and totwrk are jointly chosen by each individual, is the estimated tradeoff between sleep- ing and working subject to a “simultaneity bias” criticism? Explain. 4 Suppose that annual earnings and alcohol consumption are determined by the SEM log(earnings) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1alcohol 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 u1 alcohol 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1log(earnings) 􏱕 􏰸2educ 􏱕 􏰸3log(price) 􏱕 u2, where price is a local price index for alcohol, which includes state and local taxes. Assume that educ and price are exogenous. If 􏱬1, 􏱬2, 􏰸1, 􏰸2, and 􏰸3 are all different from zero, which equation is identified? How would you estimate that equation? 5 A simple model to determine the effectiveness of condom usage on reducing sexually transmitted diseases among sexually active high school students is infrate 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1conuse 􏱕 􏱬2percmale 􏱕 􏱬3avginc 􏱕 􏱬4city 􏱕 u1, where infrate 􏱪 the percentage of sexually active students who have contracted venereal disease. conuse 􏱪 the percentage of boys who claim to use condoms regularly. avginc 􏱪 average family income. city 􏱪 a dummy variable indicating whether a school is in a city. The model is at the school level. (i) Interpreting the preceding equation in a causal, ceteris paribus fashion, what should be the sign of 􏱬1? (ii) Why might infrate and conuse be jointly determined? (iii) If condom usage increases with the rate of venereal disease, so that 􏰸1 􏱰 0 in the equation conuse 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1infrate 􏱕 other factors, what is the likely bias in estimating 􏱬1 by OLS? (iv) Let condis be a binary variable equal to unity if a school has a program to distribute condoms. Explain how this can be used to estimate 􏱬1 (and the other betas) by IV. What do we have to assume about condis in each equation? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 577 6 Consider a linear probability model for whether employers offer a pension plan based on the percentage of workers belonging to a union, as well as other factors: pension 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1percunion 􏱕 􏱬2avgage 􏱕 􏱬3avgeduc 􏱕 􏱬4 percmale 􏱕 􏱬5 percmarr 􏱕 u1. (i) Why might percunion be jointly determined with pension? (ii) Suppose that you can survey workers at firms and collect information on workers’ families. Can you think of information that can be used to construct an IV for percunion? (iii) How would you test whether your variable is at least a reasonable IV candidate for percunion? 7 For a large university, you are asked to estimate the demand for tickets to women’s bas- ketball games. You can collect time series data over 10 seasons, for a total of about 150 observations. One possible model is lATTENDt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1lPRICEt 􏱕 􏱬2WINPERCt 􏱕 􏱬3RIVALt 􏱕 􏱬4WEEKENDt 􏱕 􏱬5t 􏱕 ut, PRICEt 􏱪 the price of admission, probably measured in real terms—say, deflating by a regional consumer price index. where The l denotes natural logarithm, so that the demand function has a constant price elasticity. (i) Why is it a good idea to have a time trend in the equation? (ii) The supply of tickets is fixed by the stadium capacity; assume this has not changed over the 10 years. This means that quantity supplied does not vary with price. Does this mean that price is necessarily exogenous in the demand equation? (Hint: The answer is no.) (iii) Suppose that the nominal price of admission changes slowly—say, at the beginning of each season. The athletic office chooses price based partly on last season’s aver- age attendance, as well as last season’s team success. Under what assumptions is last season’s winning percentage (SEASPERCt􏱦1) a valid instrumental variable for lPRICEt? (iv) Does it seem reasonable to include the (log of the) real price of men’s basketball games in the equation? Explain. What sign does economic theory predict for its coefficient? Can you think of another variable related to men’s basketball that might belong in the women’s attendance equation? (v) If you are worried that some of the series, particularly lATTEND and lPRICE, have unit roots, how might you change the estimated equation? (vi) If some games are sold out, what problems does this cause for estimating the de- mand function? (Hint: If a game is sold out, do you necessarily observe the true demand?) 8 How big is the effect of per-student school expenditures on local housing values? Let HPRICE be the median housing price in a school district and let EXPEND be per-student Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. WINPERCt 􏱪 the team’s current winning percentage. RIVALt 􏱪 a dummy variable indicating a game against a rival. WEEKENDt 􏱪 a dummy variable indicating whether the game is on a weekend. 578 PART 3 Advanced Topics expenditures. Using panel data for the years 1992, 1994, and 1996, we postulate the model lHPRICEit 􏱪 􏰩t 􏱕 􏱬1lEXPENDit 􏱕 􏱬2lPOLICEit 􏱕 􏱬3lMEDINCit 􏱕 􏱬4PROPTAXit 􏱕 ai1 􏱕 uit1, where POLICEit is per capita police expenditures, MEDINCit is median income, and PROPTAXit is the property tax rate; l denotes natural logarithm. Expenditures and housing price are simultaneously determined because the value of homes directly affects the rev- enues available for funding schools. Suppose that, in 1994, the way schools were funded was drastically changed: rather than being raised by local property taxes, school funding was largely determined at the state level. Let lSTATEALLit denote the log of the state allocation for district i in year t, which is exogenous in the preceding equation, once we control for expenditures and a dis- trict fixed effect. How would you estimate the 􏱬j? Computer Exercises C1 Use SMOKE.RAW for this exercise. (i) A model to estimate the effects of smoking on annual income (perhaps through lost work days due to illness, or productivity effects) is log(income) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1cigs 􏱕 􏱬2educ 􏱕 􏱬3age 􏱕 􏱬4age2 􏱕 u1, where cigs is number of cigarettes smoked per day, on average. How do you interpret 􏱬1? (ii) To reflect the fact that cigarette consumption might be jointly determined with income, a demand for cigarettes equation is cigs 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1log(income) 􏱕 􏰸2educ 􏱕 􏰸3age 􏱕 􏰸4age2 􏱕 􏰸5log(cigpric) 􏱕 􏰸6restaurn 􏱕 u2, where cigpric is the price of a pack of cigarettes (in cents), and restaurn is a binary variable equal to unity if the person lives in a state with restaurant smoking restrictions. Assuming these are exogenous to the individual, what signs would you expect for 􏰸5 and 􏰸6? (iii) Under what assumption is the income equation from part (i) identified? (iv) Estimate the income equation by OLS and discuss the estimate of 􏱬1. (v) Estimate the reduced form for cigs. (Recall that this entails regressing cigs on all exogenous variables.) Are log(cigpric) and restaurn significant in the reduced form? (vi) Now, estimate the income equation by 2SLS. Discuss how the estimate of 􏱬1 compares with the OLS estimate. (vii) Do you think that cigarette prices and restaurant smoking restrictions are exogenous in the income equation? C2 Use MROZ.RAW for this exercise. (i) Reestimate the labor supply function in Example 16.5, using log(hours) as the dependent variable. Compare the estimated elasticity (which is now constant) to the estimate obtained from equation (16.24) at the average hours worked. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 579 (ii) In the labor supply equation from part (i), allow educ to be endogenous because of omitted ability. Use motheduc and fatheduc as IVs for educ. Remember, you now have two endogenous variables in the equation. (iii) Test the overidentifying restrictions in the 2SLS estimation from part (ii). Do the IVs pass the test? C3 Use the data in OPENNESS.RAW for this exercise. (i) Because log(pcinc) is insignificant in both (16.22) and the reduced form for open, drop it from the analysis. Estimate (16.22) by OLS and IV without log(pcinc). Do any important conclusions change? (ii) Still leaving log( pcinc) out of the analysis, is land or log(land ) a better instrument for open? (Hint: Regress open on each of these separately and jointly.) (iii) Now, return to (16.22). Add the dummy variable oil to the equation and treat it as exogenous. Estimate the equation by IV. Does being an oil producer have a ceteris paribus effect on inflation? C4 Use the data in CONSUMP.RAW for this exercise. (i) In Example 16.7, use the method from Section 15.5 to test the single overidentifying restriction in estimating (16.35). What do you conclude? (ii) Campbell and Mankiw (1990) use second lags of all variables as IVs because of poten- tial data measurement problems and informational lags. Reestimate (16.35), using only gct􏱦2, gyt􏱦2, and r3t􏱦2 as IVs. How do the estimates compare with those in (16.36)? (iii) Regress gyt on the IVs from part (ii) and test whether gyt is sufficiently correlated with them. Why is this important? C5 Use the Economic Report of the President (2005 or later) to update the data in CONSUMP.RAW, at least through 2003. Reestimate equation (16.35). Do any important conclusions change? C6 Use the data in CEMENT.RAW for this exercise. (i) A static (inverse) supply function for the monthly growth in cement price (gprc) as a function of growth in quantity (gcem) is gprct 􏱪 􏱮1gcemt 􏱕 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1gprcpet 􏱕 􏱬2 febt 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬12dect 􏱕 uts, where gprcpet (growth in the price of petroleum) is assumed to be exogenous and feb, ..., dec are monthly dummy variables. What signs do you expect for 􏱮1 and 􏱬1? Estimate the equation by OLS. Does the supply function slope upward? (ii) The variable gdefs is the monthly growth in real defense spending in the United States. What do you need to assume about gdefs for it to be a good IV for gcem? Test whether gcem is partially correlated with gdefs. (Do not worry about possible serial correlation in the reduced form.) Can you use gdefs as an IV in estimating the supply function? (iii) Shea (1993) argues that the growth in output of residential (gres) and nonresiden- tial (gnon) construction are valid instruments for gcem. The idea is that these are demand shifters that should be roughly uncorrelated with the supply error uts. Test whether gcem is partially correlated with gres and gnon; again, do not worry about serial correlation in the reduced form. (iv) Estimate the supply function, using gres and gnon as IVs for gcem. What do you conclude about the static supply function for cement? [The dynamic supply func- tion is, apparently, upward sloping; see Shea (1993).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 580 PART 3 Advanced Topics C7 Refer to Example 13.9 and the data in CRIME4.RAW. (i) Suppose that, after differencing to remove the unobserved effect, you think 􏰧log(polpc) is simultaneously determined with 􏰧log(crmrte); in particular, increases in crime are associated with increases in police officers. How does this help to explain the positive coefficient on 􏰧log(polpc) in equation (13.33)? (ii) The variable taxpc is the taxes collected per person in the county. Does it seem reasonable to exclude this from the crime equation? (iii) Estimatethereducedformfor􏰧log(polpc)usingpooledOLS,includingthepotential IV, 􏰧log(taxpc). Does it look like 􏰧log(taxpc) is a good IV candidate? Explain. (iv) Suppose that, in several of the years, the state of North Carolina awarded grants to some counties to increase the size of their county police force. How could you use this information to estimate the effect of additional police officers on the crime rate? C8 Use the data set in FISH.RAW, which comes from Graddy (1995), to do this exercise. The data set is also used in Computer Exercise C9 in Chapter 12. Now, we will use it to estimate a demand function for fish. (i) Assume that the demand equation can be written, in equilibrium for each time period, as log(totqtyt) 􏱪 􏱮1log(avgprct) 􏱕 􏱬10 􏱕 􏱬11mont 􏱕 􏱬12tuest 􏱕 􏱬13wedt 􏱕 􏱬14thurst 􏱕 ut1, so that demand is allowed to differ across days of the week. Treating the price variable as endogenous, what additional information do we need to estimate the demand-equation parameters consistently? (ii) The variables wave2t and wave3t are measures of ocean wave heights over the past several days. What two assumptions do we need to make in order to use wave2t and wave3t as IVs for log(avgprct) in estimating the demand equation? (iii) Regress log(avgprct) on the day-of-the-week dummies and the two wave measures. Are wave2t and wave3t jointly significant? What is the p-value of the test? (iv) Now, estimate the demand equation by 2SLS. What is the 95% confidence interval for the price elasticity of demand? Is the estimated elasticity reasonable? (v) Obtain the 2SLS residuals, uˆt1. Add a single lag, uˆt􏱦1,1 in estimating the demand equation by 2SLS. Remember, use uˆt􏱦1,1 as its own instrument. Is there evidence of AR(1) serial correlation in the demand equation errors? (vi) Given that the supply equation evidently depends on the wave variables, what two assumptions would we need to make in order to estimate the price elasticity of supply? (vii) In the reduced form equation for log(avgprct), are the day-of-the-week dummies jointly significant? What do you conclude about being able to estimate the supply elasticity? C9 For this exercise, use the data in AIRFARE.RAW, but only for the year 1997. (i) A simple demand function for airline seats on routes in the United States is log(passen) 􏱪 􏱬10 􏱕 􏱮1log(fare) 􏱕 􏱬11log(dist) 􏱕 􏱬12[log(dist)]2 􏱕 u1, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. (ii) (iii) (iv) (v) (vi) C10 Use in a If this is truly a demand function, what should be the sign of 􏱮1? Estimate the equation from part (i) by OLS. What is the estimated price elasticity? Consider the variable concen, which is a measure of market concentration. (Specifically, it is the share of business accounted for by the largest carrier.) Explain in words what we must assume to treat concen as exogenous in the demand equation. Now assume concen is exogenous to the demand equation. Estimate the reduced form for log(fare) and confirm that concen has a positive (partial) effect on log(fare). Estimate the demand function using IV. Now what is the estimated price elasticity of demand? How does it compare with the OLS estimate? Using the IV estimates, describe how demand for seats depends on route distance. the entire panel data set in AIRFARE.RAW for this exercise. The demand equation simultaneous equations unobserved effects model is log(passenit) 􏱪 􏰩t1 􏱕 􏱮1log(fareit) 􏱕 ai1 􏱕 uit1, where CHAPTER 16 Simultaneous Equations Models 581 passen 􏱪 average passengers per day. fare 􏱪 average airfare. dist 􏱪 the route distance (in miles). where we absorb the distance variables into ai1. (i) Estimate the demand function using fixed effects, being sure to include year dummies to account for the different intercepts. What is the estimated elasticity? (ii) Use fixed effects to estimate the reduced form log(fareit) 􏱪 􏰩t2 􏱕 􏰵21concenit 􏱕 ai2 􏱕 vit2. Perform the appropriate test to ensure that concenit can be used as an IV for log( fareit). (iii) Now estimate the demand function using the fixed effects transformation along with IV, as in equation (16.42). What is the estimated elasticity? Is it statistically significant? C11 A common method for estimating Engel curves is to model expenditure shares as a func- tion of total expenditure, and possibly demographic variables. A common specification has the form sgood 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1ltotexpend 􏱕 demographics 􏱕 u, where sgood is the fraction of spending on a particular good out of total expenditure and ltotexpend is the log of total expenditure. The sign and magnitude of 􏱬1 are of interest across various expenditure categories. To account for the potential endogeneity of ltotexpend—which can be viewed as an omitted variables or simultaneous equations problem, or both—the log of family in- come is often used as an instrumental variable. Let lincome denote the log of family Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 582 PART 3 Advanced Topics income. For the remainder of this question, use the data in EXPENDSHARE.RAW, which comes from Blundell, Duncan, and Pendakur (1998). (i) Use sfood, the share of spending on food, as the dependent variable. What is the range of values of sfood? Are you surprised there are no zeros? (ii) Estimate the equation sfood 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1ltotexpend 􏱕 􏱬2age 􏱕 􏱬3kids 􏱕 u [16.43] by OLS, and report the coefficient on ltotexpend, 􏱬ˆOLS,1, along with its heteroske- dasticity-robust standard error. Intepret the result. (iii) Using lincome as an IV for ltotexpend, estimate the reduced form equation for ltotexpend; be sure to include age and kids. Assuming lincome is exogenous in (16.43), is lincome a valid IV for ltotexpend? ˆ (iv) Now estimate (16.43) by instrumental variables. How does 􏱬IV,1 compare with 􏱬ˆOLS,1? What about the robust 95% confidence intervals? (v) Use the test in Section 15.5 to test the null hypothesis that ltotexpend is exogenous in (16.43). Be sure to report and interpret the p-value. Are there any overidentifying restrictions to test? (vi) Substitute salcohol for sfood in (16.43) and estimate the equation by OLS and 2SLS. Now what do you find for the coefficients on ltotexpend? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 17 583 In Chapter 7, we studied the linear probability model, which is simply an application of the multiple regression model to a binary dependent variable. A binary dependent variable is an example of a limited dependent variable (LDV). An LDV is broadly defined as a dependent variable whose range of values is substantively restricted. A binary variable takes on only two values, zero and one. In Section 7.7 we discussed the interpre- tation of multiple regression estimates for generally discrete response variables, focusing on the case where y takes on a small number of integer values—for example, the number of times a young man is arrested during a year or the number of children born to a woman. Elsewhere, we have encountered several other limited dependent variables, including the percentage of people participating in a pension plan (which must be between zero and 100) and college grade point average (which is between zero and 4.0 at most colleges). Most economic variables we would like to explain are limited in some way, often because they must be positive. For example, hourly wage, housing price, and nominal interest rates must be greater than zero. But not all such variables need special treatment. If a strictly positive variable takes on many different values, a special econometric model is rarely necessary. When y is discrete and takes on a small number of values, it makes no sense to treat it as an approximately continuous variable. Discreteness of y does not in itself mean that linear models are inappropriate. However, as we saw in Chapter 7 for binary response, the linear probability model has certain drawbacks. In Section 17.1, we discuss logit and probit models, which overcome the shortcomings of the LPM; the disad- vantage is that they are more difficult to interpret. Other kinds of limited dependent variables arise in econometric analysis, especially when the behavior of individuals, families, or firms is being modeled. Optimizing behavior often leads to a corner solution response for some nontrivial fraction of the population. That is, it is optimal to choose a zero quantity or dollar value, for example. During any given year, a significant number of families will make zero charitable contributions. There- fore, annual family charitable contributions has a population distribution that is spread out Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 584 PART 3 Advanced Topics over a large range of positive values, but with a pileup at the value zero. Although a linear model could be appropriate for capturing the expected value of charitable contributions, a linear model will likely lead to negative predictions for some families. Taking the natural log is not possible because many observations are zero. The Tobit model, which we cover in Section 17.2, is explicitly designed to model corner solution dependent variables. Another important kind of LDV is a count variable, which takes on nonnegative in- teger values. Section 17.3 illustrates how Poisson regression models are well suited for modeling count variables. In some cases, we encounter limited dependent variables due to data censoring, a topic we introduce in Section 17.4. The general problem of sample selection, where we observe a nonrandom sample from the underlying population, is treated in Section 17.5. Limited dependent variable models can be used for time series and panel data, but they are most often applied to cross-sectional data. Sample selection problems are usually confined to cross-sectional or panel data. We focus on cross-sectional applications in this chapter. Wooldridge (2010) analyzes these problems in the context of panel data models and provides many more details for cross-sectional and panel data applications. 17.1 Logit and Probit Models for Binary Response The linear probability model is simple to estimate and use, but it has some drawbacks that we discussed in Section 7.5. The two most important disadvantages are that the fitted probabilities can be less than zero or greater than one and the partial effect of any explana- tory variable (appearing in level form) is constant. These limitations of the LPM can be overcome by using more sophisticated binary response models. In a binary response model, interest lies primarily in the response probability P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱪 P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk), [17.1] where we use x to denote the full set of explanatory variables. For example, when y is an employment indicator, x might contain various individual characteristics such as education, age, marital status, and other factors that affect employment status, including a binary indicator variable for participation in a recent job training program. Specifying Logit and Probit Models In the LPM, we assume that the response probability is linear in a set of parameters, 􏱬j; see equation (7.27). To avoid the LPM limitations, consider a class of binary response models of the form P(y􏱪1􏰫x)􏱪G(􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk)􏱪G(􏱬0 􏱕x􏱬), [17.2] where G is a function taking on values strictly between zero and one: 0 􏱷 G(z) 􏱷 1, for all real numbers z. This ensures that the estimated response probabilities are strictly between zero and one. As in earlier chapters, we write x􏱬 􏱪 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 585 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections Various nonlinear functions have been suggested for the function G to make sure that the probabilities are between zero and one. The two we will cover here are used in the vast majority of applications (along with the LPM). In the logit model, G is the logistic function: G(z) 􏱪 exp(z)/[1 􏱕 exp(z)] 􏱪 􏱎(z), [17.3] which is between zero and one for all real numbers z. This is the cumulative distribution function for a standard logistic random variable. In the probit model, G is the standard normal cumulative distribution function (cdf), which is expressed as an integral: 􏱛z where 􏰿(z) is the standard normal density 􏱦􏱵 G(z) 􏱪 􏱋(z) 􏱲 􏰿(z) 􏱪 (2􏰵)􏱦1/2exp(􏱦z2/2). [17.5] This choice of G again ensures that (17.2) is strictly between zero and one for all values of the parameters and the xj. The G functions in (17.3) and (17.4) are both increasing functions. Each increases most quickly at z 􏱪 0, G(z) 􏱽 0 as z 􏱽 􏱦􏱵, and G(z) 􏱽 1 as z 􏱽 􏱵. The logistic function is plotted in Figure 17.1. The standard normal cdf has a shape very similar to that of the logistic cdf. Logit and probit models can be derived from an underlying latent variable model. Let y* be an unobserved, or latent, variable, and suppose that y*􏱪􏱬0 􏱕x􏱬􏱕e, y􏱪1[y*􏱰0], [17.6] where we introduce the notation 1[􏱳] to define a binary outcome. The function 1[􏱳] is called the indicator function, which takes on the value one if the event in brackets is true, and zero otherwise. Therefore, y is one if y* 􏱰 0, and y is zero if y* 􏰯 0. We assume that 􏰿(v)dv, [17.4] F I G U R E 1 7 . 1 Graph of the logistic function G(z) 􏱪 exp(z)/[1 􏱕 exp(z)]. G(z) 5 exp(z)/[1 1 exp(z)] 1 .5 0 23 22 21 0 1 2 3 z Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 586 PART 3 Advanced Topics e is independent of x and that e either has the standard logistic distribution or the standard normal distribution. In either case, e is symmetrically distributed about zero, which means that 1 􏱦 G(􏱦z) 􏱪 G(z) for all real numbers z. Economists tend to favor the normality as- sumption for e, which is why the probit model is more popular than logit in econometrics. In addition, several specification problems, which we touch on later, are most easily ana- lyzed using probit because of properties of the normal distribution. From (17.6) and the assumptions given, we can derive the response probability for y: P(y􏱪1􏰫x)􏱪P(y*􏱰0􏰫x)􏱪P[e􏱰􏱦(􏱬0 􏱕x􏱬)􏰫x] 􏱪1􏱦G[􏱦(􏱬0 􏱕x􏱬)]􏱪G(􏱬0 􏱕x􏱬), which is exactly the same as (17.2). In most applications of binary response models, the primary goal is to explain the effects of the xj on the response probability P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x). The latent variable formulation tends to give the impression that we are primarily interested in the effects of each xj on y*. As we will see, for logit and probit, the direction of the effect of xj on E(y*􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬 and on E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱪 G(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬) is always the same. But the latent variable y* rarely has a well-defined unit of measurement. (For example, y* might be the difference in utility levels from two different actions.) Thus, the magnitudes of each 􏱬j are not, by themselves, especially useful (in contrast to the linear probability model). For most pur- poses, we want to estimate the effect of xj on the probability of success P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x), but this is complicated by the nonlinear nature of G(􏱳). To find the partial effect of roughly continuous variables on the response probability, we must rely on calculus. If xj is a roughly continuous variable, its partial effect on p(x) 􏱪 P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) is obtained from the partial derivative: ∂p(x) _____ 􏱪 g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)􏱬j, where g(z) 􏱲 _d_G_(z). [17.7] ∂xj dz Because G is the cdf of a continuous random variable, g is a probability density function. In the logit and probit cases, G(􏱳) is a strictly increasing cdf, and so g(z) 􏱰 0 for all z. Therefore, the partial effect of xj on p(x) depends on x through the positive quantity g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬), which means that the partial effect always has the same sign as 􏱬j. Equation (17.7) shows that the relative effects of any two continuous explanatory vari- ables do not depend on x: the ratio of the partial effects for xj and xh is 􏱬j /􏱬h. In the typi- cal case that g is a symmetric density about zero, with a unique mode at zero, the largest effectoccurswhen􏱬 􏱕x􏱬􏱪0.Forexample,intheprobitcasewithg(z)􏱪􏰿(z),g(0)􏱪 􏱻___ 0 2 􏰿(0) 􏱪 1/ 2􏰵 􏱴 .40. In the logit case, g(z) 􏱪 exp(z)/[1 􏱕 exp(z)] , and so g(0) 􏱪 .25. If, say, x1 is a binary explanatory variable, then the partial effect from changing x1 from zero to one, holding all other variables fixed, is simply G(􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk)􏱦G(􏱬0􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk). [17.8] Again, this depends on all the values of the other xj. For example, if y is an employment indicator and x1 is a dummy variable indicating participation in a job training program, then (17.8) is the change in the probability of employment due to the job training pro- gram; this depends on other characteristics that affect employability, such as education and experience. Note that knowing the sign of 􏱬1 is sufficient for determining whether the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 587 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections program had a positive or negative effect. But to find the magnitude of the effect, we have to estimate the quantity in (17.8). We can also use the difference in (17.8) for other kinds of discrete variables (such as number of children). If xk denotes this variable, then the effect on the probability of xk go- ing from ck to ck 􏱕 1 is simply G[􏱬0􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬k(ck 􏱕1)] 􏱦G(􏱬0􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kck). [17.9] It is straightforward to include standard functional forms among the explanatory vari- ables. For example, in the model P(y 􏱪 1􏰫z) 􏱪 G(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1z1 􏱕 􏱬2z21 􏱕 􏱬3log(z2) 􏱕 􏱬4z3), the partial effect of z1 on P(y 􏱪 1􏰫z) is ∂P(y 􏱪 1􏰫z)/∂z1 􏱪 g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)(􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2z1), and the partial effect of z2 on the response probability is ∂P(y 􏱪 1􏰫z)/∂z2 􏱪 g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)(􏱬3/z2), where x􏱬 􏱪 􏱬1z1 􏱕 􏱬2z21 􏱕 􏱬3log(z2) 􏱕 􏱬4z3. Therefore, g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)(􏱬3/100) is the ap- proximate change in the response probability when z2 increases by 1%. Sometimes we want to compute the elasticity of the response probability with re- spect to an explanatory variable, although we must be careful in interpreting percentage changes in probabilities. For example, a change in a probability from .04 to .06 represents a 2-percentage-point increase in the probability, but a 50% increase relative to the initial value. Using calculus, in the preceding model the elasticity of P(y 􏱪 1􏰫z) with respect to z2 can be shown to be 􏱬3[g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)/G(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)]. The elasticity with respect to z3 is (􏱬4z3) [g(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)/G(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬)]. In the first case, the elasticity is always the same sign as 􏱬2, but it generally depends on all parameters and all values of the explanatory variables. If z3 􏱰 0, the second elasticity always has the same sign as the parameter 􏱬4. Models with interactions among the explanatory variables can be a bit tricky, but one should compute the partial derivatives and then evaluate the resulting partial effects at interesting values. When measuring the effects of discrete variables—no matter how complicated the model—we should use (17.9). We discuss this further in the subsection on interpreting the estimates on page 589. Maximum Likelihood Estimation of Logit and Probit Models How should we estimate nonlinear binary response models? To estimate the LPM, we can use ordinary least squares (see Section 7.5) or, in some cases, weighted least squares (see Section 8.5). Because of the nonlinear nature of E(y􏰫x), OLS and WLS are not appli- cable. We could use nonlinear versions of these methods, but it is no more difficult to use maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) (see Appendix 17A for a brief discussion). Up until now, we have had little need for MLE, although we did note that, under the classical linear model assumptions, the OLS estimator is the maximum likelihood estimator (con- ditional on the explanatory variables). For estimating limited dependent variable models, maximum likelihood methods are indispensable. Because maximum likelihood estimation is based on the distribution of y given x, the heteroskedasticity in Var(y􏰫x) is automatically accounted for. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 588 PART 3 Advanced Topics Assume that we have a random sample of size n. To obtain the maximum likelihood estimator, conditional on the explanatory variables, we need the density of yi given xi. We can write this as f(y􏰫xi;􏱬) 􏱪 [G(xi􏱬)]y[1 􏱦 G(xi􏱬)]1􏱦y, y 􏱪 0, 1, [17.10] where, for simplicity, we absorb the intercept into the vector xi. We can easily see that when y 􏱪 1, we get G(xi􏱬) and when y 􏱪 0, we get 1 􏱦 G(xi􏱬). The log-likelihood function for observation i is a function of the parameters and the data (xi, yi) and is obtained by taking the log of (17.10): 􏱷i(􏱬) 􏱪 yi log[G(xi 􏱬)] 􏱕 (1 􏱦 yi)log[1 􏱦 G(xi 􏱬)]. [17.11] Because G(􏱳) is strictly between zero and one for logit and probit, 􏱷i(􏱬) is well defined for all values of 􏱬. The log-likelihood for∑a sample size of n is obtained by summing (17.11) across all observations: 􏱺( 􏱬) 􏱪 n 􏱷 (􏱬). The MLE of 􏱬, denoted by 􏱬ˆ , maximizes this i i􏱪1 ˆ log-likelihood. If G(􏱳) is the standard logit cdf, then 􏱬 is the logit estimator; if G(􏱳) is the standard normal cdf, then 􏱬ˆ is the probit estimator. Because of the nonlinear nature of the maximization problem, we cannot write formu- las for the logit or probit maximum likelihood estimates. In addition to raising computa- tional issues, this makes the statistical theory for logit and probit much more difficult than OLS or even 2SLS. Nevertheless, the general theory of MLE for random samples implies that, under very general conditions, the MLE is consistent, asymptotically normal, and as- ymptotically efficient. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 13) for a general discussion.] We will just use the results here; applying logit and probit models is fairly easy, provided we understand what the statistics mean. Each 􏱬ˆj comes with an (asymptotic) standard error, the formula for which is compli- cated and presented in the chapter appendix. Once we have the standard errors—and these are reported along with the coefficient estimates by any package that supports logit and probit—we can construct (asymptotic) t tests and confidence intervals, just as with OLS, 2SLS, and the other estimators we have encountered. In particular, to test H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0, we form the t statistic 􏱬ˆj/se(􏱬ˆj) and carry out the test in the usual way, once we have decided on a one- or two-sided alternative. Testing Multiple Hypotheses We can also test multiple restrictions in logit and probit models. In most cases, these are tests of multiple exclusion restrictions, as in Section 4.5. We will focus on exclusion restrictions here. There are three ways to test exclusion restrictions for logit and probit models. The Lagrange multiplier or score test only requires estimating the model under the null hypothesis, just as in the linear case in Section 5.2; we will not cover the score test here, since it is rarely needed to test exclusion restrictions. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 15) for other uses of the score test in binary response models.] The Wald test requires estimation of only the unrestricted model. In the linear model case, the Wald statistic, after a simple transformation, is essentially the F statistic, so there is no need to cover the Wald statistic separately. The formula for the Wald statistic is given in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 15). This statistic is computed by econometrics packages that allow exclusion restrictions to be tested after the unrestricted model has Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 589 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections been estimated. It has an asymptotic chi-square distribution, with df equal to the number of restrictions being tested. If both the restricted and unrestricted models are easy to estimate—as is usually the case with exclusion restrictions—then the likelihood ratio (LR) test becomes very attrac- tive. The LR test is based on the same concept as the F test in a linear model. The F test measures the increase in the sum of squared residuals when variables are dropped from the model. The LR test is based on the difference in the log-likelihood functions for the unrestricted and restricted models. The idea is this: Because the MLE maximizes the log-likelihood function, dropping variables generally leads to a smaller—or at least no larger—log-likelihood. (This is similar to the fact that the R-squared never increases when variables are dropped from a regression.) The question is whether the fall in the log-like- lihood is large enough to conclude that the dropped variables are important. We can make this decision once we have a test statistic and a set of critical values. The likelihood ratio statistic is twice the difference in the log-likelihoods: LR 􏱪 2(􏱺ur 􏱦 􏱺r), [17.12] where 􏱺ur is the log-likelihood value for the unrestricted model and 􏱺r is the log-likelihood value for the restricted model. Because 􏱺ur 􏱸 􏱺r, LR is nonnegative and usually strictly positive. In computing the LR statistic for binary response models, it is important to know that the log-likelihood function is always a negative number. This fact follows from equation (17.11), because yi is either zero or one and both variables in- side the log function are strictly between zero and one, which means their natural logs are negative. That the log-likelihood functions are both negative does not change the way we compute the LR sta- tistic; we simply preserve the negative signs in equation (17.12). The multiplication by two in (17.12) is needed so that LR has an approximate chi-square distribution under H0. If we are testing q exclusion restrictions, LR 􏱷a 􏱚q2. This means that, to test H0 at the 5% level, we use as our critical value the 95th percentile in the 􏱚q2 distribution. Comput- ing p-values is easy with most software packages. Interpreting the Logit and Probit Estimates Given modern computers, from a practical perspective the most difficult aspect of logit or probit models is presenting and interpreting the results. The coefficient esti- mates, their standard errors, and the value of the log-likelihood function are reported by all software packages that do logit and probit, and these should be reported in any Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 17.1 A probit model to explain whether a firm is taken over by another firm during a given year is P(takeover 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱋(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1avgprof 􏱕 􏱬2mktval 􏱕 􏱬3debtearn 􏱕 􏱬4ceoten 􏱕 􏱬5ceosal 􏱕 􏱬6ceoage), where takeover is a binary response vari- able, avgprof is the firm’s average profit margin over several prior years, mktval is market value of the firm, debtearn is the debt-to-earnings ratio, and ceoten, ceo- sal, and ceoage are the tenure, annual sal- ary, and age of the chief executive officer, respectively. State the null hypothesis that, other factors being equal, variables related to the CEO have no effect on the probabil- ity of takeover. How many df are in the chi- square distribution for the LR or Wald test? 590 PART 3 Advanced Topics application. The coefficients give the signs of the partial effects of each xj on the re- sponse probability, and the statistical significance of xj is determined by whether we can reject H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0 at a sufficiently small significance level. As we briefly discussed in Section 7.5 for the linear probability model, we can com- pute a goodness-of-fit measure called the percent correctly predicted. As before, we define a binary predictor of yi to be one if the predicted probability is at least .5, and zero otherwise. Mathematically, y ̃i 􏱪 1 if G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) 􏱸 .5 and y ̃i 􏱪 0 if G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) 􏱷 .5. Given {y ̃i : i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}, we can see how well y ̃i predicts yi across all observations. There are four possible outcomes on each pair, (yi, y ̃i); when both are zero or both are one, we make the correct prediction. In the two cases where one of the pair is zero and the other is one, we make the incorrect prediction. The percentage correctly predicted is the percent- age of times that y ̃i 􏱪 yi. Although the percentage correctly predicted is useful as a goodness-of-fit measure, it can be misleading. In particular, it is possible to get rather high percentages correctly predicted even when the least likely outcome is very poorly predicted. For example, sup- pose that n 􏱪 200, 160 observations have yi 􏱪 0, and, out of these 160 observations, 140 of the y ̃i are also zero (so we correctly predict 87.5% of the zero outcomes). Even if none of the predictions is correct when yi 􏱪 1, we still correctly predict 70% of all outcomes (140/200 􏱪 .70). Often, we hope to have some ability to predict the least likely outcome (such as whether someone is arrested for committing a crime), and so we should be up front about how well we do in predicting each outcome. Therefore, it makes sense to also compute the percentage correctly predicted for each of the outcomes. Problem 1 asks you to show that the overall percentage correctly predicted is a weighted average of ˆq0 (the percentage correctly predicted for yi 􏱪 0) and ˆq1 (the percentage correctly predicted for yi 􏱪 1), where the weights are the fractions of zeros and ones in the sample, respectively. Some have criticized the prediction rule just described for using a threshold value of .5, especially when one of the outcomes is unlikely. For example, if y- 􏱪.08 (only 8% “suc- cesses” in the sample), it could be that we never predict yi 􏱪 1 because the estimated prob- ability of success is never greater than .5. One alternative is to use the fraction of successes in the sample as the threshold—.08 in the previous example. In other words, define y ̃i 􏱪 1 when G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) 􏱸 .08 and zero otherwise. Using this rule will certainly increase the number of predicted successes, but not without cost: we will necessarily make more mistakes—perhaps many more—in predicting zeros (“failures”). In terms of the overall percentage correctly predicted, we may do worse than using the .5 threshold. A third possibility is to choose the threshold such that the fraction of ̃yi 􏱪 1 in the sample is the same as (or very close to) -y. In other words, search over thresh- 􏰭oldvalues􏰫􏰭,0􏱷􏰫􏱷1,suchthatifwedefine ̃yi 􏱪1whenG(ˆ􏱬0 􏱕xiˆ􏱬)􏱸􏰫,then n ̃y 􏱴 n y . (The trial-and-error required to find the desired value of 􏰫 can i􏱪1 i be tedious but it is feasible. In some cases, it will not be possible to make the num- i􏱪1 i ber of predicted successes exactly the same as the number of successes in the sam- ple.) Now, given this set of ̃yi, we can compute the percentage correctly predicted for each of the two outcomes as well as the overall percentage correctly predicted. There are also various pseudo R-squared measures for binary response. McFadden (1974) suggests the measure 1 􏱦 􏱺ur /􏱺o, where 􏱺ur is the log-likelihood function for the estimated model, and 􏱺o is the log-likelihood function in the model with only an intercept. Why does this measure make sense? Recall that the log-likelihoods are negative, and so 􏱺ur / 􏱺o 􏱪 􏰫􏱺ur􏰫/􏰫􏱺o􏰫. Further, 􏰫􏱺ur􏰫 􏰯 􏰫􏱺o􏰫. If the covariates have no explanatory power, then 􏱺ur /􏱺o 􏱪 1, and the pseudo R-squared is zero, just as the usual R-squared is zero in a linear Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 591 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections regression when the covariates have no explanatory power. Usually, 􏰫􏱺ur􏰫 􏱷 􏰫􏱺o􏰫, in which case 1 􏱦 􏱺ur /􏱺o 􏱰 0. If 􏱺ur were zero, the pseudo R-squared would equal unity. In fact, 􏱺ur cannot reach zero in a probit or logit model, as that would require the estimated probabili- ties when yi 􏱪 1 all to be unity and the estimated probabilities when yi 􏱪 0 all to be zero. Alternative pseudo R-squareds for probit and logit are more directly related to the usual R-squared from OLS estimation of a linear probability model. For either probit or logit, let yˆi 􏱪 G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) be the fitted probabilities. Since these probabilities are also estimates of E( yi􏰫xi), we can base an R-squared on how close the yˆi are to the yi. One pos- sibility that suggests itself from standard regression analysis is to compute the squared correlation between yi and yˆi. Remember, in a linear regression framework, this is an al- gebraically equivalent way to obtain the usual R-squared; see equation (3.29). Therefore, we can compute a pseudo R-squared for probit and logit that is directly comparable to the usual R-squared from estimation of a linear probability model. In any case, goodness- of-fit is usually less important than trying to obtain convincing estimates of the ceteris paribus effects of the explanatory variables. Often, we want to estimate the effects of the xj on the response probabilities, P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x). If xj is (roughly) continuous, then 􏰧Pˆ(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱴 [g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x􏱬ˆ)􏱬ˆj]􏰧xj, [17.13] for “small” changes in xj. So, for 􏰧xj 􏱪 1, the change in the estimated success probability is roughly g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x􏱬ˆ)􏱬ˆj. Compared with the linear probability model, the cost of using probit and logit models is that the partial effects in equation (17.13) are harder to summa- rize because the scale factor, g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x􏱬ˆ), depends on x (that is, on all of the explanatory variables). One possibility is to plug in interesting values for the xj—such as means, medi- ans, minimums, maximums, and lower and upper quartiles—and then see how g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x􏱬ˆ) changes. Although attractive, this can be tedious and result in too much information even if the number of explanatory variables is moderate. As a quick summary for getting at the magnitudes of the partial effects, it is handy to have a single scale factor that can be used to multiply each 􏱬ˆj (or at least those coefficients on roughly continuous variables). One method, commonly used in econometrics packages that routinely estimate probit and logit models, is to replace each explanatory variable with its sample average. In other words, the adjustment factor is g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 x- 􏱬ˆ) 􏱪 g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x-1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x-2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆk x-k), [17.14] where g(􏱳) is the standard normal density in the probit case and g(z) 􏱪 exp(z)/[1 􏱕 exp(z)]2 in the logit case. The idea behind (17.14) is that, when it is multiplied by 􏱬ˆj, we obtain the partial effect of xj for the “average” person in the sample. Thus, if we multiply a coeffi- cient by (17.14), we generally obtain the partial effect at the average (PEA). There are at least two potential problems with using PEAs to summarize the partial effects of the explanatory variables. First, if some of the explanatory variables are discrete, the averages of them represent no one in the sample (or population, for that matter). For example, if x1 􏱪 female and 47.5% of the sample is female, what sense does it make to plug in x-1 􏱪 .475 to represent the “average” person? Second, if a continuous explanatory variable appears as a nonlinear function—say, as a natural log or in a quadratic—it is not clear whether we want to average the nonlinear function or plug the average into the non- linear function. For example, should we use log(sales) or log(sales) to represent average Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 592 PART 3 Advanced Topics firm size? Econometrics packages that compute the scale factor in (17.14) default to the former: the software is written to compute the averages of the regressors included in the probit or logit estimation. A different approach to computing a scale factor circumvents the issue of which values to plug in for the explanatory variables. Instead, the second scale fac- tor results from averaging the individual partial effects across the sample, leading to what is called the average partial effect (APE) or, sometimes, the average marginal effect (AME). For a continuous explanatory variable xj, the average partial effect is n􏱦1􏰭n [g(􏱬ˆ 􏱕 x 􏱬ˆ)􏱬ˆ ] 􏱪 􏱋n􏱦1 i􏱪1 0 i j n g(􏱬ˆ 􏱕 x 􏱬ˆ)􏱔􏱬ˆ . The term multiplying 􏱬ˆ acts as a scale factor: i􏱪1 0 i j j 􏰭 􏱦1∑n ˆ ˆ n g(􏱬0 􏱕 xi􏱬). [17.15] i􏱪1 Equation (17.15) is easily computed after probit or logit estimation, where g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) 􏱪 􏰿(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) in the probit case and g(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ) 􏱪 exp(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ)/[1 􏱕 exp(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ)]2 in the logit case. The two scale factors differ—and are possibly quite different—because in (17.15) we are using the average of the nonlinear function rather than the nonlinear func- tion of the average [as in (17.14)]. Because both of the scale factors just described depend on the calculus approximation in (17.13), neither makes much sense for discrete explanatory variables. Instead, it is better to use equation (17.9) to directly estimate the change in the probability. For a change in xk from ck to ck 􏱕 1, the discrete analog of the partial effect based on (17.14) is G[􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x-1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆk􏱶1x-k􏱶1 􏱕 􏱬ˆk(ck 􏱕 1)] 􏱦 G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x-1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆk􏱶1x-k􏱶1 􏱕 􏱬ˆkck), [17.16] where G is the standard normal cdf in the probit case and G(z) 􏱪 exp(z)/[1 􏱕 exp(z)] in the logit case. The average partial effect, which usually is more comparable to LPM esti- mates, is 􏱦1∑n ˆˆ ˆ ˆ n {G[􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k􏱶1xik􏱶1 􏱕 􏱬k(ck 􏱕 1)] The quantity in equation (17.17) is a “partial” effect because all explanatory variables other than xk are being held fixed at their observed values. It is not necessarily a “marginal” effect because the change in xk from ck to ck 􏱕 1 may not be a “marginal” (or “small”) increase; whether it is depends on the definition of xk. Obtaining expression (17.17) for either probit or logit is actually rather simple. First, for each observation, we estimate the probability of success for the two chosen values of xk, plugging in the actual outcomes for the other explanatory variables. (So, we would have n estimated differences.) Then, we average the differences in estimated probabilities across all observations. For binary xk, both (17.16) and (17.17) are easily computed using certain econometrics packages, such as Stata.® The expression in (17.17) has a particularly useful interpretation when xk is a binary variable. For each unit i, we estimate the predicted difference in the probability that yi 􏱪 1 when xk 􏱪 1 and xk 􏱪 0, namely, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ˆˆˆˆ i􏱪1 􏱦 G(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k􏱶1xik􏱶1 􏱕 􏱬kck)}. [17.17] 593 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆk􏱶1xi,k􏱶1 􏱕 􏱬ˆk) 􏱦 G(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆk􏱶1xi,k􏱶1). For each i, this difference is the estimated effect of switching xk from zero to one, whether unit i had xik 􏱪 1 or xik 􏱪 0. For example, if y is an employment indicator (equal to one if the person is employed) after participation in a job training program, indicated by xk, then we can estimate the difference in employment probabilities for each person in both states of the world. This counterfactual reasoning is similar to that in Chapter 16, which we used to motivate simultaneous equations models. The estimated effect of the job train- ing program on the employment probability is the average of the estimated differences in probabilities. As another example, suppose that y indicates whether a family was approved for a mortgage, and xk is a binary race indicator (say, equal to one for nonwhites). Then for each family we can estimate the predicted difference in having the mortgage approved as a function of income, wealth, credit rating, and so on—which would be elements of (xi1, xi2, ..., xi,k􏱶1)—under the two scenarios that the household head is nonwhite versus white. Hopefully, we have controlled for enough factors so that averaging the differences in probabilities results in a convincing estimate of the race effect. In applications where one applies probit, logit, and the LPM, it makes sense to compute the scale factors described above for probit and logit in making comparisons of partial effects. Still, sometimes one wants a quicker way to compare magnitudes of the different estimates. As mentioned earlier, for probit g(0) 􏱴 .4 and for logit, g(0) 􏱪.25. Thus, to make the magnitudes of probit and logit roughly comparable, we can multiply the probit coefficients by .4/.25 􏱪 1.6, or we can multiply the logit estimates by .625. In the LPM, g(0) is effectively one, so the logit slope estimates can be divided by four to make them comparable to the LPM estimates; the probit slope estimates can be divided by 2.5 to make them comparable to the LPM estimates. Still, in most cases, we want the more accurate comparisons obtained by using the scale factors in (17.15) for logit and probit. EXAMPLE 17.1 MARRIED WOMEN’S LABOR FORCE PARTICIPATION We now use the MROZ.RAW data to estimate the labor force participation model from Example 8.8—see also Section 7.5—by logit and probit. We also report the linear probabil- ity model estimates from Example 8.8, using the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. The results, with standard errors in parentheses, are given in Table 17.1. The estimates from the three models tell a consistent story. The signs of the coef- ficients are the same across models, and the same variables are statistically significant in each model. The pseudo R-squared for the LPM is just the usual R-squared reported for OLS; for logit and probit, the pseudo R-squared is the measure based on the log-likelihoods described earlier. As we have already emphasized, the magnitudes of the coefficient estimates across models are not directly comparable. Instead, we compute the scale factors in equations (17.14) and (17.15). If we evaluate the standard normal probability density function 􏰿(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1x1 􏱕 􏱬ˆ2x2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬ˆkxk) at the sample aver- ages of the explanatory variables (including the average of exper2, kidslt6, and kidsge6), the result is approximately .391. When we compute (17.14) for the logit case, we Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 17.2 Using the probit estimates and the calculus approximation, what is the approximate change in the response probability when exper increases from 10 to 11? 594 PART 3 Advanced Topics T A B L E 1 7 . 1 LPM, Logit, and Probit Estimates of Labor Force Participation Dependent Variable: inlf Independent Variables LPM (OLS) Logit (MLE) Probit (MLE) nwifeinc 􏱦.0034 (.0015) 􏱦.021 (.008) 􏱦.012 (.005) educ .038 (.007) .221 (.043) .131 (.025) exper .039 (.006) .206 (.032) .123 (.019) exper2 􏱦.00060 (.00018) 􏱦.0032 (.0010) 􏱦.0019 (.0006) age 􏱦.016 (.002) 􏱦.088 (.015) 􏱦.053 (.008) kidslt6 􏱦.262 (.032) 􏱦1.443 (.204) 􏱦.868 (.119) kidsge6 .013 (.013) .060 (.075) .036 (.043) constant .586 (.151) .425 (.860) .270 (.509) Percentage correctly predicted Log-likelihood value Pseudo R-squared 73.4 — .264 73.6 􏱦401.77 .220 73.4 􏱦401.30 .221 obtain about .243. The ratio of these, .391/.243 􏱴 1.61, is very close to the simple rule of thumb for scaling up the probit estimates to make them comparable to the logit estimates: multiply the probit estimates by 1.6. Nevertheless, for comparing probit and logit to the LPM estimates, it is better to use (17.15). These scale factors are about .301 (probit) and .179 (logit). For example, the scaled logit coefficient on educ is about .179(.221) 􏱴 .040, and the scaled probit coefficient on educ is about .301(.131) 􏱴 .039; both are remarkably close to the LPM estimate of .038. Even on the discrete variable kidslt6, the scaled logit and probit coefficients are similar to the LPM coefficient of 􏱦.262. These are .179(􏱦1.443) 􏱴 􏱦.258 (logit) and .301(􏱦.868) 􏱴 􏱦.261 (probit). The biggest difference between the LPM model and the logit and probit models is that the LPM assumes constant marginal effects for educ, kidslt6, and so on, while the logit and probit models imply diminishing magnitudes of the partial effects. In the LPM, one more small child is estimated to reduce the probability of labor force participation by about .262, regardless of how many young children the woman already has (and regardless of the lev- els of the other explanatory variables). We can contrast this with the estimated marginal effect from probit. For concreteness, take a woman with nwifeinc 􏱪 20.13, educ 􏱪 12.3, exper 􏱪 10.6, and age 􏱪 42.5—which are roughly the sample averages—and kidsge6 􏱪 1. What is the estimated decrease in the probability of working in going from zero to one small child? We evaluate the standard normal cdf, 􏱋( ˆ􏱬0 􏱕 ˆ􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ˆ􏱬k xk), with kid- slt6 􏱪 1 and kidslt6 􏱪 0, and the other independent variables set at the preceding values. We get roughly .373 􏱦 .707 􏱪 􏱦.334, which means that the labor force participation Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 595 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections probability is about .334 lower when a woman has one young child. If the woman goes from one to two young children, the probability falls even more, but the marginal effect is not as large: .117 􏱦 .373 􏱪 􏱦.256. Interestingly, the estimate from the linear probability model, which is supposed to estimate the effect near the average, is in fact between these two estimates. (Note that the calculations provided here, which use coefficients mostly rounded to the third decimal place, will differ somewhat from calculations obtained within a statistical package—which would be subject to less rounding error.) Figure 17.2 illustrates how the estimated response probabilities from nonlinearbinary response models can differ from the linear probability model. The estimated proba- bility of labor force participation is graphed against years of education for the linear prob- ability model and the probit model. (The graph for the logit model is very similar to that for the probit model.) In both cases, the explanatory variables, other than educ, are set at their sample averages. In particular, the two equations graphed are 􏱾inlf 􏱪 .102 􏱕 .038 educ for the linear model and 􏱾inlf 􏱪 􏱋(􏱦1.403 􏱕 .131 educ). At lower levels of educa- tion, the linear probability model estimates higher labor force participation probabilities than the probit model. For example, at eight years of education, the linear probability model estimates a .406 labor force participation probability while the probit model esti- mates about .361. The estimates are the same at around 111􏱆3 years of education. At higher levels of education, the probit model gives higher labor force participation probabilities. In this sample, the smallest years of education is 5 and the largest is 17, so we really should not make comparisons outside this range. F I G U R E 1 7 . 2 Estimated response probabilities with respect to education for the linear probability and probit models. 1 .9 .75 .5 .25 .1 0 inlf 5 F (21.403 1 .131 educ) inlf 5 .102 1 .038 educ 0 4 8 12 16 20 years of education Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 estimated probability of labor force participation 596 PART 3 Advanced Topics The same issues concerning endogenous explanatory variables in linear models also arise in logit and probit models. We do not have the space to cover them, but it is possible to test and correct for endogenous explanatory variables using methods related to two stage least squares. Evans and Schwab (1995) estimated a probit model for whether a student attends college, where the key explanatory variable is a dummy variable for whether the student attends a Catholic school. Evans and Schwab esti- mated a model by maximum likelihood that allows attending a Catholic school to be considered endogenous. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 15) for an explanation of these methods.] Two other issues have received attention in the context of probit models. The first is nonnormality of e in the latent variable model (17.6). Naturally, if e does not have a standard normal distribution, the response probability will not have the probit form. Some authors tend to emphasize the inconsistency in estimating the 􏱬j, but this is the wrong focus unless we are only interested in the direction of the effects. Because the response probability is unknown, we could not estimate the magnitude of partial effects even if we had consistent estimates of the 􏱬j. A second specification problem, also defined in terms of the latent variable model, is heteroskedasticity in e. If Var(e􏰫x) depends on x, the response probability no longer has the form G(􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬); instead, it depends on the form of the variance and requires more general estimation. Such models are not often used in practice, since logit and probit with flexible functional forms in the independent variables tend to work well. Binary response models apply with little modification to independently pooled cross sections or to other data sets where the observations are independent but not necessarily identically distributed. Often, year or other time period dummy variables are included to account for aggregate time effects. Just as with linear models, logit and probit can be used to evaluate the impact of certain policies in the context of a natural experiment. The linear probability model can be applied with panel data; typically, it would be estimated by fixed effects (see Chapter 14). Logit and probit models with unobserved effects have recently become popular. These models are complicated by the nonlinear nature of the response probabilities, and they are difficult to estimate and interpret. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 15).] 17.2 The Tobit Model for Corner Solution Responses As mentioned in the chapter introduction, another important kind of limited dependent variable is a corner solution response. Such a variable is zero for a nontrivial fraction of the population but is roughly continuously distributed over positive values. An example is the amount an individual spends on alcohol in a given month. In the population of people over age 21 in the United States, this variable takes on a wide range of values. For some significant fraction, the amount spent on alcohol is zero. The following treatment omits verification of some details concerning the Tobit model. [These are given in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 17).] Let y be a variable that is essentially continuous over strictly positive values but that takes on a value of zero with positive probability. Nothing prevents us from using a linear model for y. In fact, a linear model might be a good approximation to E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk), especially for xj near the mean values. But we would possibly obtain negative fitted values, which leads to negative predictions for y; this is analogous to the problems with the LPM for binary outcomes. Also, the assumption that an explanatory variable appearing in level Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 597 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections form has a constant partial effect on E( y􏰫x) can be misleading. Probably, Var( y􏰫x) would be heteroskedastic, although we can easily deal with general heteroskedasticity by com- puting robust standard errors and test statistics. Because the distribution of y piles up at zero, y clearly cannot have a conditional normal distribution. So all inference would have only asymptotic justification, as with the linear probability model. In some cases, it is important to have a model that implies nonnegative predicted values for y, and which has sensible partial effects over a wide range of the explanatory variables. Plus, we sometimes want to estimate features of the distribution of y given x1, ..., xk other than the conditional expectation. The Tobit model is quite convenient for these purposes. Typically, the Tobit model expresses the observed response, y, in terms of an underlying latent variable: y* 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬 􏱕 u, u􏰫x ~ Normal(0, 􏱧2) [17.18] y 􏱪 max(0,y*). [17.19] The latent variable y* satisfies the classical linear model assumptions; in particular, it has a normal, homoskedastic distribution with a linear conditional mean. Equation (17.19) implies that the observed variable, y, equals y* when y* 􏱸 0, but y 􏱪 0 when y* 􏱷 0. Because y* is normally distributed, y has a continuous distribution over strictly positive values. In particular, the density of y given x is the same as the density of y* given x for positive values. Further, P( y 􏱪 0􏰫x) 􏱪 P(y* 􏱷 0􏰫x) 􏱪 P(u 􏱷 􏱦x􏱬􏰫x) 􏱪 P(u/􏱧 􏱷 􏱦x􏱬/􏱧􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱋(􏱦x􏱬/􏱧) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧), because u/􏱧 has a standard normal distribution and is independent of x; we have absorbed the intercept into x for notational simplicity. Therefore, if (xi, yi) is a random draw from the population, the density of yi given xi is (2􏰵􏱧2)􏱦1/2exp[􏱦( y 􏱦 xi 􏱬)2/(2􏱧2)] 􏱪 (1/􏱧)􏰿[( y 􏱦 xi 􏱬)/􏱧], y 􏱰 0 [17.20] P(yi 􏱪 0􏰫xi) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋(xi 􏱬/􏱧), [17.21] where 􏰿 is the standard normal density function. From (17.20) and (17.21), we can obtain the log-likelihood function for each observa- tion i: 􏱷i( 􏱬,􏱧) 􏱪 1( yi 􏱪 0)log[1 􏱦 􏱋(xi􏱬/􏱧)] 􏱕 1( yi 􏱰 0)log{(1/􏱧)􏰿[(yi 􏱦 xi􏱬)/􏱧]}; [17.22] notice how this depends on 􏱧, the standard deviation of u, as well as on the 􏱬j. The log-likelihood for a random sample of size n is obtained by summing (17.22) across all i. The maximum likelihood estimates of 􏱬 and 􏱧 are obtained by maximizing the log- likelihood; this requires numerical methods, although in most cases this is easily done using a packaged routine. As in the case of logit and probit, each Tobit estimate comes with a standard error, and these can be used to construct t statistics for each 􏱬ˆj; the matrix formula used to find the standard errors is complicated and will not be presented here. [See, for example, Wool- dridge (2010, Chapter 17).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 598 PART 3 Advanced Topics Testing multiple exclusion restric- tions is easily done using the Wald test or the likelihood ratio test. The Wald test has a form similar to that of the logit or probit case; the LR test is always given by (17.12), where, of course, we use the Tobit log-likelihood functions for the re- stricted and unrestricted models. EXPLORING FURTHER 17.3 Let y be the number of extramarital affairs for a married woman from the U.S. popula- tion; we would like to explain this variable in terms of other characteristics of the wom- an—in particular, whether she works outside of the home, her husband, and her family. Is this a good candidate for a Tobit model? Interpreting the Tobit Estimates Using modern computers, it is usually not much more difficult to obtain the maximum likelihood estimates for Tobit models than the OLS estimates of a linear model. Further, the outputs from Tobit and OLS are often similar. This makes it tempting to interpret the 􏱬ˆj from Tobit as if these were estimates from a linear regression. Unfortunately, things are not so easy. From equation (17.18), we see that the 􏱬j measure the partial effects of the xj on E(y*􏰫x), where y* is the latent variable. Sometimes, y* has an interesting economic mean- ing, but more often it does not. The variable we want to explain is y, as this is the observed outcome (such as hours worked or amount of charitable contributions). For example, as a policy matter, we are interested in the sensitivity of hours worked to changes in marginal tax rates. We can estimate P(y 􏱪 0􏰫x) from (17.21), which, of course, allows us to estimate P(y 􏱰 0􏰫x). What happens if we want to estimate the expected value of y as a function of x? In Tobit models, two expectations are of particular interest: E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x), which is sometimes called the “conditional expectation” because it is conditional on y 􏱰 0, and E(y􏰫x), which is, unfortunately, called the “unconditional expectation.” (Both expectations are conditional on the explanatory variables.) The expectation E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) tells us, for given values of x, the expected value of y for the subpopulation where y is positive. Given E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x), we can easily find E(y􏰫x): E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 P(y 􏱰 0􏰫x)􏱳E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) 􏱪 􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧)􏱳E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x). [17.23] To obtain E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x), we use a result for normally distributed random variables: if z ~ Normal(0,1), then E(z􏰫z 􏱰 c) 􏱪 􏰿(c)/[1 􏱦 􏱋(c)] for any constant c. But E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 E(u􏰫u 􏱰 􏱦x􏱬) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 􏱧E[(u/􏱧)􏰫(u/􏱧) 􏱰 􏱦x􏱬/􏱧] 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 􏱧􏰿(x􏱬/􏱧)/􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧), because 􏰿(􏱦c) 􏱪 􏰿(c), 1 􏱦 􏱋(􏱦c) 􏱪 􏱋(c), and u/􏱧 has a standard normal distribution independent of x. We can summarize this as E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 􏱧􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧), [17.24] where 􏲇(c) 􏱪 􏰿(c)/􏱋(c) is called the inverse Mills ratio; it is the ratio between the stan- dard normal pdf and standard normal cdf, each evaluated at c. Equation (17.24) is important. It shows that the expected value of y conditional on y 􏱰 0 is equal to x􏱬 plus a strictly positive term, which is 􏱧 times the inverse Mills ratio evalu- ated at x􏱬/􏱧. This equation also shows why using OLS only for observations where yi 􏱰 0 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 599 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections will not always consistently estimate 􏱬; essentially, the inverse Mills ratio is an omitted variable, and it is generally correlated with the elements of x. Combining (17.23) and (17.24) gives E(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧)[x􏱬 􏱕 􏱧􏰮(x􏱬/􏱧)] 􏱪 􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧)x􏱬 􏱕 􏱧􏰿(x􏱬/􏱧), [17.25] where the second equality follows because 􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧)􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧) 􏱪 􏰿(x􏱬/􏱧). This equation shows that when y follows a Tobit model, E( y􏰫x) is a nonlinear function of x and 􏱬. Al- though it is not obvious, the right-hand side of equation (17.25) can be shown to be posi- tive for any values of x and 􏱬. Therefore, once we have estimates of 􏱬, we can be sure that predicted values for y—that is, estimates of E(y􏰫x)—are positive. The cost of ensuring positive predictions for y is that equation (17.25) is more complicated than a linear model for E(y􏰫x). Even more importantly, the partial effects from (17.25) are more complicated than for a linear model. As we will see, the partial effects of xj on E( y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) and E( y􏰫x) have the same sign as the coefficient, 􏱬j, but the magnitude of the effects depends on the values of all explanatory variables and parameters. Because 􏱧 appears in (17.25), it is not surprising that the partial effects depend on 􏱧, too. If xj is a continuous variable, we can find the partial effects using calculus. First, ∂E( y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x)/∂xj 􏱪 􏱬j 􏱕 􏱬j 􏱳_d__l (x􏱬/􏱧), assuming that xj is not functionally related to other regressors. By differentiating 􏲇(c) 􏱪 􏰿(c)/􏱋(c) and using d􏱋/dc 􏱪 􏰿(c) and d􏰿/dc 􏱪 􏱦c􏰿(c), it can be shown that d􏲇/dc 􏱪 􏱦􏲇(c) [c 􏱕 􏲇(c)]. Therefore, ∂E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x)/∂xj 􏱪 􏱬j{1 􏱦 􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧)[x􏱬/􏱧 􏱕 􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧)]}. [17.26] This shows that the partial effect of xj on E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) is not determined just by 􏱬j. The ad- justment factor is given by the term in brackets, {􏱳}, and depends on a linear function of x, x􏱬/􏱧 􏱪 (􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk)/􏱧. It can be shown that the adjustment factor is strictly between zero and one. In practice, we can estimate (17.26) by plugging in the MLEs of the 􏱬j and 􏱧. As with logit and probit models, we must plug in values forthe xj, usually the mean values or other interesting values. Equation (17.26) reveals a subtlepoint that is sometimes lost in applying the Tobit model to corner solution responses: the parameter 􏱧 appears directly in the partial effects, so having an estimate of 􏱧 is crucial for estimat- ing the partial effects. Sometimes, 􏱧 is called an “ancillary” parameter (which means it is auxiliary, or unimportant). Although it is true that the value of 􏱧 does not affect the sign of the partial effects, it does affect the magnitudes, and we are often interested in the eco- nomic importance of the explanatory variables. Therefore, characterizing 􏱧 as ancillary is misleading and comes from a confusion between the Tobit model for corner solution applications and applications to true data censoring. (See Section 17.4.) All of the usual economic quantities, such as elasticities, can be computed. For example, the elasticity of y with respect to x1, conditional on y 􏱰 0, is ∂E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) x1 ____________ 􏱳___________. [17.27] ∂x1 E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) This can be computed when x1 appears in various functional forms, including level, logarithmic, and quadratic forms. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. dc 600 PART 3 Advanced Topics If x1 is a binary variable, the effect of interest is obtained as the difference between E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0, x), with x1 􏱪 1 and x1 􏱪 0. Partial effects involving other discrete variables (such as number of children) can be handled similarly. We can use (17.25) to find the partial derivative of E(y􏰫x) with respect to continuous xj. This derivative accounts for the fact that people starting at y 􏱪 0 might choose y 􏱰 0 when xj changes: ∂E(y􏰫x) ∂P(y 􏱰 0􏰫x) ∂E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) _______ 􏱪 __________ 􏱳 E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) 􏱕 P(y 􏱰 0􏰫x) 􏱳____________. ∂xj ∂xj ∂xj Because P( y 􏱰 0􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧), ∂P(y 􏱰 0􏰫x) __________ 􏱪 (􏱬j /􏱧)􏰿(x􏱬/􏱧), so we can estimate each term in (17.28), once we plug in the MLEs of the 􏱬j and 􏱧 and particular values of the xj. Remarkably, when we plug (17.26) and (17.29) into (17.28) and use the fact that 􏱋(c)􏲇(c) 􏱪 􏰿(c) for any c, we obtain ∂E(y􏰫x) _______ 􏱪 􏱬j􏱋(x􏱬/􏱧). [17.30] Equation (17.30) allows us to roughly compare OLS and Tobit estimates. [Equation (17.30) also can be derived directly from equation (17.25) using the fact that d􏰿(z)/dz 􏱪 􏱦z􏰿(z).] The OLS slope coefficients, say, 􏰸ˆj, from the regression of yi on xi1, xi2, ..., xik, i 􏱪 1, ..., n—that is, using all of the data—are direct estimates of ∂E(y􏰫x)/∂xj. To make the Tobit coefficient, 􏱬ˆj, comparable to 􏰸ˆj, we must multiply 􏱬ˆj by an adjustment factor. As in the probit and logit cases, there are two common approaches for computing an adjustment factor for obtaining partial effects—at least for continuous explanatory vari- ables. Both are based on equation (17.30). First, the partial effect at the average, PEA, is obtained by evaluating 􏱋(x􏱬ˆ/􏱧ˆ), which we denote 􏱋(-x􏱬ˆ/􏱧ˆ). We can then use this single factor to multiply the coefficients on the continuous explanatory variables. The PEA has the same drawbacks here as in the probit and logit cases: we may not be interested in the partial effect for the “average” because the average is either uninteresting or meaningless. Plus, we must decide whether to use averages of nonlinear functions or plug the averages into the nonlinear functions. i ∂xj [17.28] [17.29] ∂xj The average p∑artial effect, APE, is preferred in most cases. Here, we compute the scale factor as n􏱦1 n 􏱋(x 􏱬ˆ/􏱧ˆ). Unlike the PAE, the APE does not require us to plug i􏱪1 in a fictitious or nonexistent unit from the population, and there are no decisions to make about plugging averages into nonlinear functions. Like the PAE, the APE scale factor is always between zero and one because 0 􏱷 􏱋(x􏱬ˆ/􏱧ˆ) 􏱷 1 for any values of the explanatory variables. In fact, ˆP(yi 􏱰 0|xi) 􏱪 􏱋(xi 􏱬ˆ/􏱧ˆ), and so the APE scale factor and the PAE scale factor tend to be closer to one when there are few observations with yi 􏱪 0. In the case that yi 􏱰 0 for all i, the Tobit and OLS estimates of the parameters are identical. [Of course, if yi 􏱰 0 for all i, we cannot justify the use of a Tobit model anyway. Using log (yi) in a linear regression model makes much more sense.] Unfortunately, for discrete explanatory variables, comparing OLS and Tobit estimates is not so easy (although using the scale factor for continuous explanatory variables often is Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 601 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections a useful approximation). For Tobit, the partial effect of a discrete explanatory variable, for example, a binary variable, should really be obtained by estimating E(y|x) from equation (17.25). For example, if x1 is a binary, we should first plug in x1 􏱪 1 and then x1 􏱪 0. If we set the other explanatory variables at their sample averages, we obtain a measure analogous to (17.16) for the logit and probit cases. If we compute the difference in expected values for each individual, and then average the difference, we get an APE analogous to (17.17). EXAMPLE 17.2 MARRIED WOMEN’S ANNUAL LABOR SUPPLY The file MROZ.RAW includes data on hours worked for 753 married women, 428 of whom worked for a wage outside the home during the year; 325 of the women worked zero hours. For the women who worked positive hours, the range is fairly broad, extend- ing from 12 to 4,950. Thus, annual hours worked is a good candidate for a Tobit model. We also estimate a linear model (using all 753 observations) by OLS. The results are given in Table 17.2. This table has several noteworthy features. First, the Tobit coefficient estimates have the same sign as the corresponding OLS estimates, and the statistical significance of the estimates is similar. (Possible exceptions are the coefficients on nwifeinc and kidsge6, but the t statistics have similar magnitudes.) Second, though it is tempting to compare the magnitudes of the OLS and Tobit estimates, this is not very informative. We must be careful not to think that, because the Tobit coefficient on kidslt6 is roughly twice that of T A B L E 1 7 . 2 OLS and Tobit Estimation of Annual Hours Worked Dependent Variable: hours Independent Variables Linear (OLS) Tobit (MLE) nwifeinc 􏱦3.45 (2.54) 􏱦8.81 (4.46) educ 28.76 (12.95) 80.65 (21.58) exper 65.67 (9.96) 131.56 (17.28) exper2 􏱦.700 (.325) 􏱦1.86 (0.54) age 􏱦30.51 (4.36) 􏱦54.41 (7.42) kidslt6 􏱦442.09 (58.85) 􏱦894.02 (111.88) kidsge6 􏱦32.78 (23.18) 􏱦16.22 (38.64) constant 1,330.48 (270.78) 965.31 (446.44) Log-likelihood value R-squared ˆ􏱧 — .266 750.18 􏱦3,819.09 .274 1,122.02 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 602 PART 3 Advanced Topics the OLS coefficient, the Tobit model implies a much greater response of hours worked to young children. We can multiply the Tobit estimates by appropriate adjustment∑factors to make them roughly comparable to the OLS estimates. The APE scale factor n􏱦1 n 􏱋(x 􏱬ˆ/􏱧ˆ) turns i􏱪1 out to be about .589, which we can use to obtain the average partial effects for the Tobit estimation. If, for example, we multiply the educ coefficient by .589 we get .589(80.65) 􏱴 47.50 (that is, 47.5 hours more), which is quite a bit larger than the OLS partial effect, about 28.8 hours. So, even for estimating an average effect, the Tobit estimates are notably larger in magnitude than the corresponding OLS estimate. If, instead, we want the estimated ef- fect of another year of education starting at the average values of all explanatory variables, then we compute the PEA scale factor 􏱋(-x􏱬ˆ/ˆ􏱧). This turns out to be about .645 [when we use the squared average of experience, (exper)2, rather than the average of exper2]. This par- tial effect, which is about 52 hours, is almost twice as large as the OLS estimate. With the exception of kidsge6, the scaled Tobit slope coefficients are all greater in magnitude than the corresponding OLS coefficient. We have reported an R-squared for both the linear regression and the Tobit models. The R-squared for OLS is the usual one. For Tobit, the R-squared is the square of the cor- relation coefficient between yi and yˆi, where yˆi 􏱪 􏱋(xi􏱬ˆ/ˆ􏱧)xi􏱬ˆ 􏱕 ˆ􏱧􏰿(xi􏱬ˆ/ˆ􏱧) is the estimate of E(y􏰫x 􏱪 xi). This is motivated by the fact that the usual R-squared for OLS is equal to the squared correlation between the yi and the fitted values [see equation (3.29)]. In non- linear models such as the Tobit model, the squared correlation coefficient is not identical to an R-squared based on a sum of squared residuals as in (3.28). This is because the fitted values, as defined earlier, and the residuals, yi 􏱦 ˆyi, are not uncorrelated in the sample. An R-squared defined as the squared correlation coefficient between yi and ˆyi has the ad- vantage of always being between zero and one; an R-squared based on a sum of squared residuals need not have this feature. We can see that, based on the R-squared measures, the Tobit conditional mean func- tion fits the hours data somewhat, but not substantially, better. However, we should re- member that the Tobit estimates are not chosen to maximize an R-squared—they maximize the log-likelihood function—whereas the OLS estimates are the values that do produce the highest R-squared given the linear functional form. By construction, all of the Tobit fitted values for hours are positive. By contrast, 39 of the OLS fitted values are negative. Although negative predictions are of some concern, 39 out of 753 is just over 5% of the observations. It is not entirely clear how negative fitted values for OLS translate into differences in estimated partial effects. Figure 17.3 plots estimates of E(hours􏰫x) as a function of education; for the Tobit model, the other explanatory variables are set at their average values. For the linear model, the equation i 􏱾 graphed is hours 􏱪 387.19 􏱕 28.76 educ. For the Tobit model, the equation graphed is 􏱾 hours 􏱪 􏱋[(􏱦694.12 􏱕 80.65 educ)/1,122.02] 􏱳 (􏱦694.12 􏱕 80.65 educ) 􏱕 1,122.02 􏱳 􏰿 [(􏱦694.12 􏱕 80.65 educ)/1,122.02]. As can be seen from the figure, the linear model gives notably higher estimates of the expected hours worked at even fairly high levels of educa- tion. For example, at eight years of education, the OLS predicted value of hours is about 617.5, while the Tobit estimate is about 423.9. At 12 years of education, the predicted hours are about 732.7 and 598.3, respectively. The two prediction lines cross after 17 years of education, but no woman in the sample has more than 17 years of education. The in- creasing slope of the Tobit line clearly indicates the increasing marginal effect of educa- tion on expected hours worked. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 603 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections F I G U R E 1 7 . 3 Estimated expected values of hours with respect to education for the linear and Tobit models. 1,050 900 750 600 450 300 150 0 0 4 8 12 16 20 years of education Specification Issues in Tobit Models The Tobit model, and in particular the formulas for the expectations in (17.24) and (17.25), rely crucially on normality and homoskedasticity in the underlying latent variable model. When E( y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk, we know from Chapter 5 that conditional nor- mality of y does not play a role in unbiasedness, consistency, or large sample inference. Heteroskedasticity does not affect unbiasedness or consistency of OLS, although we must compute robust standard errors and test statistics to perform approximate inference. In a Tobit model, if any of the assumptions in (17.18) fail, then it is hard to know what the Tobit MLE is estimating. Nevertheless, for moderate departures from the assumptions, the Tobit model is likely to provide good estimates of the partial effects on the conditional means. It is possible to allow for more general assumptions in (17.18), but such models are much more complicated to estimate and interpret. One potentially important limitation of the Tobit model, at least in certain applica- tions, is that the expected value conditional on y 􏱰 0 is closely linked to the probability that y 􏱰 0. This is clear from equations (17.26) and (17.29). In particular, the effect of xj on P( y 􏱰 0􏰫x) is proportional to 􏱬j, as is the effect on E( y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x), where both func- tions multiplying 􏱬j are positive and depend on x only through x􏱬/􏱧. This rules out some interesting possibilities. For example, consider the relationship between amount of life insurance coverage and a person’s age. Young people may be less likely to have life insur- ance at all, so the probability that y 􏱰 0 increases with age (at least up to a point). Con- ditional on having life insurance, the value of policies might decrease with age, since life Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 estimated expected hours 604 PART 3 Advanced Topics insurance becomes less important as people near the end of their lives. This possibility is not allowed for in the Tobit model. One way to informally evaluate whether the Tobit model is appropriate is to estimate a probit model where the binary outcome, say, w, equals one if y 􏱰 0, and w 􏱪 0 if y 􏱪 0. Then, from (17.21), w follows a probit model, where the coefficient on xj is 􏰸j 􏱪 􏱬j /􏱧. This means we can estimate the ratio of 􏱬j to 􏱧 by probit, for each j. If the Tobit model holds, the probit estimate, 􏰸ˆj, should be “close” to 􏱬ˆj/􏱧ˆ, where 􏱬ˆj and 􏱧ˆ are the Tobit estimates. These will never be identical because of sampling error. But we can look for certain problematic signs. For example, if 􏰸ˆj is significant and negative, but 􏱬ˆj is positive, the Tobit model might not be appropriate. Or, if 􏰸ˆj and 􏱬ˆj are the same sign, but 􏱬ˆj/􏱧ˆ􏰫 is much larger or smaller than 􏰫􏰸ˆj􏰫, this could also indicate problems. We should not worry too much about sign changes or magnitude differences on explanatory variables that are insignificant in both models. In the annual hours worked example, ˆ􏱧 􏱪 1,122.02. When we divide the Tobit coefficient on nwifeinc by 􏱧ˆ, we obtain 􏱦8.81/1,122.02 􏱴 􏱦.0079; the probit coefficient on nwifeinc is about 􏱦.012, which is different, but not dramatically so. On kidslt6, the coefficient estimate over 􏱧ˆ is about 􏱦.797, compared with the probit estimate of 􏱦.868. Again, this is not a huge difference, but it indicates that having small children has a larger effect on the initial labor force participation decision than on how many hours a woman chooses to work once she is in the labor force. (Tobit effectively averages these two ef- fects together.) We do not know whether the effects are statistically different, but they are of the same order of magnitude. What happens if we conclude that the Tobit model is inappropriate? There are models, usually called hurdle or two-part models, that can be used when Tobit seems unsuitable. These all have the property that P(y 􏱰 0􏰫x) and E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) depend on different param- eters, so xj can have dissimilar effects on these two functions. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 17) for a description of these models.] 17.3 The Poisson Regression Model Another kind of nonnegative dependent variable is a count variable, which can take on nonnegative integer values: {0, 1, 2, ...}. We are especially interested in cases where y takes on relatively few values, including zero. Examples include the number of children ever born to a woman, the number of times someone is arrested in a year, or the number of patents applied for by a firm in a year. For the same reasons discussed for binary and Tobit responses, a linear model for E(y􏰫x1, ..., xk) might not provide the best fit over all values of the explanatory variables. (Nevertheless, it is always informative to start with a linear model, as we did in Example 3.5.) As with a Tobit outcome, we cannot take the logarithm of a count variable because it takes on the value zero. A profitable approach is to model the expected value as an expo- nential function: E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk). [17.31] Because exp(􏱳) is always positive, (17.31) ensures that predicted values for y will also be positive. The exponential function is graphed in Figure A.5 of Appendix A. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 605 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections Athough (17.31) is more complicated than a linear model, we basically already know how to interpret the coefficients. Taking the log of equation (17.31) shows that log[E( y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk)] 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xk, [17.32] so that the log of the expected value is linear. Therefore, using the approximation proper- ties of the log function that we have used often in previous chapters, %􏰧E(y􏰫x) 􏱴 (100􏱬j)􏰧xj. In other words, 100􏱬j is roughly the percentage change in E( y􏰫x), given a one-unit increase in xj. Sometimes, a more accurate estimate is needed, and we can easily find one by look- ing at discrete changes in the expected value. Keep all explanatory variables except xk fixed and let x0 be the initial value and x1 the subsequent value. Then, the proportionate kk change in the expected value is [exp(􏱬0 􏱕 xk􏱦1􏱬k􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬kx1k)/exp(􏱬0 􏱕 xk􏱦1􏱬k􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬k x0k)] 􏱦 1 􏱪 exp( 􏱬k 􏰧xk) 􏱦 1, where xk􏱦1􏱬k􏱦1 is shorthand for 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k􏱦1xk􏱦1, and 􏰧xk 􏱪 x1k 􏱦 x0k. When 􏰧xk 􏱪 1—for example, if xk is a dummy variable that we change from zero to one—then the change is exp(􏱬k) 􏱦 1. Given 􏱬ˆk, we obtain exp(􏱬ˆk) 􏱦 1 and multiply this by 100 to turn the proportionate change into a percentage change. If, say, xj 􏱪 log(zj) for some variable zj 􏱰 0, then its coefficient, 􏱬j, is interpreted as an elasticity with respect to zj. Technically, it is an elasticity of the expected value of y with re- spect to zj because we cannot compute the percentage change in cases where y 􏱪 0. For our purposes, the distinction is unimportant. The bottom line is that, for practical purposes, we can interpret the coefficients in equation (17.31) as if we have a linear model, with log(y) as the dependent variable. There are some subtle differences that we need not study here. Because (17.31) is nonlinear in its parameters—remember, exp(􏱳) is a nonlinear function—we cannot use linear regression methods. We could use nonlinear least squares, which, just as with OLS, minimizes the sum of squared residuals. It turns out, however, that all standard count data distributions exhibit heteroskedasticity, and nonlinear least squares does not exploit this [see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 12)]. Instead, we will rely on maxi- mum likelihood and the important related method of quasi-maximum likelihood estimation. In Chapter 4, we introduced normality as the standard distributional assumption for linear regression. The normality assumption is reasonable for (roughly) continuous de- pendent variables that can take on a large range of values. A count variable cannot have a normal distribution (because the normal distribution is for continuous variables that can take on all values), and if it takes on very few values, the distribution can be very different from normal. Instead, the nominal distribution for count data is the Poisson distribution. Because we are interested in the effect of explanatory variables on y, we must look at the Poisson distribution conditional on x. The Poisson distribution is entirely determined by its mean, so we only need to specify E(y􏰫x). We assume this has the same form as (17.31), which we write in shorthand as exp(x􏱬). Then, the probability that y equals the value h, conditional on x, is P(y 􏱪 h􏰫x) 􏱪 exp[􏱦exp(x􏱬)][exp(x􏱬)]h/h!, h 􏱪 0, 1, ..., where h! denotes factorial (see Appendix B). This distribution, which is the basis for the Poisson regression model, allows us to find conditional probabilities for any values of Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 606 PART 3 Advanced Topics the explanatory variables. For example, P( y 􏱪 0􏰫x) 􏱪 exp[􏱦exp(x􏱬)]. Once we have esti- mates of the 􏱬j, we can plug them into the probabilities for various values of x. Given a random sample {(xi, yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}, we can construct the log-likelihood function: 􏱺(􏱬) 􏱪 ∑n i􏱪1 􏱷(􏱬) 􏱪 i ∑n i􏱪1 {y x 􏱬 􏱦 exp(x 􏱬)}, iii [17.33] where we drop the term 􏱦log(yi!) because it does not depend on 􏱬. This log-likelihood function is simple to maximize, although the Poisson MLEs are not obtained in closed form. ˆ The standard errors of the Poisson estimates 􏱬j are easy to obtain after the log- likelihood function has been maximized; the formula is in Appendix 17B. These are re- ported along with the 􏱬ˆj by any software package. As with the probit, logit, and Tobit models, we cannot directly compare the mag- nitudes of the Poisson estimates of an exponential function with the OLS estimates of a linear function. Nevertheless, a rough comparison is possible, at least for continuous explanatory variables. If (17.31) holds, then the partial effect of xj with respect to E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) is ∂E(y􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk)/xj 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk) ∙ 􏱬j. This expression fol- lows from the chain rule in calculus because the derivative of the exponential function is just the exponential function. If we let 􏰸ˆj denote an OLS slope coefficient from the regression y on x1, x2, ..., xk, then we can roughly compare the magnitude of the 􏰸ˆj and the average partial effect fo∑r an exponential regression function. Intere∑stingly, the APE scale factorinthiscase,n􏱦1 n exp(􏱬ˆ 􏱕􏱬ˆ x 􏱕...􏱕􏱬ˆ x )􏱪n􏱦1 n yˆ,issimplythe 0 1 i1 k ik sample average y- of yi, where we define the fitted values as yˆi􏱪 exp(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 xi􏱬ˆ). In other i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i words, for Poisson regression with an exponential mean function, the average of the fit- ted values is the same as the average of the original outcomes on yi—just as in the linear regression case. This makes it simple to scale the Poisson estimates, 􏱬ˆj, to make them comparable to the corresponding OLS estimates, 􏰸ˆj: for a continuous explanatory variable, we can compare 􏰸ˆj to y- · 􏱬ˆj. Although Poisson MLE analysis is a natural first step for count data, it is often much too restrictive. All of the probabilities and higher moments of the Poisson distribution are determined entirely by the mean. In particular, the variance is equal to the mean: Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 E(y􏰫x). [17.34] This is restrictive and has been shown to be violated in many applications. Fortunately, the Poisson distribution has a very nice robustness property: whether or not the Poisson distribution holds, we still get consistent, asymptotically normal estimators of the 􏱬j. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 18) for details.] This is analogous to the OLS estimator, which is consistent and asymptotically normal whether or not the normality assumption holds; yet OLS is the MLE under normality. When we use Poisson MLE, but we do not assume that the Poisson distribution is en- tirely correct, we call the analysis quasi-maximum likelihood estimation (QMLE). The Poisson QMLE is very handy because it is programmed in many econometrics packages. However, unless the Poisson variance assumption (17.34) holds, the standard errors need to be adjusted. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 607 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections A simple adjustment to the standard errors is available when we assume that the variance is proportional to the mean: Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 􏱧2E(y􏰫x), [17.35] where 􏱧2 􏱰 0 is an unknown parameter. When 􏱧2 􏱪 1, we obtain the Poisson variance assumption. When 􏱧2 􏱰 1, the variance is greater than the mean for all x; this is called overdispersion because the variance is larger than in the Poisson case, and it is observed in many applications of count regressions. The case 􏱧2 􏱷 1, called underdispersion, is less common but is allowed in (17.35). ˆ Under (17.35), it is easy to adjust the usual Poisson MLE standard errors. Let 􏱬j de- note the Poisson QMLE and define the residuals as uˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 yˆi, where yˆi 􏱪 exp(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1 ˆ∑ between yi and its fitted value. A consistent estimator of 􏱧2 is (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)􏱦1 x 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬 x ) is the fitted value. As usual, the residual for observation i is the difference i1 kik n uˆ2/yˆ , ii i􏱪1 where the division by yˆi is the proper heteroskedasticity adjustment, and n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 is the df given n observations and k 􏱕 1 estimates 􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, ..., 􏱬ˆk. Letting ˆ􏱧 be the positive square root of ˆ􏱧2, we multiply the usual Poisson standard errors by ˆ􏱧. If ˆ􏱧 is notably greater than one, the corrected standard errors can be much bigger than the nominal, generally incor- rect, Poisson MLE standard errors. Even (17.35) is not entirely general. Just as in the linear model, we can obtain stan- dard errors for the Poisson QMLE that do not restrict the variance at all. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 18) for further explanation.] Under the Poisson distributional assumption, we can use the likelihood ratio statis- tic to test exclusion restrictions, which, as always, has the form in (17.12). If we have q exclusion restrictions, the statistic is distributed approximately as 􏱚2q under the null. Under the less restrictive as- sumption (17.35), a simple adjustment is available (and then we call the statis- tic the quasi-likelihood ratio statistic): we divide (17.12) by ˆ􏱧2, where ˆ􏱧2 is obtained from the unrestricted model. EXAMPLE 17.3 POISSON REGRESSION FOR NUMBER OF ARRESTS We now apply the Poisson regression model to the arrest data in CRIME1.RAW, used, among other places, in Example 9.1. The dependent variable, narr86, is the number of times a man is arrested during 1986. This variable is zero for 1,970 of the 2,725 men in the sample, and only eight values of narr86 are greater than five. Thus, a Poisson regression model is more appropriate than a linear regression model. Table 17.3 also presents the results of OLS estimation of a linear regression model. The standard errors for OLS are the usual ones; we could certainly have made these robust to heteroskedasticity. The standard errors for Poisson regression are the usual maximum likelihood standard errors. Because ˆ􏱧 􏱪 1.232, the standard errors for Poisson regression should be inflated by this factor (so each corrected standard error is about 23% higher). For example, a more reliable standard error for tottime is 1.23(.015) 􏱴 .0185, which gives a t statistic of about 1.3. The adjustment to the standard errors reduces the significance of all variables, but several of them are still very statistically significant. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 17.4 Suppose that we obtain ˆ􏱧2 􏱪 2. How will the adjusted standard errors compare with the usual Poisson MLE standard errors? How will the quasi-LR statistic compare with the usual LR statistic? 608 PART 3 Advanced Topics T A B L E 1 7 . 3 Determinants of Number of Arrests for Young Men Dependent Variable: narr86 Independent Variables Linear (OLS) Exponential (Poisson QMLE) pcnv 􏱦.132 (.040) 􏱦.402 (.085) avgsen 􏱦.011 (.012) 􏱦.024 (.020) tottime .012 (.009) .024 (.015) ptime86 􏱦.041 (.009) 􏱦.099 (.021) qemp86 􏱦.051 (.014) 􏱦.038 (.029) inc86 􏱦.0015 (.0003) 􏱦.0081 (.0010) black .327 (.045) .661 (.074) hispan .194 (.040) .500 (.074) born60 􏱦.022 (.033) 􏱦.051 (.064) constant .577 (.038) 􏱦.600 (.067) Log-likelihood value R-squared ˆ􏱧 — .073 .829 􏱦2,248.76 .077 1.232 The OLS and Poisson coefficients are not directly comparable, and they have very different meanings. For example, the coefficient on pcnv implies that, if 􏰧pcnv 􏱪 .10, the expected number of arrests falls by .013 ( pcnv is the proportion of prior arrests that led to conviction). The Poisson coefficient implies that 􏰧pcnv 􏱪 .10 reduces expected arrests by about 4% [.402(.10) 􏱪 .0402, and we multiply this by 100 to get the percentage effect]. As a policy matter, this suggests we can reduce overall arrests by about 4% if we can increase the probability of conviction by .1. The Poisson coefficient on black implies that, other factors being equal, the expected number of arrests for a black man is estimated to be about 100 􏱳 [exp(.661) 􏱦1] 􏱴 93.7% higher than for a white man with the same values for the other explanatory variables. As with the Tobit application in Table 17.2, we report an R-squared for Poisson re- gression: the squared correlation coefficient between yi and ˆyi 􏱪 exp(􏱬ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬ˆ1xi1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ˆ􏱬k xik). The motivation for this goodness-of-fit measure is the same as for the Tobit model. We see that the exponential regression model, estimated by Poisson QMLE, fits slightly better. Remember that the OLS estimates are chosen to maximize the R-squared, but the Poisson estimates are not. (They are selected to maximize the log-likelihood function.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 609 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections Other count data regression models have been proposed and used in applications, which generalize the Poisson distribution in a variety of ways. If we are interested in the effects of the xj on the mean response, there is little reason to go beyond Poisson regression: it is simple, often gives good results, and has the robustness property discussed earlier. In fact, we could apply Poisson regression to a y that is a Tobit-like outcome, provided (17.31) holds. This might give good estimates of the mean effects. Extensions of Pois- son regression are more useful when we are interested in estimating probabilities, such as P(y 􏱰 1􏰫x). [See, for example, Cameron and Trivedi (1998).] 17.4 Censored and Truncated Regression Models The models in Sections 17.1, 17.2, and 17.3 apply to various kinds of limited dependent variables that arise frequently in applied econometric work. In using these methods, it is important to remember that we use a probit or logit model for a binary response, a Tobit model for a corner solution outcome, or a Poisson regression model for a count response because we want models that account for important features of the distribution of y. There is no issue of data observability. For example, in the Tobit application to women’s labor supply in Example 17.2, there is no problem with observing hours worked: it is simply the case that a nontrivial fraction of married women in the population choose not to work for a wage. In the Poisson regression application to annual arrests, we observe the dependent variable for every young man in a random sample from the population, but the dependent variable can be zero as well as other small integer values. Unfortunately, the distinction between lumpiness in an outcome variable (such as taking on the value zero for a nontrivial fraction of the population) and problems of data censoring can be confusing. This is particularly true when applying the Tobit model. In this book, the standard Tobit model described in Section 17.2 is only for corner solution outcomes. But the literature on Tobit models usually treats another situation within the same framework: the response variable has been censored above or below some thresh- old. Typically, the censoring is due to survey design and, in some cases, institutional constraints. Rather than treat data censoring problems along with corner solution out- comes, we solve data censoring by applying a censored regression model. Essentially, the problem solved by a censored regression model is one of missing data on the response variable, y. Although we are able to randomly draw units from the population and obtain information on the explanatory variables for all units, the outcome on yi is missing for some i. Still, we know whether the missing values are above or below a given threshold, and this knowledge provides useful information for estimating the parameters. A truncated regression model arises when we exclude, on the basis of y, a subset of the population in our sampling scheme. In other words, we do not have a random sample from the underlying population, but we know the rule that was used to include units in the sample. This rule is determined by whether y is above or below a certain threshold. We explain more fully the difference between censored and truncated regres- sion models later. Censored Regression Models While censored regression models can be defined without distributional assumptions, in this subsection we study the censored normal regression model. The variable we would Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 610 PART 3 Advanced Topics like to explain, y, follows the classical linear model. For emphasis, we put an i subscript on a random draw from the population: yi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 xi 􏱬 􏱕 ui, ui􏰫xi, ci ~ Normal(0, 􏱧2) [17.36] wi 􏱪 min(yi,ci). [17.37] Rather than observing yi, we observe it only if it is less than a censoring value, ci. Notice that (17.36) includes the assumption that ui is independent of ci. (For concreteness, we explicitly consider censoring from above, or right censoring; the problem of censoring from below, or left censoring, is handled similarly.) One example of right data censoring is top coding. When a variable is top coded, we know its value only up to a certain threshold. For responses greater than the threshold, we only know that the variable is at least as large as the threshold. For example, in some surveys family wealth is top coded. Suppose that respondents are asked their wealth, but people are allowed to respond with “more than $500,000.” Then, we observe actual wealth for those respon- dents whose wealth is less than $500,000 but not for those whose wealth is greater than $500,000. In this case, the censor- ing threshold, ci, is the same for all i. In many situations, the censoring thresh- old changes with individual or family characteristics. If we observed a random sample for (x, y), we would simply estimate 􏱬 by OLS, and statistical inference would be standard. (We again absorb the intercept into x for simplicity.) The censoring causes problems. Using arguments similar to the Tobit model, an OLS regression using only the uncensored observations—that is, those with yi 􏱷 ci—produces inconsistent estimators of the 􏱬j. An OLS regression of wi on xi, using all observations, does not consistently estimate the 􏱬j, unless there is no censoring. This is similar to the Tobit case, but the problem is much different. In the To- bit model, we are modeling economic behavior, which often yields zero outcomes; the Tobit model is supposed to reflect this. With censored regression, we have a data collection problem because, for some reason, the data are censored. Under the assumptions in (17.36) and (17.37), we can estimate 􏱬 (and 􏱧2) by maxi- mum likelihood, given a random sample on (xi, wi). For this, we need the density of wi, given (xi, ci). For uncensored observations, wi 􏱪 yi, and the density of wi is the same as that for yi: Normal(xi􏱬,􏱧2). For censored observations, we need the probability that wi equals the censoring value, ci, given xi: P(wi 􏱪ci􏰫xi)􏱪P(yi􏱸ci􏰫xi)􏱪P(ui􏱸ci 􏱦xi􏱬)􏱪1􏱦􏱋[(ci 􏱦xi􏱬)/􏱧]. We can combine these two parts to obtain the density of wi, given xi and ci: f (w􏰫xi,ci) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋[(ci 􏱦 xi 􏱬)/􏱧], w 􏱪 ci, [17.38] 􏱪 (1/􏱧)􏰿 [(w 􏱦 xi 􏱬)/􏱧], w 􏱷 ci. [17.39] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 17.5 Let mvpi be the marginal value product for worker i; this is the price of a firm’s good multiplied by the marginal product of the worker. Assume mvpi is a linear function of exogenous variables, such as education, experience, and so on, and an unobservable error. Under perfect competition and with- out institutional constraints, each worker is paid his or her marginal value product. Let minwagei denote the minimum wage for worker i, which varies by state. We observe wagei, which is the larger of mvpi and min- wagei. Write the appropriate model for the observed wage. 611 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections The log-likelihood for observation i is obtained by taking the natural log of the density for each i. We can maximize the sum of these across i, with respect to the 􏱬j and 􏱧, to obtain the MLEs. It is important to know that we can interpret the 􏱬j just as in a linear regression model under random sampling. This is much different than Tobit applications to corner solution responses, where the expectations of interest are nonlinear functions of the 􏱬j. An important application of censored regression models is duration analysis. A duration is a variable that measures the time before a certain event occurs. For exam- ple, we might wish to explain the number of days before a felon released from prison is arrested. For some felons, this may never happen, or it may happen after such a long time that we must censor the duration in order to analyze the data. In duration applications of censored normal regression, as well as in top coding, we often use the natural log as the dependent variable, which means we also take the log of the censoring threshold in (17.37). As we have seen throughout this text, using the log transformation for the dependent variable causes the parameters to be interpreted as per- centage changes. Further, as with many positive variables, the log of a duration typically has a distribution closer to (conditional) normal than the duration itself. EXAMPLE 17.4 DURATION OF RECIDIVISM The file RECID.RAW contains data on the time in months until an inmate in a North Carolina prison is arrested after being released from prison; call this durat. Some inmates participated in a work program while in prison. We also control for a variety of demo- graphic variables, as well as for measures of prison and criminal history. Of 1,445 inmates, 893 had not been arrested during the period they were followed; therefore, these observations are censored. The censoring times differed among inmates, ranging from 70 to 81 months. Table 17.4 gives the results of censored normal regression for log(durat). Each of the coefficients, when multiplied by 100, gives the estimated percentage change in expected duration given a ceteris paribus increase of one unit in the corresponding explanatory variable. Several of the coefficients in Table 17.4 are interesting. The variables priors (number of prior convictions) and tserved (total months spent in prison) have negative effects on the time until the next arrest occurs. This suggests that these variables measure proclivity for criminal activity rather than representing a deterrent effect. For example, an inmate with one more prior conviction has a duration until next arrest that is almost 14% less. A year of time served reduces duration by about 100 􏱳 12(.019) 􏱪 22.8%. A somewhat surprising finding is that a man serving time for a felony has an estimated expected duration that is almost 56% [exp(.444) 􏱦 1 􏱴 .56] longer than a man serving time for a nonfelony. Those with a history of drug or alcohol abuse have substantially shorter expected durations until the next arrest. (The variables alcohol and drugs are binary variables.) Older men, and men who were married at the time of incarceration, are expected to have signifi- cantly longer durations until their next arrest. Black men have substantially shorter dura- tions, on the order of 42% [exp(􏱦.543) 􏱦 1 􏱴 􏱦.42]. The key policy variable, workprg, does not have the desired effect. The point estimate is that, other things being equal, men who participated in the work program have estimated recidivism durations that are about 6.3% shorter than men who did not participate. The Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 612 PART 3 Advanced Topics T A B L E 1 7 . 4 Censored Regression Estimation of Criminal Recidivism Dependent Variable: log(durat) Independent Variables Coefficient (Standard Error) workprg 􏱦.063 (.120) priors 􏱦.137 (.021) tserved 􏱦.019 (.003) felon .444 (.145) alcohol 􏱦.635 (.144) drugs 􏱦.298 (.133) black 􏱦.543 (.117) married .341 (.140) educ .023 (.025) age .0039 (.0006) constant 4.099 (.348) Log-likelihood value ˆ􏱧 􏱦1,597.06 1.810 coefficient has a small t statistic, so we would probably conclude that the work program has no effect. This could be due to a self-selection problem, or it could be a product of the way men were assigned to the program. Of course, it may simply be that the program was ineffective. In this example, it is crucial to account for the censoring, especially because almost 62% of the durations are censored. If we apply straight OLS to the entire sample and treat the censored durations as if they were uncensored, the coefficient estimates are markedly different. In fact, they are all shrunk toward zero. For example, the coefficient on priors becomes 􏱦.059 (se 􏱪 .009), and that on alcohol becomes 􏱦.262 (se 􏱪 .060). Although the directions of the effects are the same, the importance of these variables is greatly diminished. The censored regression estimates are much more reliable. There are other ways of measuring the effects of each of the explanatory variables in Table 17.4 on the duration, rather than focusing only on the expected duration. A treat- ment of modern duration analysis is beyond the scope of this text. [For an introduction, see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 22).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 613 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections If any of the assumptions of the censored normal regression model are violated—in particular, if there is heteroskedasticity or nonnormality in ui—the MLEs are generally inconsistent. This shows that the censoring is potentially very costly, as OLS using an un- censored sample requires neither normality nor homoskedasticity for consistency. There are methods that do not require us to assume a distribution, but they are more advanced. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19).] Truncated Regression Models The truncated regression model differs in an important respect from the censored regres- sion model. In the case of data censoring, we do randomly sample units from the popula- tion. The censoring problem is that, while we always observe the explanatory variables for each randomly drawn unit, we observe the outcome on y only when it is not censored above or below a given threshold. With data truncation, we restrict attention to a subset of the population prior to sampling; so there is a part of the population for which we observe no information. In particular, we have no information on explanatory variables. The trun- cated sampling scenario typically arises when a survey targets a particular subset of the population and, perhaps due to cost considerations, entirely ignores the other part of the population. Subsequently, researchers might want to use the truncated sample to answer questions about the entire population, but one must recognize that the sampling scheme did not generate a random sample from the whole population. As an example, Hausman and Wise (1977) used data from a negative income tax ex- periment to study various determinants of earnings. To be included in the study, a family had to have income less than 1.5 times the 1967 poverty line, where the poverty line de- pended on family size. Hausman and Wise wanted to use the data to estimate an earnings equation for the entire population. The truncated normal regression model begins with an underlying population model that satisfies the classical linear model assumptions: y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 x􏱬 􏱕 u, u􏰫x ~ Normal(0,􏱧2). [17.40] Recall that this is a strong set of assumptions, because u must not only be independent of x, but also normally distributed. We focus on this model because relaxing the assumptions is difficult. Under (17.40) we know that, given a random sample from the population, OLS is the most efficient estimation procedure. The problem arises because we do not observe a ran- dom sample from the population: Assumption MLR.2 is violated. In particular, a random draw (xi, yi) is observed only if yi 􏰯 ci, where ci is the truncation threshold that can depend on exogenous variables—in particular, the xi. (In the Hausman and Wise example, ci de- pends on family size.) This means that, if {(xi, yi): i 􏱪 1, ..., n} is our observed sample, then yi is necessarily less than or equal to ci. This differs from the censored regression model: in a censored regression model, we observe xi for any randomly drawn observation from the population; in the truncated model, we only observe xi if yi 􏰯 ci. To estimate the 􏱬j (along with 􏱧), we need the distribution of yi, given that yi 􏰯 ci and xi. This is written as Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. f(y􏰫x􏱬,􏱧2) __________ g(y􏰫x,c)􏱪 i , y􏰯c, [17.41] i i F(ci􏰫xi􏱬,􏱧2) i 614 PART 3 Advanced Topics where f (y􏰫xi 􏱬,􏱧2) denotes the normal density with mean 􏱬0 􏱕 xi 􏱬 and variance 􏱧2, and F(ci􏰫xi 􏱬,􏱧2) is the normal cdf with the same mean and variance, evaluated at ci. This ex- pression for the density, conditional on yi 􏰯 ci, makes intuitive sense: it is the population density for y, given x, divided by the probability that yi is less than or equal to ci (given xi), P(yi 􏰯 ci􏰫xi). In effect, we renormalize the density by dividing by the area under f (􏱳|xi 􏱬,􏱧2) that is to the left of ci. If we take the log of (17.41), sum across all i, and maximize the result with respect to the 􏱬j and 􏱧2, we obtain the maximum likelihood estimators. This leads to consistent, approximately normal estimators. The inference, including standard errors and log- likelihood statistics, is standard and treated in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19). We could analyze the data from Example 17.4 as a truncated sample if we drop all data on an observation whenever it is censored. This would give us 552 observations from a truncated normal distribution, where the truncation point differs across i. However, we would never analyze duration data (or top-coded data) in this way, as it eliminates use- ful information. The fact that we know a lower bound for 893 durations, along with the explanatory variables, is useful information; censored regression uses this information, while truncated regression does not. A better example of truncated regression is given in Hausman and Wise (1977), where they emphasize that OLS applied to a sample truncated from above generally produces estimators biased toward zero. Intuitively, this makes sense. Suppose that the relation- ship of interest is between income and education levels. If we only observe people whose income is below a certain threshold, we are lopping off the upper end. This tends to flatten the estimated line relative to the true regression line in the whole population. Figure 17.4 illustrates the problem when income is truncated from above at $50,000. Although we F I G U R E 1 7 . 4 A true, or population, regression line and the incorrect regression line for the truncated population with observed incomes below $50,000. income (in thousands 150 of dollars) 50 15 true regression line regression line for truncated population 10 20 education (in years) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 615 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections observe the data points represented by the open circles, we do not observe the data sets represented by the darkened circles. A regression analysis using the truncated sample does not lead to consistent estimators. Incidentally, if the sample in Figure 17.4 were censored rather than truncated—that is, we had top-coded data—we would observe education levels for all points in Figure 17.4, but for individuals with incomes above $50,000 we would not know the exact income amount. We would only know that income was at least $50,000. In effect, all observations represented by the darkened circles would be brought down to the horizontal line at income 􏱪 50. As with censored regression, if the underlying homoskedastic normal assumption in (17.40) is violated, the truncated normal MLE is biased and inconsistent. Methods that do not require these assumptions are available; see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19) for dis- cussion and references. 17.5 Sample Selection Corrections Truncated regression is a special case of a general problem known as nonrandom sample selection. But survey design is not the only cause of nonrandom sample selection. Often, respondents fail to provide answers to certain questions, which leads to missing data for the dependent or independent variables. Because we cannot use these observations in our estimation, we should wonder whether dropping them leads to bias in our estimators. Another general example is usually called incidental truncation. Here, we do not observe y because of the outcome of another variable. The leading example is estimating the so-called wage offer function from labor economics. Interest lies in how various fac- tors, such as education, affect the wage an individual could earn in the labor force. For people who are in the workforce, we observe the wage offer as the current wage. But for those currently out of the workforce, we do not observe the wage offer. Because working may be systematically correlated with unobservables that affect the wage offer, using only working people—as we have in all wage examples so far—might produce biased estima- tors of the parameters in the wage offer equation. Nonrandom sample selection can also arise when we have panel data. In the simplest case, we have two years of data, but, due to attrition, some people leave the sample. This is particularly a problem in policy analysis, where attrition may be related to the effective- ness of a program. When Is OLS on the Selected Sample Consistent? In Section 9.4, we provided a brief discussion of the kinds of sample selection that can be ignored. The key distinction is between exogenous and endogenous sample selection. In the truncated Tobit case, we clearly have endogenous sample selection, and OLS is biased and inconsistent. On the other hand, if our sample is determined solely by an exogenous explanatory variable, we have exogenous sample selection. Cases between these extremes are less clear, and we now provide careful definitions and assumptions for them. The pop- ulation model is y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxk 􏱕 u, E(u􏰫x1, x2, ..., xk) 􏱪 0. [17.42] It is useful to write the population model for a random draw as Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 616 PART 3 Advanced Topics yi 􏱪 xi 􏱬 􏱕 ui, [17.43] where we use xi􏱬 as shorthand for 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xi1 􏱕 􏱬2xi2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬kxik. Now, let n be the size of a random sample from the population. If we could observe yi and each xij for all i, we would simply use OLS. Assume that, for some reason, either yi or some of the independent variables are not observed for certain i. For at least some observations, we observe the full set of variables. Define a selection indicator si for each i by si 􏱪 1 if we observe all of (yi, xi), and si 􏱪 0 otherwise. Thus, si 􏱪 1 indicates that we will use the observation in our analysis; si 􏱪 0 means the observation will not be used. We are interested in the statistical properties of the OLS estimators using the selected sample, that is, using observations for which si 􏱪 1. Therefore, we use fewer than n observations, say, n1. It turns out to be easy to obtain conditions under which OLS is consistent (and even unbiased). Effectively, rather than estimating (17.43), we can only estimate the equation si yi 􏱪 sixi 􏱬 􏱕 siui. [17.44] Whensi 􏱪1,wesimplyhave(17.43);whensi 􏱪0,wesimplyhave0􏱪0􏱕0,which clearly tells us nothing about 􏱬. Regressing si yi on si xi for i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n is the same as regressing yi on xi using the observations for which si 􏱪 1. Thus, we can learn about the consistency of the ˆ􏱬j by studying (17.44) on a random sample. From our analysis in Chapter 5, the OLS estimators from (17.44) are consistent if the error term has zero mean and is uncorrelated with each explanatory variable. In the popu- lation, the zero mean assumption is E(su) 􏱪 0, and the zero correlation assumptions can be stated as E[(sxj)(su)] 􏱪 E(sxju) 􏱪 0, [17.45] where s, xj, and u are random variables representing the population; we have used the fact that s2 􏱪 s because s is a binary variable. Condition (17.45) is different from what we need if we observe all variables for a random sample: E(xju) 􏱪 0. Therefore, in the population, we need u to be uncorrelated with sxj. The key condition for unbiasedness is E(su􏰫sx1, ..., sxk) 􏱪 0. As usual, this is a stron- ger assumption than that needed for consistency. If s is a function only of the explanatory variables, then sxj is just a function of x1, x2, ..., xk; by the conditional mean assumption in (17.42), sxj is also uncorrelated with u. In fact, E(su􏰫sx1, ..., sxk) 􏱪 sE(u􏰫sx1, ..., sxk) 􏱪 0, because E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 0. This is the case of exogenous sample selection, where si 􏱪 1 is determined entirely by xi1, ..., xik. As an example, if we are estimating a wage equation where the explanatory variables are education, experience, tenure, gender, marital status, and so on—which are assumed to be exogenous—we can select the sample on the basis of any or all of the explanatory variables. If sample selection is entirely random in the sense that si is independent of (xi, ui), then E(sxju) 􏱪 E(s)E(xju) 􏱪 0, because E(xju) 􏱪 0 under (17.42). Therefore, if we begin with a random sample and randomly drop observations, OLS is still consistent. In fact, OLS is again unbiased in this case, provided there is not perfect multicollinearity in the selected sample. If s depends on the explanatory variables and additional random terms that are independent of x and u, OLS is also consistent and unbiased. For example, suppose that IQ score is an explanatory variable in a wage equation, but IQ is missing for some people. Suppose we think that selection can be described by s 􏱪 1 if IQ 􏱸 v, and s 􏱪 0 if IQ 􏱷 v, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 617 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections where v is an unobserved random variable that is independent of IQ, u, and the other explanatory variables. This means that we are more likely to observe an IQ that is high, but there is always some chance of not observing any IQ. Conditional on the explanatory variables, s is independent of u, which means that E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk, s) 􏱪 E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk), and the last expectation is zero by assumption on the population model. If we add the homo- skedasticity assumption E(u2􏰫x,s) 􏱪 E(u2) 􏱪 􏱧2, then the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics are valid. So far, we have shown several situations where OLS on the selected sample is unbiased, or at least consistent. When is OLS on the selected sample inconsistent? We already saw one example: regression using a truncated sample. When the truncation is from above, si 􏱪 1 if yi 􏰯 ci, where ci is the truncation threshold. Equivalently, si 􏱪 1 if ui 􏰯 ci 􏱦 xi 􏱬. Because si depends directly on ui, si and ui will not be uncorrelated, even conditional on xi. This is why OLS on the selected sample does not consistently estimate the 􏱬j. There are less obvious ways that s and u can be correlated; we consider this in the next subsection. The results on consistency of OLS extend to instrumental variables estimation. If the IVs are denoted zh in the population, the key condition for consistency of 2SLS is E(szhu) 􏱪 0, which holds if E(u􏰫z,s) 􏱪 0. Therefore, if selection is determined entirely by the exoge- nous variables z, or if s depends on other factors that are independent of u and z, then 2SLS on the selected sample is generally consistent. We do need to assume that the explanatory and instrumental variables are appropriately correlated in the selected part of the popula- tion. Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19) contains precise statements of these assumptions. It can also be shown that, when selection is entirely a function of the exogenous vari- ables, maximum likelihood estimation of a nonlinear model—such as a logit or probit model—produces consistent, asymptotically normal estimators, and the usual standard errors and test statistics are valid. [Again, see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19).] Incidental Truncation As we mentioned earlier, a common form of sample selection is called incidental trunca- tion. We again start with the population model in (17.42). However, we assume that we will always observe the explanatory variables xj. The problem is, we only observe y for a subset of the population. The rule determining whether we observe y does not depend di- rectly on the outcome of y. A leading example is when y 􏱪 log(wageo), where wageo is the wage offer, or the hourly wage that an individual could receive in the labor market. If the person is actually working at the time of the survey, then we observe the wage offer be- cause we assume it is the observed wage. But for people out of the workforce, we cannot observe wageo. Therefore, the truncation of wage offer is incidental because it depends on another variable, namely, labor force participation. Importantly, we would generally observe all other information about an individual, such as education, prior experience, gender, marital status, and so on. The usual approach to incidental truncation is to add an explicit selection equation to the population model of interest: y 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 u, E(u􏰫x) 􏱪 0 [17.46] s 􏱪 1[z􏰿 􏱕 v 􏱸 0], [17.47] where s 􏱪 1 if we observe y, and zero otherwise. We assume that elements of x and z are al- waysobserved,andwewritex􏱬􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxk andz􏰿􏱪􏰿0 􏱕􏰿1z1 􏱕...􏱕􏰿mzm. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 618 PART 3 Advanced Topics The equation of primary interest is (17.46), and we could estimate 􏱬 by OLS given a random sample. The selection equation, (17.47), depends on observed variables, zh, and an unobserved error, v. A standard assumption, which we will make, is that z is exog- enous in (17.46): E(u􏰫x,z) 􏱪 0. In fact, for the following proposed methods to work well, we will require that x be a strict subset of z: any xj is also an element of z, and we have some elements of z that are not also in x. We will see later why this is crucial. The error term v in the sample selection equation is assumed to be independent of z (and therefore x). We also assume that v has a standard normal distribution. We can easily see that correlation between u and v generally causes a sample selection problem. To see why, assume that (u, v) is independent of z. Then, taking the expectation of (17.46), conditional on z and v, and using the fact that x is a subset of z gives E(y􏰫z,v) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 E(u􏰫z,v) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 E(u􏰫v), where E(u􏰫z,v) 􏱪 E(u􏰫v) because (u, v) is independent of z. Now, if u and v are jointly nor- mal (with zero mean), then E(u􏰫v) 􏱪 􏰴v for some parameter 􏰴. Therefore, E(y􏰫z,v) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 􏰴v. We do not observe v, but we can use this equation to compute E(y􏰫z,s) and then specialize this to s 􏱪 1. We now have: E(y􏰫z,s) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 􏰴E(v􏰫z,s). Because s and v are related by (17.47), and v has a standard normal distribution, we can show that E(v􏰫z,s) is simply the inverse Mills ratio, 􏲇(z􏰸), when s 􏱪 1. This leads to the important equation E(y􏰫z,s 􏱪 1) 􏱪 x􏱬 􏱕 􏰴􏰮(z􏰸). [17.48] Equation (17.48) shows that the expected value of y, given z and observability of y, is equal to x􏱬, plus an additional term that depends on the inverse Mills ratio evaluated at z􏰸. Remember, we hope to estimate 􏱬. This equation shows that we can do so using only the selected sample, provided we include the term 􏲇(z􏰸) as an additional regressor. If 􏰴 􏱪 0, 􏲇(z􏰸) does not appear, and OLS of y on x using the selected sample consis- tently estimates 􏱬. Otherwise, we have effectively omitted a variable, 􏲇(z􏰸), which is gen- erally correlated with x. When does 􏰴 􏱪 0? The answer is when u and v are uncorrelated. Because 􏰸 is unknown, we cannot evaluate 􏲇(zi􏰸) for each i. However, from the as- sumptions we have made, s given z follows a probit model: P(s 􏱪 1􏰫z) 􏱪 􏱋(z􏰸). [17.49] Therefore, we can estimate 􏰸 by probit of si on zi, using the entire sample. In a second step, we can estimate 􏱬. We summarize the procedure, which has recently been dubbed the Heckit method in econometrics literature after the work of Heckman (1976). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 619 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections Sample Selection Correction: (i) Using all n observations, estimate a probit model of si on zi and obtain the esti- mates ˆ􏰿h. Compute the inverse Mills ratio, ˆ􏲇i 􏱪 􏲇(ziˆ􏰸) for each i. (Actually, we need these only for the i with si 􏱪 1.) (ii) Using the selected sample, that is, the observations for which si 􏱪 1 (say, n1 of them), run the regression of yi on xi, ˆ􏲇i. [17.50] The ˆ􏱬j are consistent and approximately normally distributed. A simple test of selection bias is available from regression (17.50). Namely, we can use the usual t statistic on ˆ􏲇i as a test of H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0. Under H0, there is no sample selection problem. When 􏰴 􏱻 0, the usual OLS standard errors reported from (17.50) are not exactly cor- rect. This is because they do not account for estimation of 􏰸, which uses the same obser- vations in regression (17.50), and more. Some econometrics packages compute corrected standard errors. [Unfortunately, it is not as simple as a heteroskedasticity adjustment. See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 6) for further discussion.] In many cases, the adjustments do not lead to important differences, but it is hard to know that beforehand (unless ˆ􏰴 is small and insignificant). We recently mentioned that x should be a strict subset of z. This has two implica- tions. First, any element that appears as an explanatory variable in (17.46) should also be an explanatory variable in the selection equation. Although in rare cases it makes sense to exclude elements from the selection equation, including all elements of x in z is not very costly; excluding them can lead to inconsistency if they are incorrectly excluded. A second major implication is that we have at least one element of z that is not also in x. This means that we need a variable that affects selection but does not have a partial effect on y. This is not absolutely necessary to apply the procedure—in fact, we can me- chanically carry out the two steps when z 􏱪 x—but the results are usually less than con- vincing unless we have an exclusion restriction in (17.46). The reason for this is that while the inverse Mills ratio is a nonlinear function of z, it is often well approximated by a linear function. If z 􏱪 x, ˆ􏲇i can be highly correlated with the elements of xi. As we know, such multicollinearity can lead to very high standard errors for the ˆ􏱬j. Intuitively, if we do not have a variable that affects selection but not y, it is extremely difficult, if not impossible, to distinguish sample selection from a misspecified functional form in (17.46). EXAMPLE 17.5 WAGE OFFER EQUATION FOR MARRIED WOMEN We apply the sample selection correction to the data on married women in MROZ.RAW. Recall that of the 753 women in the sample, 428 worked for a wage during the year. The wage offer equation is standard, with log(wage) as the dependent variable and educ, exper, and exper2 as the explanatory variables. In order to test and correct for sample selection bias—due to unobservability of the wage offer for nonworking women—we need to esti- mate a probit model for labor force participation. In addition to the education and experi- ence variables, we include the factors in Table 17.1: other income, age, number of young children, and number of older children. The fact that these four variables are excluded from the wage offer equation is an assumption: we assume that, given the productivity factors, nwifeinc, age, kidslt6, and kidsge6 have no effect on the wage offer. It is clear from the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 620 PART 3 Advanced Topics probit results in Table 17.1 that at least age and kidslt6 have a strong effect on labor force participation. Table 17.5 contains the results from OLS and Heckit. [The standard errors reported for the Heckit results are just the usual OLS standard errors from regression (17.50).] There is no evidence of a sample selection problem in estimating the wage offer equa- tion. The coefficient on ˆ􏲇 has a very small t statistic (.239), so we fail to reject H0: 􏰴 􏱪 0. Just as importantly, there are no practically large differences in the estimated slope coef- ficients in Table 17.5. The estimated returns to education differ by only one-tenth of a percentage point. TABLE 17.5 Wage Offer Equation for Married Women Dependent Variable: log(wage) Independent Variables OLS Heckit educ .108 (.014) .109 (.016) exper .042 .044 (.012) (.016) exper2 􏱦.00081 (.00039) 􏱦.00086 (.00044) constant 􏱦.522 􏱦.578 (.199) (.307) ˆ􏲇 — .032 (.134) Sample size R-squared 428 428 .157 .157 An alternative to the preceding two-step estimation method is full maximum likeli- hood estimation. This is more complicated as it requires obtaining the joint distribution of y and s. It often makes sense to test for sample selection using the previous procedure; if there is no evidence of sample selection, there is no reason to continue. If we detect sample selection bias, we can either use the two-step estimates or estimate the regression and selection equations jointly by MLE. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19).] In Example 17.5, we know more than just whether a woman worked during the year: we know how many hours each woman worked. It turns out that we can use this informa- tion in an alternative sample selection procedure. In place of the inverse Mills ratio ˆ􏲇i, we use the Tobit residuals, say, vˆi, which are computed as vˆi 􏱪 yi 􏱦 xi􏱬ˆ whenever yi 􏱰 0. It can be shown that the regression in (17.50) with vˆi in place of ˆ􏲇i also produces consis- tent estimates of the 􏱬j, and the standard t statistic on vˆi is a valid test for sample selection bias. This approach has the advantage of using more information, but it is less widely applicable. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19).] There are many more topics concerning sample selection. One worth mentioning is models with endogenous explanatory variables in addition to possible sample selection bias. Write a model with a single endogenous explanatory variable as y1 􏱪 􏱮1y2 􏱕 z1􏱬1 􏱕 u1, [17.51] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 621 where y1 is only observed when s 􏱪 1, and y2 may only be observed along with y1. An example is when y1 is the percentage of votes received by an incumbent, and y2 is the percentage of total expenditures accounted for by the incumbent. For incumbents who do not run, we cannot observe y1 or y2. If we have exogenous factors that affect the deci- sion to run and that are correlated with campaign expenditures, we can consistently es- timate 􏱮1 and the elements of 􏱬1 by instrumental variables. To be convincing, we need two exogenous variables that do not appear in (17.51). Effectively, one should affect the selection decision, and one should be correlated with y2 [the usual requirement for estimat- ing (17.51) by 2SLS]. Briefly, the method is to estimate the selection equation by probit, where all exogenous variables appear in the probit equation. Then, we add the inverse Mills ratio to (17.51) and estimate the equation by 2SLS. The inverse Mills ratio acts as its own instrument, as it depends only on exogenous variables. We use all exogenous variables as the other instruments. As before, we can use the t statistic on ˆ􏲇i as a test for selection bias. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 19) for further information.] Summary In this chapter, we have covered several advanced methods that are often used in applications, especially in microeconomics. Logit and probit models are used for binary response variables. These models have some advantages over the linear probability model: fitted probabilities are between zero and one, and the partial effects diminish. The primary cost to logit and probit is that they are harder to interpret. The Tobit model is applicable to nonnegative outcomes that pile up at zero but also take on a broad range of positive values. Many individual choice variables, such as labor sup- ply, amount of life insurance, and amount of pension fund invested in stocks, have this fea- ture. As with logit and probit, the expected values of y given x—either conditional on y 􏱰 0 or unconditionally—depend on x and 􏱬 in nonlinear ways. We gave the expressions for these expectations as well as formulas for the partial effects of each xj on the expectations. These can be estimated after the Tobit model has been estimated by maximum likelihood. When the dependent variable is a count variable—that is, it takes on nonnegative, integer values—a Poisson regression model is appropriate. The expected value of y given the xj has an exponential form. This gives the parameter interpretations as semi-elasticities or elasticities, depending on whether xj is in level or logarithmic form. In short, we can interpret the param- eters as if they are in a linear model with log(y) as the dependent variable. The parameters can be estimated by MLE. However, because the Poisson distribution imposes equality of the vari- ance and mean, it is often necessary to compute standard errors and test statistics that allow for over- or underdispersion. These are simple adjustments to the usual MLE standard errors and statistics. Censored and truncated regression models handle specific kinds of missing data problems. In censored regression, the dependent variable is censored above or below a threshold. We can use information on the censored outcomes because we always observe the explanatory variables, as in duration applications or top coding of observations. A truncated regression model arises when a part of the population is excluded entirely: we observe no information on units that are not covered by the sampling scheme. This is a special case of a sample selection problem. Section 17.5 gave a systematic treatment of nonrandom sample selection. We showed that exogenous sample selection does not affect consistency of OLS when it is applied to the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 622 PART 3 Advanced Topics Problems 1 (i) For a binary response y, let y- be the proportion of ones in the sample (which is equal to the sample average of the yi). Let qˆ0 be the percent correctly predicted for the outcome y 􏱪 0 and let qˆ1 be the percent correctly predicted for the outcome y 􏱪 1. If pˆ is the overall percent correctly predicted, show that ˆp is a weighted average of qˆ0 and qˆ1: pˆ􏱪(1􏱦y-)qˆ0 􏱕y-qˆ1. subsample, but endogenous sample selection does. We showed how to test and correct for sample selection bias for the general problem of incidental truncation, where observations are missing on y due to the outcome of another variable (such as labor force participation). Heck- man’s method is relatively easy to implement in these situations. Key Terms Average Partial Effect (APE) Binary Response Models Censored Normal Regression Model Censored Regression Model Corner Solution Response Count Variable Duration Analysis Exogenous Sample Selection Heckit Method Incidental Truncation Inverse Mills Ratio Latent Variable Model Likelihood Ratio Statistic Limited Dependent Variable (LDV) Logit Model Log-Likelihood Function Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE) Nonrandom Sample Selection Overdispersion Partial Effect at the Average (PEA) Percent Correctly Predicted Poisson Distribution Poisson Regression Model Probit Model Pseudo R-Squared Quasi-Likelihood Ratio Statistic Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimation (QMLE) Response Probability Selected Sample Tobit Model Top Coding Truncated Normal Regression Model Truncated Regression Model Wald Statistic (ii) In a sample of 300, suppose that y- 􏱪 .70, so that there are 210 outcomes with yi 􏱪 1 and 90 with yi 􏱪 0. Suppose that the percent correctly predicted when y 􏱪 0 is 80, and the percent correctly predicted when y 􏱪 1 is 40. Find the overall percent cor- rectly predicted. 2 Let grad be a dummy variable for whether a student-athlete at a large university gradu- ates in five years. Let hsGPA and SAT be high school grade point average and SAT score, respectively. Let study be the number of hours spent per week in an organized study hall. Suppose that, using data on 420 student-athletes, the following logit model is obtained: Pˆ(grad 􏱪 1􏰫hsGPA,SAT,study) 􏱪 􏱎(􏱦1.17 􏱕 .24 hsGPA 􏱕 .00058 SAT 􏱕 .073 study), where 􏱎(z) 􏱪 exp(z)/[1 􏱕 exp(z)] is the logit function. Holding hsGPA fixed at 3.0 and SAT fixed at 1,200, compute the estimated difference in the graduation probability for someone who spent 10 hours per week in study hall and someone who spent 5 hours per week. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 623 3 (Requires calculus) (i) Suppose in the Tobit model that x1 􏱪 log(z1), and this is the only place z1 appears in x. Show that ∂E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) _____________􏱪 (􏱬1/z1){1 􏱦 􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧)[x􏱬/􏱧 􏱕 􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧)]}, [17.52] 4 Let mvpi be the marginal value product for worker i, which is the price of a firm’s good multiplied by the marginal product of the worker. Assume that log(mvpi)􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1xi1 􏱕...􏱕􏱬kxik 􏱕ui wagei 􏱪 max(mvpi,minwagei), where the explanatory variables include education, experience, and so on, and minwagei is the minimum wage relevant for person i. Write log(wagei) in terms of log(mvpi) and log(minwagei). 5 (Requires calculus) Let patents be the number of patents applied for by a firm during a given year. Assume that the conditional expectation of patents given sales and RD is E(patents􏰫sales,RD) 􏱪 exp[􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(sales) 􏱕 􏱬2RD 􏱕 􏱬3RD2], where sales is annual firm sales and RD is total spending on research and development over the past 10 years. (i) How would you estimate the 􏱬j? Justify your answer by discussing the nature of patents. (ii) How do you interpret 􏱬1? (iii) Find the partial effect of RD on E(patents􏰫sales, RD). 6 Consider a family saving function for the population of all families in the United States: sav 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1inc 􏱕 􏱬2hhsize 􏱕 􏱬3educ 􏱕 􏱬4age 􏱕 u, where hhsize is household size, educ is years of education of the household head, and age is age of the household head. Assume that E(u􏰫inc,hhsize,educ,age) 􏱪 0. (i) Suppose that the sample includes only families whose head is over 25 years old. If we use OLS on such a sample, do we get unbiased estimators of the 􏱬j? Explain. (ii) Now, suppose our sample includes only married couples without children. Can we estimate all of the parameters in the saving equation? Which ones can we estimate? (iii) Suppose we exclude from our sample families that save more than $25,000 per year. Does OLS produce consistent estimators of the 􏱬j? 7 Suppose you are hired by a university to study the factors that determine whether students admitted to the university actually come to the university. You are given a large random sample of students who were admitted the previous year. You have information on whether Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∂z1 where 􏱬1 is the coefficient on log(z1). (ii) If x1 􏱪 z1, and x2 􏱪 z12, show that ∂E(y􏰫y 􏱰 0,x) ____________ 􏱪 (􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2z1){1 􏱦 􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧)[x􏱬/􏱧 􏱕 􏲇(x􏱬/􏱧)]}, ∂z1 where 􏱬1 is the coefficient on z1 and 􏱬2 is the coefficient on z12. 624 PART 3 Advanced Topics each student chose to attend, high school performance, family income, financial aid of- fered, race, and geographic variables. Someone says to you, “Any analysis of that data will lead to biased results because it is not a random sample of all college applicants, but only those who apply to this university.” What do you think of this criticism? Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in PNTSPRD.RAW for this exercise. (i) The variable favwin is a binary variable if the team favored by the Las Vegas point spread wins. A linear probability model to estimate the probability that the favored team wins is P( favwin 􏱪 1􏰫spread ) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1spread. Explain why, if the spread incorporates all relevant information, we expect 􏱬0 􏱪 .5. (ii) Estimate the model from part (i) by OLS. Test H0: 􏱬0 􏱪 .5 against a two-sided alternative. Use both the usual and heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. (iii) Is spread statistically significant? What is the estimated probability that the favored team wins when spread 􏱪 10? (iv) Now, estimate a probit model for P( favwin 􏱪 1􏰫spread ). Interpret and test the null hypothesis that the intercept is zero. [Hint: Remember that 􏱋(0) 􏱪 .5.] (v) Use the probit model to estimate the probability that the favored team wins when spread 􏱪 10. Compare this with the LPM estimate from part (iii). (vi) Add the variables favhome, fav25, and und25 to the probit model and test joint sig- nificance of these variables using the likelihood ratio test. (How many df are in the chi-square distribution?) Interpret this result, focusing on the question of whether the spread incorporates all observable information prior to a game. C2 Use the data in LOANAPP.RAW for this exercise; see also Computer Exercise C8 in Chapter 7. (i) Estimate a probit model of approve on white. Find the estimated probability of loan approval for both whites and nonwhites. How do these compare with the linear probability estimates? (ii) Now, add the variables hrat, obrat, loanprc, unem, male, married, dep, sch, cosign, chist, pubrec, mortlat1, mortlat2, and vr to the probit model. Is there statistically significant evidence of discrimination against nonwhites? (iii) Estimate the model from part (ii) by logit. Compare the coefficient on white to the probit estimate. (iv) Use equation (17.17) to estimate the sizes of the discrimination effects for probit and logit. C3 Use the data in FRINGE.RAW for this exercise. (i) For what percentage of the workers in the sample is pension equal to zero? What is the range of pension for workers with nonzero pension benefits? Why is a Tobit model appropriate for modeling pension? (ii) Estimate a Tobit model explaining pension in terms of exper, age, tenure, educ, depends, married, white, and male. Do whites and males have statistically signifi- cant higher expected pension benefits? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 625 (iii) Use the results from part (ii) to estimate the difference in expected pension benefits for a white male and a nonwhite female, both of whom are 35 years old, are single with no dependents, have 16 years of education, and have 10 years of experience. (iv) Add union to the Tobit model and comment on its significance. (v) Apply the Tobit model from part (iv) but with peratio, the pension-earnings ratio, as the dependent variable. (Notice that this is a fraction between zero and one, but, though it often takes on the value zero, it never gets close to being unity. Thus, a Tobit model is fine as an approximation.) Does gender or race have an effect on the pension-earnings ratio? C4 In Example 9.1, we added the quadratic terms pcnv2, ptime862, and inc862 to a linear model for narr86. (i) Use the data in CRIME1.RAW to add these same terms to the Poisson regression in Example 17.3. 􏰭n (ii) Compute the estimate of 􏱧2 given by ˆ􏱧2 􏱪 (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)􏱦1 i􏱪1 ˆu2i /yˆi. Is there evidence of overdispersion? How should the Poisson MLE standard errors be adjusted? (iii) Use the results from parts (i) and (ii) and Table 17.3 to compute the quasi- likelihood ratio statistic for joint significance of the three quadratic terms. What do you conclude? C5 Refer to Table 13.1 in Chapter 13. There, we used the data in FERTIL1.RAW to esti- mate a linear model for kids, the number of children ever born to a woman. (i) Estimate a Poisson regression model for kids, using the same variables in Table 13.1. Interpret the coefficient on y82. (ii) What is the estimated percentage difference in fertility between a black woman and a nonblack woman, holding other factors fixed? (iii) Obtain ˆ􏱧. Is there evidence of over- or underdispersion? (iv) Compute the fitted values from the Poisson regression and obtain the R-squared as the squared correlation between kidsi and 􏱾kidsi.. Compare this with the R-squared for the linear regression model. C6 Use the data in RECID.RAW to estimate the model from Example 17.4 by OLS, using only the 552 uncensored durations. Comment generally on how these estimates compare with those in Table 17.4. C7 Use the MROZ.RAW data for this exercise. (i) Using the 428 women who were in the workforce, estimate the return to education by OLS including exper, exper2, nwifeinc, age, kidslt6, and kidsge6 as explanatory variables. Report your estimate on educ and its standard error. (ii) Now, estimate the return to education by Heckit, where all exogenous variables show up in the second-stage regression. In other words, the regression is log(wage) on educ, exper, exper2, nwifeinc, age, kidslt6, kidsge6, and ˆ􏲇. Compare the estimated return to education and its standard error to that from part (i). (iii) Using only the 428 observations for working women, regress ˆ􏲇 on educ, exper, exper2, nwifeinc, age, kidslt6, and kidsge6. How big is the R-squared? How does this help explain your findings from part (ii)? (Hint: Think multicollinearity.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 626 PART 3 Advanced Topics C8 The file JTRAIN2.RAW contains data on a job training experiment for a group of men. Men could enter the program starting in January 1976 through about mid-1977. The program ended in December 1977. The idea is to test whether participation in thejob training program had an effect on unemployment probabilities and earnings in 1978. (i) The variable train is the job training indicator. How many men in the sample participated in the job training program? What was the highest number of months a man actually participated in the program? (ii) Run a linear regression of train on several demographic and pretraining variables: unem74, unem75, age, educ, black, hisp, and married. Are these variables jointly significant at the 5% level? (iii) Estimate a probit version of the linear model in part (ii). Compute the likelihood ratio test for joint significance of all variables. What do you conclude? (iv) Based on your answers to parts (ii) and (iii), does it appear that participation in job training can be treated as exogenous for explaining 1978 unemployment status? Explain. (v) Run a simple regression of unem78 on train and report the results in equation form. What is the estimated effect of participating in the job training program on the probability of being unemployed in 1978? Is it statistically significant? (vi) Run a probit of unem78 on train. Does it make sense to compare the probit coefficient on train with the coefficient obtained from the linear model in part (v)? (vii) Find the fitted probabilities from parts (v) and (vi). Explain why they are identical. Which approach would you use to measure the effect and statistical significance of the job training program? (viii) Add all of the variables from part (ii) as additional controls to the models from parts (v) and (vi). Are the fitted probabilities now identical? What is the correla- tion between them? (ix) Using the model from part (viii), estimate the average partial effect of train on the 1978 unemployment probability. Use (17.17) with ck 􏱪 0. How does the estimate compare with the OLS estimate from part (viii)? C9 Use the data in APPLE.RAW for this exercise. These are telephone survey data attempt- ing to elicit the demand for a (fictional) “ecologically friendly” apple. Each family was (randomly) presented with a set of prices for regular apples and the eco-labeled apples. They were asked how many pounds of each kind of apple they would buy. (i) Of the 660 families in the sample, how many report wanting none of the eco-labeled apples at the set price? (ii) Does the variable ecolbs seem to have a continuous distribution over strictly positive values? What implications does your answer have for the suitability of a Tobit model for ecolbs? (iii) Estimate a Tobit model for ecolbs with ecoprc, regprc, faminc, and hhsize as explanatory variables. Which variables are significant at the 1% level? (iv) Are faminc and hhsize jointly significant? (v) Are the signs of the coefficients on the price variables from part (iii) what you expect? Explain. (vi) Let 􏱬1 be the coefficient on ecoprc and let 􏱬2 be the coefficient on regprc. Test the hypothesis H0: 􏱦 􏱬1 􏱪 􏱬2 against the two-sided alternative. Report the p-value of the test. (You might want to refer to Section 4.4 if your regression package does not easily compute such tests.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 627 (vii) Obtain the estimates of E(ecolbs􏰫x) for all observations in the sample. [See equation (17.25).] Call these 􏱾ecolbsi.What are the smallest and largest fitted values? 􏱾 (viii) Compute the squared correlation between ecolbsi and ecolbsi . (ix) Now, estimate a linear model for ecolbs using the same explanatory variables from part (iii). Why are the OLS estimates so much smaller than the Tobit estimates? In terms of goodness-of-fit, is the Tobit model better than the linear model? (x) Evaluate the following statement: “Because the R-squared from the Tobit model is so small, the estimated price effects are probably inconsistent.” the data in SMOKE.RAW for this exercise. C10 Use (i) The variable cigs is the number of cigarettes smoked per day. How many people in the sample do not smoke at all? What fraction of people claim to smoke 20 cigarettes a day? Why do you think there is a pileup of people at 20 cigarettes? (ii) Given your answers to part (i), does cigs seem a good candidate for having a conditional Poisson distribution? (iii) Estimate a Poisson regression model for cigs, including log(cigpric), log(income), white, educ, age, and age2 as explanatory variables. What are the estimated price and income elasticities? (iv) Using the maximum likelihood standard errors, are the price and income variables statistically significant at the 5% level? (v) Obtain the estimate of 􏱧2 described after equation (17.35). What is 􏱧ˆ? How should you adjust the standard errors from part (iv)? (vi) Using the adjusted standard errors from part (v), are the price and income elastici- ties now statistically different from zero? Explain. (vii) Are the education and age variables significant using the more robust standard errors? How do you interpret the coefficient on educ? (viii) Obtain the fitted values, yˆi, from the Poisson regression model. Find the minimum and maximum values and discuss how well the exponential model predicts heavy cigarette smoking. (ix) Using the fitted values from part (viii), obtain the squared correlation coefficient between yˆi and yi. (x) Estimate a linear model for cigs by OLS, using the explanatory variables (and same functional forms) as in part (iii). Does the linear model or exponential model provide a better fit? Is either R-squared very large? C11 Use the data in CPS91.RAW for this exercise. These data are for married women, where we also have information on each husband’s income and demographics. (i) What fraction of the women report being in the labor force? (ii) Using only the data for working women—you have no choice—estimate the wage equation log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 􏱬2exper 􏱕 􏱬3exper2 􏱕 􏱬4black 􏱕 􏱬5hispanic 􏱕 u by ordinary least squares. Report the results in the usual form. Do there appear to be significant wage differences by race and ethnicity? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 628 PART 3 Advanced Topics (iii) Estimate a probit model for inlf that includes the explanatory variables in the wage equation from part (ii) as well as nwifeinc and kidlt6. Do these last two variables have coefficients of the expected sign? Are they statistically significant? (iv) Explain why, for the purposes of testing and, possibly, correcting the wage equation for selection into the workforce, it is important for nwifeinc and kidlt6 to help explain inlf. What must you assume about nwifeinc and kidlt6 in the wage equation? (v) Compute the inverse Mills ratio (for each observation) and add it as an additional regressor to the wage equation from part (ii). What is its two-sided p-value? Do you think this is particularly small with 3,286 observations? (vi) Does adding the inverse Mills ratio change the coefficients in the wage regression in important ways? Explain. C12 Use (i) The variable respond is a binary variable equal to one if an individual responded the data in CHARITY.RAW to answer these questions. with a donation to the most recent request. The database consists only of people who have responded at least once in the past. What fraction of people responded most recently? (ii) Estimate a probit model for respond, using resplast, weekslast, propresp, mails- year, and avggift as explanatory variables. Which of the explanatory variables is statistically significant? (iii) Find the average partial effect for mailsyear and compare it with the coefficient from a linear probability model. (iv) Using the same explanatory variables, estimate a Tobit model for gift, the amount of the most recent gift (in Dutch guilders). Now which explanatory variable is statistically significant? (v) Compare the Tobit APE for mailsyear with that from a linear regression. Are they similar? (vi) Are the estimates from parts (ii) and (iv) entirely compatible with at Tobit model? Explain. C13 Use (i) Using OLS on the full sample, estimate a model for log(wage) using explanatory variables educ, abil, exper, nc, west, south, and urban. Report the estimated return to education and its standard error. (ii) Now estimate the equation from part (i) using only people with educ 􏱷 16. What percentage of the sample is lost? Now what is the estimated return to a year of schooling? How does it compare with part (i)? (iii) Nowdropallobservationswithwage􏱸20,sothateveryoneremaininginthesam- ple earns less than $20 an hour. Run the regression from part (i) and comment on the coefficient on educ. (Because the normal truncated regression model assumes that y is continuous, it does not matter in theory whether we drop observations with wage 􏱸 20 or wage 􏱰 20. In practice, including in this application, it can matter slightly because there are some people who earn exactly $20 per hour.) (iv) Using the sample in part (iii), apply truncated regression [with the upper trunca- tion point being log(20)]. Does truncated regression appear to recover the return to education in the full population, assuming the estimate from (i) is consistent? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in HTV.RAW to answer this question. CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 629 C14 Use the data in HAPPINESS.RAW for this question. See also Computer Exercise C15 in Chapter 13. (i) Estimate a probit probability model relating vhappy to occattend and regattend, and include a full set of year dummies. Find the average partial effects for occat- tend and regattend. How do these compare with those from estimating a linear probability model? (ii) Define a variable, highinc, equal to one if family income is above $25,000. Include highinc, unem10, educ, and teens to the probit estimation in part (ii). Is the APE of regattend affected much? What about its statistical significance? (iii) Discuss the APEs and statistical significance of the four new variables in part (ii). Do the estimates make sense? (iv) Controlling for the factors in part (ii), do there appear to be differences in happi- ness by gender or race? Justify your answer. C15 Use the data set in ALCOHOL.RAW, obtained from Terza (2002), to answer this ques- tion. The data, on 9,822 men, includes labor market information, whether the man abuses alcohol, and demographic and background variables. In this question you will study the effects of alcohol abuse on employ, which is a binary variable equal to one if the man has a job. If employ 􏱪 0 the man is either unemployed or not in the workforce. (i) What fraction of the sample is employed at the time of the interview? What fraction of the sample has abused alcohol? (ii) Run the simple regression of employ on abuse and report the results in the usual form, obtaining the heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors. Interpret the estimated equation. Is the relationship as you expected? Is it statistically significant? (iii) Run a probit of employ on abuse. Do you get the same sign and statistical significance as in part (ii)? How does the average partial effect for the probit compare with that for the linear probability model? (iv) Obtain the fitted values for the LPM estimated in part (ii) and report what they are when abuse 􏱪 0 and when abuse 􏱪 1. How do these compare to the probit fitted values, and why? (v) To the LPM in part (ii) add the variables age, agesq, educ, educsq, married, famsize, white, northeast, midwest, south, centcity, outercity, qrt1, qrt2, and qrt3. What happens to the coefficient on abuse and its statistical significance? (vi) Estimate a probit model using the variables in part (v). Find the APE of abuse and its t statistic. Is the estimated effect now identical to that for the linear model? Is it “close”? (vii) Variables indicating the overall health of each man are also included in the data set. Is it obvious that such variables should be included as controls? Explain. (viii) Why might abuse be properly thought of as endogenous in the employ equation? Do you think the variables mothalc and fathalc, indicating whether a man’s mother or father were alcoholics, are sensible instrumental variables for abuse? (ix) Estimate the LPM underlying part (v) by 2SLS, where mothalc and fathalc act as IVs for abuse. Is the difference between the 2SLS and OLS coefficients practically large? (x) Use the test described in Section 15.5 to test whether abuse is endogenous in the LPM. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 630 PART 3 Advanced Topics APPENDIX 17A 17A.1 Maximum Likelihood Estimation with Explanatory Variables Appendix C provides a review of maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) in the simplest case of estimating the parameters in an unconditional distribution. But most models in econometrics have explanatory variables, whether we estimate those models by OLS or MLE. The latter is indispensable for nonlinear models, and here we provide a very brief description of the general approach. All of the models covered in this chapter can be put in the following form. Let f (y|x,􏱬) denote the density function for a random draw yi from the population, conditional on xi 􏱪 x. The maximum likelihood estimator (MLE) of 􏱬 maximizes the log-likelihood function, [17.53] max log f (y |x , b), b i􏱪1 ∑n ii where the vector b is the dummy argument in the maximization problem. In most cases, the MLE, which we write as 􏱬ˆ, is consistent and has an approximate normal distribution in large samples. This is true even though we cannot write down a formula for 􏱬ˆ except in very special circumstances. For the binary response case (logit and probit), the conditional density is determined by two values, f(1|x,􏱬) 􏱪 P(yi 􏱪 1|xi) 􏱪 G(xi􏱬) and f(0|x,􏱬) 􏱪 P(yi 􏱪 0|xi) 􏱪 1 􏱦 G(xi􏱬). In fact, a succinct way to write the density is f(y|x,􏱬) 􏱪 [1 􏱦 G(x􏱬)](1􏱦y)[G(x􏱬)]y for y 􏱪 0, 1. Thus, we can write (17.53) as max {(1 􏱦 y ) log[1 􏱦 G(x b)] 􏱕 y log[G(x b)]}. b i􏱪1 ∑n iiii [17.54] Generally, the solutions to (17.54) are quickly found by modern computers using iterative methods to maximize a function. The total computation time even for fairly large data sets is typically quite low. The log-likelihood function for the Tobit model and for censored and truncated regression are only slightly more complicated, depending on an additional variance parameter in addition to 􏱬. They are easily derived from the densities obtained in the text. See Wooldridge (2010) for details. APPENDIX 17B 17B.1 Asymptotic Standard Errors in Limited Dependent Variable Models Derivations of the asymptotic standard errors for the models and methods introduced in this chapter are well beyond the scope of this text. Not only do the derivations require matrix algebra, but they also require advanced asymptotic theory of nonlinear estimation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 17 Limited Dependent Variable Models and Sample Selection Corrections 631 The background needed for a careful analysis of these methods and several derivations are given in Wooldridge (2010). It is instructive to see the formulas for obtaining the asymptotic standard errors for at least some of the methods. Given the binary response model P(y 􏱪 1􏰫x) 􏱪 G(x􏱬), where G(􏱳) is the logit or probit function, and 􏱬 is the k 􏱶 1 vector of parameters, the asymptotic variance matrix of ˆ􏱬 is estimated as [17.55] which is a k 􏱶 k matrix. (See Appendix D for a summary of matrix algebra.) Without the terms involving g(􏱳) and G(􏱳), this formula looks a lot like the estimated variance matrix for the OLS estimator, minus the term ˆ􏱧2. The expression in (17.55) accounts for the nonlinear nature of the response probability—that is, the nonlinear nature of G(􏱳)—as well as the particular form of heteroskedasticity in a binary response model: Var(y􏰫x) 􏱪 G(x􏱬)[1 􏱦 G(x􏱬)]. The square roots of the diagonal elements of (17.55) are the asymptotic standard errors of the 􏱬ˆj, and they are routinely reported by econometrics software that supports logit and probit analysis. Once we have these, (asymptotic) t statistics and confidence intervals are obtained in the usual ways. The matrix in (17.55) is also the basis for Wald tests of multiple restrictions on 􏱬 [see Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 15)]. The asymptotic variance matrix for Tobit is more complicated but has a similar struc- ture. Note that we can obtain a standard error for ˆ􏱧 as well. The asymptotic variance for Poisson regression, allowing for 􏱧2 􏱻 1 in (17.35), has a form much like (17.55): 􏱾ˆ2∑n ˆ􏱦1 Avar(􏱬)􏱪ˆ􏱧 􏱵 exp(xi􏱬)x􏲃ixi􏱷 . [17.56] i􏱪1 The square roots of the diagonal elements of this matrix are the asymptotic standard errors. If the Poisson assumption holds, we can drop ˆ􏱧2 from the formula (because 􏱧2 􏱪 1). Asymptotic standard errors for censored regression, truncated regression, and the Heckit sample selection correction are more complicated, although they share features with the previous formulas. [See Wooldridge (2010) for details.] 􏱾Avar(􏱬ˆ) 􏱲 [g(x 􏱬)] x􏲃x ________i_____i__i___ , 􏱕n ˆ2 􏱦􏱦1 ∑ i􏱪1 G(xi 􏱬)[1 􏱦 G(xi 􏱬)] ˆˆ Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 632 Advanced Time Series Topics 18 CHAPTER In this chapter, we cover some more advanced topics in time series econometrics. In Chapters 10, 11, and 12, we emphasized in several places that using time series data in regression analysis requires some care due to the trending, persistent nature of many eco- nomic time series. In addition to studying topics such as infinite distributed lag models and fore- casting, we also discuss some recent advances in analyzing time series processes with unit roots. In Section 18.1, we describe infinite distributed lag models, which allow a change in an explanatory variable to affect all future values of the dependent variable. Conceptually, these models are straightforward extensions of the finite distributed lag models in Chapter 10, but estimating these models poses some interesting challenges. In Section 18.2, we show how to formally test for unit roots in a time series process. Recall from Chapter 11 that we excluded unit root processes to apply the usual asymptotic theory. Because the presence of a unit root implies that a shock today has a long-lasting impact, determining whether a process has a unit root is of interest in its own right. We cover the notion of spurious regression between two time series processes, each of which has a unit root, in Section 18.3. The main result is that even if two unit root series are independent, it is quite likely that the regression of one on the other will yield a statistically significant t statistic. This emphasizes the potentially serious consequences of using standard inference when the dependent and independent variables are integrated processes. The notion of cointegration applies when two series are I(1), but a linear combination of them is I(0); in this case, the regression of one on the other is not spurious, but instead tells us something about the long-run relationship between them. Cointegration between two series also implies a particular kind of model, called an error correction model, for the short-term dynamics. We cover these models in Section 18.4. In Section 18.5, we provide an overview of forecasting and bring together all of the tools in this and previous chapters to show how regression methods can be used to forecast future outcomes of a time series. The forecasting literature is vast, so we focus only on the most common regression-based methods. We also touch on the related topic of Granger causality. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 633 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 18.1 Infinite Distributed Lag Models Let {(yt, zt): t 􏱪 ..., 􏱦2, 􏱦1, 0, 1, 2, ...} be a bivariate time series process (which is only partially observed). An infinite distributed lag (IDL) model relating yt to current and all past values of z is yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛0zt 􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕􏱛2zt􏱦2 􏱕...􏱕ut, [18.1] where the sum on lagged z extends back to the indefinite past. This model is only an approximation to reality, as no economic process started infinitely far into the past. Compared with a finite distributed lag model, an IDL model does not require that we truncate the lag at a particular value. In order for model (18.1) to make sense, the lag coefficients, 􏱛j, must tend to zero as j 􏱽 􏱵. This is not to say that 􏱛2 is smaller in magnitude than 􏱛1; it only means that the impact of zt􏱦j on yt must eventually become small as j gets large. In most applications, this makes economic sense as well: the distant past of z should be less important for explaining y than the recent past of z. Even if we decide that (18.1) is a useful model, we clearly cannot estimate it without some restrictions. For one, we only observe a finite history of data. Equation (18.1) involves an infinite number of parameters, 􏱛0, 􏱛1, 􏱛2, ..., which cannot be estimated without restrictions. Later, we place restrictions on the 􏱛j that allow us to estimate (18.1). As with finite distributed lag (FDL) models, the impact propensity in (18.1) is simply 􏱛0 (see Chapter 10). Generally, the 􏱛h have the same interpretation as in an FDL. Suppose thatzs 􏱪0foralls􏱷0andthatz0 􏱪1andzs 􏱪0foralls􏱰1;inotherwords,attime t 􏱪 0, z increases temporarily by one unit and then reverts to its initial level of zero. For any h 􏱸 0, we have yh 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱛h 􏱕 uh for all h 􏱸 0, and so E(yh) 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱛h, [18.2] where we use the standard assumption that uh has zero mean. It follows that 􏱛h is the change in E(yh) given a one-unit, temporary change in z at time zero. We just said that 􏱛h must be tending to zero as h gets large for the IDL to make sense. This means that a tem- porary change in z has no long-run effect on expected y: E(yh) 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱛h 􏱽 􏱮 as h 􏱽 􏱵. We assumed that the process z starts at zs 􏱪 0 and that the one-unit increase occurred at t 􏱪 0. These were only for the purpose of illustration. More generally, if z temporar- ily increases by one unit (from any initial level) at time t, then 􏱛h measures the change in the expected value of y after h periods. The lag distribution, which is 􏱛h plotted as a function of h, shows the expected path that future y follow given the one-unit, temporary increase in z. The long-run propensity in model (18.1) is the sum of all of the lag coefficients: LRP􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1 􏱕􏱛2 􏱕􏱛3 􏱕..., [18.3] where we assume that the infinite sum is well defined. Because the 􏱛j must converge to zero, the LRP can often be well approximated by a finite sum of the form 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1 􏱕 ... 􏱕􏱛p for sufficiently large p. To interpret the LRP, suppose that the process zt is steady at zs 􏱪 0 for s 􏱷 0. At t 􏱪 0, the process permanently increases by one unit. For example, if zt is the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 634 PART 3 Advanced Topics percentage change in the money supply and yt is the inflation rate, then we are interested in the effects of a permanent increase of one percentage point in money supply growth. Then, by substituting zs 􏱪 0 for s 􏱷 0 and zt 􏱪 1 for t 􏱸 0, we have yh 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1 􏱕...􏱕􏱛h 􏱕uh, where h 􏱸 0 is any horizon. Because ut has a zero mean for all t, we have E(yh)􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛0 􏱕􏱛1 􏱕...􏱕􏱛h. [18.4] [It is useful to compare (18.4) and (18.2).] As the horizon increases, that is, as h 􏱽 􏱵, the right-hand side of (18.4) is, by definition, the long-run propensity, plus 􏱮. Thus, the LRP measures the long-run change in the expected value of y given a one-unit, permanent increase in z. The previous derivation of the LRP and the interpretation of 􏱛j used the fact that the errors have a zero mean; as usual, this is not much of an assumption, pro- vided an intercept is included in the model. A closer examination of our reasoning shows that we assumed that the change in z during any time period had no effect on the expected value of ut. This is the infinite distributed lag version of the strict exogeneity assumption that we introduced in Chapter 10 (in particular, Assumption TS.3). Formally, E(ut􏰫..., zt􏱦2, zt􏱦1, zt, zt􏱕1, ...) 􏱪 0, [18.5] so that the expected value of ut does not depend on the z in any time period. Although (18.5) is natural for some applications, it rules out other important possibilities. In effect, (18.5) does not allow feedback from yt to future z because zt􏱕h must be uncorrelated with ut for h 􏱰 0. In the inflation/money supply growth example, where yt is inflation and zt is money supply growth, (18.5) rules out future changes in money supply growth that are tied to changes in today’s inflation rate. Given that money supply policy often attempts to keep interest rates and inflation at certain levels, this might be unrealistic. One approach to estimating the 􏱛j, which we cover in the next subsection, requires a strict exogeneity assumption in order to produce consistent estimators of the 􏱛j. A weaker assumption is E(ut􏰫zt, zt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 0. [18.6] Under (18.6), the error is uncorrelated with current and past z, but it may be correlated with future z; this allows zt to be a variable that follows policy rules that depend on past y. Sometimes, (18.6) is sufficient to estimate the 􏱛j; we explain this in the next subsection. One thing to remember is that neither (18.5) nor (18.6) says anything about the serial correlation properties of {ut}. (This is just as in finite distributed lag models.) If any- thing, we might expect the {ut} to be serially correlated because (18.1) is not generally Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 18.1 Supposethatzs 􏱪0fors􏱷0andthatz0 􏱪1, z1 􏱪1,andzs 􏱪0fors􏱰1.FindE(y􏱦1), E(y0), and E(yh) for h 􏱸 1. What happens as h 􏱽 􏱵? 635 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics dynamically complete in the sense discussed in Section 11.4. We will study the serial correlation problem later. How do we interpret the lag coefficients and the LRP if (18.6) holds but (18.5) does not? The answer is: the same way as before. We can still do the previous thought (or counterfactual) experiment even though the data we observe are generated by some feed- back between yt and future z. For example, we can certainly ask about the long-run effect of a permanent increase in money supply growth on inflation even though the data on money supply growth cannot be characterized as strictly exogenous. The Geometric (or Koyck) Distributed Lag Because there are generally an infinite number of 􏱛j, we cannot consistently estimate them without some restrictions. The simplest version of (18.1), which still makes the model depend on an infinite number of lags, is the geometric (or Koyck) distributed lag. In this model, the 􏱛j depend on only two parameters: 􏱛j 􏱪 􏰸􏰴 j, 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1, j 􏱪 0, 1, 2, .... [18.7] The parameters 􏰸 and 􏰴 may be positive or negative, but 􏰴 must be less than one in abso- lute value. This ensures that 􏱛j 􏱽 0 as j 􏱽 􏱵. In fact, this convergence happens at a very fast rate. (For example, with 􏰴 􏱪 .5 and j 􏱪 10, 􏰴 j 􏱪 1/1024 􏱷 .001.) The impact propensity (IP) in the GDL is simply 􏱛0 􏱪 􏰸, so the sign of the IP is determined by the sign of 􏰸. If 􏰸 􏱰 0, say, and 􏰴 􏱰 0, then all lag coefficients are posi- tive. If 􏰴 􏱷 0, the lag coefficients alternate in sign (􏰴 j is negative for odd j). The long-run propensity is more difficult to obtain, but we can use a standard result on the sum of a geometric series: for 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1, 1 􏱕 􏰴 􏱕 􏰴2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰴 j 􏱕 ... 􏱪 1/(1 􏱦 􏰴), and so LRP 􏱪 􏰸/(1 􏱦 􏰴). The LRP has the same sign as 􏰸. If we plug (18.7) into (18.1), we still have a model that depends on the z back to the indefinite past. Nevertheless, a simple subtraction yields an estimable model. Write the IDL at times t and t 􏱦 1 as: and yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏰸zt 􏱕􏰸􏰴zt􏱦1 􏱕􏰸􏰴2zt􏱦2 􏱕...􏱕ut [18.8] yt􏱦1 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰸zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸􏰴zt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰸􏰴2zt􏱦3 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ut􏱦1. [18.9] If we multiply the second equation by 􏰴 and subtract it from the first, all but a few of the terms cancel: which we can write as yt 􏱦􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱪(1􏱦􏰴)􏱮􏱕􏰸zt 􏱕ut 􏱦􏰴ut􏱦1, yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰸zt 􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕ut 􏱦􏰴ut􏱦1, [18.10] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 636 PART 3 Advanced Topics where 􏱮0 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴)􏱮. This equation looks like a standard model with a lagged dependent variable, where zt appears contemporaneously. Because 􏰸 is the coefficient on zt and 􏰴 is the coefficient on yt􏱦1, it appears that we can estimate these parameters. [If, for some reason, we are interested in 􏱮, we can always obtain 􏱮ˆ 􏱪 􏱮ˆ0/(1 􏱦 􏰴ˆ) after estimating 􏰴 and 􏱮0.] The simplicity of (18.10) is somewhat misleading. The error term in this equation, ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1, is generally correlated with yt􏱦1. From (18.9), it is pretty clear that ut􏱦1 and yt􏱦1 are correlated. Therefore, if we write (18.10) as yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰸zt 􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕vt, [18.11] where vt 􏱲 ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1, then we generally have correlation between vt and yt􏱦1. Without further assumptions, OLS estimation of (18.11) produces inconsistent estimates of 􏰸 and 􏰴. One case where vt must be correlated with yt􏱦1 occurs when ut is independent of zt and all past values of z and y. Then, (18.8) is dynamically complete, so ut is uncorrelated with yt􏱦1. From (18.9), the covariance between vt and yt􏱦1 is 􏱦􏰴Var(ut􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱦􏰴􏱧u2, which is zero only if 􏰴 􏱪 0. We can easily see that vt is serially correlated: because {ut} is serially uncorrelated,E(vtvt􏱦1)􏱪E(utut􏱦1)􏱦􏰴E(ut2􏱦1)􏱦􏰴E(utut􏱦2)􏱕􏰴2E(ut􏱦1ut􏱦2)􏱪􏱦􏰴􏱧u2.Forj􏱰1, E(vtvt􏱦j) 􏱪 0. Thus, {vt} is a moving average process of order one (see Section 11.1). This, and equation (18.11), gives an example of a model—which is derived from the origi- nal model of interest—that has a lagged dependent variable and a particular kind of serial correlation. If we make the strict exogeneity assumption (18.5), then zt is uncorrelated with ut and ut􏱦1, and therefore with vt. Thus, if we can find a suitable instrumental variable for yt􏱦1, then we can estimate (18.11) by IV. What is a good IV candidate for yt􏱦1? By assumption, ut and ut􏱦1 are both uncorrelated with zt􏱦1, so vt is uncorrelated with zt􏱦1. If 􏰸 􏱻 0, zt􏱦1 and yt􏱦1 are correlated, even after partialling out zt. Therefore, we can use instruments (zt, zt􏱦1) to estimate (18.11). Generally, the standard errors need to be adjusted for serial correlation in the {vt}, as we discussed in Section 15.7. An alternative to IV estimation exploits the fact that {ut} may contain a specific kind of serial correlation. In particular, in addition to (18.6), suppose that {ut} follows the AR(1) model ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et [18.12] E(et􏰫zt, yt􏱦1, zt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 0. [18.13] It is important to notice that the 􏰴 appearing in (18.12) is the same parameter multiplying yt􏱦1 in (18.11). If (18.12) and (18.13) hold, we can write equation (18.10) as yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰸zt 􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕et, [18.14] which is a dynamically complete model under (18.13). From Chapter 11, we can obtain consistent, asymptotically normal estimators of the parameters by OLS. This is very con- venient, as there is no need to deal with serial correlation in the errors. If et satisfies the homoskedasticity assumption Var(et􏰫zt, yt􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱧2e, the usual inference applies. Once we have estimated 􏰸 and 􏰴, we can easily estimate the LRP: 􏱾LRP􏱪 􏰸ˆ/(1 􏱦 􏰴ˆ). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 637 The simplicity of this procedure relies on the potentially strong assumption that {ut} follows an AR(1) process with the same 􏰴 appearing in (18.7). This is usually no worse than assuming the {ut} are serially uncorrelated. Nevertheless, because consistency of the estimators relies heavily on this assumption, it is a good idea to test it. A simple test begins by specifying {ut} as an AR(1) process with a different parameter, say, ut 􏱪 􏲇ut􏱦1 􏱕 et. McClain and Wooldridge (1995) devised a simple Lagrange multiplier test of H0: 􏲇 􏱪 􏰴 that can be computed after OLS estimation of (18.14). The geometric distributed lag model extends to multiple explanatory variables—so that we have an infinite DL in each explanatory variable—but then we must be able to write the coefficient on zt􏱦j,h as 􏰸h􏰴j. In other words, though 􏰸h is different for each explanatory variable, 􏰴 is the same. Thus, we can write yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰸1zt1 􏱕...􏱕􏰸kztk 􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕vt. [18.15] The same issues that arose in the case with one z arise in the case with many z. Under the natural extension of (18.12) and (18.13)—just replace zt with zt 􏱪 (zt1, ..., ztk)—OLS is consistent and asymptotically normal. Or, an IV method can be used. Rational Distributed Lag Models The geometric DL implies a fairly restrictive lag distribution. When 􏰸 􏱰 0 and 􏰴 􏱰 0, the 􏱛j are positive and monotonically declining to zero. It is possible to have more general infinite distributed lag models. The GDL is a special case of what is generally called a rational distributed lag (RDL) model. A general treatment is beyond our scope—Harvey (1990) is a good reference—but we can cover one simple, useful extension. Such an RDL model is most easily described by adding a lag of z to equation (18.11): yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸0zt 􏱕 􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸1zt􏱦1 􏱕 vt, [18.16] where vt 􏱪 ut 􏱦 􏰴ut􏱦1, as before. By repeated substitution, it can be shown that (18.16) is equivalent to the infinite distributed lag model yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏰸0(zt 􏱕􏰴zt􏱦1 􏱕􏰴2zt􏱦2 􏱕...) 􏱕 􏰸1(zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴zt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰴2zt􏱦3 􏱕 ...) 􏱕 ut 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰸0zt 􏱕 (􏰴􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1)zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴(􏰴􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1)zt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰴2(􏰴􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1)zt􏱦3 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ut, where we again need the assumption 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1. From this last equation, we can read off the lag distribution. In particular, the impact propensity is 􏰸0, while the coefficient on zt􏱦h is 􏰴h􏱦1(􏰴􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1) for h 􏱸 1. Therefore, this model allows the impact propensity to differ in sign from the other lag coefficients, even if 􏰴 􏱰 0. However, if 􏰴 􏱰 0, the 􏱛h have the same sign as (􏰴􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1) for all h 􏱸 1. The lag distribution is plotted in Figure 18.1 for 􏰴 􏱪 .5, 􏰸0 􏱪 􏱦1, and 􏰸1 􏱪 1. The easiest way to compute the long-run propensity is to set y and z at their long-run val- ues for all t, say, y* and z*, and then find the change in y* with respect to z* (see also Problem 3 inChapter10).Wehavey*􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰸0z*􏱕􏰴y*􏱕􏰸1z*,andsolvinggivesy*􏱪􏱮0/(1􏱦􏰴)􏱕 (􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1)/(1 􏱦 􏰴)z*. Now, we use the fact that LRP 􏱪 􏰧y*/􏰧z*: LRP 􏱪 (􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1)/(1 􏱦 􏰴). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 638 PART 3 Advanced Topics F I G U R E 1 8 . 1 Lag distribution for the rational distributed lag (18.16) with 􏰴 􏱪 .5, 􏰸0 􏱪 􏱦1, and 􏰸1 􏱪 1. coefficient .5 0 21 5 10 lag Because 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1, the LRP has the same sign as 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1, and the LRP is zero if, and only if, 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1 􏱪 0, as in Figure 18.1. EXAMPLE 18.1 HOUSING INVESTMENT AND RESIDENTIAL PRICE INFLATION We estimate both the basic geometric and the rational distributed lag models by applying OLS to (18.14) and (18.16), respectively. The dependent variable is log(invpc) after a lin- ear time trend has been removed [that is, we linearly detrend log(invpc)]. For zt, we use the growth in the price index. This allows us to estimate how residential price inflation affects movements in housing investment around its trend. The results of the estimation, using the data in HSEINV.RAW, are given in Table 18.1. The geometric distributed lag model is clearly rejected by the data, as gprice􏱦1 is very significant. The adjusted R-squareds also show that the RDL model fits much better. The two models give very different estimates of the long-run propensity. If we in- correctly use the GDL, the estimated LRP is almost five: a permanent one percentage point increase in residential price inflation increases long-term housing investment by 4.7% (above its trend value). Economically, this seems implausible. The LRP estimated from the rational distributed lag model is below one. In fact, we cannot reject the null hypothesis H0: 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1 􏱪 0 at any reasonable significance level (p-value 􏱪 .83), so there is no evidence that the LRP is different from zero. This is a good example of how misspecifying the dynamics of a model by omitting relevant lags can lead to erroneous conclusions. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 639 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics T A B L E 1 8 . 1 Distributed Lag Models for Housing Investment Dependent Variable: log(invpc), detrended Independent Variables GeometricDL RationalDL gprice 3.095 (.933) 3.256 (.970) y􏱦1 .340 (.132) .547 (.152) gprice􏱦1 — 􏱦2.936 (.973) constant 􏱦.010 (.018) .006 (.017) Long-run propensity 4.689 .706 Sample size Adjusted R-squared 41 .375 40 .504 18.2 Testing for Unit Roots We now turn to the important problem of testing whether a time series follows a unit root process. In Chapter 11, we gave some vague, necessarily informal guidelines to decide whether a series is I(1) or not. In many cases, it is useful to have a formal test for a unit root. As we will see, such tests must be applied with caution. The simplest approach to testing for a unit root begins with an AR(1) model: yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [18.17] where y0 is the observed initial value. Throughout this section, we let {et} denote a process that has zero mean, given past observed y: E(et􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ..., y0) 􏱪 0. [18.18] [Under (18.18), {et} is said to be a martingale difference sequence with respect to {yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...}. If {et} is assumed to be i.i.d. with zero mean and is independent of y0, then it also satisfies (18.18).] If {yt} follows (18.17), it has a unit root if, and only if, 􏰴 􏱪 1. If 􏱮 􏱪 0 and 􏰴 􏱪 1, {yt} follows a random walk without drift [with the innovations et satisfying (18.18)]. If 􏱮 􏱻 0 and 􏰴 􏱪 1, {yt} is a random walk with drift, which means that E(yt) is a linear func- tion of t. A unit root process with drift behaves very differently from one without drift. Nevertheless, it is common to leave 􏱮 unspecified under the null hypothesis, and this is the approach we take. Therefore, the null hypothesis is that {yt} has a unit root: H0: 􏰴 􏱪 1. [18.19] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 640 PART 3 Advanced Topics In almost all cases, we are interested in the one-sided alternative H1: 􏰴 􏱷 1. [18.20] (In practice, this means 0 􏱷 􏰴 􏱷 1, as 􏰴 􏱷 0 for a series that we suspect has a unit root would be very rare.) The alternative H1: 􏰴 􏱰 1 is not usually considered, since it implies that yt is explosive. In fact, if 􏱮 􏱰 0, yt has an exponential trend in its mean when 􏰴 􏱰 1. When 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1, {yt} is a stable AR(1) process, which means it is weakly dependent or asymptotically uncorrelated. Recall from Chapter 11 that Corr(yt,yt􏱕h) 􏱪 􏰴h 􏱽 0 when 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1. Therefore, testing (18.19) in model (18.17), with the alternative given by (18.20), is really a test of whether {yt} is I(1) against the alternative that {yt} is I(0). [We do not take the null to be I(0) in this setup because {yt} is I(0) for any value of 􏰴 strictly between 􏱦1 and 1, something that classical hypothesis testing does not handle easily. There are tests where the null hypothesis is I(0) against the alternative of I(1), but these take a different approach. See, for example, Kwiatkowski, Phillips, Schmidt, and Shin (1992).] A convenient equation for carrying out the unit root test is to subtract yt􏱦1 from both sides of (18.17) and to define 􏰩 􏱪 􏰴 􏱦 1: 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰩yt􏱦1 􏱕 et. [18.21] Under (18.18), this is a dynamically complete model, and so it seems straightforward to test H0: 􏰩 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏰩 􏱷 0. The problem is that, under H0, yt􏱦1 is I(1), and so the usual central limit theorem that underlies the asymptotic standard normal distribution for the t statistic does not apply: the t statistic does not have an approximate standard normal distribution even in large sample sizes. The asymptotic distribution of the t sta- tistic under H0 has come to be known as the Dickey-Fuller distribution after Dickey and Fuller (1979). ˆ Although we cannot use the usual critical values, we can use the usual t statistic for 􏰩 in (18.21), at least once the appropriate critical values have been tabulated. The resulting test is known as the Dickey-Fuller (DF) test for a unit root. The theory used to obtain the asymptotic critical values is rather complicated and is covered in advanced texts on time series econometrics. [See, for example, Banerjee, Dolado, Galbraith, and Hendry (1993), or BDGH for short.] By contrast, using these results is very easy. The critical values for the t statistic have been tabulated by several authors, beginning with the original work by Dickey and Fuller (1979). Table 18.2 contains the large sample critical values for vari- ous significance levels, taken from BDGH (1993, Table 4.2). (Critical values adjusted for small sample sizes are available in BDGH.) We reject the null hypothesis H0: 􏰩 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏰩 􏱷 0 if t􏰩ˆ􏱷 c, where c is one of the negative values in Table 18.2. For example, to carry out the test at the 5% significance level, we reject if t􏰩ˆ 􏱷 􏱦2.86. This requires a t statistic with a much larger magnitude than if we used the standard normal critical value, which would be 􏱦1.65. If we use the stan- dard normal critical value to test for a unit root, we would reject H0 much more often than 5% of the time when H0 is true. © Cengage Learning, 2013 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. T A B L E 1 8 . 2 Asymptotic Critical Values for Unit Root t Test: No Time Trend Significance level 1% 2.5% 5% 10% Critical value 􏱦3.43 􏱦3.12 􏱦2.86 􏱦2.57 641 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics EXAMPLE 18.2 UNIT ROOT TEST FOR THREE-MONTH T-BILL RATES We use the quarterly data in INTQRT.RAW to test for a unit root in three-month T-bill rates. When we estimate (18.20), we obtain 􏰧r3 􏱪 .625 􏱦 .091 r3 where we keep with our convention of reporting standard errors in parentheses below the estimates. We must remember that these standard errors cannot be used to construct usual confidence intervals or to carry out traditional t tests because these do not behave in the usual ways when there is a unit root. The coefficient on r3t􏱦1 shows that the estimate of 􏰴 is 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 1 􏱕 􏰩ˆ 􏱪 .909. While this is less than unity, we do not know whether it is statisti- cally less than one. The t statistic on r3t􏱦1 is 􏱦.091/.037 􏱪 􏱦2.46. From Table 18.2, the 10% critical value is 􏱦2.57; therefore, we fail to reject H0: 􏰴 􏱪 1 against H1: 􏰴 􏱷 1 at the 10% significance level. As with other hypothesis tests, when we fail to reject H0, we do not say that we accept H0. Why? Suppose we test H0: 􏰴 􏱪 .9 in the previous example using a standard t test—which is asymptotically valid, because yt is I(0) under H0. Then, we obtain t 􏱪 .001/.037, which is very small and provides no evidence against 􏰴 􏱪 .9. Yet, it makes no sense to accept 􏰴 􏱪 1 and 􏰴 􏱪 .9. When we fail to reject a unit root, as in the previous example, we should only con- clude that the data do not provide strong evidence against H0. In this example, the test does provide some evidence against H0 because the t statistic is close to the 10% critical value. (Ideally, we would compute a p-value, but this requires special software because of the nonnormal distribution.) In addition, though 􏰴ˆ 􏱴 .91 implies a fair amount of persis- tence in {r3t}, the correlation between observations that are 10 periods apart for an AR(1) model with 􏰴 􏱪 .9 is about .35, rather than almost one if 􏰴 􏱪 1. What happens if we now want to use r3t as an explanatory variable in a regression analysis? The outcome of the unit root test implies that we should be extremely cautious: if r3t does have a unit root, the usual asymptotic approximations need not hold (as we dis- cussed in Chapter 11). One solution is to use the first difference of r3t in any analysis. As we will see in Section 18.4, that is not the only possibility. We also need to test for unit roots in models with more complicated dynamics. If {yt} follows (18.17) with 􏰴 􏱪 1, then 􏰧yt is serially uncorrelated. We can easily allow {􏰧yt} to follow an AR model by augmenting equation (18.21) with additional lags. For example, 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰩yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕 et, [18.23] where 􏰫􏰸1􏰫 􏱷 1. This ensures that, under H0: 􏰩 􏱪 0, {􏰧yt} follows a stable AR(1) model. Under the alternative H1: 􏰩 􏱷 0, it can be shown that {yt} follows a stable AR(2) model. More generally, we can add p lags of 􏰧yt to the equation to account for the dynamics in the process. The way we test the null hypothesis of a unit root is very similar: we run the regression of 􏰧yt on yt􏱦1, 􏰧yt􏱦1, ..., 􏰧yt􏱦p [18.24] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱾 t􏱦1 t n 􏱪 123, R2 􏱪 .048, [18.22] (.261) (.037) 642 PART 3 Advanced Topics and carry out the t test on 􏰩ˆ, the coefficient on yt􏱦1, just as before. This extended version of the Dickey-Fuller test is usually called the augmented Dickey-Fuller test because the regression has been augmented with the lagged changes, 􏰧yt􏱦h. The critical values and rejec- tion rule are the same as before. The inclusion of the lagged changes in (18.24) is intended to clean up any serial correlation in 􏰧yt. The more lags we include in (18.24), the more initial observations we lose. If we include too many lags, the small sample power of the test generally suffers. But if we include too few lags, the size of the test will be incorrect, even asymptotically, because the validity of the critical values in Table 18.2 relies on the dynam- ics being completely modeled. Often, the lag length is dictated by the frequency of the data (as well as the sample size). For annual data, one or two lags usually suffice. For monthly data, we might include 12 lags. But there are no hard rules to follow in any case. Interestingly, the t statistics on the lagged changes have approximate t distributions. The F statistics for joint significance of any group of terms 􏰧yt􏱦h are also asymptotically valid. (These maintain the homoskedasticity assumption discussed in Section 11.5.) Therefore, we can use standard tests to determine whether we have enough lagged changes in (18.24). EXAMPLE 18.3 UNIT ROOT TEST FOR ANNUAL U.S. INFLATION We use annual data on U.S. inflation, based on the CPI, to test for a unit root in inflation (see PHILLIPS.RAW), restricting ourselves to the years from 1948 through 1996. Allowing for one lag of 􏰧inft in the augmented Dickey-Fuller regression gives 􏰧􏱾inf 􏱪(1.36 􏱦 .310)inf 􏱕 .138 􏰧inf t t􏱦1 t􏱦1 􏰧inˆft 􏱪0(.517)(.103) (.126) n􏱪47,R2 􏱪.172. The t statistic for the unit root test is 􏱦.310/.103 􏱪 􏱦3.01. Because the 5% critical value is 􏱦2.86, we reject the unit root hypothesis at the 5% level. The estimate of 􏰴 is about .690. Together, this is reasonably strong evidence against a unit root in inflation. The lag 􏰧inft􏱦1 has a t statistic of about 1.10, so we do not need to include it, but we could not know this ahead of time. If we drop 􏰧inft􏱦1, the evidence against a unit root is slightly stronger: 􏰩ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.335 (􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .665), and t􏰩ˆ􏱪 􏱦3.13. For series that have clear time trends, we need to modify the test for unit roots. A trend-stationary process—which has a linear trend in its mean but is I(0) about its trend— can be mistaken for a unit root process if we do not control for a time trend in the Dickey- Fuller regression. In other words, if we carry out the usual DF or augmented DF test on a trending but I(0) series, we will probably have little power for rejecting a unit root. To allow for series with time trends, we change the basic equation to 􏰧yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛t􏱕􏰩yt􏱦1 􏱕et, [18.25] where again the null hypothesis is H0: 􏰩 􏱪 0, and the alternative is H1: 􏰩 􏱷 0. Under the alternative, {yt} is a trend-stationary process. If yt has a unit root, then 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱛t 􏱕 et, and so the change in yt has a mean linear in t unless 􏱛 􏱪 0. [It can be shown that E(yt) is actually a quadratic in t.] It is unusual for the first difference of an economic series to have a linear trend, so a more appropriate null hypothesis is probably H0: 􏰩 􏱪 0, 􏱛 􏱪 0. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 643 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics T A B L E 1 8 . 3 Asymptotic Critical Values for Unit Root t Test: Linear Time Trend Significance level 1% 2.5% 5% 10% Critical value 􏱦3.96 􏱦3.66 􏱦3.41 􏱦3.12 © Cengage Learning, 2013 Although it is possible to test this joint hypothesis using an F test—but with modified critical values—it is common to test H0: 􏰩 􏱪 0 using only a t test. We follow that approach here. [See BDGH (1993, Section 4.4) for more details on the joint test.] When we include a time trend in the regression, the critical values of the test change. Intuitively, this occurs because detrending a unit root process tends to make it look more like an I(0) process. Therefore, we require a larger magnitude for the t statistic in order to reject H0. The Dickey-Fuller critical values for the t test that includes a time trend are given in Table 18.3; they are taken from BDGH (1993, Table 4.2). ˆ For example, to reject a unit root at the 5% level, we need the t statistic on 􏰩 to be less than 􏱦3.41, as compared with 􏱦2.86 without a time trend. We can augment equation (18.25) with lags of 􏰧yt to account for serial correlation, just as in the case without a trend. EXAMPLE 18.4 UNIT ROOT IN THE LOG OF U.S. REAL GROSS DOMESTIC PRODUCT We can apply the unit root test with a time trend to the U.S. GDP data in INVEN. RAW. These annual data cover the years from 1959 through 1995. We test whether log(GDPt) has a unit root. This series has a pronounced trend that looks roughly linear. We include a single lag of 􏰧log(GDPt), which is simply the growth in GDP (in decimal form), to account for dynamics: 􏱾gGDPt 􏱪 1.65 􏱕 .0059 t 􏱦 .210 log(GDPt􏱦1) 􏱕 .264 gGDPt􏱦1 (.67) (.0027) (.087) (.165) [18.26] n􏱪35,R2 􏱪.268. From this equation, we get 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 1 􏱦 .21 􏱪 .79, which is clearly less than one. But we cannot reject a unit root in the log of GDP: the t statistic on log(GDPt􏱦1) is 􏱦.210/.087 􏱪 􏱦2.41, which is well above the 10% critical value of 􏱦3.12. The t statistic on gGDPt􏱦1 is 1.60, which is almost significant at the 10% level against a two-sided alternative. What should we conclude about a unit root? Again, we cannot reject a unit root, but the point estimate of 􏰴 is not especially close to one. When we have a small sample size— and n 􏱪 35 is considered to be pretty small—it is very difficult to reject the null hypothesis of a unit root if the process has something close to a unit root. Using more data over longer time periods, many researchers have concluded that there is little evidence against the unit root hypothesis for log(GDP). This has led most of them to assume that the growth in GDP is I(0), which means that log(GDP) is I(1). Unfortunately, given currently available sample sizes, we cannot have much confidence in this conclusion. ˆ If we omit the time trend, there is much less evidence against H0, as 􏰩 􏱪 􏱦.023 and t􏰩ˆ 􏱪 􏱦1.92. Here, the estimate of 􏰴 is much closer to one, but this is misleading due to the omitted time trend. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 644 PART 3 Advanced Topics It is tempting to compare the t statistic on the time trend in (18.26) with the critical value from a standard normal or t distribution, to see whether the time trend is significant. Unfortunately, the t statistic on the trend does not have an asymptotic standard normal dis- tribution (unless 􏰫􏰴􏰫 􏱷 1). The asymptotic distribution of this t statistic is known, but it is rarely used. Typically, we rely on intuition (or plots of the time series) to decide whether to include a trend in the DF test. There are many other variants on unit root tests. In one version that is applicable only to series that are clearly not trending, the intercept is omitted from the regression; that is, 􏱮 is set to zero in (18.21). This variant of the Dickey-Fuller test is rarely used because of biases induced if 􏱮 􏱻 0. Also, we can allow for more complicated time trends, such as quadratic. Again, this is seldom used. Another class of tests attempts to account for serial correlation in 􏰧yt in a different manner than by including lags in (18.21) or (18.25). The approach is related to the serial correlation-robust standard errors for the OLS estimators that we discussed in Section 12.5. The idea is to be as agnostic as possible about serial correlation in 􏰧yt. In practice, the (augmented) Dickey-Fuller test has held up pretty well. [See BDGH (1993, Section 4.3) for a discussion on other tests.] 18.3 Spurious Regression In a cross-sectional environment, we use the phrase “spurious correlation” to describe a situation where two variables are related through their correlation with a third variable. In particular, if we regress y on x, we find a significant relationship. But when we control for another variable, say, z, the partial effect of x on y becomes zero. Naturally, this can also happen in time series contexts with I(0) variables. As we discussed in Section 10.5, it is possible to find a spurious relationship between time series that have increasing or decreasing trends. Provided the series are weakly de- pendent about their time trends, the problem is effectively solved by including a time trend in the regression model. When we are dealing with integrated processes of order one, there is an additional com- plication. Even if the two series have means that are not trending, a simple regression involv- ing two independent I(1) series will often result in a significant t statistic. To be more precise, let {xt} and {yt} be random walks generated by xt 􏱪 xt􏱦1 􏱕 at, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [18.27] and yt 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱕 et, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [18.28] where {at} and {et} are independent, identically distributed innovations, with mean zero and variances 􏱧a2 and 􏱧e2, respectively. For concreteness, take the initial values to be x0 􏱪 y0 􏱪 0. Assume further that {at} and {et} are independent processes. This implies that {xt} and {yt} are also independent. But what if we run the simple regression yˆt 􏱪􏱬ˆ0 􏱕􏱬ˆ1xt [18.29] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 645 and obtain the usual t statistic for 􏱬ˆ1 and the usual R-squared? Because yt and xt are independent, we would hope that plim 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 0. Even more importantly, if we test H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱬1 􏱻 0 at the 5% level, we hope that the t statistic for 􏱬ˆ1 is in- significant 95% of the time. Through a simulation, Granger and Newbold (1974) showed that this is not the case: even though yt and xt are independent, the regression of yt on xt yields a statistically significant t statistic a large percentage of the time, much larger than the nominal significance level. Granger and Newbold called this the spurious regression problem: there is no sense in which y and x are related, but an OLS regression using the usual t statistics will often indicate a relationship. Recent simulation results are given by Davidson and MacKinnon (1993, Table 19.1), where at and et are generated as independent, identically distributed normal random vari- ables, and 10,000 different samples are generated. For a sample size of n 􏱪 50 at the 5% significance level, the standard t statistic for H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0 against the two- sided alternative rejects H0 about 66.2% of the time under H0, rather than 5% of the time. As the sample size increases, things get worse: with n 􏱪 250, the null is rejected 84.7% of the time! Here is one way to see what is happening when we regress the level of y on the level of x. Write the model underlying (18.29) as yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt 􏱕 ut. [18.30] For the t statistic of 􏱬ˆ1 to have an approximate standard normal distribution in large sam- ples, at a minimum, {ut} should be a mean zero, serially uncorrelated process. But un- der H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0, yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 ut, and, because {yt} is a random walk starting at∑y0 t􏱪 0, equation(18.30) holds under H0 only if 􏱬0 􏱪 0 and, more importantly, if ut 􏱪 yt 􏱪 j􏱪1 ej. In other words, {ut} is a random walk under H0. This clearly violates even the asymptotic version of the Gauss-Markov assumptions from Chapter 11. Including a time trend does not really change the conclusion. If yt or xt is a random walk with drift and a time trend is not included, the spurious regression problem is even worse. The same qualitative conclusions hold if {at} and {et} are general I(0) processes, rather than i.i.d. sequences. In addition to the usual t statistic not having a limiting standard normal distribution—in fact, it increases to infinity as n 􏱽 􏱵—the behavior of R-squared is nonstandard. In cross- sectional contexts or in regressions with I(0) time series variables, the R-squared converges in probability to the population R-squared: 1 􏱦 􏱧u2/􏱧y2. This is not the case in spurious re- gressions with I(1) processes. Rather than the R-squared having a well-defined plim, it ac- tually converges to a random variable. Formalizing this notion is well beyond the scope of this text. [A discussion of the asymptotic properties of the t statistic and the R-squared can be found in BDGH (Section 3.1).] The implication is that the R-squared is large with high probability, even though {yt} and {xt} are independent time series processes. The same considerations arise with multiple independent variables, each of which may be I(1) or some of which may be I(0). If {yt} is I(1) and at least some of the explanatory variables are I(1), the regression results may be spurious. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics EXPLORING FURTHER 18.2 Under the preceding setup, where {xt} and {yt} are generated by (18.27) and (18.28) and {et} and {at} are i.i.d. sequences, what is the plim of the slope coefficient, say, 􏰸ˆ1, from the regression of 􏰧yt on 􏰧xt? Describe the behavior of the t statistic of 􏰸ˆ1. 646 PART 3 Advanced Topics The possibility of spurious regression with I(1) variables is quite important and has led economists to reexamine many aggregate time series regressions whose t statistics were very significant and whose R-squareds were extremely high. In the next section, we show that regressing an I(1) dependent variable on an I(1) independent variable can be informative, but only if these variables are related in a precise sense. 18.4 Cointegration and Error Correction Models The discussion of spurious regression in the previous section certainly makes one wary of using the levels of I(1) variables in regression analysis. In earlier chapters, we suggested that I(1) variables should be differenced before they are used in linear regression mod- els, whether they are estimated by OLS or instrumental variables. This is certainly a safe course to follow, and it is the approach used in many time series regressions after Granger and Newbold’s original paper on the spurious regression problem. Unfortunately, always differencing I(1) variables limits the scope of the questions that we can answer. Cointegration The notion of cointegration, which was given a formal treatment in Engle and Granger (1987), makes regressions involving I(1) variables potentially meaningful. A full treatment of cointegration is mathematically involved, but we can describe the basic issues and methods that are used in many applications. If {yt: t 􏱪 0, 1, ...} and {xt: t 􏱪 0, 1, ...} are two I(1) processes, then, in general, yt 􏱦 􏱬xt is an I(1) process for any number 􏱬. Nevertheless, it is possible that for some 􏱬 􏱻 0, yt 􏱦 􏱬xt is an I(0) process, which means it has constant mean, constant variance, and autocorrelations that depend only on the time distance between any two variables in the series, and it is asymptotically uncorrelated. If such a 􏱬 exists, we say that y and x are cointegrated, and we call 􏱬 the cointegration parameter. [Alternatively, we could lookatxt 􏱦􏰸yt for􏰸􏱻0:ifyt 􏱦􏱬xt is I(0), then xt 􏱦 (1/􏱬)yt is I(0). Therefore, the linear combination of yt and xt is not unique, but if we fix the coefficient on yt at unity, then 􏱬 is unique. See Problem 3. For concreteness, we consider linear combinations of the form yt 􏱦 􏱬xt.] For the sake of illustration, take 􏱬 􏱪 1, suppose that y0 􏱪 x0 􏱪 0, and write yt 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱕 rt, xt 􏱪 xt􏱦1 􏱕 vt, where {rt} and {vt} are two I(0) processes with zero means. Then, yt and xt have a tendency to wander around and not return to the initial value of zero with any regularity. By contrast, if yt 􏱦 xt is I(0), it has zero mean and does return to zero with some regularity. As a specific example, let r6t be the annualized interest rate for six-month T-bills (at the end of quarter t) and let r3t be the annualized interest rate for three-month T-bills. (These are typically called bond equivalent yields, and they are reported in the finan- cial pages.) In Example 18.2, using the data in INTQRT.RAW, we found little evidence against the hypothesis that r3t has a unit root; the same is true of r6t. Define the spread between six- and three-month T-bill rates as sprt 􏱪 r6t 􏱦 r3t. Then, using equation (18.21), the Dickey-Fuller t statistic for sprt is 􏱦7.71 (with 􏰩ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.67 or ˆ􏰴 􏱪 .33). Therefore, we Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 18.3 Let {(yt, xt): t 􏱪 1, 2, ...} be a bivariate time series where each series is I(1) without drift. Explain why, if yt and xt are cointegrated, yt and xt􏱦1 are also cointegrated. 647 strongly reject a unit root for sprt in favor of I(0). The upshot of this is that though r6t and r3t each appear to be unit root processes, the difference between them is an I(0) process. In other words, r6 and r3 are cointegrated. Cointegration in this example, as in many examples, has an economic interpreta- tion. If r6 and r3 were not cointegrated, the difference between interest rates could be- come very large, with no tendency for them to come back together. Based on a simple arbitrage argument, this seems unlikely. Suppose that the spread sprt continues to grow for several time periods, making six-month T-bills a much more desirable investment. Then, investors would shift away from three-month and toward six-month T-bills, driv- ing up the price of six-month T-bills, while lowering the price of three-month T-bills. Because interest rates are inversely related to price, this would lower r6 and increase r3, until the spread is reduced. Therefore, large deviations between r6 and r3 are not ex- pected to continue: the spread has a tendency to return to its mean value. (The spread actually has a slightly positive mean because long-term investors are more rewarded relative to short-term investors.) There is another way to characterize the fact that sprt will not deviate for long periods from its average value: r6 and r3 have a long-run relationship. To describe what we mean by this, let 􏱙 􏱪 E(sprt) denote the expected value of the spread. Then, we can write r6t 􏱪r3t 􏱕􏱙􏱕et, where {et} is a zero mean, I(0) process. The equilibrium or long-run relationship occurs when et 􏱪 0, or r6* 􏱪 r3* 􏱕 􏱙. At any time period, there can be deviations from equi- librium, but they will be temporary: there are economic forces that drive r6 and r3 back toward the equilibrium relationship. In the interest rate example, we used economic reasoning to tell us the value of 􏱬 if yt and xt are cointegrated. If we have a hypothesized value of 􏱬, then testing whether two series are cointegrated is easy: we simply define a new variable, st 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏱬xt, and apply either the usual DF or augmented DF test to {st}. If we reject a unit root in {st} in favor of the I(0) alternative, then we find that yt and xt are cointegrated. In other words, the null hypothesis is that yt and xt are not cointegrated. Testing for cointegration is more difficult when the (potential) cointegration parameter 􏱬 is unknown. Rather than test for a unit root in {st}, we must first estimate 􏱬. If yt and xt are cointegrated, it turns out that the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ from the regression yt 􏱪􏱮ˆ􏱕􏱬ˆxt [18.31] is consistent for 􏱬. The problem is that the null hypothesis states that the two series are not cointegrated, which means that, under H0, we are running a spurious regression. Fortu- nately, it is possible to tabulate critical values even when 􏱬 is estimated, where we apply the Dickey-Fuller or augmented Dickey-Fuller test to the residuals, say, uˆt 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏱮ˆ 􏱦 􏱬ˆxt, from (18.31). The only difference is that the critical values account for estimation of 􏱬. The resulting test is called the Engle-Granger test, and the asymptotic critical values are given in Table 18.4. These are taken from Davidson and MacKinnon (1993, Table 20.2). © Cengage Learning, 2013 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics T A B L E 1 8 . 4 Asymptotic Critical Values for Cointegration Test: No Time Trend Significance level 1% 2.5% 5% 10% Critical value 􏱦3.90 􏱦3.59 􏱦3.34 􏱦3.04 648 PART 3 Advanced Topics In the basic test, we run the regression of 􏰧uˆt on uˆt􏱦1 and compare the t statistic on uˆt􏱦1 to the desired critical value in Table 18.4. If the t statistic is below the critical value, we have evidence that yt 􏱦 􏱬xt is I(0) for some 􏱬; that is, yt and xt are cointegrated. We can add lags of 􏰧uˆt to account for serial correlation. If we compare the critical values in Table 18.4 with those in Table 18.2, we must get a t statistic much larger in magnitude to find cointegration than if we used the usual DF critical values. This happens because OLS, which minimizes the sum of squared residuals, tends to produce residuals that look like an I(0) sequence even if yt and xt are not cointegrated. As with the usual Dickey-Fuller test, we can augment the Engle-Granger test by including lags of 􏰧uˆt as additional regressors. If yt and xt are not cointegrated, a regression of yt on xt is spurious and tells us nothing meaningful: there is no long-run relationship between y and x. We can still run a regression involving the first differences, 􏰧yt and 􏰧xt, including lags. But we should interpret these regressions for what they are: they explain the difference in y in terms of the difference in x and have nothing necessarily to do with a relationship in levels. If yt and xt are cointegrated, we can use this to specify more general dynamic models, as we will see in the next subsection. The previous discussion assumes that neither yt nor xt has a drift. This is reasonable for interest rates but not for other time series. If yt and xt contain drift terms, E(yt) and E(xt) are linear (usually increasing) functions of time. The strict definition of cointegration requires yt 􏱦 􏱬xt to be I(0) without a trend. To see what this entails, write yt 􏱪 􏱛t 􏱕 gt and xt 􏱪 􏲇t 􏱕 ht, where {gt} and {ht} are I(1) processes, 􏱛 is the drift in yt [􏱛 􏱪 E(􏰧yt)], and 􏲇 is the drift in xt [􏲇 􏱪 E(􏰧xt)]. Now, if yt and xt are cointegrated, there must exist 􏱬 such that gt 􏱦 􏱬ht is I(0). But then yt 􏱦􏱬xt 􏱪(􏱛􏱦􏱬􏲇)t􏱕(gt 􏱦􏱬ht), which is generally a trend-stationary process. The strict form of cointegration requires that there not be a trend, which means 􏱛 􏱪 􏱬􏲇. For I(1) processes with drift, it is possible that the stochastic parts—that is, gt and ht—are cointegrated, but that the parameter 􏱬 that causes gt 􏱦 􏱬ht to be I(0) does not eliminate the linear time trend. We can test for cointegration between gt and ht, without taking a stand on the trend part, by running the regression yˆt 􏱪 􏱮ˆ􏱕 􏱗ˆt 􏱕 􏱬ˆxt [18.32] and applying the usual DF or augmented DF test to the residuals ˆut. The asymp- totic critical values are given in Table 18.5 [from Davidson and MacKinnon (1993, Table 20.2)]. © Cengage Learning, 2013 A finding of cointegration in this case leaves open the possibility that yt 􏱦 􏱬xt has a linear trend. But at least it is not I(1). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. T A B L E 1 8 . 5 Asymptotic Critical Values for Cointegration Test: Linear Time Trend Significance level 1% 2.5% 5% 10% Critical value 􏱦4.32 􏱦4.03 􏱦3.78 􏱦3.50 649 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics EXAMPLE 18.5 COINTEGRATION BETWEEN FERTILITY AND PERSONAL EXEMPTION In Chapters 10 and 11, we studied various models to estimate the relationship between the general fertility rate (gfr) and the real value of the personal tax exemption (pe) in the United States. The static regression results in levels and first differences are notably different. The regression in levels, with a time trend included, gives an OLS coefficient on pe equal to .187 (se 􏱪 .035) and R2 􏱪 .500. In first differences (without a trend), the coefficient on 􏰧pe is 􏱦.043 (se 􏱪 .028), and R2 􏱪 .032. Although there are other reasons for these differences—such as misspecified distributed lag dynamics—the discrepancy between the levels and changes regressions suggests that we should test for cointegration. Of course, this presumes that gfr and pe are I(1) processes. This appears to be the case: the augmented DF tests, with a single lagged change and a linear time trend, each yield t statistics of about 􏱦1.47, and the estimated AR(1) coefficients are close to one. When we obtain the residuals from the regression of gfr on t and pe and apply the augmented DF test with one lag, we obtain a t statistic on uˆt􏱦1 of 􏱦2.43, which is nowhere near the 10% critical value, 􏱦3.50. Therefore, we must conclude that there is little evidence of cointegration between gfr and pe, even allowing for separate trends. It is very likely that the earlier regression results we obtained in levels suffer from the spurious regression problem. The good news is that, when we used first differences and allowed for two lags— see equation (11.27)—we found an overall positive and significant long-run effect of 􏰧pe on 􏰧gfr. If we think two series are cointegrated, we often want to test hypotheses about the cointegrating parameter. For example, a theory may state that the cointegrating parameter is one. Ideally, we could use a t statistic to test this hypothesis. We explicitly cover the case without time trends, although the extension to the linear trend case is immediate. When yt and xt are I(1) and cointegrated, we can write yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱬xt 􏱕ut, [18.33] where ut is a zero mean, I(0) process. Generally, {ut} contains serial correlation, but we know from Chapter 11 that this does not affect consistency of OLS. As mentioned ear- lier, OLS applied to (18.33) consistently estimates 􏱬 (and 􏱮). Unfortunately, because xt is I(1), the usual inference procedures do not necessarily apply: OLS is not asymptotically normally distributed, and the t statistic for 􏱬ˆ does not necessarily have an approximate t distribution. We do know from Chapter 10 that, if {xt} is strictly exogenous—see As- sumption TS.3—and the errors are homoskedastic, serially uncorrelated, and normally distributed, the OLS estimator is also normally distributed (conditional on the explanatory variables) and the t statistic has an exact t distribution. Unfortunately, these assumptions are too strong to apply to most situations. The notion of cointegration implies nothing about the relationship between {xt} and {ut}—indeed, they can be arbitrarily correlated. Further, except for requiring that {ut} is I(0), cointegration between yt and xt does not re- strict the serial dependence in {ut}. Fortunately, the feature of (18.33) that makes inference the most difficult—the lack of strict exogeneity of {xt}—can be fixed. Because xt is I(1), the proper notion of strict exogeneity is that ut is uncorrelated with 􏰧xs, for all t and s. We can always arrange this Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 650 PART 3 Advanced Topics for a new set of errors, at least approximately, by writing ut as a function of the 􏰧xs for all s close to t. For example, ut 􏱪 􏱗 􏱕 􏰿0􏰧xt 􏱕 􏰿1􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰿2􏰧xt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧xt􏱕1 􏱕 􏰸2􏰧xt􏱕2 􏱕 et, [18.34] where, by construction, et is uncorrelated with each 􏰧xs appearing in the equation. The hope is that et is uncorrelated with further lags and leads of 􏰧xs. We know that, as 􏰫s 􏱦 t􏰫 gets large, the correlation between et and 􏰧xs approaches zero, because these are I(0) processes. Now, if we plug (18.34) into (18.33), we obtain yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱬xt 􏱕 􏰿0􏰧xt 􏱕 􏰿1􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰿2􏰧xt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧xt􏱕1 􏱕 􏰸2􏰧xt􏱕2 􏱕 et. [18.35] This equation looks a bit strange because future 􏰧xs appear with both current and lagged 􏰧xt. The key is that the coefficient on xt is still 􏱬, and, by construction, xt is now strictly exogenous in this equation. The strict exogeneity assumption is the important condition needed to obtain an approximately normal t statistic for 􏱬ˆ. If ut is uncorrelated with all 􏰧xs, s 􏱻 t, then we can drop the leads and lags of the changes and simply include the con- temporaneous change, 􏰧xt. Then, the equation we estimate looks more standard but still includes the first difference of xt along with its level: yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱬xt 􏱕 􏰿0􏰧xt 􏱕 et. In effect, adding 􏰧xt solves any contemporaneous endogeneity between xt and ut. (Remember, any endogeneity does not cause inconsistency. But we are trying to obtain an asymptotically normal t statistic.) Whether we need to include leads and lags of the changes, and how many, is really an empirical issue. Each time we add an additional lead or lag, we lose one observation, and this can be costly unless we have a large data set. The OLS estimator of 􏱬 from (18.35) is called the leads and lags estimator of 􏱬 because of the way it employs 􏰧x. [See, for example, Stock and Watson (1993).] The only issue we must worry about in (18.35) is the possibility of serial correlation in {et}. This can be dealt with by computing a serial correlation-robust standard error for 􏱬ˆ (as described in Section 12.5) or by using a standard AR(1) correction (such as Cochrane-Orcutt). EXAMPLE 18.6 COINTEGRATING PARAMETER FOR INTEREST RATES Earlier, we tested for cointegration between r6 and r3—six- and three-month T-bill rates—by assuming that the cointegrating parameter was equal to one. This led us to find cointegration and, naturally, to conclude that the cointegrating parameter is equal to unity. Nevertheless, let us estimate the cointegrating parameter directly and test H0: 􏱬 􏱪 1. We apply the leads and lags estimator with two leads and two lags of 􏰧r3, as well as the contemporaneous change. The estimate of 􏱬 is 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 1.038, and the usual OLS standard error is .0081. Therefore, the t statistic for H0: 􏱬 􏱪 1 is (1.038 􏱦 1)/.0081 􏱴 4.69, which is a strong statistical rejection of H0. (Of course, whether 1.038 is economically different from 1 is a relevant consideration.) There is little evidence of serial correlation in the residuals, so we can use this t statistic as having an approximate normal distribution. [For comparison, the OLS estimate of 􏱬 without the leads, lags, or contemporaneous 􏰧r3 terms—and using five more observations—is 1.026 (se 􏱪 .0077). But the t statistic from (18.33) is not necessarily valid.] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 651 There are many other estimators of cointegrating parameters, and this continues to be a very active area of research. The notion of cointegration applies to more than two pro- cesses, but the interpretation, testing, and estimation are much more complicated. One issue is that, even after we normalize a coefficient to be one, there can be many cointegrating relationships. BDGH provide some discussion and several references. Error Correction Models In addition to learning about a potential long-run relationship between two series, the con- cept of cointegration enriches the kinds of dynamic models at our disposal. If yt and xt are I(1) processes and are not cointegrated, we might estimate a dynamic model in first differ- ences. As an example, consider the equation 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸0􏰧xt 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 ut, [18.36] where ut has zero mean given 􏰧xt, 􏰧yt􏱦1, 􏰧xt􏱦1, and further lags. This is essentially equation (18.16), but in first differences rather than in levels. If we view this as a rational distributed lag model, we can find the impact propensity, long-run propensity, and lag distribution for 􏰧y as a distributed lag in 􏰧x. If yt and xt are cointegrated with parameter 􏱬, then we have additional I(0) variables that we can include in (18.36). Let st 􏱪 yt 􏱦 􏱬xt, so that st is I(0), and assume for the sake of simplicity that st has zero mean. Now, we can include lags of st in the equation. In the simplest case, we include one lag of st: 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸0􏰧xt 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛st􏱦1 􏱕 ut 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸0􏰧xt 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛(yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦1) 􏱕 ut, [18.37] where E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, and It􏱦1 contains information on 􏰧xt and all past values of x and y. The term 􏱛(yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦1) is called the error correction term, and (18.37) is an example of an error correction model. (In some error correction models, the contem- poraneous change in x, 􏰧xt, is omitted. Whether it is included or not depends partly on the purpose of the equation. In forecasting, 􏰧xt is rarely included, for reasons we will see in Section 18.5.) An error correction model allows us to study the short-run dynamics in the relationship between y and x. For simplicity, consider the model without lags of 􏰧yt and 􏰧xt: 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸0􏰧xt 􏱕 􏱛(yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦1) 􏱕 ut, [18.38] where 􏱛 􏱷 0. If yt􏱦1 􏱰 􏱬xt􏱦1, then y in the previous period has overshot the equilibrium; because 􏱛 􏱷 0, the error correction term works to push y back toward the equilibrium. Similarly, if yt􏱦1 􏱷 􏱬xt􏱦1, the error correction term induces a positive change in y back toward the equilibrium. How do we estimate the parameters of an error correction model? If we know 􏱬, this is easy. For example, in (18.38), we simply regress 􏰧yt on 􏰧xt and st􏱦1, where st􏱦1 􏱪 (yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦1). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 652 PART 3 Advanced Topics EXAMPLE 18.7 ERROR CORRECTION MODEL FOR HOLDING YIELDS In Problem 6 in Chapter 11, we regressed hy6t, the three-month holding yield (in percent) from buying a six-month T-bill at time t 􏱦 1 and selling it at time t as a three-month T-bill, on hy3t􏱦1, the three-month holding yield from buying a three-month T-bill at time t 􏱦 1. The expectations hypothesis im- plies that the slope coefficient should not be statistically different from one. It turns out that there is evidence of a unit root in {hy3t}, which calls into question the standard regression analysis. We will assume that both holding yields are I(1) processes. The expectations hypothesis implies, at a minimum, that hy6t and hy3t􏱦1 are cointegrated with 􏱬 equal to one, which appears to be the case (see Computer Exercise C5). Under this assumption, an error correction model is 􏰧hy6t 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸0􏰧hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛(hy6t􏱦1 􏱦 hy3t􏱦2) 􏱕 ut, where ut has zero mean, given all hy3 and hy6 dated at time t 􏱦 1 and earlier. The lags on the variables in the error correction model are dictated by the expectations hypothesis. Using the data in INTQRT.RAW gives 􏰧􏱾hy6t 􏱪 .090 􏱕 1.218 􏰧hy3t􏱦1 􏱦 .840 (hy6t􏱦1 􏱦 hy3t􏱦2) (.043) (.264) (.244) [18.39] n 􏱪 122, R2 􏱪 .790. The error correction coefficient is negative and very significant. For example, if the hold- ing yield on six-month T-bills is above that for three-month T-bills by one point, hy6 falls by .84 points on average in the next quarter. Interestingly, 􏱛ˆ 􏱪 􏱦.84 is not statistically different from 􏱦1, as is easily seen by computing the 95% confidence interval. In many other examples, the cointegrating parameter must be estimated. Then, we replace st􏱦1 with sˆt􏱦1 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬ˆxt􏱦1, where 􏱬ˆ can be various estimators of 􏱬. We have covered the standard OLS estimator as well as the leads and lags estimator. This raises the issue about how sampling variation in 􏱬ˆ affects inference on the other parameters in the error correction model. Fortunately, as shown by Engle and Granger (1987), we can ignore the preliminary estimation of 􏱬 (asymptotically). This property is very convenient and implies that the asymptotic efficiency of the estimators of the parameters in the error correction model is unaffected by whether we use the OLS estimator or the leads and lags estimator for 􏱬ˆ. Of course, the choice of 􏱬ˆ will generally have an effect on the estimated error correction parameters in any particular sample, but we have no systematic way of deciding which preliminary estimator of 􏱬 to use. The procedure of replacing 􏱬 with 􏱬ˆ is called the Engle-Granger two-step procedure. 18.5 Forecasting Forecasting economic time series is very important in some branches of economics, and it is an area that continues to be actively studied. In this section, we focus on regression- based forecasting methods. Diebold (2001) provides a comprehensive introduction to forecasting, including recent developments. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. EXPLORING FURTHER 18.4 HowwouldyoutestH0:􏰸0 􏱪1,􏱛􏱪􏱦1in the holding yield error correction model? 653 We assume in this section that the primary focus is on forecasting future values of a time series process and not necessarily on estimating causal or structural economic models. It is useful to first cover some fundamentals of forecasting that do not depend on a spe- cific model. Suppose that at time t we want to forecast the outcome of y at time t 􏱕 1, or yt􏱕1. The time period could correspond to a year, a quarter, a month, a week, or even a day. Let It denote information that we can observe at time t. This information set includes yt, earlier values of y, and often other variables dated at time t or earlier. We can combine this infor- mation in innumerable ways to forecast yt􏱕1. Is there one best way? The answer is yes, provided we specify the loss associated with forecast error. Let ft denote the forecast of yt􏱕1 made at time t. We call ft a one-step-ahead forecast. The fore- cast error is et􏱕1 􏱪 yt􏱕1 􏱦 ft, which we observe once the outcome on yt􏱕1 is observed. The most common measure of loss is the same one that leads to ordinary least squares estima- tion of a multiple linear regression model: the squared error, e2t 􏱕1. The squared forecast error treats positive and negative prediction errors symmetrically, and larger forecast errors receive relatively more weight. For example, errors of 􏱕2 and 􏱦2 yield the same loss, and the loss is four times as great as forecast errors of 􏱕1 or 􏱦1. The squared forecast error is an example of a loss function. Another popular loss function is the absolute value of the prediction error, 􏰫et􏱕1􏰫. For reasons to be seen shortly, we focus now on squared error loss. Given the squared error loss function, we can determine how to best use the informa- tion at time t to forecast yt􏱕1. But we must recognize that at time t, we do not know et􏱕1: it is a random variable, because yt􏱕1 is a random variable. Therefore, any useful criterion for choosing ft must be based on what we know at time t. It is natural to choose the forecast to minimize the expected squared forecast error, given It: E(e2t􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 E[(yt􏱕1 􏱦 ft)2􏰫It]. [18.40] A basic fact from probability (see Property CE.6 in Appendix B) is that the conditional expectation, E(yt􏱕1􏰫It), minimizes (18.40). In other words, if we wish to minimize the expected squared forecast error given information at time t, our forecast should be the expected value of yt􏱕1 given variables we know at time t. For many popular time series processes, the conditional expectation is easy to obtain. Suppose that {yt: t 􏱪 0, 1, ...} is a martingale difference sequence (MDS) and take It to be {yt, yt􏱦1, ..., y0}, the observed past of y. By definition, E(yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 0 for all t; the best prediction of yt􏱕1 at time t is always zero! Recall from Section 18.2 that an i.i.d. sequence with zero mean is a martingale difference sequence. A martingale difference sequence is one in which the past is not useful for predicting the future. Stock returns are widely thought to be well approximated as an MDS or, perhaps, with a positive mean. The key is that E(yt􏱕1􏰫yt, yt􏱦1, ...) 􏱪 E(yt􏱕1): the conditional mean is equal to the unconditional mean, in which case past y do not help to predict future y. A process {yt} is a martingale if E(yt􏱕1􏰫yt, yt􏱦1, ..., y0) 􏱪 yt for all t 􏱸 0. [If {yt} is a martingale, then {􏰧yt} is a martingale difference sequence, which is where the latter name comes from.] The predicted value of y for the next period is always the value of y for this period. A more complicated example is E(yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 􏱮yt 􏱕 􏱮(1 􏱦 􏱮)yt􏱦1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱮(1 􏱦 􏱮)ty0, [18.41] where 0 􏱷 􏱮 􏱷 1 is a parameter that we must choose. This method of forecasting is called exponential smoothing because the weights on the lagged y decline to zero exponentially. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 654 PART 3 Advanced Topics The reason for writing the expectation as in (18.41) is that it leads to a very simple recurrence relation. Set f0 􏱪 y0. Then, for t 􏱸 1, the forecasts can be obtained as ft 􏱪􏱮yt 􏱕(1􏱦􏱮)ft􏱦1. In other words, the forecast of yt􏱕1 is a weighted average of yt and the forecast of yt made at time t 􏱦 1. Exponential smoothing is suitable only for very specific time series and requires choosing 􏱮. Regression methods, which we turn to next, are more flexible. The previous discussion has focused on forecasting y only one period ahead. The general issues that arise in forecasting yt􏱕h at time t, where h is any positive integer, are similar. In particular, if we use expected squared forecast error as our measure of loss, the best predictor is E(yt􏱕h􏰫It). When dealing with a multiple-step-ahead forecast, we use the notation ft,h to indicate the forecast of yt􏱕h made at time t. Types of Regression Models Used for Forecasting There are many different regression models that we can use to forecast future values of a time series. The first regression model for time series data from Chapter 10 was the static model. To see how we can forecast with this model, assume that we have a single explana- tory variable: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt 􏱕 ut. [18.42] Suppose, for the moment, that the parameters 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 are known. Write this equation attimet􏱕1asyt􏱕1 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1zt􏱕1 􏱕ut􏱕1.Now,ifzt􏱕1 isknownattimet,sothatitisan element of It and E(ut􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 0, then E(yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1zt􏱕1, where It contains zt􏱕1, yt, zt, ..., y1, z1. The right-hand side of this equation is the forecast of yt􏱕1 at time t. This kind of forecast is usually called a conditional forecast because it is conditional on knowing the value of z at time t 􏱕 1. Unfortunately, at any time, we rarely know the value of the explanatory variables in future time periods. Exceptions include time trends and seasonal dummy variables, which we cover explicitly below, but otherwise knowledge of zt􏱕1 at time t is rare. Sometimes, we wish to generate conditional forecasts for several values of zt􏱕1. Another problem with (18.42) as a model for forecasting is that E(ut􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 0 means that {ut} cannot contain serial correlation, something we have seen to be false in most static regression models. [Problem 8 asks you to derive the forecast in a simple distributed lag model with AR(1) errors.] If zt􏱕1 is not known at time t, we cannot include it in It. Then, we have E(yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1E(zt􏱕1􏰫It). This means that in order to forecast yt􏱕1, we must first forecast zt􏱕1, based on the same information set. This is usually called an unconditional forecast because we do not as- sume knowledge of zt􏱕1 at time t. Unfortunately, this is somewhat of a misnomer, as our forecast is still conditional on the information in It. But the name is entrenched in the forecasting literature. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 655 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics For forecasting, unless we are wedded to the static model in (18.42) for other reasons, it makes more sense to specify a model that depends only on lagged values of y and z. This saves us the extra step of having to forecast a right-hand side variable before forecasting y. The kind of model we have in mind is yt 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏰸1zt􏱦1 􏱕ut E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, [18.43] where It􏱦1 contains y and z dated at time t 􏱦 1 and earlier. Now, the forecast of yt􏱕1 at time t is 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱮1yt 􏱕 􏰸1zt; if we know the parameters, we can just plug in the values of yt and zt. If we only want to use past y to predict future y, then we can drop zt􏱦1 from (18.43). Naturally, we can add more lags of y or z and lags of other variables. Especially for fore- casting one step ahead, such models can be very useful. One-Step-Ahead Forecasting Obtaining a forecast one period after the sample ends is relatively straightforward using models such as (18.43). As usual, let n be the sample size. The forecast of yn􏱕1 is fˆ 􏱪 􏱛ˆ 􏱕 􏱮ˆ y 􏱕 􏰸ˆ z , [18.44] n01n1n where we assume that the parameters have been estimated by OLS. We use a hat on fn to emphasize that we have estimated the parameters in the regression model. (If we knew the parameters, there would be no estimation error in the forecast.) The forecast error—which we will not know until time n 􏱕 1—is eˆ 􏱪 y 􏱦 fˆ. [18.45] n􏱕1 n􏱕1 n If we add more lags of y or z to the forecasting equation, we simply lose more observa- tions at the beginning of the sample. The forecast fˆ of y is usually called a point forecast. We can also obtain a fore- n n􏱕1 cast interval. A forecast interval is essentially the same as a prediction interval, which we studied in Section 6.4. There we showed how, under the classical linear model assump- tions, to obtain an exact 95% prediction interval. A forecast interval is obtained in exactly the same way. If the model does not satisfy the classical linear model assumptions—for example, if it contains lagged dependent variables, as in (18.44)—the forecast interval is still approximately valid, provided ut given It􏱦1 is normally distributed with zero mean and constant variance. (This ensures that the OLS estimators are approximately normally distributed with the usual OLS variances and that un􏱕1 is independent of the OLS esti- mators with mean zero and variance 􏱧2.) Let se( fˆ) be the standard error of the forecast nˆ and let 􏱧ˆ be the standard error of the regression. [From Section 6.4, we can obtain fn and se( fˆ) as the intercept and its standard error from the regression of y on (y 􏱦 y ) and n t t􏱦1 n (zt􏱦1 􏱦 zn), t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n; that is, we subtract the time n value of y from each lagged y, and similarly for z, before doing the regression.] Then, se(eˆ )􏱪{[se(fˆ)]2 􏱕􏱧ˆ2}1/2, [18.46] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. n􏱕1 n 656 PART 3 Advanced Topics and the (approximate) 95% forecast interval is fˆ 􏲁 1.96􏱳se(eˆ ). [18.47] n n􏱕1 ˆ __ˆ Because se( fn) is roughly proportional to 1/􏱯 n, se( fn) is usually small relative to the uncer- tainty in the error un􏱕1, as measured by 􏱧ˆ . [Some econometrics packages compute forecast intervals routinely, but others require some simple manipulations to obtain (18.47).] EXAMPLE 18.8 FORECASTING THE U.S. UNEMPLOYMENT RATE We use the data in PHILLIPS.RAW, but only for the years 1948 through 1996, to forecast the U.S. civilian unemployment rate for 1997. We use two models. The first is a simple AR(1) model for unem: [18.48] [18.49] The lagged inflation rate is very significant in (18.49) (t 􏱴 4.5), and the adjusted R-squared from the second equation is much higher than that from the first. Nevertheless, this does not necessarily mean that the second equation will produce a better forecast for 1997. All we can say so far is that, using the data up through 1996, a lag of inflation helps to explain variation in the unemployment rate. To obtain the forecasts for 1997, we need to know unem and inf in 1996. These are 5.4 and 3.0, respectively. Therefore, the forecast of unem1997 from equation (18.48) is 1.572 􏱕 .732(5.4), or about 5.52. The forecast from equation (18.49) is 1.304 􏱕 .647(5.4) 􏱕 .184(3.0), or about 5.35. The actual civilian unemployment rate for 1997 was 4.9, so both equations overpredict the actual rate. The second equation does provide a somewhat better forecast. We can easily obtain a 95% forecast interval. When we regress unemt on (unemt􏱦1 􏱦 5.4) u􏱾nemt 􏱪 1.572 􏱕 .732 unemt􏱦1 (.577) (.097) n􏱪48,R-2 􏱪.544,􏱧ˆ􏱪1.049. In a second model, we add inflation with a lag of one year: u􏱾nemt 􏱪 1.304 􏱕 .647 unemt􏱦1 􏱕 .184 inft􏱦1 (.490) (.084) (.041) n 􏱪 48, R- 2 􏱪 .677, 􏱧ˆ 􏱪 .883. and (inft􏱦1 􏱦 3.0), we obtain 5.35 as the intercept—which we already computed as the forecast—and se( fˆ) 􏱪 .137. Therefore, because 􏱧ˆ 􏱪 .883, we have se(eˆ ) 􏱪 [(.137)2 􏱕 n n􏱕1 (.883)2]1/2 􏱴 .894. The 95% forecast interval from (18.47) is 5.35 􏲁 1.96(.894), or about [3.6, 7.1]. This is a wide interval, and the realized 1997 value, 4.9, is well within the in- terval. As expected, the standard error of un􏱕1, which is .883, is a very large fraction of se(eˆn􏱕1). A professional forecaster must usually produce a forecast for every time period. For example, at time n, she or he produces a forecast of yn􏱕1. Then, when yn􏱕1 and zn􏱕1 become available, he or she must forecast yn􏱕2. Even if the forecaster has settled on model (18.43), there are two choices for forecasting yn􏱕2. The first is to use 􏱛ˆ0 􏱕 􏱮ˆ1yn􏱕1 􏱕 􏰸ˆ1zn􏱕1, where the parameters are estimated using the first n observations. The second possibility is to Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 657 and yt 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱮2yt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰸2zt􏱦2 􏱕 ... [18.50] zt 􏱪 􏱗0 􏱕 􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬2yt􏱦2 􏱕 􏰴2zt􏱦2 􏱕 ..., where each equation contains an error that has zero expected value given past information on y and z. In equation (18.43)—and in the example estimated in (18.49)—we assumed that one lag of each variable captured all of the dynamics. (An F test for joint significance of unemt􏱦2 and inft􏱦2 confirms that only one lag of each is needed.) As Example 18.8 illustrates, VAR models can be useful for forecasting. In many cases, we are interested in forecasting only one variable, y, in which case we only need to estimate and analyze the equation for y. Nothing prevents us from adding other lagged variables, say, wt􏱦1, wt􏱦2, ..., to equation (18.50). Such equations are efficiently estimated by OLS, provided we have included enough lags of all variables and the equation satisfies the homo- skedasticity assumption for time series regressions. Equations such as (18.50) allow us to test whether, after controlling for past y, past z help to forecast yt. Generally, we say that z Granger causes y if E(yt􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱻 E(yt􏰫Jt􏱦1), [18.51] where It􏱦1 contains past information on y and z, and Jt􏱦1 contains only information on past y. When (18.51) holds, past z is useful, in addition to past y, for predicting yt. The term “causes” in “Granger causes” should be interpreted with caution. The only sense in which z “causes” y is given in (18.51). In particular, it has nothing to say about contemporaneous causality between y and z, so it does not allow us to determine whether zt is an exogenous or endogenous variable in an equation relating yt to zt. (This is also why the notion of Granger causality does not apply in pure cross-sectional contexts.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics reestimate the parameters using all n 􏱕 1 observations and then to use the same formula to forecast yn􏱕2. To forecast in subsequent time periods, we can generally use the parameter estimates obtained from the initial n observations, or we can update the regression param- eters each time we obtain a new data point. Although the latter approach requires more computation, the extra burden is relatively minor, and it can (although it need not) work better because the regression coefficients adjust at least somewhat to the new data points. As a specific example, suppose we wish to forecast the unemployment rate for 1998, using the model with a single lag of unem and inf. The first possibility is to just plug the 1997 values of unemployment and inflation into the right-hand side of (18.49). With unem 􏱪 4.9 and inf 􏱪 2.3 in 1997, we have a forecast for unem1998 of about 4.9. (It is just a coincidence that this is the same as the 1997 unemployment rate.) The second possibility is to reestimate the equation by adding the 1997 observation and then using this new equa- tion (see Computer Exercise C6). The model in equation (18.43) is one equation in what is known as a vector autore- gressive (VAR) model. We know what an autoregressive model is from Chapter 11: we model a single series, {yt}, in terms of its own past. In vector autoregressive models, we model several series—which, if you are familiar with linear algebra, is where the word “vector” comes from—in terms of their own past. If we have two series, yt and zt, a vector autoregression consists of equations that look like 658 PART 3 Advanced Topics Once we assume a linear model and decide how many lags of y should be included in E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...), we can easily test the null hypothesis that z does not Granger cause y. To be more specific, suppose that E(yt􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) depends on only three lags: yt 􏱪􏱛0 􏱕􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏱮2yt􏱦2 􏱕􏱮3yt􏱦3 􏱕ut E(ut􏰫yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...) 􏱪 0. Now, under the null hypothesis that z does not Granger cause y, any lags of z that we add to the equation should have zero population coefficients. If we add zt􏱦1, then we can simply do a t test on zt􏱦1. If we add two lags of z, then we can do an F test for joint signifi- cance of zt􏱦1 and zt􏱦2 in the equation yt 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱮2yt􏱦2 􏱕 􏱮3yt􏱦3 􏱕 􏰸1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸2zt􏱦2 􏱕 ut. (If there is heteroskedasticity, we can use a robust form of the test. There cannot be serial correlation under H0 because the model is dynamically complete.) As a practical matter, how do we decide on which lags of y and z to include? First, we start by estimating an autoregressive model for y and performing t and F tests to determine how many lags of y should appear. With annual data, the number of lags is typically small, say, one or two. With quarterly or monthly data, there are usually many more lags. Once an autoregressive model for y has been chosen, we can test for lags of z. The choice of lags of z is less important because, when z does not Granger cause y, no set of lagged z’s should be significant. With annual data, 1 or 2 lags are typically used; with quarterly data, usually 4 or 8; and with monthly data, perhaps 6, 12, or maybe even 24, given enough data. We have already done one example of testing for Granger causality in equa- tion (18.49). The autoregressive model that best fits unemployment is an AR(1). In equa- tion (18.49), we added a single lag of inflation, and it was very significant. Therefore, inflation Granger causes unemployment. There is an extended definition of Granger causality that is often useful. Let {wt} be a third series (or, it could represent several additional series). Then, z Granger causes y con- ditional on w if (18.51) holds, but now It􏱦1 contains past information on y, z, and w, while Jt􏱦1 contains past information on y and w. It is certainly possible that z Granger causes y, but z does not Granger cause y conditional on w. A test of the null that z does not Granger cause y conditional on w is obtained by testing for significance of lagged z in a model for y that also depends on lagged y and lagged w. For example, to test whether growth in the money supply Granger causes growth in real GDP, conditional on the change in interest rates, we would regress gGDPt on lags of gGDP, 􏰧int, and gM and do significance tests on the lags of gM. [See, for example, Stock and Watson (1989).] Comparing One-Step-Ahead Forecasts In almost any forecasting problem, there are several competing methods for forecasting. Even when we restrict attention to regression models, there are many possibilities. Which variables should be included, and with how many lags? Should we use logs, levels of vari- ables, or first differences? In order to decide on a forecasting method, we need a way to choose which one is most suitable. Broadly, we can distinguish between in-sample criteria and out-of-sample Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 659 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics criteria. In a regression context, in-sample criteria include R-squared and especially adjusted R-squared. There are many other model selection statistics, but we will not cover those here [see, for example, Ramanathan (1995, Chapter 4)]. For forecasting, it is better to use out-of-sample criteria, as forecasting is essentially an out-of-sample problem. A model might provide a good fit to y in the sample used to estimate the parameters. But this need not translate to good forecasting performance. An out-of-sample comparison involves using the first part of a sample to estimate the param- eters of the model and saving the latter part of the sample to gauge its forecasting capabili- ties. This mimics what we would have to do in practice if we did not yet know the future values of the variables. Suppose that we have n 􏱕 m observations, where we use the first n observations to estimate the parameters in our model and save the last m observations for forecasting. Let fˆ be the one-step-ahead forecast of y for h 􏱪 0, 1, ..., m 􏱦 1. The m forecast errors n􏱕h ˆ n􏱕h􏱕1 are eˆn􏱕h􏱕1 􏱪 yn􏱕h􏱕1 􏱦 fn􏱕h. How should we measure how well our model forecasts y when it is out of sample? Two measures are most common. The first is the root mean squared error (RMSE): eˆn2􏱕h􏱕1􏱷 . [18.52] This is essentially the sample standard deviation of the forecast errors (without any degrees of freedom adjustment). If we compute RMSE for two or more forecasting methods, then we prefer the method with the smallest out-of-sample RMSE. A second common measure is the mean absolute error (MAE), which is the average of the absolute forecast errors: ∑m􏱦1 MAE 􏱪 m􏱦1 􏰫eˆ 􏰫. [18.53] RMSE􏱪􏱵m􏱦1 h􏱪0 Again, we prefer a smaller MAE. Other possible criteria include minimizing the largest of the absolute values of the forecast errors. EXAMPLE 18.9 OUT-OF-SAMPLE COMPARISONS OF UNEMPLOYMENT FORECASTS In Example 18.8, we found that equation (18.49) fit notably better over the years 1948 through 1996 than did equation (18.48), and, at least for forecasting unemployment in 1997, the model that included lagged inflation worked better. Now, we use the two models, still estimated using the data only through 1996, to compare one-step-ahead forecasts for 1997 through 2003. This leaves seven out-of-sample observations (n 􏱪 48 and m 􏱪 7) to use in equations (18.52) and (18.53). For the AR(1) model, RMSE 􏱪 .962 and MAE 􏱪 .778. For the model that adds lagged inflation (a VAR model of order one), RMSE 􏱪 .673 and MAE 􏱪 .628. Thus, by either measure, the model that includes inft􏱦1 produces better out- of-sample forecasts for 1997 through 2003. In this case, the in-sample and out-of-sample criteria choose the same model. Rather than using only the first n observations to estimate the parameters of the model, we can reestimate the models each time we add a new observation and use the new model to forecast the next time period. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∑m 􏱦 1 1 / 2 n􏱕h􏱕1 h􏱪0 660 PART 3 Advanced Topics Multiple-Step-Ahead Forecasts Forecasting more than one period ahead is generally more difficult than forecasting one period ahead. We can formalize this as follows. Suppose we consider forecasting yt􏱕1 at time t and at an earlier time period s (so that s 􏱷 t). Then Var[yt􏱕1 􏱦 E(yt􏱕1􏰫It)] 􏰯 Var[yt􏱕1 􏱦 E(yt􏱕1􏰫Is)], where the inequality is usually strict. We will not prove this result generally, but, intuitively, it makes sense: the forecast error variance in predicting yt􏱕1 is larger when we make that forecast based on less information. If {yt} follows an AR(1) model (which includes a random walk, possibly with drift), we can easily show that the error variance increases with the forecast horizon. The model is yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕ut E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, It􏱦1 􏱪 {yt􏱦1, yt􏱦2, ...}, and {ut} has constant variance 􏱧2 conditional on It􏱦1. At time t 􏱕 h 􏱦 1, our forecast of yt􏱕h is 􏱮 􏱕 􏰴yt􏱕h􏱦1, and the forecast error is simply ut􏱕h. Therefore, the one-step-ahead forecast variance is simply 􏱧2. To find multiple-step-ahead forecasts, we have, by repeated substitution, yt􏱕h 􏱪(1􏱕􏰴􏱕...􏱕􏰴h􏱦1)􏱮􏱕􏰴hyt 􏱕 􏰴h􏱦1ut􏱕1 􏱕 􏰴h􏱦2ut􏱕2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ut􏱕h. At time t, the expected value of ut􏱕j, for all j 􏱸 1, is zero. So E(yt􏱕h􏰫It) 􏱪 (1 􏱕 􏰴 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰴h􏱦1)􏱮 􏱕 􏰴hyt, [18.54] and the forecast error is et,h 􏱪 􏰴h􏱦1ut􏱕1 􏱕 􏰴h􏱦2ut􏱕2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ut􏱕h. This is a sum of un- correlated random variables, and so the variance of the sum is the sum of the variances: Var(et,h) 􏱪 􏱧2[􏰴2(h􏱦1) 􏱕 􏰴2(h􏱦2) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰴2 􏱕 1]. Because 􏰴2 􏱰 0, each term multiplying 􏱧2 is positive, so the forecast error variance increases with h. When 􏰴2 􏱷 1, as h gets large the forecast variance converges to 􏱧2/(1 􏱦 􏰴2), which is just the unconditional variance of yt. In the case of a random walk (􏰴 􏱪 1), ft,h 􏱪 􏱮h 􏱕 yt, and Var(et,h) 􏱪 􏱧2h: the fore- cast variance grows without bound as the horizon h increases. This demonstrates that it is very difficult to forecast a random walk, with or without drift, far out into the future. For example, forecasts of interest rates farther into the future become dramatically less precise. Equation (18.54) shows that using the AR(1) model for multistep forecasting is easy, once we have estimated 􏰴 by OLS. The forecast of yn􏱕h at time n is fˆ 􏱪(1􏱕􏰴ˆ􏱕...􏱕􏰴ˆh􏱦1)􏱮ˆ􏱕􏰴ˆhy . [18.55] n,h n Obtaining forecast intervals is harder, unless h 􏱪 1, because obtaining the standard error of fˆ isdifficult.Nevertheless,thestandarderroroffˆ isusuallysmallcomparedwiththestan- n,h n,h dard deviation of the error term, and the latter can be estimated as 􏱧ˆ [􏰴ˆ2(h􏱦1) 􏱕 􏰴ˆ2(h􏱦2) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰴ˆ2 􏱕 1]1/2, where 􏱧ˆ is the standard error of the regression from the AR(1) estimation. We can use this to obtain an approximate confidence interval. For example, when h 􏱪 2, an approximate 95% confidence interval (for large n) is fˆ 􏲁1.96􏱧ˆ(1􏱕􏰴ˆ2)1/2. [18.56] n,2 Because we are underestimating the standard deviation of yn􏱕h, this interval is too narrow, but perhaps not by much, especially if n is large. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 661 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics A less traditional, but useful, approach is to estimate a different model for each forecast horizon. For example, suppose we wish to forecast y two periods ahead. If It depends only on y through time t, we might assume that E(yt􏱕2􏰫It) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸1yt [which, as we saw earlier, holds if {yt} follows an AR(1) model]. We can estimate 􏱮0 and 􏰸1 by regressing yt on an intercept and on yt􏱦2. Even though the errors in this equation contain serial correlation—errors in adjacent periods are correlated—we can obtain consistent and approximately normal estimators of 􏱮0 and 􏰸1. The forecast of yn􏱕2 at time n is simply fˆ 􏱪 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏰸ˆ y . Further, and very importantly, the standard error of the regression is just n,2 0 1n what we need for computing a confidence interval for the forecast. Unfortunately, to get the standard error of fˆ , using the trick for a one-step-ahead forecast requires us to obtain a n,2 serial correlation-robust standard error of the kind described in Section 12.5. This standard error goes to zero as n gets large while the variance of the error is constant. Therefore, we can get an approximate interval by using (18.56) and by putting the SER from the regres- s i o n o f y t o n y t 􏱦 2 i n p l a c e o f 􏱧ˆ ( 1 􏱕 􏰴ˆ 2 ) 1 / 2 . B u t w e s h o u l d r e m e m b e r t h a t t h i s i g n o r e s t h e estimation error in 􏱮ˆ0 and 􏰸ˆ1. We can also compute multiple-step-ahead forecasts with more complicated autore- gressive models. For example, suppose {yt} follows an AR(2) model and that at time n, we wish to forecast yn􏱕2. Now, yn􏱕2 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰴1yn􏱕1 􏱕 􏰴2yn 􏱕 un􏱕2, so We can write this as E(yn􏱕2􏰫In) 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰴1E(yn􏱕1􏰫In) 􏱕 􏰴2yn. fn,2 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏰴1fn,1 􏱕􏰴2yn, so that the two-step-ahead forecast at time n can be obtained once we get the one-step- ahead forecast. If the parameters of the AR(2) model have been estimated by OLS, then we operationalize this as fˆ 􏱪 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏰴ˆ fˆ 􏱕 􏰴ˆ y . [18.57] n,2 1 n,1 2 n Now,fˆ 􏱪􏱮ˆ􏱕􏰴ˆ y 􏱕􏰴ˆ y ,whichwecancomputeattimen.Then,weplugthisinto n,1 1 n 2 n􏱦1 ˆ (18.57), along with yn, to obtain fn,2. For any h 􏱰 2, obtaining any h-step-ahead forecast for an AR(2) model is easy to find in a recursive manner: fˆ 􏱪 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏰴ˆ fˆ 􏱕 􏰴ˆ fˆ . n,h 1 n,h􏱦1 2 n,h􏱦2 Similar reasoning can be used to obtain multiple-step-ahead forecasts for VAR mod- els. To illustrate, suppose we have yt 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱮1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸1zt􏱦1 􏱕 ut [18.58] and zt 􏱪􏱗0 􏱕􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏰴1zt􏱦1 􏱕vt. Now,ifwewishtoforecasty attimen,wesimplyusefˆ 􏱪􏱛ˆ 􏱕􏱮ˆ y 􏱕􏰸ˆ z .Like- n􏱕1 ˆn,1 0 1n 1n wise, the forecast of zn􏱕1 at time n is (say) gˆn,1 􏱪 􏱗ˆ0 􏱕 􏱬1yn 􏱕 􏰴ˆ1zn. Now, suppose we wish to obtain a two-step-ahead forecast of y at time n. From (18.58), we have E(yn􏱕2􏰫In) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱮1E(yn􏱕1􏰫In) 􏱕 􏰸1E(zn􏱕1􏰫In) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 662 PART 3 Advanced Topics [because E(un􏱕2􏰫In) 􏱪 0], so we can write the forecast as fˆ 􏱪 􏱛ˆ 􏱕 􏱮ˆ fˆ 􏱕 􏰸ˆ gˆ . [18.59] n,2 0 1 n,1 1 n,1 This equation shows that the two-step-ahead forecast for y depends on the one-step-ahead forecasts for y and z. Generally, we can build up multiple-step-ahead forecasts of y by using the recursive formula fˆ􏱪􏱛ˆ􏱕􏱮ˆfˆ 􏱕􏰸ˆgˆ ,h􏱸2. n,h 0 1 n,h􏱦1 1 n,h􏱦1 EXAMPLE 18.10 TWO-YEAR-AHEAD FORECAST FOR THE UNEMPLOYMENT RATE To use equation (18.49) to forecast unemployment two years out—say, the 1998 rate us- ing the data through 1996—we need a model for inflation. The best model for inf in terms of lagged unem and inf appears to be a simple AR(1) model (unem􏱦1 is not significant when added to the regression): 􏱾inf 􏱪(1.277)􏱕(.665)inf ˆt t􏱦1 inft 􏱪0(.558)􏱕(.107)inft􏱦1 n􏱪48,R2 􏱪.457,R-2 􏱪.445. If we plug the 1996 value of inf into this equation, we get the forecast of inf for 1997: 􏱾inf 􏱪 3.27. Now, we can plug this, along with 􏱾unem 􏱪 5.35 (which we obtained 1997 1997 earlier), into (18.59) to forecast unem1998: u􏱾nem1998 􏱪 1.304 􏱕 .647(5.35) 􏱕 .184(3.27) 􏱴 5.37. Remember, this forecast uses information only through 1996. The one-step-ahead forecast of unem1998, obtained by plugging the 1997 values of unem and inf into (18.48), was about 4.90. The actual unemployment rate in 1998 was 4.5%, which means that, in this case, the one-step-ahead forecast does quite a bit better than the two-step-ahead forecast. Just as with one-step-ahead forecasting, an out-of-sample root mean squared error or a mean absolute error can be used to choose among multiple-step-ahead forecasting methods. Forecasting Trending, Seasonal, and Integrated Processes We now turn to forecasting series that either exhibit trends, have seasonality, or have unit roots. Recall from Chapters 10 and 11 that one approach to handling trending dependent or independent variables in regression models is to include time trends, the most popular being a linear trend. Trends can be included in forecasting equations as well, although they must be used with caution. In the simplest case, suppose that {yt} has a linear trend but is unpredictable around that trend. Then, we can write Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 663 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬t 􏱕 ut, E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., [18.60] where, as usual, It􏱦1 contains information observed through time t 􏱦 1 (which includes at least past y). How do we forecast yn􏱕h at time n for any h 􏱸 1? This is simple because E(yn􏱕h􏰫In) 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬(n 􏱕 h). The forecast error variance is simply 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(ut) (assuming a constant variance over time). If we estimate 􏱮 and 􏱬 by OLS using the at time n is fˆ 􏱪 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏱬ˆ (n 􏱕 h). In other words, n􏱕h n,h first n observations, then our forecast for y we simply plug the time period corresponding to y into the estimated trend function. For ex- ample, if we use the n 􏱪 131 observations in BARIUM.RAW to forecast monthly imports of Chinese barium chloride to the United States from China, we obtain 􏱮ˆ 􏱪 249.56 and 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 5.15. The sample period ends in December 1988, so the forecast of imports of Chinese barium chloride six months later is 249.56 􏱕 5.15(137) 􏱪 955.11, measured as short tons. For comparison, the December 1988 value is 1,087.81, so it is greater than the fore- casted value six months later. The series and its estimated trend line are shown in Figure 18.2. As we discussed in Chapter 10, most economic time series are better characterized as having, at least approximately, a constant growth rate, which suggests that log(yt) follows a linear time trend. Suppose we use n observations to obtain the equation log(yt) 􏱪 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏱬ˆt, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. [18.61] Then, to forecast log(y) at any future time period n 􏱕 h, we just plug n 􏱕 h into the trend equation, as before. But this does not allow us to forecast y, which is usually what we want. It is tempting to simply exponenti- ate 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏱬ˆ(n 􏱕 h) to obtain the forecast EXPLORING FURTHER 18.5 Suppose you model {yt: t 􏱪 1, 2,..., 46} as a linear time trend, where data are annual starting in 1950 and ending in 1995. Define the variable yeart as ranging from 50 when t 􏱪 1 to 95 when t 􏱪 46. If you estimate the equation yˆt 􏱪 􏰸ˆ 􏱕 􏱛ˆyeart, how do 􏰸ˆ and 􏱛ˆ compare with ˆ􏱮 and ˆ􏱬 in ˆyt 􏱪 ˆ􏱮 􏱕 ˆ􏱬t? How will forecasts from the two equations compare? for yn􏱕h, but this is not quite right, for the same reasons we gave in Section 6.4. We must properly account for the error im- plicit in (18.61). The simplest way to do this is to use the n observations to regress yt on exp(􏱾logyt) without an intercept. Let 􏰸ˆ be the slope coefficient on exp(􏱾logyt). Then, the forecast of y in period n 􏱕 h is simply fˆ 􏱪 􏰸ˆexp[􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏱬ˆ(n 􏱕 h)]. n,h [18.62] As an example, if we use the first 687 weeks of data on the New York Stock Exchange index in NYSE.RAW, we obtain 􏱮ˆ 􏱪 3.782 and 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 .0019 [by regressing log( pricet) on a linear time trend]; this shows that the index grows about .2% per week, on average. When we regress price on the exponentiated fitted values, we obtain 􏰸ˆ 􏱪 1.018. Now, we forecast price four weeks out, which is the last week in the sample, using (18.62): 1.018􏱳exp[3.782 􏱕 .0019(691)] 􏱴 166.12. The actual value turned out to be 164.25, so we have somewhat overpredicted. But this result is much better than if we estimate a linear time trend for the first 687 weeks: the forecasted value for week 691 is 152.23, which is a substantial underprediction. Although trend models can be useful for prediction, they must be used with caution, especially for forecasting far into the future integrated series that have drift. The Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 664 PART 3 Advanced Topics F I G U R E 1 8 . 2 U.S. imports of Chinese barium chloride (in short tons) and its estimated linear trend line, 249.56 􏱕 5.15t. barium chloride (short tons) 1,500 1,000 500 40 1 35 70 100 131 t potential problem can be seen by considering a random walk with drift. At time t 􏱕 h, we can write yt􏱕h as yt􏱕h 􏱪􏱬h􏱕yt 􏱕ut􏱕1 􏱕...􏱕ut􏱕h, where 􏱬 is the drift term (usually 􏱬 􏱰 0), and each ut􏱕j has zero mean given It and con- stant variance 􏱧2. As we saw earlier, the forecast of yt􏱕h at time t is E(yt􏱕h􏰫It) 􏱪 􏱬h 􏱕 yt, and the forecast error variance is 􏱧2h. What happens if we use a linear trend model? Let y0 be the initial value of the process at time zero, which we take as nonrandom. Then, we can also write yt􏱕h 􏱪y0 􏱕􏱬(t􏱕h)􏱕u1 􏱕u2 􏱕...􏱕ut􏱕h 􏱪y0 􏱕􏱬(t􏱕h)􏱕vt􏱕h. This looks like a linear trend model with the intercept 􏱮 􏱪 y0. But the error, vt􏱕h, while having mean zero, has variance 􏱧2(t 􏱕 h). Therefore, if we use the linear trend y0 􏱕 􏱬(t 􏱕 h) to forecast yt􏱕h at time t, the forecast error variance is 􏱧2(t 􏱕 h), compared with 􏱧2h when we use 􏱬h 􏱕 yt. The ratio of the forecast variances is (t 􏱕 h)/h, which can be big for large t. The bottom line is that we should not use a linear trend to forecast a random walk with drift. (Computer Exercise C8 asks you to compare forecasts from a cubic trend line and those from the simple random walk model for the general fertility rate in the United States.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 665 CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics Deterministic trends can also produce poor forecasts if the trend parameters are esti- mated using old data and the process has a subsequent shift in the trend line. Sometimes, exogenous shocks—such as the oil crises of the 1970s—can change the trajectory of trend- ing variables. If an old trend line is used to forecast far into the future, the forecasts can be way off. This problem can be mitigated by using the most recent data available to obtain the trend line parameters. Nothing prevents us from combining trends with other models for forecasting. For ex- ample, we can add a linear trend to an AR(1) model, which can work well for forecasting series with linear trends but which are also stable AR processes around the trend. It is also straightforward to forecast processes with deterministic seasonality (monthly or quarterly series). For example, the file BARIUM.RAW contains the monthly produc- tion of gasoline in the United States from 1978 through 1988. This series has no obvious trend, but it does have a strong seasonal pattern. (Gasoline production is higher in the sum- mer months and in December.) In the simplest model, we would regress gas (measured in gallons) on 11 month dummies, say, for February through December. Then, the forecast for any future month is simply the intercept plus the coefficient on the appropriate month dummy. (For January, the forecast is just the intercept in the regression.) We can also add lags of variables and time trends to allow for general series with seasonality. Forecasting processes with unit roots also deserves special attention. Earlier, we ob- tained the expected value of a random walk conditional on information through time n. To forecast a random walk, with possible drift 􏱮, h periods into the future at time n, we use fˆ 􏱪􏱮ˆh􏱕y,where􏱮ˆisthesampleaverageofthe􏰧y upthrought􏱪n.(Ifthereisno n,hn t drift, we set 􏱮ˆ 􏱪 0.) This approach imposes the unit root. An alternative would be to esti- mate an AR(1) model for {yt} and to use the forecast formula (18.55). This approach does not impose a unit root, but if one is present, 􏰴ˆ converges in probability to one as n gets large. Nevertheless, 􏰴ˆ can be substantially different than one, especially if the sample size is not very large. The matter of which approach produces better out-of-sample forecasts is an empirical issue. If in the AR(1) model, 􏰴 is less than one, even slightly, the AR(1) model will tend to produce better long-run forecasts. Generally, there are two approaches to producing forecasts for I(1) processes. The first is to impose a unit root. For a one-step-ahead forecast, we obtain a model to forecast the change in y, 􏰧yt􏱕1, given information through time t. Then, because yt􏱕1 􏱪 􏰧yt􏱕1 􏱕 yt, E(yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 E(􏰧yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱕 yt. Therefore, our forecast of yn􏱕1 at time n is just fˆ 􏱪 gˆ 􏱕 y , nnn where gˆn is the forecast of 􏰧yn􏱕1 at time n. Typically, an AR model (which is necessarily stable) is used for 􏰧yt, or a vector autoregression. This can be extended to multiple-step-ahead forecasts by writing yn􏱕h as yn􏱕h 􏱪 (yn􏱕h 􏱦 yn􏱕h􏱦1) 􏱕 (yn􏱕h􏱦1 􏱦 yn􏱕h􏱦2) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 (yn􏱕1 􏱦 yn) 􏱕 yn, or yn􏱕h 􏱪 􏰧yn􏱕h 􏱕 􏰧yn􏱕h􏱦1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏰧yn􏱕1 􏱕 yn. Therefore, the forecast of yn􏱕h at time n is Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 666 PART 3 Advanced Topics fˆ 􏱪gˆ 􏱕gˆ 􏱕...􏱕gˆ 􏱕y, [18.63] n,h n,h n,h􏱦1 n,1 n where gˆn,j is the forecast of 􏰧yn􏱕j at time n. For example, we might model 􏰧yt as a stable AR(1), obtain the multiple-step-ahead forecasts from (18.55) (but with 􏱮ˆ and 􏰴ˆ obtained from 􏰧yt on 􏰧yt􏱦1, and yn replaced with 􏰧yn), and then plug these into (18.63). The second approach to forecasting I(1) variables is to use a general AR or VAR model for {yt}. This does not impose the unit root. For example, if we use an AR(2) model, yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰴1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴2yt􏱦2 􏱕 ut, [18.64] then􏰴1 􏱕􏰴2 􏱪1.Ifweplugin􏰴1 􏱪1􏱦􏰴2 andrearrange,weobtain􏰧yt 􏱪􏱮􏱦􏰴2􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕ut, which is a stable AR(1) model in the difference that takes us back to the first approach described earlier. Nothing prevents us from estimating (18.64) directly by OLS. One nice thing about this regression is that we can use the usual t statistic on 􏰴ˆ2 to determine if yt􏱦2 is significant. (This assumes that the homoskedasticity assumption holds; if not, we can use the heteroskedasticity-robust form.) We will not show this formally, but, intuitively, it follows by rewriting the equation as yt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰸yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏰴2􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕 ut, where 􏰸 􏱪 􏰴1 􏱕 􏰴2. Even if 􏰸 􏱪 1, 􏰴2 is minus the coefficient on a stationary, weakly dependent process {􏰧yt􏱦1}. Because the regression results will be identical to (18.64), we can use (18.64) directly. As an example, let us estimate an AR(2) model for the general fertility rate in FERTIL3.RAW, using the observations through 1979. (In Computer Exercise C8, you are asked to use this model for forecasting, which is why we save some observations at the end of the sample.) gfr 􏱪 3.22 􏱕 1.272 gfr t t􏱦1 (2.92) (.120) - n 􏱪 65, R2 􏱪 .949, R2 􏱪 .947. 􏱾 􏱦 .311 gfr t􏱦2 The t statistic on the second lag is about 􏱦2.57, which is statistically different from zero at about the 1% level. (The first lag also has a very significant t statistic, which has an approximate t distribution by the same reasoning used for 􏰴ˆ2.) The R-squared, adjusted or not, is not especially informative as a goodness-of-fit measure because gfr apparently contains a unit root, and it makes little sense to ask how much of the variance in gfr we are explaining. The coefficients on the two lags in (18.65) add up to .961, which is close to and not statistically different from one (as can be verified by applying the augmented Dickey-Fuller test to the equation 􏰧gfrt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏰩gfrt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛1􏰧gfrt􏱦1 􏱕 ut). Even though we have not imposed the unit root restriction, we can still use (18.65) for forecasting, as we discussed earlier. Before ending this section, we point out one potential improvement in forecasting in the context of vector autoregressive models with I(1) variables. Suppose {yt} and {zt} are each I(1) processes. One approach for obtaining forecasts of y is to estimate a bivari- ate autoregression in the variables 􏰧yt and 􏰧zt and then to use (18.63) to generate one- or multiple-step-ahead forecasts; this is essentially the first approach we described earlier. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. (.121) [18.65] To forecast yn􏱕1, we use observations up through n to estimate the cointegrating param- eter, 􏱬, and then estimate the parameters of the error correction model by OLS, as de- scribed in Section 18.4. Forecasting 􏰧yn􏱕1 is easy: we just plug 􏰧yn, 􏰧zn, and yn 􏱦 􏱬ˆzn into the estimated equation. Having obtained the forecast of 􏰧yn􏱕1, we add it to yn. By rearranging the error correction model, we can write yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰴1yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴2yt􏱦2 􏱕 􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛2zt􏱦2 􏱕 ut, [18.67] where􏰴1 􏱪1􏱕􏱮1 􏱕􏱛,􏰴2 􏱪􏱦􏱮1,andsoon,whichisthefirstequationinaVAR model for yt and zt. Notice that this depends on five parameters, just as many as in the error correction model. The point is that, for the purposes of forecasting, the VAR model in the levels and the error correction model are essentially the same. This is not the case in more general error correction models. For example, suppose that 􏱮1 􏱪 􏰸1 􏱪 0 in (18.66), but we have a second error correction term, 􏱛2(yt􏱦2 􏱦 􏱬zt􏱦2). Then, the error correction model involves only four parameters, whereas (18.67)—which has the same order of lags for y and z—contains five parameters. Thus, error correction models can economize on parameters; that is, they are generally more parsimonious than VARs in levels. If yt and zt are I(1) but not cointegrated, the appropriate model is (18.66) without the error correction term. This can be used to forecast 􏰧yn􏱕1, and we can add this to yn to forecast yn􏱕1. Summary The time series topics covered in this chapter are used routinely in empirical macroeco- nomics, empirical finance, and a variety of other applied fields. We began by showing how infinite distributed lag models can be interpreted and estimated. These can provide flex- ible lag distributions with fewer parameters than a similar finite distributed lag model. The geometric distributed lag and, more generally, rational distributed lag models are the most popular. They can be estimated using standard econometric procedures on simple dynamic equations. Testing for a unit root has become very common in time series econometrics. If a series has a unit root, then, in many cases, the usual large sample normal approximations are no longer valid. In addition, a unit root process has the property that an innovation has a long- lasting effect, which is of interest in its own right. While there are many tests for unit roots, the Dickey-Fuller t test—and its extension, the augmented Dickey-Fuller test—is probably the most popular and easiest to implement. We can allow for a linear trend when testing for unit roots by adding a trend to the Dickey-Fuller regression. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 667 However, if yt and zt are cointegrated, we have more stationary, stable variables in the information set that can be used in forecasting 􏰧y: namely, lags of yt 􏱦 􏱬zt, where 􏱬 is the cointegrating parameter. A simple error correction model is 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1􏰧yt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧zt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛1(yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬zt􏱦1) 􏱕 et, E(et􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0. [18.66] 668 PART 3 Advanced Topics When an I(1) series, yt, is regressed on another I(1) series, xt, there is serious concern about spurious regression, even if the series do not contain obvious trends. This has been studied thoroughly in the case of a random walk: even if the two random walks are independent, the usual t test for significance of the slope coefficient, based on the usual critical values, will reject much more than the nominal size of the test. In addition, the R2 tends to a random variable, rather than to zero (as would be the case if we regress the difference in yt on the difference in xt). In one important case, a regression involving I(1) variables is not spurious, and that is when the series are cointegrated. This means that a linear function of the two I(1) vari- ables is I(0). If yt and xt are I(1) but yt 􏱦 xt is I(0), yt and xt cannot drift arbitrarily far apart. There are simple tests of the null of no cointegration against the alternative of cointegra- tion, one of which is based on applying a Dickey-Fuller unit root test to the residuals from a static regression. There are also simple estimators of the cointegrating parameter that yield t statistics with approximate standard normal distributions (and asymptotically valid confidence intervals). We covered the leads and lags estimator in Section 18.4. Cointegration between yt and xt implies that error correction terms may appear in a model relating 􏰧yt to 􏰧xt; the error correction terms are lags in yt 􏱦 􏱬xt, where 􏱬 is the cointegrating parameter. A simple two-step estimation procedure is available for estimat- ing error correction models. First, 􏱬 is estimated using a static regression (or the leads and lags regression). Then, OLS is used to estimate a simple dynamic model in first differ- ences that includes the error correction terms. Section 18.5 contained an introduction to forecasting, with emphasis on regression- based forecasting methods. Static models or, more generally, models that contain explana- tory variables dated contemporaneously with the dependent variable, are limited because then the explanatory variables need to be forecasted. If we plug in hypothesized values of unknown future explanatory variables, we obtain a conditional forecast. Unconditional forecasts are similar to simply modeling yt as a function of past information we have observed at the time the forecast is needed. Dynamic regression models, including au- toregressions and vector autoregressions, are used routinely. In addition to obtaining one- step-ahead point forecasts, we also discussed the construction of forecast intervals, which are very similar to prediction intervals. Various criteria are used for choosing among forecasting methods. The most common performance measures are the root mean squared error and the mean absolute error. Both estimate the size of the average forecast error. It is most informative to compute these measures using out-of-sample forecasts. Multiple-step-ahead forecasts present new challenges and are subject to large forecast error variances. Nevertheless, for models such as autoregressions and vector autoregres- sions, multi-step-ahead forecasts can be computed, and approximate forecast intervals can be obtained. Forecasting trending and I(1) series requires special care. Processes with deterministic trends can be forecasted by including time trends in regression models, possibly with lags of variables. A potential drawback is that deterministic trends can provide poor forecasts for long-horizon forecasts: once it is estimated, a linear trend continues to increase or decrease. The typical approach to forecasting an I(1) process is to forecast the difference in the process and to add the level of the variable to that forecasted difference. Alterna- tively, vector autoregressive models can be used in the levels of the series. If the series are cointegrated, error correction models can be used instead. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Key Terms Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test Cointegration Conditional Forecast Dickey-Fuller Distribution Dickey-Fuller (DF) Test Engle-Granger Test Engle-Granger Two-Step Procedure Error Correction Model Exponential Smoothing Forecast Error Forecast Interval Geometric (or Koyck) Distributed Lag Problems 1 Consider equation (18.15) with k 􏱪 2. Using the IV approach to estimating the 􏰸h and 􏰴, what would you use as instruments for yt􏱦1? 2 An interesting economic model that leads to an econometric model with a lagged depen- dent variable relates yt to the expected value of xt, say, x*t , where the expectation is based on all observed information at time t 􏱦 1: yt 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1x*t 􏱕 ut. [18.68] A natural assumption on {ut} is that E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, where It􏱦1 denotes all information on y and x observed at time t 􏱦 1; this means that E(yt􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏱮1x*t . To complete this model, we need an assumption about how the expectation x*t is formed. We saw a simple example of adaptive expectations in Section 11.2, where x*t 􏱪 xt􏱦1. A more complicated adaptive expectations scheme is x*t 􏱦 x*t 􏱦1 􏱪 l(xt􏱦1 􏱦 x*t 􏱦1), [18.69] where 0 􏱷 l 􏱷 1. This equation implies that the change in expectations reacts to whether last period’s realized value was above or below its expectation. The assumption 0 􏱷 􏲇 􏱷 1 im- plies that the change in expectations is a fraction of last period’s error. (i) Show that the two equations imply that yt 􏱪􏲇􏱮0 􏱕(1􏱦􏲇)yt􏱦1 􏱕􏲇􏱮1xt􏱦1 􏱕ut 􏱦(1􏱦􏲇)ut􏱦1. [Hint: Lag equation (18.68) one period, multiply it by (1 􏱦 􏲇), and subtract this from (18.68). Then, use (18.69).] (ii) Under E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, {ut} is serially uncorrelated. What does this imply about the new errors, vt 􏱪 ut 􏱦 (1 􏱦 􏲇)ut􏱦1? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 669 Granger Causality Infinite Distributed Lag (IDL) Model Information Set In-Sample Criteria Leads and Lags Estimator Loss Function Martingale Martingale Difference Sequence Mean Absolute Error (MAE) Multiple-Step-Ahead Forecast One-Step-Ahead Forecast Out-of-Sample Criteria Point Forecast Rational Distributed Lag (RDL) Model Root Mean Squared Error (RMSE) Spurious Regression Problem Unconditional Forecast Unit Roots Vector Autoregressive (VAR) Model 670 PART 3 Advanced Topics (iii) If we write the equation from part (i) as yt 􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1yt􏱦1 􏱕􏱬2xt􏱦1 􏱕vt, how would you consistently estimate the 􏱬j? (iv) Given consistent estimators of the 􏱬j, how would you consistently estimate 􏲇 and 􏱮1? 3 Suppose that {yt} and {zt} are I(1) series, but yt 􏱦 􏱬zt is I(0) for some 􏱬 􏱻 0. Show that for any 􏱛 􏱻 􏱬, yt 􏱦 􏱛zt must be I(1). 4 Consider the error correction model in equation (18.37). Show that if you add another lag of the error correction term, yt􏱦2 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦2, the equation suffers from perfect collinearity. (Hint: Show that yt􏱦2 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦2 is a perfect linear function of yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦1, 􏰧xt􏱦1, and 􏰧yt􏱦1.) 5 Suppose the process {(xt, yt): t 􏱪 0, 1, 2, ...} satisfies the equations yt 􏱪􏱬xt 􏱕ut and 􏰧xt 􏱪 􏰸􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 vt, where E(ut􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 E(vt􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, It􏱦1 contains information on x and y dated at time t 􏱦 1 and earlier, 􏱬 􏱻 0, and 􏰫􏰸􏰫 􏱷 1 [so that xt, and therefore yt, is I(1)]. Show that these two equations imply an error correction model of the form 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏰸1􏰧xt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛(yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱬xt􏱦1) 􏱕 et, where 􏰸1 􏱪 􏱬􏰸, 􏱛 􏱪 􏱦1, and et 􏱪 ut 􏱕 􏱬vt. (Hint: First subtract yt􏱦1 from both sides of the first equation. Then, add and subtract 􏱬xt􏱦1 from the right-hand side and rearrange. Finally, use the second equation to get the error correction model that contains 􏰧xt􏱦1.) 6 Using the monthly data in VOLAT.RAW, the following model was estimated: 􏱾pcip 􏱪(1.54)􏱕(.344)pcip􏱦1 􏱕(.074)pcip􏱦2 􏱕(.073)pcip􏱦3 􏱕(.031)pcsp􏱦1 pciˆp 􏱪0(.56)􏱕(.042) - (.045) (.042) (.013) n 􏱪 554, R2 􏱪 .174,R2 􏱪 .168, where pcip is the percentage change in monthly industrial production, at an annualized rate, and pcsp is the percentage change in the Standard & Poor’s 500 Index, also at an an- nualized rate. (i) If the past three months of pcip are zero and pcsp􏱦1 􏱪 0, what is the predicted growth in industrial production for this month? Is it statistically different from zero? (ii) If the past three months of pcip are zero but pcsp􏱦1 􏱪 10, what is the predicted growth in industrial production? (iii) What do you conclude about the effects of the stock market on real economic activity? 7 Let gMt be the annual growth in the money supply and let unemt be the unemployment rate. Assuming that unemt follows a stable AR(1) process, explain in detail how you would test whether gM Granger causes unem. 8 Suppose that yt follows the model Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 671 yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛1zt􏱦1 􏱕ut ut 􏱪 􏰴ut􏱦1 􏱕 et E(et􏰫It􏱦1) 􏱪 0, where It􏱦1 contains y and z dated at t 􏱦 1 and earlier. (i) Show that E(yt􏱕1􏰫It) 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏰴)􏱮 􏱕 􏰴yt 􏱕 􏱛1zt 􏱦 􏰴􏱛1zt􏱦1. (Hint: Write ut􏱦1 􏱪 yt􏱦1 􏱦 􏱮 􏱦 􏱛1zt􏱦2 and plug this into the second equation; then, plug the result into the first equation and take the conditional expectation.) (ii) Suppose that you use n observations to estimate 􏱮, 􏱛1, and 􏰴. Write the equation for forecasting yn􏱕1. (iii) Explain why the model with one lag of z and AR(1) serial correlation is a special case of the model yt 􏱪􏱮0 􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕􏰸1zt􏱦1 􏱕􏰸2zt􏱦2 􏱕et. (iv) What does part (iii) suggest about using models with AR(1) serial correlation for forecasting? 9 Let {yt} be an I(1) sequence. Suppose that gˆn is the one-step-ahead forecast of 􏰧yn􏱕1 and let fˆ 􏱪 gˆ 􏱕 y be the one-step-ahead forecast of y . Explain why the forecast errors for nnn n􏱕1 forecasting 􏰧yn􏱕1 and yn􏱕1 are identical. Computer Exercises C1 Use the data in WAGEPRC.RAW for this exercise. Problem 5 in Chapter 11 gave estimates of a finite distributed lag model of gprice on gwage, where 12 lags of gwage are used. (i) Estimate a simple geometric DL model of gprice on gwage. In particular, estimate equation (18.11) by OLS. What are the estimated impact propensity and LRP? Sketch the estimated lag distribution. (ii) Compare the estimated IP and LRP to those obtained in Problem 5 in Chapter 11. How do the estimated lag distributions compare? (iii) Now, estimate the rational distributed lag model from (18.16). Sketch the lag distri- bution and compare the estimated IP and LRP to those obtained in part (ii). C2 Use the data in HSEINV.RAW for this exercise. (i) Test for a unit root in log(invpc), including a linear time trend and two lags of 􏰧log(invpct). Use a 5% significance level. (ii) Use the approach from part (i) to test for a unit root in log(price). (iii) Given the outcomes in parts (i) and (ii), does it make sense to test for cointegration between log(invpc) and log(price)? C3 Use the data in VOLAT.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate an AR(3) model for pcip. Now, add a fourth lag and verify that it is very insignificant. (ii) To the AR(3) model from part (i), add three lags of pcsp to test whether pcsp Granger causes pcip. Carefully, state your conclusion. (iii) To the model in part (ii), add three lags of the change in i3, the three-month T-bill rate. Does pcsp Granger cause pcip conditional on past 􏰧i3? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 672 PART 3 Advanced Topics C4 In testing for cointegration between gfr and pe in Example 18.5, add t2 to equation (18.32) to obtain the OLS residuals. Include one lag in the augmented DF test. The 5% critical value for the test is 􏱦4.15. C5 Use INTQRT.RAW for this exercise. (i) In Example 18.7, we estimated an error correction model for the holding yield on six-month T-bills, where one lag of the holding yield on three-month T-bills is the explanatory variable. We assumed that the cointegration parameter was one in the equation hy6t 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 ut. Now, add the lead change, 􏰧hy3t, the contem- poraneous change, 􏰧hy3t􏱦1, and the lagged change, 􏰧hy3t􏱦2, of hy3t􏱦1. That is, estimate the equation hy6t 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 􏰿0􏰧hy3t 􏱕 􏰿1􏰧hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴1􏰧hy3t􏱦2 􏱕 et and report the results in equation form. Test H0: 􏱬 􏱪 1 against a two-sided alternative. Assume that the lead and lag are sufficient so that {hy3t􏱦1} is strictly exogenous in this equation and do not worry about serial correlation. (ii) To the error correction model in (18.39), add 􏰧hy3t􏱦2 and (hy6t􏱦2 􏱦 hy3t􏱦3). Are these terms jointly significant? What do you conclude about the appropriate error correction model? C6 Use the data in PHILLIPS.RAW to answer these questions. (i) Estimate the models in (18.48) and (18.49) using the data through 1997. Do the parameter estimates change much compared with (18.48) and (18.49)? (ii) Use the new equations to forecast unem1998; round to two places after the decimal. Which equation produces a better forecast? (iii) As we discussed in the text, the forecast for unem1998 using (18.49) is 4.90. Compare this with the forecast obtained using the data through 1997. Does using the extra year of data to obtain the parameter estimates produce a better forecast? (iv) Use the model estimated in (18.48) to obtain a two-step-ahead forecast of unem. That is, forecast unem1998 using equation (18.55) with 􏱮ˆ 􏱪 1.572, 􏰴ˆ 􏱪 .732, and h 􏱪 2. Is this better or worse than the one-step-ahead forecast obtained by plugging unem1997 􏱪 4.9 into (18.48)? C7 Use the data in BARIUM.RAW for this exercise. (i) Estimate the linear trend model chnimpt 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬t 􏱕 ut, using the first 119 obser- vations (this excludes the last 12 months of observations for 1988). What is the standard error of the regression? (ii) Now, estimate an AR(1) model for chnimp, again using all data but the last 12 months. Compare the standard error of the regression with that from part (i). Which model provides a better in-sample fit? (iii) Use the models from parts (i) and (ii) to compute the one-step-ahead forecast errors for the 12 months in 1988. (You should obtain 12 forecast errors for each method.) Compute and compare the RMSEs and the MAEs for the two meth- ods. Which forecasting method works better out-of-sample for one-step-ahead forecasts? (iv) Add monthly dummy variables to the regression from part (i). Are these jointly significant? (Do not worry about the slight serial correlation in the errors from this regression when doing the joint test.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 673 C8 Use the data in FERTIL3.RAW for this exercise. (i) Graph gfr against time. Does it contain a clear upward or downward trend over the entire sample period? (ii) Using the data through 1979, estimate a cubic time trend model for gfr (that is, regress gfr on t, t2, and t3, along with an intercept). Comment on the R-squared of the regression. (iii) Using the model in part (ii), compute the mean absolute error of the one-step-ahead forecast errors for the years 1980 through 1984. (iv) Using the data through 1979, regress 􏰧gfrt on a constant only. Is the constant statistically different from zero? Does it make sense to assume that any drift term is zero, if we assume that gfrt follows a random walk? (v) Now, forecast gfr for 1980 through 1984, using a random walk model: the forecast of gfrn􏱕1 is simply gfrn. Find the MAE. How does it compare with the MAE from part (iii)? Which method of forecasting do you prefer? (vi) Now, estimate an AR(2) model for gfr, again using the data only through 1979. Is the second lag significant? (vii) Obtain the MAE for 1980 through 1984, using the AR(2) model. Does this more general model work better out-of-sample than the random walk model? C9 Use (i) Let yt be real per capita disposable income. Use the data through 1989 to estimate CONSUMP.RAW for this exercise. the model yt 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱬t􏱕􏰴yt􏱦1 􏱕ut and report the results in the usual form. (ii) Use the estimated equation from part (i) to forecast y in 1990. What is the forecast error? (iii) Compute the mean absolute error of the one-step-ahead forecasts for the 1990s, using the parameters estimated in part (i). (iv) Now, compute the MAE over the same period, but drop yt􏱦1 from the equation. Is it better to include yt􏱦1 in the model or not? C10 Use (i) Using the data from all but the last four years (16 quarters), estimate an AR(1) model for 􏰧r6t. (We use the difference because it appears that r6t has a unit root.) Find the RMSE of the one-step-ahead forecasts for 􏰧r6, using the last 16 quarters. (ii) Now, add the error correction term sprt􏱦1 􏱪 r6t􏱦1 􏱦 r3t􏱦1 to the equation from part (i). (This assumes that the cointegrating parameter is one.) Compute the RMSE for the last 16 quarters. Does the error correction term help with out-of-sample forecasting in this case? (iii) Now, estimate the cointegrating parameter, rather than setting it to one. Use the last 16 quarters again to produce the out-of-sample RMSE. How does this compare with the forecasts from parts (i) and (ii)? (iv) Would your conclusions change if you wanted to predict r6 rather than 􏰧r6? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. the data in INTQRT.RAW for this exercise. 674 PART 3 Advanced Topics C11 Use the data in VOLAT.RAW for this exercise. (i) Confirm that lsp500 􏱪 log(sp500) and lip 􏱪 log(ip) appear to contain unit roots. Use Dickey-Fuller tests with four lagged changes and do the tests with and with- out a linear time trend. (ii) Run a simple regression of lsp500 on lip. Comment on the sizes of the t statistic and R-squared. (iii) Use the residuals from part (ii) to test whether lsp500 and lip are cointegrated. Use the standard Dickey-Fuller test and the ADF test with two lags. What do you conclude? (iv) Add a linear time trend to the regression from part (ii) and now test for cointegration using the same tests from part (iii). (v) Does it appear that stock prices and real economic activity have a long-run equilibrium relationship? C12 This exercise also uses the data from VOLAT.RAW. Computer Exercise C11 studies the long-run relationship between stock prices and industrial production. Here, you will study the question of Granger causality using the percentage changes. (i) Estimate an AR(3) model for pcipt, the percentage change in industrial production (reported at an annualized rate). Show that the second and third lags are jointly significant at the 2.5% level. (ii) Add one lag of pcspt to the equation estimated in part (i). Is the lag statistically significant? What does this tell you about Granger causality between the growth in industrial production and the growth in stock prices? (iii) Redo part (ii) but obtain a heteroskedasticity-robust t statistic. Does the robust test change your conclusions from part (ii)? C13 Use the data in TRAFFIC2.RAW for this exercise. These monthly data, on traffic accidents in California over the years 1981 to 1989, were used in Computer Exercise C11 in Chapter 10. (i) Using the standard Dickey-Fuller regression, test whether ltotacct has a unit root. Can you reject a unit root at the 2.5% level? (ii) Now, add two lagged changes to the test from part (i) and compute the augmented Dickey-Fuller test. What do you conclude? (iii) Add a linear time trend to the ADF regression from part (ii). Now what happens? (iv) Given the findings from parts (i) through (iii), what would you say is the best characterization of ltotacct: an I(1) process or an I(0) process about a linear time trend? (v) Test the percentage of fatalities, prcfatt, for a unit root, using two lags in an ADF regression. In this case, does it matter whether you include a linear time trend? C14 Use the data in MINWAGE.DTA for sector 232 to answer the following questions. (i) Confirm that lwage232t and lemp232t are best characterized as I(1) processes. Use the augmented DF test with one lag of gwage232 and gemp232, respectively, and a linear time trend. Is there any doubt that these series should be assumed to have unit roots? (ii) Regress lemp232t on lwage232t and test for cointegration, both with and without a time trend, allowing for two lags in the augmented Engle-Granger test. What do you conclude? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 18 Advanced Time Series Topics 675 (iii) Now regress lemp232t on log of the real wage rate, lrwage232t 􏱪 lwage232t − lcpit, and a time trend. Do you find cointegration? Are they “closer” to being cointegrated when you use real wages rather than nominal wages? (iv) What are some factors that might be missing from the cointegrating regression in part (iii)? C15 This question asks you to study the so-called Beveridge Curve from the perspective of cointegration analysis. The U.S. monthly data from December 2000 through February 2012 are in BEVERIDGE.RAW. (i) Test for a unit root in urate using the usual Dickey-Fuller test (with a constant) and the augmented DF with two lags of curate. What do you conclude? Are the lags of curate in the augmented DF test statistically significant? Does it matter to the outcome of the unit root test? (ii) Repeat part (i) but with the vacancy rate, vrate. (iii) Assuming that urate and vrate are both I(1), the Beveridge Curve, uratet 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱬vrate 􏱕 ut, only makes sense if urate and vrate are cointegrated (with cointegrating parameter 􏱬 < 0). Test for cointegration using the Engle-Granger test with no lags. Are urate and vrate cointegrated at the 10% significance level? What about at the 5% level? (iv) Obtain the leads and lags estimator with cvratet, cvratet−1, and cvratet+1 as the I(0) explanatory variables added to the equation in part (ii). Obtain the Newey-West standard error for 􏱬ˆ using four lags (so g 􏱪 4 in the notation of Section 12.5). What is the resulting 95% confidence interval for 􏱬? How does it compare with the confidence interval that is not robust to serial correlation (or heteroskedasticity)? (v) Redo the Engle-Granger test but with two lags in the augmented DF regression. What happens? What do you conclude about the robustness of the claim that urate and vrate are cointegrated? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Carrying Out an Empirical Project 19 676 CHAPTER In this chapter, we discuss the ingredients of a successful empirical analysis, with emphasis on completing a term project. In addition to reminding you of the impor- tant issues that have arisen throughout the text, we emphasize recurring themes that are important for applied research. We also provide suggestions for topics as a way of stimulating your imagination. Several sources of economic research and data are given as references. 19.1 Posing a Question The importance of posing a very specific question that, in principle, can be answered with data cannot be overstated. Without being explicit about the goal of your analysis, you can- not know where to begin. The widespread availability of rich data sets makes it tempting to launch into data collection based on half-baked ideas, but this is often counterproduc- tive. It is likely that, without carefully formulating your hypotheses and the kind of model you will need to estimate, you will forget to collect information on important variables, obtain a sample from the wrong population, or collect data for the wrong time period. This does not mean that you should pose your question in a vacuum. Especially for a one-term project you cannot be too ambitious. Therefore, when choosing a topic, you should be reasonably sure that data sources exist that will allow you to answer your ques- tion in the allotted time. You need to decide what areas of economics or other social sciences interest you when selecting a topic. For example, if you have taken a course in labor economics you have probably seen theories that can be tested empirically or relationships that have some policy relevance. Labor economists are constantly coming up with new variables that can explain wage differentials. Examples include quality of high school [Card and Krueger (1992) and Betts (1995)], amount of math and science taken in high school [Levine and Zimmerman (1995)], and physical appearance [Hamermesh and Biddle (1994), Averett and Korenman (1996), Biddle and Hamermesh (1998), and Hamermesh and Parker (2005)]. Researchers in state and local public finance study how local economic activity depends on economic policy variables, such as property taxes, sales taxes, level and quality of services (such as schools, fire, and police), and so on. [See, for example, White (1986), Papke (1987), Bartik (1991), Netzer (1992), and Mark, McGuire, and Papke (2000).] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 677 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project Economists that study education issues are interested in determining how spending affects performance [Hanushek (1986)], whether attending certain kinds of schools im- proves performance [for example, Evans and Schwab (1995)], and what factors affect where private schools choose to locate [Downes and Greenstein (1996)]. Macroeconomists are interested in relationships between various aggregate time se- ries, such as the link between growth in gross domestic product and growth in fixed invest- ment or machinery [see De Long and Summers (1991)] or the effect of taxes on interest rates [for example, Peek (1982)]. There are certainly reasons for estimating models that are mostly descriptive. For ex- ample, property tax assessors use models (called hedonic price models) to estimate hous- ing values for homes that have not been sold recently. This involves a regression model relating the price of a house to its characteristics (size, number of bedrooms, number of bathrooms, and so on). As a topic for a term paper, this is not very exciting: we are un- likely to learn much that is surprising, and such an analysis has no obvious policy implica- tions. Adding the crime rate in the neighborhood as an explanatory variable would allow us to determine how important a factor crime is on housing prices, something that would be useful in estimating the costs of crime. Several relationships have been estimated using macroeconomic data that are mostly descriptive. For example, an aggregate saving function can be used to estimate the aggre- gate marginal propensity to save, as well as the response of saving to asset returns (such as interest rates). Such an analysis could be made more interesting by using time series data on a country that has a history of political upheavals and determining whether savings rates decline during times of political uncertainty. Once you decide on an area of research, there are a variety of ways to locate spe- cific papers on the topic. The Journal of Economic Literature (JEL) has a detailed clas- sification system in which each paper is given a set of identifying codes that places it within certain subfields of economics. The JEL also contains a list of articles published in a wide variety of journals, organized by topic, and it even contains short abstracts of some articles. Especially convenient for finding published papers on various topics are Internet ser- vices, such as EconLit, which many universities subscribe to. EconLit allows users to do a comprehensive search of almost all economics journals by author, subject, words in the title, and so on. The Social Sciences Citation Index is useful for finding papers on a broad range of topics in the social sciences, including popular papers that have been cited often in other published works. Google Scholar is an Internet search engine that can be very helpful for tracking down research on various topics or research by a particular author. This is especially true of work that has not been published in an academic journal or that has not yet been published. In thinking about a topic, you should keep some things in mind. First, for a question to be interesting, it does not need to have broad-based policy implications; rather, it can be of local interest. For example, you might be interested in knowing whether living in a fraternity at your university causes students to have lower or higher grade point averages. This may or may not be of interest to people outside your university, but it is probably of concern to at least some people within the university. On the other hand, you might study a problem that starts by being of local interest but turns out to have widespread interest, such as determining which factors affect, and which university policies can stem, alcohol abuse on college campuses. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 678 PART 3 Advanced Topics Second, it is very difficult, especially for a quarter or semester project, to do truly original research using the standard macroeconomic aggregates on the U.S. economy. For example, the question of whether money growth, government spending growth, and so on affect economic growth has been and continues to be studied by professional macro- economists. The question of whether stock or other asset returns can be systematically predicted using known information has, for obvious reasons, been studied pretty carefully. This does not mean that you should avoid estimating macroeconomic or empirical finance models, as even just using more recent data can add constructively to a debate. In addition, you can sometimes find a new variable that has an important effect on economic aggre- gates or financial returns; such a discovery can be exciting. The point is that exercises such as using a few additional years to estimate a standard Phillips curve or an aggregate consumption function for the U.S. economy, or some other large economy, are unlikely to yield additional insights, although they can be instructive for the student. Instead, you might use data on a smaller country to estimate a static or dynamic Phillips curve or a Beveridge curve (possibly allowing the slopes of the curves to depend on information known prior to the current time period), or to test the efficient markets hypothesis, and so on. At the nonmacroeconomic level, there are also plenty of questions that have been studied extensively. For example, labor economists have published many papers on esti- mating the return to education. This question is still studied because it is very important, and new data sets, as well as new econometric approaches, continue to be developed. For example, as we saw in Chapter 9, certain data sets have better proxy variables for unob- served ability than other data sets. (Compare WAGE1.RAW and WAGE2.RAW.) In other cases, we can obtain panel data or data from a natural experiment—see Chapter 13—that allow us to approach an old question from a different perspective. As another example, criminologists are interested in studying the effects of various laws on crime. The question of whether capital punishment has a deterrent effect has long been debated. Similarly, economists have been interested in whether taxes on cigarettes and alcohol reduce consumption (as always, in a ceteris paribus sense). As more years of data at the state level become available, a richer panel data set can be created, and this can help us better answer major policy questions. Plus, the effectiveness of fairly recent crime-fighting innovations—such as community policing—can be evaluated empirically. While you are formulating your question, it is helpful to discuss your ideas with your classmates, instructor, and friends. You should be able to convince people that the answer to your question is of some interest. (Of course, whether you can persuasively answer your question is another issue, but you need to begin with an interesting question.) If someone asks you about your paper and you respond with “I’m doing my paper on crime” or “I’m doing my paper on interest rates,” chances are you have only decided on a general area without formulating a true question. You should be able to say something like “I’m study- ing the effects of community policing on city crime rates in the United States” or “I’m looking at how inflation volatility affects short-term interest rates in Brazil.” 19.2 Literature Review All papers, even if they are relatively short, should contain a review of relevant literature. It is rare that one attempts an empirical project for which no published precedent exists. If you search through journals or use online search services such as EconLit to come up with Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 679 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project a topic, you are already well on your way to a literature review. If you select a topic on your own—such as studying the effects of drug usage on college performance at your universi- ty—then you will probably have to work a little harder. But online search services make that work a lot easier, as you can search by keywords, by words in the title, by author, and so on. You can then read abstracts of papers to see how relevant they are to your own work. When doing your literature search, you should think of related topics that might not show up in a search using a handful of keywords. For example, if you are studying the effects of drug usage on wages or grade point average, you should probably look at the literature on how alcohol usage affects such factors. Knowing how to do a thorough litera- ture search is an acquired skill, but you can get a long way by thinking before searching. Researchers differ on how a literature review should be incorporated into a paper. Some like to have a separate section called “literature review,” while others like to include the literature review as part of the introduction. This is largely a matter of taste, although an extensive literature review probably deserves its own section. If the term paper is the focus of the course—say, in a senior seminar or an advanced econometrics course—your literature review probably will be lengthy. Term papers at the end of a first course are typically shorter, and the literature reviews are briefer. 19.3 Data Collection Deciding on the Appropriate Data Set Collecting data for a term paper can be educational, exciting, and sometimes even frustrat- ing. You must first decide on the kind of data needed to answer your posed question. As we discussed in the introduction and have covered throughout this text, data sets come in a variety of forms. The most common kinds are cross-sectional, time series, pooled cross sections, and panel data sets. Many questions can be addressed using any of the data structures we have described. For example, to study whether more law enforcement lowers crime, we could use a cross section of cities, a time series for a given city, or a panel data set of cities—which consists of data on the same cities over two or more years. Deciding on which kind of data to collect often depends on the nature of the analysis. To answer questions at the individual or family level, we often only have access to a sin- gle cross section; typically, these are obtained via surveys. Then, we must ask whether we can obtain a rich enough data set to do a convincing ceteris paribus analysis. For example, suppose we want to know whether families who save through individual retirement ac- counts (IRAs)—which have certain tax advantages—have less non-IRA savings. In other words, does IRA saving simply crowd out other forms of saving? There are data sets, such as the Survey of Consumer Finances, that contain information on various kinds of saving for a different sample of families each year. Several issues arise in using such a data set. Perhaps the most important is whether there are enough controls—including income, de- mographics, and proxies for saving tastes—to do a reasonable ceteris paribus analysis. If these are the only kinds of data available, we must do what we can with them. The same issues arise with cross-sectional data on firms, cities, states, and so on. In most cases, it is not obvious that we will be able to do a ceteris paribus analysis with a single cross section. For example, any study of the effects of law enforcement on crime must recognize the endogeneity of law enforcement expenditures. When using standard Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 680 PART 3 Advanced Topics regression methods, it may be very hard to complete a convincing ceteris paribus analysis, no matter how many controls we have. (See Section 19.4 for more discussion.) If you have read the advanced chapters on panel data methods, you know that having the same cross-sectional units at two or more different points in time can allow us to control for time-constant unobserved effects that would normally confound regression on a single cross section. Panel data sets are relatively hard to obtain for individuals or fam- ilies—although some important ones exist, such as the Panel Study of Income Dynam- ics—but they can be used in very convincing ways. Panel data sets on firms also exist. For example, Compustat and the Center for Research in Security Prices (CRSP) manage very large panel data sets of financial information on firms. Easier to obtain are panel data sets on larger units, such as schools, cities, counties, and states, as these tend not to disap- pear over time, and government agencies are responsible for collecting information on the same variables each year. For example, the Federal Bureau of Investigation collects and reports detailed information on crime rates at the city level. Sources of data are listed at the end of this chapter. Data come in a variety of forms. Some data sets, especially historical ones, are avail- able only in printed form. For small data sets, entering the data yourself from the printed source is manageable and convenient. Sometimes, articles are published with small data sets—especially time series applications. These can be used in an empirical study, perhaps by supplementing the data with more recent years. Many data sets are available in electronic form. Various government agencies pro- vide data on their websites. Private companies sometimes compile data sets to make them user friendly, and then they provide them for a fee. Authors of papers are often willing to provide their data sets in electronic form. More and more data sets are available on the Internet. The web is a vast resource of online databases. Numerous websites containing economic and related data sets have been created. Several other websites contain links to data sets that are of interest to economists; some of these are listed at the end of this chap- ter. Generally, searching the Internet for data sources is easy and will become even more convenient in the future. Entering and Storing Your Data Once you have decided on a data type and have located a data source, you must put the data into a usable format. If the data came in electronic form, they are already in some for- mat, hopefully one in widespread use. The most flexible way to obtain data in electronic form is as a standard text (ASCII) file. All statistics and econometrics software packages allow raw data to be stored this way. Typically, it is straightforward to read a text file directly into an econometrics package, provided the file is properly structured. The data files we have used throughout the text provide several examples of how cross-sectional, time series, pooled cross sections, and panel data sets are usually stored. As a rule, the data should have a tabular form, with each observation representing a different row; the columns in the data set represent different variables. Occasionally, you might encounter a data set stored with each column representing an observation and each row a different variable. This is not ideal, but most software packages allow data to be read in this form and then reshaped. Naturally, it is crucial to know how the data are organized before read- ing them into your econometrics package. For time series data sets, there is only one sensible way to enter and store the data: namely, chronologically, with the earliest time period listed as the first observation and Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 681 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project the most recent time period as the last observation. It is often useful to include variables indicating year and, if relevant, quarter or month. This facilitates estimation of a variety of models later on, including allowing for seasonality and breaks at different time periods. For cross sections pooled over time, it is usually best to have the cross section for the ear- liest year fill the first block of observations, followed by the cross section for the second year, and so on. (See FERTIL1.RAW as an example.) This arrangement is not crucial, but it is very important to have a variable stating the year attached to each observation. For panel data, as we discussed in Section 13.5, it is best if all the years for each cross- sectional observation are adjacent and in chronological order. With this ordering, we can use all of the panel data methods from Chapters 13 and 14. With panel data, it is important to include a unique identifier for each cross-sectional unit, along with a year variable. If you obtain your data in printed form, you have several options for entering them into a computer. First, you can create a text file using a standard text editor. (This is how several of the raw data sets included with the text were initially created.) Typically, it is required that each row starts a new observation, that each row contains the same ordering of the variables—in particular, each row should have the same number of entries—and that the values are separated by at least one space. Sometimes, a different separator, such as a comma, is better, but this depends on the software you are using. If you have miss- ing observations on some variables, you must decide how to denote that; simply leaving a blank does not generally work. Many regression packages accept a period as the missing value symbol. Some people prefer to use a number—presumably an impossible value for the variable of interest—to denote missing values. If you are not careful, this can be dan- gerous; we discuss this further later. If you have nonnumerical data—for example, you want to include the names in a sample of colleges or the names of cities—then you should check the econometrics pack- age you will use to see the best way to enter such variables (often called strings). Typi- cally, strings are put between double or single quotation marks. Or the text file can follow a rigid formatting, which usually requires a small program to read in the text file. But you need to check your econometrics package for details. Another generally available option is to use a spreadsheet to enter your data, such as Excel. This has a couple of advantages over a text file. First, because each observation on each variable is a cell, it is less likely that numbers will be run together (as would happen if you forget to enter a space in a text file). Second, spreadsheets allow manipulation of data, such as sorting or computing averages. This benefit is less important if you use a software package that allows sophisticated data management; many software packages, including EViews and Stata, fall into this category. If you use a spreadsheet for initial data entry, then you must often export the data in a form that can be read by your econometrics pack- age. This is usually straightforward, as spreadsheets export to text files using a variety of formats. A third alternative is to enter the data directly into your econometrics package. Although this obviates the need for a text editor or a spreadsheet, it can be more awk- ward if you cannot freely move across different observations to make corrections or additions. Data downloaded from the Internet may come in a variety of forms. Often data come as text files, but different conventions are used for separating variables; for panel data sets, the conventions on how to order the data may differ. Some Internet data sets come as spreadsheet files, in which case you must use an appropriate spreadsheet to read them. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 682 PART 3 Advanced Topics Inspecting, Cleaning, and Summarizing Your Data It is extremely important to become familiar with any data set you will use in an empirical analysis. If you enter the data yourself, you will be forced to know everything about it. But if you obtain data from an outside source, you should still spend some time understanding its structure and conventions. Even data sets that are widely used and heavily documented can contain glitches. If you are using a data set obtained from the author of a paper, you must be aware that rules used for data set construction can be forgotten. Earlier, we reviewed the standard ways that various data sets are stored. You also need to know how missing values are coded. Preferably, missing values are indicated with a nonnumeric character, such as a period. If a number is used as a missing value code, such as “999” or “􏱦1”, you must be very careful when using these observations in com- puting any statistics. Your econometrics package will probably not know that a certain number really represents a missing value: it is likely that such observations will be used as if they are valid, and this can produce rather misleading results. The best approach is to set any numerical codes for missing values to some other character (such as a period) that cannot be mistaken for real data. You must also know the nature of the variables in the data set. Which are binary variables? Which are ordinal variables (such as a credit rating)? What are the units of measurement of the variables? For example, are monetary values expressed in dollars, thousands of dollars, millions of dollars, or some other units? Are variables representing a rate—such as school dropout rates, inflation rates, unionization rates, or interest rates— measured as a percentage or a proportion? Especially for time series data, it is crucial to know if monetary values are in nominal (current) or real (constant) dollars. If the values are in real terms, what is the base year or period? If you receive a data set from an author, some variables may already be transformed in certain ways. For example, sometimes only the log of a variable (such as wage or sal- ary) is reported in the data set. Detecting mistakes in a data set is necessary for preserving the integrity of any data analysis. It is always useful to find minimums, maximums, means, and standard devia- tions of all, or at least the most important, variables in the analysis. For example, if you find that the minimum value of education in your sample is 􏱦99, you know that at least one entry on education needs to be set to a missing value. If, upon further inspection, you find that several observations have 􏱦99 as the level of education, you can be confident that you have stumbled onto the missing value code for education. As another example, if you find that an average murder conviction rate across a sample of cities is .632, you know that conviction rate is measured as a proportion, not a percentage. Then, if the max- imum value is above one, this is likely a typographical error. (It is not uncommon to find data sets where most of the entries on a rate variable were entered as a percentage, but where some were entered as a proportion, and vice versa. Such data coding errors can be difficult to detect, but it is important to try.) We must also be careful in using time series data. If we are using monthly or quarterly data, we must know which variables, if any, have been seasonally adjusted. Transforming data also requires great care. Suppose we have a monthly data set and we want to create the change in a variable from one month to the next. To do this, we must be sure that the data are ordered chronologically, from earliest period to latest. If for some reason this is not the case, the differencing will result in garbage. To be sure the data are properly or- dered, it is useful to have a time period indicator. With annual data, it is sufficient to know Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 683 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project the year, but then we should know whether the year is entered as four digits or two digits (for example, 1998 versus 98). With monthly or quarterly data, it is also useful to have a variable or variables indicating month or quarter. With monthly data, we may have a set of dummy variables (11 or 12) or one variable indicating the month (1 through 12 or a string variable, such as jan, feb, and so on). With or without yearly, monthly, or quarterly indicators, we can easily construct time trends in all econometrics software packages. Creating seasonal dummy variables is easy if the month or quarter is indicated; at a minimum, we need to know the month or quarter of the first observation. Manipulating panel data can be even more challenging. In Chapter 13, we discussed pooled OLS on the differenced data as one general approach to controlling for unobserved effects. In constructing the differenced data, we must be careful not to create phantom observations. Suppose we have a balanced panel on cities from 1992 through 1997. Even if the data are ordered chronologically within each cross-sectional unit—something that should be done before proceeding—a mindless differencing will create an observation for 1992 for all cities except the first in the sample. This observation will be the 1992 value for city i, minus the 1997 value for city i 􏱦 1; this is clearly nonsense. Thus, we must make sure that 1992 is missing for all differenced variables. 19.4 Econometric Analysis This text has focused on econometric analysis, and we are not about to provide a review of econometric methods in this section. Nevertheless, we can give some general guidelines about the sorts of issues that need to be considered in an empirical analysis. As we discussed earlier, after deciding on a topic, we must collect an appropriate data set. Assuming that this has also been done, we must next decide on the appropriate econo- metric methods. If your course has focused on ordinary least squares estimation of a multiple linear re- gression model, using either cross-sectional or time series data, the econometric approach has pretty much been decided for you. This is not necessarily a weakness, as OLS is still the most widely used econometric method. Of course, you still have to decide whether any of the variants of OLS—such as weighted least squares or correcting for serial correlation in a time series regression—are warranted. In order to justify OLS, you must also make a convincing case that the key OLS assumptions are satisfied for your model. As we have discussed at some length, the first issue is whether the error term is uncorrelated with the explanatory variables. Ideally, you have been able to control for enough other factors to assume that those that are left in the error are unrelated to the regressors. Especially when dealing with individual-, family-, or firm-level cross-sectional data, the self-selection problem—which we discussed in Chapters 7 and 15—is often relevant. For instance, in the IRA example from Section 19.3, it may be that families with an unobserved taste for saving are also the ones that open IRAs. You should also be able to argue that the other potential sources of endogeneity— namely, measurement error and simultaneity—are not a serious problem. When specifying your model you must also make functional form decisions. Should some variables appear in logarithmic form? (In econometric applications, the answer is often yes.) Should some variables be included in levels and squares, to possibly capture a diminishing effect? How should qualitative factors appear? Is it enough to just include binary variables for different attributes or groups? Or do these need to be interacted with quantitative variables? (See Chapter 7 for details.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 684 PART 3 Advanced Topics A common mistake, especially among beginners, is to incorrectly include explanatory variables in a regression model that are listed as numerical values but have no quantitative meaning. For example, in an individual-level data set that contains information on wages, education, experience, and other variables, an “occupation” variable might be included. Typically, these are just arbitrary codes that have been assigned to different occupations; the fact that an elementary school teacher is given, say, the value 453 while a computer technician is, say, 751 is relevant only in that it allows us to distinguish between the two occupations. It makes no sense to include the raw occupational variable in a regression model. (What sense would it make to measure the effect of increasing occupation by one unit when the one-unit increase has no quantitative meaning?) Instead, different dummy variables should be defined for different occupations (or groups of occupations, if there are many occupations). Then, the dummy variables can be included in the regression model. A less egregious problem occurs when an ordered qualitative variable is included as an explanatory variable. Suppose that in a wage data set a variable is included measuring “job satisfaction,” defined on a scale from 1 to 7, with 7 being the most satisfied. Provided we have enough data, we would want to define a set of six dummy variables for, say, job satisfaction levels of 2 through 7, leaving job satisfaction level 1 as the base group. By including the six job satisfaction dummies in the regression, we allow a completely flexible relationship between the response variable and job satisfaction. Putting in the job satisfaction variable in raw form implicitly assumes that a one-unit increase in the ordinal variable has quantitative meaning. While the direction of the effect will often be estimated appropriately, interpreting the coefficient on an ordinal variable is difficult. If an ordinal variable takes on many values, then we can define a set of dummy variables for ranges of values. See Section 7.3 for an example. Sometimes, we want to explain a variable that is an ordinal response. For example, one could think of using a job satisfaction variable of the type described above as the dependent variable in a regression model, with both worker and employer characteristics among the independent variables. Unfortunately, with the job satisfaction variable in its original form, the coefficients in the model are hard to interpret: each measures the change in job satisfaction given a unit increase in the independent variable. Certain models— ordered probit and ordered logit are the most common—are well suited for ordered re- sponses. These models essentially extend the binary probit and logit models we discussed in Chapter 17. [See Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 15) for a treatment of ordered response models.] A simple solution is to turn any ordered response into a binary response. For example, we could define a variable equal to one if job satisfaction is at least 4, and zero otherwise. Unfortunately, creating a binary variable throws away information and requires us to use a somewhat arbitrary cutoff. For cross-sectional analysis, a secondary, but nevertheless important, issue is whether there is heteroskedasticity. In Chapter 8, we explained how this can be dealt with. The simplest way is to compute heteroskedasticity-robust statistics. As we emphasized in Chapters 10, 11, and 12, time series applications require addi- tional care. Should the equation be estimated in levels? If levels are used, are time trends needed? Is differencing the data more appropriate? If the data are monthly or quarterly, does seasonality have to be accounted for? If you are allowing for dynamics—for example, distributed lag dynamics—how many lags should be included? You must start with some lags based on intuition or common sense, but eventually it is an empirical matter. If your model has some potential misspecification, such as omitted variables, and you use OLS, you should attempt some sort of misspecification analysis of the kinds we Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 685 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project discussed in Chapters 3 and 5. Can you determine, based on reasonable assumptions, the direction of any bias in the estimators? If you have studied the method of instrumental variables, you know that it can be used to solve various forms of endogeneity, including omitted variables (Chapter 15), errors- in-variables (Chapter 15), and simultaneity (Chapter 16). Naturally, you need to think hard about whether the instrumental variables you are considering are likely to be valid. Good papers in the empirical social sciences contain sensitivity analysis. Broadly, this means you estimate your original model and modify it in ways that seem reasonable. Hope- fully, the important conclusions do not change. For example, if you use as an explanatory variable a measure of alcohol consumption (say, in a grade point average equation), do you get qualitatively similar results if you replace the quantitative measure with a dummy variable indicating alcohol usage? If the binary usage variable is significant but the alcohol quantity variable is not, it could be that usage reflects some unobserved attribute that affects GPA and is also correlated with alcohol usage. But this needs to be considered on a case-by-case basis. If some observations are much different from the bulk of the sample—say, you have a few firms in a sample that are much larger than the other firms—do your results change much when those observations are excluded from the estimation? If so, you may have to alter functional forms to allow for these observations or argue that they follow a com- pletely different model. The issue of outliers was discussed in Chapter 9. Using panel data raises some additional econometric issues. Suppose you have col- lected two periods. There are at least four ways to use two periods of panel data without resorting to instrumental variables. You can pool the two years in a standard OLS analy- sis, as discussed in Chapter 13. Although this might increase the sample size relative to a single cross section, it does not control for time-constant unobservables. In addition, the errors in such an equation are almost always serially correlated because of an unobserved effect. Random effects estimation corrects the serial correlation problem and produces asymptotically efficient estimators, provided the unobserved effect has zero mean given values of the explanatory variables in all time periods. Another possibility is to include a lagged dependent variable in the equation for the second year. In Chapter 9, we presented this as a way to at least mitigate the omitted variables problem, as we are in any event holding fixed the initial outcome of the dependent variable. This often leads to similar results as differencing the data, as we covered in Chapter 13. With more years of panel data, we have the same options, plus an additional choice. We can use the fixed effects transformation to eliminate the unobserved effect. (With two years of data, this is the same as differencing.) In Chapter 15, we showed how instrumen- tal variables techniques can be combined with panel data transformations to relax exo- geneity assumptions even more. As a rule, it is a good idea to apply several reasonable econometric methods and compare the results. This often allows us to determine which of our assumptions are likely to be false. Even if you are very careful in devising your topic, postulating your model, collect- ing your data, and carrying out the econometrics, it is quite possible that you will obtain puzzling results—at least some of the time. When that happens, the natural inclination is to try different models, different estimation techniques, or perhaps different subsets of data until the results correspond more closely to what was expected. Virtually all applied researchers search over various models before finding the “best” model. Unfortunately, this practice of data mining violates the assumptions we have made in our econometric analysis. The results on unbiasedness of OLS and other estimators, as well as the t and F distributions we derived for hypothesis testing, assume that we observe a sample following Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 686 PART 3 Advanced Topics the population model and we estimate that model once. Estimating models that are vari- ants of our original model violates that assumption because we are using the same set of data in a specification search. In effect, we use the outcome of tests by using the data to respecify our model. The estimates and tests from different model specifications are not independent of one another. Some specification searches have been programmed into standard software pack- ages. A popular one is known as stepwise regression, where different combinations of explanatory variables are used in multiple regression analysis in an attempt to come up with the best model. There are various ways that stepwise regression can be used, and we have no intention of reviewing them here. The general idea is either to start with a large model and keep variables whose p-values are below a certain significance level or to start with a simple model and add variables that have significant p-values. Some- times, groups of variables are tested with an F test. Unfortunately, the final model often depends on the order in which variables were dropped or added. [For more on stepwise regression, see Draper and Smith (1981).] In addition, this is a severe form of data mining, and it is difficult to interpret t and F statistics in the final model. One might argue that stepwise regression simply automates what researchers do anyway in searching over various models. However, in most applications, one or two explanatory variables are of primary interest, and then the goal is to see how robust the coeffi- cients on those variables are to either adding or dropping other variables, or to chang- ing functional form. In principle, it is possible to incorporate the effects of data mining into our statistical inference; in practice, this is very difficult and is rarely done, especially in sophisticated empirical work. [See Leamer (1983) for an engaging discussion of this problem.] But we can try to minimize data mining by not searching over numerous models or estimation methods until a significant result is found and then reporting only that result. If a variable is statistically significant in only a small fraction of the models estimated, it is quite likely that the variable has no effect in the population. 19.5 Writing an Empirical Paper Writing a paper that uses econometric analysis is very challenging, but it can also be rewarding. A successful paper combines a careful, convincing data analysis with good explanations and exposition. Therefore, you must have a good grasp of your topic, good understanding of econometric methods, and solid writing skills. Do not be discouraged if you find writing an empirical paper difficult; most professional researchers have spent many years learning how to craft an empirical analysis and to write the results in a convincing form. While writing styles vary, many papers follow the same general outline. The follow- ing paragraphs include ideas for section headings and explanations about what each sec- tion should contain. These are only suggestions and hardly need to be strictly followed. In the final paper, each section would be given a number, usually starting with one for the introduction. Introduction The introduction states the basic objectives of the study and explains why it is important. It generally entails a review of the literature, indicating what has been done and how pre- vious work can be improved upon. (As discussed in Section 19.2, an extensive literature Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 687 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project review can be put in a separate section.) Presenting simple statistics or graphs that re- veal a seemingly paradoxical relationship is a useful way to introduce the paper’s topic. For example, suppose that you are writing a paper about factors affecting fertility in a developing country, with the focus on education levels of women. An appealing way to introduce the topic would be to produce a table or a graph showing that fertility has been falling (say) over time and a brief explanation of how you hope to examine the factors contributing to the decline. At this point, you may already know that, ceteris paribus, more highly educated women have fewer children and that average education levels have risen over time. Most researchers like to summarize the findings of their paper in the introduction. This can be a useful device for grabbing the reader’s attention. For example, you might state that your best estimate of the effect of missing 10 hours of lecture during a 30-hour term is about one-half a grade point. But the summary should not be too involved because neither the methods nor the data used to obtain the estimates have yet been introduced. Conceptual (or Theoretical) Framework In this section, you describe the general approach to answering the question you have posed. It can be formal economic theory, but in many cases, it is an intuitive discussion about what conceptual problems arise in answering your question. As an example, suppose you are studying the effects of economic opportunities and severity of punishment on criminal behavior. One approach to explaining participation in crime is to specify a utility maximization problem where the individual chooses the amount of time spent in legal and illegal activities, given wage rates in both kinds of ac- tivities, as well as variables measuring probability and severity of punishment for criminal activity. The usefulness of such an exercise is that it suggests which variables should be included in the empirical analysis; it gives guidance (but rarely specifics) as to how the variables should appear in the econometric model. Often, there is no need to write down an economic theory. For econometric policy analysis, common sense usually suffices for specifying a model. For example, suppose you are interested in estimating the effects of participation in Aid to Families with Dependent Children (AFDC) on the effects of child performance in school. AFDC pro- vides supplemental income, but participation also makes it easier to receive Medicaid and other benefits. The hard part of such an analysis is deciding on the set of variables that should be controlled for. In this example, we could control for family income (in- cluding AFDC and any other welfare income), mother’s education, whether the family lives in an urban area, and other variables. Then, the inclusion of an AFDC partici- pation indicator (hopefully) measures the nonincome benefits of AFDC participation. A discussion of which factors should be controlled for and the mechanisms through which AFDC participation might improve school performance substitute for formal economic theory. Econometric Models and Estimation Methods It is very useful to have a section that contains a few equations of the sort you estimate and present in the results section of the paper. This allows you to fix ideas about what the key explanatory variable is and what other factors you will control for. Writing equations containing error terms allows you to discuss whether OLS is a suitable estimation method. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 688 PART 3 Advanced Topics The distinction between a model and an estimation method should be made in this section. A model represents a population relationship (broadly defined to allow for time series equations). For example, we should write colGPA 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1alcohol 􏱕 􏱬2hsGPA 􏱕 􏱬3SAT 􏱕 􏱬4 female 􏱕 u [19.1] to describe the relationship between college GPA and alcohol consumption, with some other controls in the equation. Presumably, this equation represents a population, such as all undergraduates at a particular university. There are no “hats” (ˆ) on the 􏱬j or on colGPA because this is a model, not an estimated equation. We do not put in numbers for the 􏱬j because we do not know (and never will know) these numbers. Later, we will estimate them. In this section, do not anticipate the presentation of your empirical results. In other words, do not start with a general model and then say that you omitted certain variables because they turned out to be insignificant. Such discussions should be left for the results section. A time series model to relate city-level car thefts to the unemployment rate and con- viction rates could look like theftst 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unemt 􏱕 􏱬2unemt􏱦1 􏱕 􏱬3carst 􏱕 􏱬4convratet 􏱕 􏱬5convratet􏱦1 􏱕 ut, [19.2] where the t subscript is useful for emphasizing any dynamics in the equation (in this case, allowing for unemployment and the automobile theft conviction rate to have lagged effects). After specifying a model or models, it is appropriate to discuss estimation methods. In most cases, this will be OLS, but, for example, in a time series equation, you might use feasible GLS to do a serial correlation correction (as in Chapter 12). However, the method for estimating a model is quite distinct from the model itself. It is not meaningful, for in- stance, to talk about “an OLS model.” Ordinary least squares is a method of estimation, and so are weighted least squares, Cochrane-Orcutt, and so on. There are usually several ways to estimate any model. You should explain why the method you are choosing is warranted. Any assumptions that are used in obtaining an estimable econometric model from an underlying economic model should be clearly discussed. For example, in the quality of high school example mentioned in Section 19.1, the issue of how to measure school quality is central to the analysis. Should it be based on average SAT scores, percentage of graduates attending college, student-teacher ratios, average education level of teachers, some combination of these, or possibly other measures? We always have to make assumptions about functional form whether or not a theoreti- cal model has been presented. As you know, constant elasticity and constant semi-elasticity models are attractive because the coefficients are easy to interpret (as percentage effects). There are no hard rules on how to choose functional form, but the guidelines discussed in Section 6.2 seem to work well in practice. You do not need an extensive discussion of func- tional form, but it is useful to mention whether you will be estimating elasticities or a semi- elasticity. For example, if you are estimating the effect of some variable on wage or salary, the dependent variable will almost surely be in logarithmic form, and you might as well include this in any equations from the beginning. You do not have to present every one, or even most, of the functional form variations that you will report later in the results section. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 689 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project Often, the data used in empirical economics are at the city or county level. For ex- ample, suppose that for the population of small to midsize cities, you wish to test the hypothesis that having a minor league baseball team causes a city to have a lower divorce rate. In this case, you must account for the fact that larger cities will have more divorces. One way to account for the size of the city is to scale divorces by the city or adult popula- tion. Thus, a reasonable model is log(div/pop) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1mlb 􏱕 􏱬2 perCath 􏱕 􏱬3log(inc/pop) 􏱕 other factors, [19.3] where mlb is a dummy variable equal to one if the city has a minor league baseball team and perCath is the percentage of the population that is Catholic (so a number such as 34.6 means 34.6%). Note that div/pop is a divorce rate, which is generally easier to interpret than the absolute number of divorces. Another way to control for population is to estimate the model log(div) 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1mlb 􏱕 􏰸2 perCath 􏱕 􏰸3log(inc) 􏱕 􏰸4log( pop) [19.4] 􏱕 other factors. The parameter of interest, 􏰸1, when multiplied by 100, gives the percentage difference between divorce rates, holding population, percent Catholic, income, and whatever else is in “other factors” constant. In equation (19.3), 􏱬1 measures the percentage effect of minor league baseball on div/pop, which can change either because the number of divorces or the population changes. Using the fact that log(div/pop) 􏱪 log(div) 􏱦 log(pop) and log(inc/ pop) 􏱪 log(inc) 􏱦 log(pop), we can rewrite (19.3) as log(div) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1mlb 􏱕 􏱬2 perCath 􏱕 􏱬3log(inc) 􏱕 (1 􏱦 􏱬3)log( pop) 􏱕 other factors, which shows that (19.3) is a special case of (19.4) with 􏰸4 􏱪 (1 􏱦 􏱬3) and 􏰸j 􏱪 􏱬j, j 􏱪 0,1,2,3. Alternatively, (19.4) is equivalent to adding log(pop) as an additional explana- tory variable to (19.3). This makes it easy to test for a separate population effect on the divorce rate. If you are using a more advanced estimation method, such as two stage least squares, you need to provide some reasons for doing so. If you use 2SLS, you must provide a careful discussion on why your IV choices for the endogenous explanatory variable (or variables) are valid. As we mentioned in Chapter 15, there are two requirements for a variable to be considered a good IV. First, it must be omitted from and exogenous to the equation of interest (structural equation). This is something we must assume. Second, it must have some partial correlation with the endogenous explanatory variable. This we can test. For example, in equation (19.1), you might use a binary variable for whether a student lives in a dormitory (dorm) as an IV for alcohol consumption. This requires that living situation has no direct impact on colGPA—so that it is omitted from (19.1)—and that it is uncorrelated with unobserved factors in u that have an effect on colGPA. We would also have to verify that dorm is partially correlated with alcohol by regressing alcohol on dorm, hsGPA, SAT, and female. (See Chapter 15 for details.) You might account for the omitted variable problem (or omitted heterogeneity) by using panel data. Again, this is easily described by writing an equation or two. In fact, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 690 PART 3 Advanced Topics it is useful to show how to difference the equations over time to remove time-constant unobservables; this gives an equation that can be estimated by OLS. Or, if you are using fixed effects estimation instead, you simply state so. As a simple example, suppose you are testing whether higher county tax rates reduce economic activity, as measured by per capita manufacturing output. Suppose that for the years 1982, 1987, and 1992, the model is log(manufit) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛1d87t 􏱕 􏱛2d92t 􏱕 􏱬1taxit 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ai 􏱕 uit, where d87t and d92t are year dummy variables and taxit is the tax rate for county i at time t (in percent form). We would have other variables that change over time in the equa- tion, including measures for costs of doing business (such as average wages), measures of worker productivity (as measured by average education), and so on. The term ai is the fixed effect, containing all factors that do not vary over time, and uit is the idiosyncratic error term. To remove ai, we can either difference across the years or use time-demeaning (the fixed effects transformation). The Data You should always have a section that carefully describes the data used in the empiri- cal analysis. This is particularly important if your data are nonstandard or have not been widely used by other researchers. Enough information should be presented so that a reader could, in principle, obtain the data and redo your analysis. In particular, all applicable pub- lic data sources should be included in the references, and short data sets can be listed in an appendix. If you used your own survey to collect the data, a copy of the questionnaire should be presented in an appendix. Along with a discussion of the data sources, be sure to discuss the units of each of the variables (for example, is income measured in hundreds or thousands of dollars?). Including a table of variable definitions is very useful to the reader. The names in the table should correspond to the names used in describing the econometric results in the following section. It is also very informative to present a table of summary statistics, such as mini- mum and maximum values, means, and standard deviations for each variable. Having such a table makes it easier to interpret the coefficient estimates in the next section, and it emphasizes the units of measurement of the variables. For binary variables, the only necessary summary statistic is the fraction of ones in the sample (which is the same as the sample mean). For trending variables, things like means are less interesting. It is often useful to compute the average growth rate in a variable over the years in your sample. You should always clearly state how many observations you have. For time series data sets, identify the years that you are using in the analysis, including a description of any special periods in history (such as World War II). If you use a pooled cross section or a panel data set, be sure to report how many cross-sectional units (people, cities, and so on) you have for each year. Results The results section should include your estimates of any models formulated in the models section. You might start with a very simple analysis. For example, suppose that percentage Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 691 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project of students attending college from the graduating class (percoll) is used as a measure of the quality of the high school a person attended. Then, an equation to estimate is log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1 percoll 􏱕 u. Of course, this does not control for several other factors that may determine wages and that may be correlated with percoll. But a simple analysis can draw the reader into the more sophisticated analysis and reveal the importance of controlling for other factors. If only a few equations are estimated, you can present the results in equation form with standard errors in parentheses below estimated coefficients. If your model has several explanatory variables and you are presenting several variations on the general model, it is better to report the results in tabular rather than equation form. Most of your papers should have at least one table, which should always include at least the R-squared and the number of observations for each equation. Other statistics, such as the adjusted R-squared, can also be listed. The most important thing is to discuss the interpretation and strength of your em- pirical results. Do the coefficients have the expected signs? Are they statistically sig- nificant? If a coefficient is statistically significant but has a counterintuitive sign, why might this be true? It might be revealing a problem with the data or the econometric method (for example, OLS may be inappropriate due to omitted variables problems). Be sure to describe the magnitudes of the coefficients on the major explanatory vari- ables. Often, one or two policy variables are central to the study. Their signs, magnitudes, and statistical significance should be treated in detail. Remember to distinguish between economic and statistical significance. If a t statistic is small, is it because the coefficient is practically small or because its standard error is large? In addition to discussing estimates from the most general model, you can provide in- teresting special cases, especially those needed to test certain multiple hypotheses. For example, in a study to determine wage differentials across industries, you might present the equation without the industry dummies; this allows the reader to easily test whether the industry differentials are statistically significant (using the R-squared form of the F test). Do not worry too much about dropping various variables to find the “best” combination of explanatory variables. As we mentioned earlier, this is a difficult and not even very well-defined task. Only if eliminating a set of variables substantially alters the magnitudes and/or significance of the coefficients of interest is this important. Dropping a group of variables to simplify the model—such as quadratics or interactions—can be justified via an F test. If you have used at least two different methods—such as OLS and 2SLS, or levels and differencing for a time series, or pooled OLS versus differencing with a panel data set— then you should comment on any critical differences. If OLS gives counterintuitive results, did using 2SLS or panel data methods improve the estimates? Or, did the opposite happen? Conclusions This can be a short section that summarizes what you have learned. For example, you might want to present the magnitude of a coefficient that was of particular interest. The conclusion should also discuss caveats to the conclusions drawn, and it might even suggest directions for further research. It is useful to imagine readers turning first to the conclusion to decide whether to read the rest of the paper. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 692 PART 3 Advanced Topics Style Hints You should give your paper a title that reflects its topic, but make sure the title is not so long as to be cumbersome. The title should be on a separate title page that also includes your name, affiliation, and—if relevant—the course number. The title page can also include a short abstract, or an abstract can be included on a separate page. Papers should be typed and double-spaced. All equations should begin on a new line, and they should be centered and numbered consecutively, that is, (1), (2), (3), and so on. Large graphs and tables may be included after the main body. In the text, refer to papers by author and date, for example, White (1980). The reference section at the end of the paper should be done in standard format. Several examples are given in the references at the back of the text. When you introduce an equation in the econometric models section, you should describe the important variables: the dependent variable and the key independent variable or variables. To focus on a single independent variable, you can write an equation, such as or GPA􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1alcohol􏱕x􏱛􏱕u log(wage) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1educ 􏱕 x􏱛 􏱕 u, where the notation x􏱛 is shorthand for several other explanatory variables. At this point, you need only describe them generally; they can be described specifically in the data sec- tion in a table. For example, in a study of the factors affecting chief executive officer sala- ries, you might include a table like Table 19.1. A table of summary statistics, obtained from Table I in Papke and Wooldridge (1996) and similar to the data in 401K.RAW, might be set up as shown in Table 19.2. In the results section, you can write the estimates either in equation form, as we of- ten have done, or in a table. Especially when several models have been estimated with TABLE 19.1 Variable Descriptions salary annual salary (including bonuses) in 1990 (in thousands) sales firm sales in 1990 (in millions) roe average return on equity, 1988–1990 (in percent) pcsal percentage change in salary, 1988–1990 pcroe percentage change in roe, 1988–1990 indust 􏱪 1 if an industrial company, 0 otherwise finance 􏱪 1 if a financial company, 0 otherwise consprod 􏱪 1 if a consumer products company, 0 otherwise util 􏱪 1 if a utility company, 0 otherwise ceoten number of years as CEO of the company Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 693 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project TABLE 19.2 Summary Statistics Variable Mean Standard Deviation Minimum Maximum prate .869 .167 .023 1 mrate .746 .844 .011 5 employ 4,621.01 16,299.64 53 443,040 age 13.14 9.63 4 76 sole .415 .493 0 1 Number of observations 􏱪 3,784 different sets of explanatory variables, tables are very useful. If you write out the estimates as an equation, for example, 􏱾log(salary) 􏱪 2.45 􏱕 .236 log(sales) 􏱕 .008 roe 􏱕 .061 ceoten (0.93) (.115) (.003) (.028) n 􏱪 204, R2 􏱪 .351, be sure to state near the first equation that standard errors are in parentheses. It is accept- able to report the t statistics for testing H0: 􏱬j 􏱪 0, or their absolute values, but it is most important to state what you are doing. If you report your results in tabular form, make sure the dependent and independent variables are clearly indicated. Again, state whether standard errors or t statistics are below the coefficients (with the former preferred). Some authors like to use asterisks to indicate statistical significance at different significance levels (for example, one star means significant at 5%, two stars mean significant at 10% but not 5%, and so on). This is not necessary if you carefully discuss the significance of the explanatory variables in the text. A sample table of results, derived from Table II in Papke and Wooldridge (1996), is shown in Table 19.3. Your results will be easier to read and interpret if you choose the units of both your dependent and independent variables so that coefficients are not too large or too small. You should never report numbers such as 1.051e􏱦007 or 3.524e􏱕006 for your coeffi- cients or standard errors, and you should not use scientific notation. If coefficients are either extremely small or large, rescale the dependent or independent variables, as we discussed in Chapter 6. You should limit the number of digits reported after the decimal point so as not to convey a false sense of precision. For example, if your regression pack- age estimates a coefficient to be .54821059, you should report this as .548, or even .55, in the paper. As a rule, the commands that your particular econometrics package uses to produce results should not appear in the paper; only the results are important. If some special com- mand was used to carry out a certain estimation method, this can be given in an appendix. An appendix is also a good place to include extra results that support your analysis but are not central to it. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 694 PART 3 Advanced Topics T A B L E 1 9 . 3 OLS Results. Dependent Variable: Participation Rate Independent Variables (1) (2) (3) mrate .156 (.012) .239 (.042) .218 (.342) mrate2 — 􏱦.087 (.043) 􏱦.096 (.073) log(emp) 􏱦.112 (.014) 􏱦.112 (.014) 􏱦.098 (.111) log(emp)2 .0057 (.0009) .0057 (.0009) .0052 (.0007) age .0060 (.0010) .0059 (.0010) .0050 (.0021) age2 􏱦.00007 (.00002) 􏱦.00007 (.00002) 􏱦.00006 (.00002) sole 􏱦.0001 (.0058) .0008 (.0058) .0006 (.0061) constant 1.213 (.051) .198 (.052) .085 (.041) industry dummies? no no yes Observations R-squared 3,784 .143 3,784 .152 3,784 .162 Note: The quantities in parentheses below the estimates are the standard errors. Summary In this chapter, we have discussed the ingredients of a successful empirical study and have provided hints that can improve the quality of an analysis. Ultimately, the success of any study depends crucially on the care and effort put into it. Key Terms Data Mining Internet Misspecification Analysis Sample Empirical Projects Online Databases Online Search Services Sensitivity Analysis Spreadsheet Text Editor Text (ASCII) File Throughout the text, we have seen examples of econometric analysis that either came from or were motivated by published works. We hope these have given you a good idea about the scope of empirical analysis. We include the following list as additional examples of questions Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project 695 that others have found or are likely to find interesting. These are intended to stimulate your imagination; no attempt is made to fill in all the details of specific models, data requirements, or alternative estimation methods. It should be possible to complete these projects in one term. 1 Do your own campus survey to answer a question of interest at your university. For example: What is the effect of working on college GPA? You can ask students about high school GPA, college GPA, ACT or SAT scores, hours worked per week, participation in athletics, major, gender, race, and so on. Then, use these variables to create a model that explains GPA. How much of an effect, if any, does another hour worked per week have on GPA? One issue of concern is that hours worked might be endogenous: it might be correlated with unobserved factors that affect college GPA, or lower GPAs might cause students to work more. A better approach would be to collect cumulative GPA prior to the semester and then to obtain GPA for the most recent semester, along with amount worked during that semes- ter, and the other variables. Now, cumulative GPA could be used as a control (explanatory variable) in the equation. 2 There are many variants on the preceding topic. You can study the effects of drug or alcohol usage, or of living in a fraternity, on grade point average. You would want to control for many family background variables, as well as previous performance variables. 3 Do gun control laws at the city level reduce violent crimes? Such questions can be difficult to answer with a single cross section because city and state laws are often endogenous. [See Kleck and Patterson (1993) for an example. They used cross-sectional data and instrumen- tal variables methods, but their IVs are questionable.] Panel data can be very useful for inferring causality in these contexts. At a minimum, you could control for a previous year’s violent crime rate. 4 Low and McPheters (1983) used city cross-sectional data on wage rates and estimates of risk of death for police officers, along with other controls. The idea is to determine whether police officers are compensated for working in cities with a higher risk of on-the-job injury or death. 5 Do parental consent laws increase the teenage birthrate? You can use state level data for this: either a time series for a given state or, even better, a panel data set of states. Do the same laws reduce abortion rates among teenagers? The Statistical Abstract of the United States contains all kinds of state-level data. Levine, Trainor, and Zimmerman (1996) stud- ied the effects of abortion funding restrictions on similar outcomes. Other factors, such as access to abortions, may affect teen birth and abortion rates. There is also recent interest in the effects of “abstinence-only” sex education cur- ricula. One can again use state-level panel data, or maybe even panel data at the school district level, to determine the effects of abstinence-only approaches to sex education on various outcomes, including rates of sexually transmitted diseases and teen birth rates. 6 Do changes in traffic laws affect traffic fatalities? McCarthy (1994) contains an analysis of monthly time series data for the state of California. A set of dummy variables can be used to indicate the months in which certain laws were in effect. The file TRAFFIC2.RAW contains the data used by McCarthy. An alternative is to obtain a panel data set on states in the United States, where you can exploit variation in laws across states, as well as across time. Freedman (2007) is a good example of a state-level analysis, using 25 years of data that straddle changes in various state drunk driving, seat belt, and speed limit laws. The data can be found in the file DRIVING.RAW. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 696 PART 3 Advanced Topics Mullahy and Sindelar (1994) used individual-level data matched with state laws and taxes on alcohol to estimate the effects of laws and taxes on the probability of driving drunk. 7 Areblacksdiscriminatedagainstinthelendingmarket?HunterandWalker(1996)lookedat this question; in fact, we used their data in Computer Exercises C.8 in Chapter 7 and C.2 in Chapter 17. 8 Is there a marriage premium for professional athletes? Korenman and Neumark (1991) found a significant wage premium for married men after using a variety of econometric methods, but their analysis is limited because they cannot directly observe productivity. (Plus, Korenman and Neumark used men in a variety of occupations.) Professional ath- letes provide an interesting group in which to study the marriage premium because we can easily collect data on various productivity measures, in addition to salary. The data set NBASAL.RAW, on players in the National Basketball Association (NBA), is one ex- ample. For each player, we have information on points scored, rebounds, assists, playing time, and demographics. As in Computer Exercise C.9 in Chapter 6, we can use multiple regression analysis to test whether the productivity measures differ by marital status. We can also use this kind of data to test whether married men are paid more after we account for productivity differences. (For example, NBA owners may think that married men bring stability to the team, or are better for the team image.) For individual sports—such as golf and tennis—annual earnings directly reflect productivity. Such data, along with age and experience, are relatively easy to collect. 9 Answerthisquestion:Arecigarettesmokerslessproductive?Avariantonthisis:Dowork- ers who smoke take more sick days (everything else being equal)? Mullahy and Portney (1990) use individual-level data to evaluate this question. You could use data at, say, the metropolitan level. Something like average productivity in manufacturing can be related to percentage of manufacturing workers who smoke. Other variables, such as average worker education, capital per worker, and size of the city (you can think of more), should be con- trolled for. 10 Do minimum wages alleviate poverty? You can use state or county data to answer this question. The idea is that the minimum wage varies across states because some states have higher minimums than the federal minimum. Further, there are changes over time in the nominal minimum within a state, some due to changes at the federal level and some be- cause of changes at the state level. Neumark and Wascher (1995) used a panel data set on states to estimate the effects of the minimum wage on the employment rates of young workers, as well as on school enrollment rates. 11 What factors affect student performance at public schools? It is fairly easy to get school- level or at least district-level data in most states. Does spending per student matter? Do student-teacher ratios have any effects? It is difficult to estimate ceteris paribus effects be- cause spending is related to other factors, such as family incomes or poverty rates. The data set MEAP93.RAW, for Michigan high schools, contains a measure of the poverty rates. Another possibility is to use panel data, or at least to control for a previous year’s perfor- mance measure (such as average test score or percentage of students passing an exam). You can look at less obvious factors that affect student performance. For example, after controlling for income, does family structure matter? Perhaps families with two par- ents, but only one working for a wage, have a positive effect on performance. (There could Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project 697 be at least two channels: parents spend more time with the children, and they might also volunteer at school.) What about the effect of single-parent households, controlling for income and other factors? You can merge census data for one or two years with school district data. Do public schools with more charter or private schools nearby better educate their students because of competition? There is a tricky simultaneity issue here because private schools are probably located in areas where the public schools are already poor. Hoxby (1994) used an instrumental variables approach, where population proportions of various religions were IVs for the number of private schools. Rouse (1998) studied a different question: Did students who were able to attend a private school due to the Milwaukee voucher program perform better than those who did not? She used panel data and was able to control for an unobserved student effect. A subset of Rouse’s data is contained in the file VOUCHER.RAW. 12 Can excess returns on a stock, or a stock index, be predicted by the lagged price/dividend ratio? Or by lagged interest rates or weekly monetary policy? It would be interesting to pick a foreign stock index, or one of the less well-known U.S. indexes. Cochrane (1997) provides a nice survey of recent theories and empirical results for explaining excess stock returns. 13 Is there racial discrimination in the market for baseball cards? This involves relating the prices of baseball cards to factors that should affect their prices, such as career statistics, whether the player is in the Hall of Fame, and so on. Holding other factors fixed, do cards of black or Hispanic players sell at a discount? 14 Youcantestwhetherthemarketforgamblingonsportsisefficient.Forexample,doesthe spread on football or basketball games contain all usable information for picking against the spread? The data set PNTSPRD.RAW contains information on men’s college basket- ball games. The outcome variable is binary. Was the spread covered or not? Then, you can try to find information that was known prior to each game’s being played in order to predict whether the spread is covered. (Good luck!) A useful website that contains historical spreads and outcomes for college football and men’s basketball games is www .goldsheet.com. 15 What effect, if any, does success in college athletics have on other aspects of the university (applications, quality of students, quality of nonathletic departments)? Mc- Cormick and Tinsley (1987) looked at the effects of athletic success at major colleges on changes in SAT scores of entering freshmen. Timing is important here: presumably, it is recent past success that affects current applications and student quality. One must control for many other factors—such as tuition and measures of school quality—to make the analysis convincing because, without controlling for other factors, there is a negative correlation between academics and athletic performance. A more recent examination of the link between academic and athletic performance is provided by Tucker (2004), who also looks at how alumni contributions are affected by athletic success. A variant is to match natural rivals in football or men’s basketball and to look at dif- ferences across schools as a function of which school won the football game or one or more basketball games. ATHLET1.RAW and ATHLET2.RAW are small data sets that could be expanded and updated. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 698 PART 3 Advanced Topics 16 Collect murder rates for a sample of counties (say, from the FBI Uniform Crime Reports) for two years. Make the latter year such that economic and demographic variables are easy to obtain from the County and City Data Book. You can obtain the total number of people on death row plus executions for intervening years at the county level. If the years are 1990 and 1985, you might estimate mrdrte90 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1mrdrte85 􏱕 􏱬2executions 􏱕 other factors, where interest is in the coefficient on executions. The lagged murder rate and other factors serve as controls. If more than two years of data are obtained then the panel data methods in Chapters 13 and 14 can be applied. Other factors may also act as a deterrent to crime. For example, Cloninger (1991) presented a cross-sectional analysis of the effects of lethal police response on crime rates. As a different twist, what factors affect crime rates on college campuses? Does the fraction of students living in fraternities or sororities have an effect? Does the size of the police force matter, or the kind of policing used? (Be careful about inferring causality here.) Does having an escort program help reduce crime? What about crime rates in nearby communities? Recently, colleges and universities have been required to report crime statis- tics; in previous years, reporting was voluntary. 17 What factors affect manufacturing productivity at the state level? In addition to levels of capital and worker education, you could look at degree of unionization. A panel data anal- ysis would be most convincing here, using multiple years of census data, say 1980, 1990, 2000, and 2010. Clark (1984) provides an analysis of how unionization affects firm perfor- mance and productivity. What other variables might explain productivity? Firm-level data can be obtained from Compustat. For example, other factors being fixed, do changes in unionization affect stock price of a firm? 18 Use state- or county-level data or, if possible, school district–level data to look at the fac- tors that affect education spending per pupil. An interesting question is: Other things being equal (such as income and education levels of residents), do districts with a larger percent- age of elderly people spend less on schools? Census data can be matched with school dis- trict spending data to obtain a very large cross section. The U.S. Department of Education compiles such data. 19 What are the effects of state regulations, such as motorcycle helmet laws, on motorcycle fatalities? Or do differences in boating laws—such as minimum operating age—help to explain boating accident rates? The U.S. Department of Transportation compiles such in- formation. This can be merged with data from the Statistical Abstract of the United States. A panel data analysis seems to be warranted here. 20 What factors affect output growth? Two factors of interest are inflation and investment [for example, Blomström, Lipsey, and Zejan (1996)]. You might use time series data on a country you find interesting. Or you could use a cross section of countries, as in De Long and Summers (1991). Friedman and Kuttner (1992) found evidence that, at least in the 1980s, the spread between the commercial paper rate and the Treasury bill rate affects real output. 21 What is the behavior of mergers in the U.S. economy (or some other economy)? Shughart and Tollison (1984) characterize (the log of) annual mergers in the U.S. economy as a Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project 699 random walk by showing that the difference in logs—roughly, the growth rate—is unpre- dictable given past growth rates. Does this still hold? Does it hold across various indus- tries? What past measures of economic activity can be used to forecast mergers? 22 What factors might explain racial and gender differences in employment and wages? For example, Holzer (1991) reviewed the evidence on the “spatial mismatch hypothesis” to ex- plain differences in employment rates between blacks and whites. Korenman and Neumark (1992) examined the effects of childbearing on women’s wages, while Hersch and Stratton (1997) looked at the effects of household responsibilities on men’s and women’s wages. 23 Obtain monthly or quarterly data on teenage employment rates, the minimum wage, and factors that affect teen employment to estimate the effects of the minimum wage on teen employment. Solon (1985) used quarterly U.S. data, while Castillo-Freeman and Freeman (1992) used annual data on Puerto Rico. It might be informative to analyze time series data on a low-wage state in the United States—where changes in the minimum wage are likely to have the largest effect. 24 At the city level, estimate a time series model for crime. An example is Cloninger and Sar- torius (1979). As a twist, you might estimate the effects of community policing or midnight basketball programs, relatively new innovations in fighting crime. Inferring causality is tricky. Including a lagged dependent variable might be helpful. Because you are using time series data, you should be aware of the spurious regression problem. Grogger (1990) used data on daily homicide counts to estimate the deterrent effects of capital punishment. Might there be other factors—such as news on lethal response by police—that have an effect on daily crime counts? 25 Are there aggregate productivity effects of computer usage? You would need to obtain time series data, perhaps at the national level, on productivity, percentage of employees using computers, and other factors. What about spending (probably as a fraction of total sales) on research and development? What sociological factors (for example, alcohol us- age or divorce rates) might affect productivity? 26 What factors affect chief executive officer salaries? The files CEOSAL1.RAW and CEO- SAL2.RAW are data sets that have various firm performance measures as well as informa- tion such as tenure and education. You can certainly update these data files and look for other interesting factors. Rose and Shepard (1997) considered firm diversification as one important determinant of CEO compensation. 27 Do differences in tax codes across states affect the amount of foreign direct investment? Hines (1996) studied the effects of state corporate taxes, along with the ability to apply foreign tax credits, on investment from outside the United States. 28 What factors affect election outcomes? Does spending matter? Do votes on specific issues matter? Does the state of the local economy matter? See, for example, Levitt (1994) and the data sets VOTE1.RAW and VOTE2.RAW. Fair (1996) performed a time series analy- sis of U.S. presidential elections. 29 Test whether stores or restaurants practice price discrimination based on race or ethnicity. Graddy (1997) used data on fast-food restaurants in New Jersey and Pennsylvania, along with zip code-level characteristics, to see whether prices vary by characteristics of the lo- cal population. She found that prices of standard items, such as sodas, increase when the fraction of black residents increases. (Her data are contained in the file DISCRIM.RAW.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 700 PART 3 Advanced Topics You can collect similar data in your local area by surveying stores or restaurants for prices of common items and matching those with recent census data. See Graddy’s paper for de- tails of her analysis. 30 Do your own “audit” study to test for race or gender discrimination in hiring. (One such study is described in Example C.3 of Appendix C.) Have pairs of equally qualified friends, say, one male and one female, apply for job openings in local bars or restaurants. You can provide them with phony résumés that give each the same experience and background, where the only difference is gender (or race). Then, you can keep track of who gets the interviews and job offers. Neumark (1996) described one such study conducted in Philadelphia. A vari- ant would be to test whether general physical attractiveness or a specific characteristic, such as being obese or having visible tattoos or body piercings, plays a role in hiring decisions. You would want to use the same gender in the matched pairs, and it may not be easy to get volunteers for such a study. 31 Following Hamermesh and Parker (2005), try to establish a link between the physical appearance of college instructors and student evaluations. This can be done on campus via a survey. Somewhat crude data can be obtained from websites that allow students to rank their professors and provide some information about appearance. Ideally, though, any evaluations of attractiveness are not done by current or former students, as those evaluations can be influenced by the grade received. 32 Use panel data to study the effects of various economic policies on regional economic growth. Studying the effects of taxes and spending is natural, but other policies may be of interest. For example, Craig, Jackson, and Thomson (2007) study the effects of Small Busi- ness Association Loan Guarantee programs on per capita income growth. List of Journals The following is a partial list of popular journals containing empirical research in business, economics, and other social sciences. A complete list of journals can be found on the Internet at http://www.econlit.org. American Economic Review American Journal of Agricultural Economics American Political Science Review Applied Economics Brookings Papers on Economic Activity Canadian Journal of Economics Demography Economic Development and Cultural Change Economic Inquiry Economica Economics Letters Empirical Economics Federal Reserve Bulletin International Economic Review International Tax and Public Finance Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. CHAPTER 19 Carrying Out an Empirical Project 701 Journal of Applied Econometrics Journal of Business and Economic Statistics Journal of Development Economics Journal of Economic Education Journal of Empirical Finance Journal of Environmental Economics and Management Journal of Finance Journal of Health Economics Journal of Human Resources Journal of Industrial Economics Journal of International Economics Journal of Labor Economics Journal of Monetary Economics Journal of Money, Credit and Banking Journal of Political Economy Journal of Public Economics Journal of Quantitative Criminology Journal of Urban Economics National Bureau of Economic Research Working Papers Series National Tax Journal Public Finance Quarterly Quarterly Journal of Economics Regional Science & Urban Economics Review of Economic Studies Review of Economics and Statistics Data Sources Numerous data sources are available throughout the world. Governments of most countries compile a wealth of data; some general and easily accessible data sources for the United States, such as the Economic Report of the President, the Statistical Abstract of the United States, and the County and City Data Book, have already been mentioned. International financial data on many countries are published annually in International Financial Statistics. Various maga- zines, like BusinessWeek and U.S. News and World Report, often publish statistics—such as CEO salaries and firm performance, or ranking of academic programs—that are novel and can be used in an econometric analysis. Rather than attempting to provide a list here, we instead give some Internet addresses that are comprehensive sources for economists. A very useful site for economists, called Resources for Economists on the Internet, is maintained by Bill Goffe at SUNY, Oswego. The address is http://www.rfe.org. This site provides links to journals, data sources, and lists of professional and academic econo- mists. It is quite simple to use. Another very useful site is http://econometriclinks.com, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 702 PART 3 Advanced Topics which contains links to lots of data sources as well as to other sites of interest to empirical economists. In addition, the Journal of Applied Econometrics and the Journal of Business and Economic Statistics have data archives that contain data sets used in most papers published in the journals over the past several years. If you find a data set that interests you, this is a good way to go, as much of the cleaning and formatting of the data have already been done. The downside is that some of these data sets are used in econometric analyses that are more advanced than we have learned about in this text. On the other hand, it is often useful to estimate simpler models using standard econometric methods for comparison. Many universities, such as the University of California–Berkeley, the University of Mich- igan, and the University of Maryland, maintain very extensive data sets as well as links to a variety of data sets. Your own library possibly contains an extensive set of links to databases in business, economics, and the other social sciences. The regional Federal Reserve banks, such as the one in St. Louis, manage a variety of data. The National Bureau of Economic Research posts data sets used by some of its researchers. State and federal governments now publish a wealth of data that can be accessed via the Internet. Census data are publicly available from the U.S. Census Bureau. (Two useful publications are the Economic Census, published in years ending with two and seven, and the Census of Population and Housing, published at the begin- ning of each decade.) Other agencies, such as the U.S. Department of Justice, also make data available to the public. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. This appendix covers some basic mathematics that are used in econometric analysis. We summarize various properties of the summation operator, study properties of linear and certain nonlinear equations, and review proportions and percentages. We also present some special functions that often arise in applied econometrics, including quadratic functions and the natural logarithm. The first four sections require only basic algebra skills. Section A.5 contains a brief review of differential calculus; although a knowledge of calculus is not necessary to understand most of the text, it is used in some end-of-chapter appendices and in several of the more advanced chapters in Part 3. A.1 The Summation Operator and Descriptive Statistics The summation operator is a useful shorthand for manipulating expressions involving the sums of many numbers, and it plays a key role in statistics and econometric analy- sis. If {xi: i 􏱪 1, ..., n} denotes a sequence of n numbers, then we write the sum of these numbers as APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools n ∑x 􏱲x 􏱕x 􏱕...􏱕x. [A.1] i12 n i􏱪1 With this definition, the summation operator is easily shown to have the following properties: Property Sum.1: For any constant c, [A.2] [A.3] 703 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i􏱪1 Property Sum.2: For any constant c, n ∑ c 􏱪 nc. nn ∑ cx 􏱪 c i i􏱪1 i􏱪1 ∑ x . i 704 APPENDICES Property Sum.3: If {(xi,yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is a set of n pairs of numbers, and a and b are constants, then We summarize this as ∑n ∑n (x 􏱦x-)􏱪 i ∑∑ ∑n - x 􏱦nx-􏱪nx-􏱦nx-􏱪0. i d 􏱪 i i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 ∑n ∑n∑n [A.4] (ax 􏱕by)􏱪a x 􏱕b y. ii i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 It is also important to be aware of some things that cannot be done with the summa- tion operator. Let {(xi,yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} again be a set of n pairs of numbers with yi 􏱻 0 for each i. Then, 􏱚∑ x∑/y 􏱻 (x 􏱕∑x )/(y 􏱕 y ). Similarly, the sum of the squares is not the square of the sum: ∑n ∑ application of familiar elementary algebra also reveals this lack of equality: x1/y1 􏱕 nn (x/y)􏱻􏱵 x􏱷 􏱵 y􏱷. i In other words, the sum of the ratios is not the ratio of the sums. In the n 􏱪 2 case, the ii i i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 221212 n x2 􏱻 􏱵 n x 􏱷2, except in special cases. That these two quantities are not generally i i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i equal is easiest to see when n 􏱪 2: x21 􏱕 x2 􏱻 (x1 􏱕 x2)2 􏱪 x21 􏱕 2x1x2 􏱕 x2. Given n numbers {xi: i 􏱪 1, ..., n}, we compute their average or mean by adding them up and dividing by n: - ∑n x 􏱪 (1/n) xi. [A.5] i􏱪1 When the xi are a sample of data on a particular variable (such as years of education), we often call this the sample average (or sample mean) to emphasize that it is computed from a particular set of data. The sample average is an example of a descriptive statistic; in this case, the statistic describes the central tendency of the set of points xi. There are some basic properties about averages that are important to understand. First, suppose we take each observation on x and subtract off the average: di 􏱲 xi 􏱦 x- (the “d” here stands for deviation from the average). Then, the sum of these deviations is always zero: ∑n n n x 􏱦 x-􏱪 i􏱪1 A simple numerical example shows how this works. Suppose n 􏱪 5 and x1 􏱪 6, x2 􏱪 1, x3 􏱪􏱦2,x4 􏱪0,andx5 􏱪5.Then,x-􏱪2,andthedemeanedsampleis{4,􏱦1,􏱦4,􏱦2,3}. Adding these gives zero, which is just what equation (A.6) says. In our treatment of regression analysis in Chapter 2, we need to know some additional algebraic facts involving deviations from sample averages. An important one is that the sum of squared deviations is the sum of the squared xi minus n times the square of x-: ∑n i􏱪1 (x 􏱦 x-)2 􏱪 i ∑n i􏱪1 x2 􏱦 n(x-)2. [A.7] i (xi 􏱦 x) 􏱪 0. [A.6] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i i APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 705 This can be shown using basic properties of the summation operator: ∑n i􏱪1 ∑n (x􏱦x-)2 􏱪 (x2􏱦2xx-􏱕xˉ2) i ii 􏱪 􏱪 i􏱪1 ∑n i􏱪1 ∑n x 2 􏱦 2 xˉ i ∑n i􏱪1 x 􏱕 n ( x- ) 2 i ∑n i􏱪1 this is a generalization of equation (A.7). (There, yi 􏱪 xi for all i.) The average is the measure of central tendency that we will focus on in most of this text. However, it is sometimes informative to use the median (or sample median) to describe the central value. To obtain the median of the n numbers {x1, ..., xn}, we first order the values of the xi from smallest to largest. Then, if n is odd, the sample median is the middle number of the ordered observations. For example, given the numbers {􏱦4,8,2,0,21,􏱦10,18}, the median value is 2 (because the ordered sequence is {􏱦10,􏱦4,0,2,8,18,21}). If we change the largest number in this list, 21, to twice its value, 42, the median is still 2. By contrast, the sample average would increase from 5 to 8, a sizable change. Generally, the median is less sensitive than the average to changes in the extreme values (large or small) in a list of numbers. This is why “median incomes” or “median housing values” are often reported, rather than averages, when summarizing income or housing values in a city or county. If n is even, there is no unique way to define the median because there are two numbers at the center. Usually, the median is defined to be the average of the two middle values (again, after ordering the numbers from smallest to largest). Using this rule, the median for the set of numbers {4,12,2,6} would be (4 􏱕 6)/2 􏱪 5. A.2 Properties of Linear Functions Linear functions play an important role in econometrics because they are simple to inter- pret and manipulate. If x and y are two variables related by y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x, [A.9] then we say that y is a linear function of x, and 􏱬0 and 􏱬1 are two parameters (numbers) describing this relationship. The intercept is 􏱬0, and the slope is 􏱬1. The defining feature of a linear function is that the change in y is always 􏱬1 times the change in x: 􏰧y 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧x, [A.10] where 􏰧 denotes “change.” In other words, the marginal effect of x on y is constant and equal to 􏱬1. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. x2 􏱦 2n(x-)2 􏱕 n(x-)2 􏱪 i x2 􏱦 n(x-)2. i i􏱪1 Given a data set on two variables, {(xi,yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n}, it can also be shown that ∑n --∑n - (xi 􏱦x)(yi 􏱦y)􏱪 xi(yi 􏱦y) i􏱪1 i􏱪1 ∑n -∑n -.- [A.8] 􏱪 (xi 􏱦x)yi 􏱪 xiyi 􏱦n(xy); i􏱪1 i􏱪1 706 APPENDICES EXAMPLE A.1 LINEAR HOUSING EXPENDITURE FUNCTION Suppose that the relationship between monthly housing expenditure and monthly income is housing 􏱪 164 􏱕 .27 income. [A.11] Then, for each additional dollar of income, 27 cents is spent on housing. If family income increases by $200, then housing expenditure increases by (.27)200 􏱪 $54. This function is graphed in Figure A.1. According to equation (A.11), a family with no income spends $164 on housing, which of course cannot be literally true. For low levels of income, this linear function would not describe the relationship between housing and income very well, which is why we will eventually have to use other types of functions to describe such relationships. In (A.11), the marginal propensity to consume (MPC) housing out of income is .27. This is different from the average propensity to consume (APC), which is housing _______ 􏱪 164/income 􏱕 .27. The APC is not constant, it is always larger than the MPC, and it gets closer to the MPC as income increases. Linear functions are easily defined for more than two variables. Suppose that y is related to two variables, x1 and x2, in the general form y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x1 􏱕 􏱬2x2. [A.12] income FIGURE A.1 Graph of housing 􏱪 164 􏱕 .27 income. housing D housing = .27 1,514 D income 164 5,000 income Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 􏰧y 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧x1 􏱕 􏱬2􏰧x2. If x2 does not change, that is, 􏰧x2 􏱪 0, then we have 􏰧y􏱪􏱬1􏰧x1 if􏰧x2 􏱪0, so that 􏱬1 is the slope of the relationship in the direction of x1: 􏰧y 􏱬1 􏱪____if􏰧x2 􏱪0. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 707 It is rather difficult to envision this function because its graph is three-dimensional. Nevertheless, 􏱬0 is still the intercept (the value of y when x1 􏱪 0 and x2 􏱪 0), and 􏱬1 and 􏱬2 measure particular slopes. From (A.12), the change in y, for given changes in x1 and x2, is [A.13] Because it measures how y changes with x1, holding x2 fixed, 􏱬1 is often called the partial effect of x1 on y. Because the partial effect involves holding other factors fixed, it is closely linked to the notion of ceteris paribus. The parameter 􏱬2 has a similar interpretation: 􏱬2 􏱪 􏰧y/􏰧x2 if 􏰧x1 􏱪 0, so that 􏱬2 is the partial effect of x2 on y. EXAMPLE A.2 DEMAND FOR COMPACT DISCS For college students, suppose that the monthly quantity demanded of compact discs is related to the price of compact discs and monthly discretionary income by quantity 􏱪 120 􏱦 9.8 price 􏱕 .03 income, where price is dollars per disc and income is measured in dollars. The demand curve is the relationship between quantity and price, holding income (and other factors) fixed. This is graphed in two dimensions in Figure A.2 at an income level of $900. The slope of the demand curve, 􏱦9.8, is the partial effect of price on quantity: holding income fixed, if the price of compact discs increases by one dollar, then the quantity demanded falls by 9.8. (We abstract from the fact that CDs can only be purchased in discrete units.) An increase in income simply shifts the demand curve up (changes the intercept), but the slope remains the same. A.3 Proportions and Percentages Proportions and percentages play such an important role in applied economics that it is necessary to become very comfortable in working with them. Many quantities reported in the popular press are in the form of percentages; a few examples are interest rates, un- employment rates, and high school graduation rates. An important skill is being able to convert proportions to percentages and vice versa. A percentage is easily obtained by multiplying a proportion by 100. For example, if the proportion of adults in a county with a high school degree is .82, then we say that 82% (82 percent) of adults have a high school degree. Another way to think of percentages and proportions is that a proportion is the decimal form of a percentage. For example, if Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏰧x1 708 APPENDICES FIGURE A.2 Graph of quantity 􏱪 120 􏱦 9.8 price 􏱕 .03 income, with income fixed at $900. quantity 147 D quantity = –9.8 D price 15 price the marginal tax rate for a family earning $30,000 per year is reported as 28%, then the proportion of the next dollar of income that is paid in income taxes is .28 (or 28¢). When using percentages, we often need to convert them to decimal form. For exam- ple, if a state sales tax is 6% and $200 is spent on a taxable item, then the sales tax paid is 200(.06) 􏱪 $12. If the annual return on a certificate of deposit (CD) is 7.6% and we invest $3,000 in such a CD at the beginning of the year, then our interest income is 3,000(.076) 􏱪 $228. As much as we would like it, the interest income is not obtained by multiplying 3,000 by 7.6. We must be wary of proportions that are sometimes incorrectly reported as percent- ages in the popular media. If we read, “The percentage of high school students who drink alcohol is .57,” we know that this really means 57% (not just over one-half of a percent, as the statement literally implies). College volleyball fans are probably familiar with press clips containing statements such as “Her hitting percentage was .372.” This really means that her hitting percentage was 37.2%. In econometrics, we are often interested in measuring the changes in various quan- tities. Let x denote some variable, such as an individual’s income, the number of crimes committed in a community, or the profits of a firm. Let x0 and x1 denote two values for x: x0 is the initial value, and x1 is the subsequent value. For example, x0 could be the an- nual income of an individual in 1994 and x1 the income of the same individual in 1995. The proportionate change in x in moving from x0 to x1, sometimes called the relative change, is simply (x1 􏱦 x0)/x0 􏱪 􏰧x/x0, [A.14] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 assuming, of course, that x0 􏱻 0. In other words, to get the proportionate change, we sim- ply divide the change in x by its initial value. This is a way of standardizing the change so that it is free of units. For example, if an individual’s income goes from $30,000 per year to $36,000 per year, then the proportionate change is 6,000/30,000 􏱪 .20. It is more common to state changes in terms of percentages. The percentage change in x in going from x0 to x1 is simply 100 times the proportionate change: %􏰧x 􏱪 100(􏰧x/x0); [A.15] the notation “%􏰧x” is read as “the percentage change in x.” For example, when income goes from $30,000 to $33,750, income has increased by 12.5%; to get this, we simply multiply the proportionate change, .125, by 100. Again, we must be on guard for proportionate changes that are reported as percentage changes. In the previous example, for instance, reporting the percentage change in income as .125 is incorrect and could lead to confusion. When we look at changes in things like dollar amounts or population, there is no ambiguity about what is meant by a percentage change. By contrast, interpreting percent- age change calculations can be tricky when the variable of interest is itself a percentage, something that happens often in economics and other social sciences. To illustrate, let x denote the percentage of adults in a particular city having a college education. Suppose the initial value is x0 􏱪 24 (24% have a college education), and the new value is x1 􏱪 30. We can compute two quantities to describe how the percentage of college-educated people has changed. The first is the change in x, 􏰧x. In this case, 􏰧x 􏱪 x1 􏱦 x0 􏱪 6: the percentage of people with a college education has increased by six percentage points. On the other hand, we can compute the percentage change in x using equation (A.15): %􏰧 x 􏱪 100[(30 􏱦 24)/24] 􏱪 25. In this example, the percentage point change and the percentage change are very different. The percentage point change is just the change in the percentages. The percentage change is the change relative to the initial value. Generally, we must pay close attention to which number is being computed. The careful researcher makes this distinc- tion perfectly clear; unfortunately, in the popular press as well as in academic research, the type of reported change is often unclear. EXAMPLE A.3 MICHIGAN SALES TAX INCREASE In March 1994, Michigan voters approved a sales tax increase from 4% to 6%. In politi- cal advertisements, supporters of the measure referred to this as a two percentage point increase, or an increase of two cents on the dollar. Opponents of the tax increase called it a 50% increase in the sales tax rate. Both claims are correct; they are simply different ways of measuring the increase in the sales tax. Naturally, each group reported the measure that made its position most favorable. For a variable such as salary, it makes no sense to talk of a “percentage point change in salary” because salary is not measured as a percentage. We can describe a change in salary either in dollar or percentage terms. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 709 710 APPENDICES A.4 Some Special Functions and Their Properties In Section A.2, we reviewed the basic properties of linear functions. We already indicated one important feature of functions like y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x: a one-unit change in x results in the same change in y, regardless of the initial value of x. As we noted earlier, this is the same as saying the marginal effect of x on y is constant, something that is not realistic for many economic relationships. For example, the important economic notion of diminishing marginal returns is not consistent with a linear relationship. In order to model a variety of economic phenomena, we need to study several nonlin- ear functions. A nonlinear function is characterized by the fact that the change in y for a given change in x depends on the starting value of x. Certain nonlinear functions appear frequently in empirical economics, so it is important to know how to interpret them. A complete understanding of nonlinear functions takes us into the realm of calculus. Here, we simply summarize the most significant aspects of the functions, leaving the details of some derivations for Section A.5. Quadratic Functions One simple way to capture diminishing returns is to add a quadratic term to a linear rela- tionship. Consider the equation y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x 􏱕 􏱬2x2, [A.16] where 􏱬0, 􏱬1, and 􏱬2 are parameters. When 􏱬1 􏱰 0 and 􏱬2 􏱷 0, the relationship between y and x has the parabolic shape given in Figure A.3, where 􏱬0 􏱪 6, 􏱬1 􏱪 8, and 􏱬2 􏱪 􏱦2. When 􏱬1 􏱰 0 and 􏱬2 􏱷 0, it can be shown (using calculus in the next section) that the maximum of the function occurs at the point x* 􏱪 􏱬1/(􏱦2􏱬2). [A.17] Forexample,ify􏱪6􏱕8x􏱦2x2 (so􏱬1 􏱪8and􏱬2 􏱪􏱦2),thenthelargestvalueofy occurs at x* 􏱪 8/4 􏱪 2, and this value is 6 􏱕 8(2) 􏱦 2(2)2 􏱪 14 (see Figure A.3). The fact that equation (A.16) implies a diminishing marginal effect of x on y is easily seen from its graph. Suppose we start at a low value of x and then increase x by some amount, say, c. This has a larger effect on y than if we start at a higher value of x and increase x by the same amount c. In fact, once x 􏱰 x*, an increase in x actually decreases y. The statement that x has a diminishing marginal effect on y is the same as saying that the slope of the function in Figure A.3 decreases as x increases. Although this is clear from looking at the graph, we usually want to quantify how quickly the slope is changing. An application of calculus gives the approximate slope of the quadratic function as 􏰧y slope 􏱪 ___ 􏱴 􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2 x, [A.18] 􏰧x for “small” changes in x. [The right-hand side of equation (A.18) is the derivative of the function in equation (A.16) with respect to x.] Another way to write this is 􏰧y 􏱴 (􏱬1 􏱕 2􏱬2x)􏰧x for “small” 􏰧x. [A.19] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 711 F I G U R E A . 3 Graph of y 􏱪 6 􏱕 8x 􏱦 2x2. y 14 12 10 8 6 4 2 0 01234x x* To see how well this approximation works, consider again the function y 􏱪 6 􏱕 8x 􏱦 2x2. Then, according to equation (A.19), 􏰧y 􏱴 (8 􏱦 4x)􏰧 x. Now, suppose we start at x 􏱪 1 and change x by 􏰧x 􏱪 .1. Using (A.19), 􏰧y 􏱴 (8 􏱦 4)(.1) 􏱪 .4. Of course, we can compute thechangeexactlybyfindingthevaluesofywhenx􏱪1andx􏱪1.1:y0 􏱪6􏱕8(1)􏱦 2(1)2 􏱪 12 and y1 􏱪 6 􏱕 8(1.1) 􏱦 2(1.1)2 􏱪 12.38, so the exact change in y is .38. The approximation is pretty close in this case. Now, suppose we start at x 􏱪 1 but change x by a larger amount: 􏰧x 􏱪 .5. Then, the approximation gives 􏰧y 􏱴 4(.5) 􏱪 2. The exact change is determined by finding the dif- ference in y when x 􏱪 1 and x 􏱪 1.5. The former value of y was 12, and the latter value is 6 􏱕 8(1.5) 􏱦 2(1.5)2 􏱪 13.5, so the actual change is 1.5 (not 2). The approximation is worse in this case because the change in x is larger. For many applications, equation (A.19) can be used to compute the approximate mar- ginal effect of x on y for any initial value of x and small changes. And, we can always compute the exact change if necessary. EXAMPLE A.4 A QUADRATIC WAGE FUNCTION Suppose the relationship between hourly wages and years in the workforce (exper) is given by This function has the same general shape as the one in Figure A.3. Using equation (A.17), wage 􏱪 5.25 􏱕 .48 exper 􏱦 .008 exper2. [A.20] exper has a positive effect on wage up to the turning point, exper* 􏱪 .48/[2(.008)] 􏱪 30. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 712 APPENDICES The first year of experience is worth approximately .48, or 48 cents [see (A.19) with x 􏱪 0, 􏰧 x 􏱪 1]. Each additional year of experience increases wage by less than the previous year— reflecting a diminishing marginal return to experience. At 30 years, an additional year of experience would actually lower the wage. This is not very realistic, but it is one of the con- sequences of using a quadratic function to capture a diminishing marginal effect: at some point, the function must reach a maximum and curve downward. For practical purposes, the point at which this happens is often large enough to be inconsequential, but not always. The graph of the quadratic function in (A.16) has a U-shape if 􏱬1 􏱷 0 and 􏱬2 􏱰 0, in which case there is an increasing marginal return. The minimum of the function is at the point 􏱦􏱬1/(2􏱬2). The Natural Logarithm The nonlinear function that plays the most important role in econometric analysis is the natural logarithm. In this text, we denote the natural logarithm, which we often refer to simply as the log function, as y 􏱪 log(x). [A.21] You might remember learning different symbols for the natural log; ln(x) or loge(x) are the most common. These different notations are useful when logarithms with several dif- ferent bases are being used. For our purposes, only the natural logarithm is important, and so log(x) denotes the natural logarithm throughout this text. This corresponds to the nota- tional usage in many statistical packages, although some use ln(x) [and most calculators use ln(x)]. Economists use both log(x) and ln(x), which is useful to know when you are reading papers in applied economics. The function y 􏱪 log(x) is defined only for x 􏱰 0, and it is plotted in Figure A.4. It is not very important to know how the values of log(x) are obtained. For our purposes, the function can be thought of as a black box: we can plug in any x 􏱰 0 and obtain log(x) from a calculator or a computer. Several things are apparent from Figure A.4. First, when y 􏱪 log(x), the relationship between y and x displays diminishing marginal returns. One important difference between the log and the quadratic function in Figure A.3 is that when y 􏱪 log(x), the effect of x on y never becomes negative: the slope of the function gets closer and closer to zero as x gets large, but the slope never quite reaches zero and certainly never becomes negative. The following are also apparent from Figure A.4: log(x) 􏱷 0 for 0 􏱷 x 􏱷 1 log(1) 􏱪 0 log(x) 􏱰 0 for x 􏱰 1. In particular, log(x) can be positive or negative. Some useful algebraic facts about the log function are log(x1.x2) 􏱪 log(x1) 􏱕 log(x2), x1, x2 􏱰 0 log(x1/x2) 􏱪 log(x1) 􏱦 log(x2), x1, x2 􏱰 0 log(xc) 􏱪 clog(x), x 􏱰 0, c any number. Occasionally, we will need to rely on these properties. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 713 FIGURE A.4 Graph of y 􏱪 log(x). y 0 y = log(x) 1 x The logarithm can be used for various approximations that arise in econometric appli- cations.First,log(1􏱕x)􏱴xforx􏱴0.Youcantrythiswithx􏱪.02,.1,and.5toseehow the quality of the approximation deteriorates as x gets larger. Even more useful is the fact that the difference in logs can be used to approximate proportionate changes. Let x0 and x1 be positive values. Then, it can be shown (using calculus) that log(x1) 􏱦 log(x0) 􏱴 (x1 􏱦 x0)/x0 􏱪 􏰧x/x0 [A.22] for small changes in x. If we multiply equation (A.22) by 100 and write 􏰧log(x) 􏱪 log(x1) 􏱦 log(x0), then 100.􏰧log(x) 􏱴 %􏰧x [A.23] for small changes in x. The meaning of “small” depends on the context, and we will en- counter several examples throughout this text. Why should we approximate the percentage change using (A.23) when the exact per- centage change is so easy to compute? Momentarily, we will see why the approximation in (A.23) is useful in econometrics. First, let us see how good the approximation is in two examples. First, suppose x0 􏱪 40 and x1 􏱪 41. Then, the percentage change in x in moving from x0 to x1 is 2.5%, using 100(x1 􏱦 x0)/x0. Now, log(41) 􏱦 log(40) 􏱪 .0247 to four decimal places, which when multiplied by 100 is very close to 2.5. The approximation works pretty well. Now, consider a much bigger change: x0 􏱪 40 and x1 􏱪 60. The exact percentage change is 50%. However, log(60) 􏱦 log(40) 􏱴 .4055, so the approximation gives 40.55%, which is much farther off. Why is the approximation in (A.23) useful if it is only satisfactory for small changes? To build up to the answer, we first define the elasticity of y with respect to x as Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 714 APPENDICES 􏰧y %􏰧y ___ . _x_ 􏱪 _____ . [A.24] 􏰧x y %􏰧x In other words, the elasticity of y with respect to x is the percentage change in y when x increases by 1%. This notion should be familiar from introductory economics. If y is a linear function of x, y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x, then the elasticity is 􏰧y ___._x_􏱪􏱬._x_ 􏱪􏱬.____x____, [A.25] 􏰧xy 1y 1􏱬0􏱕􏱬1x which clearly depends on the value of x. (This is a generalization of the well-known result from basic demand theory: the elasticity is not constant along a straight-line demand curve.) Elasticities are of critical importance in many areas of applied economics, not just in demand theory. It is convenient in many situations to have constant elasticity models, and the log function allows us to specify such models. If we use the approximation in (A.23) for both x and y, then the elasticity is approximately equal to 􏰧log(y)/􏰧log(x). Thus, a constant elasticity model is approximated by the equation log(y) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(x), and 􏱬1 is the elasticity of y with respect to x (assuming that x, y 􏱰 0). EXAMPLE A.5 CONSTANT ELASTICITY DEMAND FUNCTION If q is quantity demanded and p is price and these variables are related by [A.26] log(q) 􏱪 4.7 􏱦 1.25 log(p), then the price elasticity of demand is 􏱦1.25. Roughly, a 1% increase in price leads to a 1.25% fall in the quantity demanded. For our purposes, the fact that 􏱬1 in (A.26) is only close to the elasticity is not important. In fact, when the elasticity is defined using calculus—as in Section A.5—the definition is exact. For the purposes of econometric analysis, (A.26) defines a constant elasticity model. Such models play a large role in empirical economics. Other possibilities for using the log function often arise in empirical work. Suppose that y 􏱰 0 and log(y) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x. [A.27] Then, 􏰧log(y) 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧x, so 100.􏰧log(y) 􏱪 (100.􏱬1)􏰧x. It follows that, when y and x are related by equation (A.27), %􏰧y 􏱴 (100.􏱬1)􏰧x. [A.28] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 715 EXAMPLE A.6 LOGARITHMIC WAGE EQUATION Suppose that hourly wage and years of education are related by log(wage) 􏱪 2.78 􏱕 .094 educ. Then, using equation (A.28), %􏰧wage 􏱴 100(.094) 􏰧educ 􏱪 9.4 􏰧educ. It follows that one more year of education increases hourly wage by about 9.4%. Generally, the quantity %􏰧y/􏰧x is called the semi-elasticity of y with respect to x. The semi-elasticity is the percentage change in y when x increases by one unit. What we have just shown is that, in model (A.27), the semi-elasticity is constant and equal to 100.􏱬1. In Example A.6, we can conveniently summarize the relationship between wages and education by saying that one more year of education—starting from any amount of education—increases the wage by about 9.4%. This is why such models play an important role in economics. Another relationship of some interest in applied economics is y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(x), [A.29] where x 􏱰 0. How can we interpret this equation? If we take the change in y, we get 􏰧y 􏱪 􏱬1􏰧log(x), which can be rewritten as 􏰧y 􏱪 (􏱬1/100)[100.􏰧log(x)]. Thus, using the approximation in (A.23), we have 􏰧y 􏱴 (􏱬1/100)(%􏰧x). In other words, 􏱬1/100 is the unit change in y when x increases by 1%. EXAMPLE A.7 LABOR SUPPLY FUNCTION Assume that the labor supply of a worker can be described by [A.30] hours 􏱪 33 􏱕 45.1 log(wage), where wage is hourly wage and hours is hours worked per week. Then, from (A.30), 􏰧hours 􏱴 (45.1/100)(%􏰧wage) 􏱪 .451 %􏰧wage. In other words, a 1% increase in wage increases the weekly hours worked by about .45, or slightly less than one-half hour. If the wage increases by 10%, then 􏰧hours 􏱪 .451(10) 􏱪 4.51, or about four and one-half hours. We would not want to use this approximation for much larger percentage changes in wages. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 716 APPENDICES The Exponential Function Before leaving this section, we need to discuss a special function that is related to the log. As motivation, consider equation (A.27). There, log(y) is a linear function of x. But how do we find y itself as a function of x? The answer is given by the exponential function. We will write the exponential function as y 􏱪 exp(x), which is graphed in Figure A.5. From Figure A.5, we see that exp(x) is defined for any value of x and is always greater than zero. Sometimes, the exponential function is written as y 􏱪 ex, but we will not use this notation. Two important values of the exponential function are exp(0) 􏱪 1 and exp(1) 􏱪 2.7183 (to four decimal places). The exponential function is the inverse of the log function in the following sense: log[exp(x)] 􏱪 x for all x, and exp[log(x)] 􏱪 x for x 􏱰 0. In other words, the log “undoes” the exponential, and vice versa. (This is why the exponential function is sometimes called the anti-log function.) In particular, note that log(y) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x is equivalent to y 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x). If 􏱬1 􏱰 0, the relationship between x and y has the same shape as in Figure A.5. Thus, if log(y) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x with 􏱬1 􏱰 0, then x has an increasing marginal effect on y. In Example A.6, this means that another year of education leads to a larger change in wage than the previous year of education. Two useful facts about the exponential function are exp(x1 􏱕 x2) 􏱪 exp(x1)exp(x2) and exp[c.log(x)] 􏱪 xc. FIGURE A.5 Graph of y 􏱪 exp(x). y y = exp(x) 0 x Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 717 A.5 Differential Calculus In the previous section, we asserted several approximations that have foundations in cal- culus. Let y 􏱪 f (x) for some function f. Then, for small changes in x, df . 􏰧y􏱴___ 􏰧x, [A.31] where df/dx is the derivative of the function f, evaluated at the initial point x0. We also write the derivative as dy/dx. For example, if y 􏱪 log(x), then dy/dx 􏱪 1/x. Using (A.31), with dy/dx evaluated at x0, we have 􏰧y 􏱴 (1/x0)􏰧x, or 􏰧log(x) 􏱴 􏰧x/x0, which is the approximation given in (A.22). In applying econometrics, it helps to recall the derivatives of a handful of functions because we use the derivative to define the slope of a function at a given point. We can then use (A.31) to find the approximate change in y for small changes in x. In the linear case, the derivative is simply the slope of the line, as we would hope: if y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x, then dy/dx 􏱪 􏱬1. If y 􏱪 xc, then dy/dx 􏱪 cxc􏱦1. The derivative of a sum of two functions is the sum of the derivatives: d[ f(x) 􏱕 g(x)]/dx 􏱪 df(x)/dx 􏱕 dg(x)/dx. The derivative of a constant times any function is that same constant times the derivative of the function: d[cf(x)]/dx 􏱪 c[df(x)/dx]. These simple rules allow us to find derivatives of more complicated functions. Other rules, such as the product, quotient, and chain rules, will be familiar to those who have taken calculus, but we will not review those here. Some functions that are often used in economics, along with their derivatives, are y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x􏱕􏱬2x2;dy/dx􏱪􏱬1 􏱕2􏱬2x y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1/x; dy/dx 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1/(x2) __ 􏱦1/2 dx y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1􏱯x; dy/dx 􏱪 (􏱬1/2)x y 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(x); dy/dx 􏱪 􏱬1/x y 􏱪 exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x); dy/dx 􏱪 􏱬1exp(􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1x). If 􏱬0 􏱪 0 and 􏱬1 􏱪 1 in this last expression, we get dy/dx 􏱪 exp(x), when y 􏱪 exp(x). In Section A.4, we noted that equation (A.26) defines a constant elasticity model when calculus is used. The calculus definition of elasticity is (dy/dx) . (x/y). It can be shown using properties of logs and exponentials that, when (A.26) holds, (dy/dx) . (x/y) 􏱪 􏱬1. When y is a function of multiple variables, the notion of a partial derivative becomes important. Suppose that y 􏱪 f (x1, x2). [A.32] Then, there are two partial derivatives, one with respect to x1 and one with respect to x2. The partial derivative of y with respect to x1, denoted here by 􏲉y/􏲉x1, is just the usual derivative of (A.32) with respect to x1, where x2 is treated as a constant. Similarly, 􏲉y/􏲉x2 is just the derivative of (A.32) with respect to x2, holding x1 fixed. Partial derivatives are useful for much the same reason as ordinary derivatives. We can approximate the change in y as 􏲉y 􏰧y 􏱴 ___ .􏰧x1, holding x2 fixed. [A.33] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏲉x1 718 APPENDICES Thus, calculus allows us to define partial effects in nonlinear models just as we could in linear models. In fact, if then y􏱪􏱬0 􏱕􏱬1x1 􏱕􏱬2x2, 􏲉y 􏲉y ___ 􏱪 􏱬1, ____ 􏱪 􏱬2. 􏲉x1 􏲉x2 These can be recognized as the partial effects defined in Section A.2. A more complicated example is y􏱪5􏱕4x1 􏱕x12 􏱦3x2 􏱕7x1.x2. Now, the derivative of (A.34), with respect to x1 (treating x2 as a constant), is simply 􏲉y ___􏱪4􏱕2x1 􏱕7x2; 􏲉x1 note how this depends on x1 and x2. The derivative of (A.34), with respect to x2, is 􏲉y/􏲉x2 􏱪 􏱦3 􏱕 7x1, so this depends only on x1. EXAMPLE A.8 WAGE FUNCTION WITH INTERACTION A function relating wages to years of education and experience is wage 􏱪 3.10 􏱕 .41 educ 􏱕 .19 exper 􏱦 .004 exper2 􏱕 .007 educ.exper. The partial effect of exper on wage is the partial derivative of (A.35): 􏲉wage ______ 􏱪 .19 􏱦 .008 exper 􏱕 .007 educ. 􏲉exper [A.35] [A.34] This is the approximate change in wage due to increasing experience by one year. Notice that this partial effect depends on the initial level of exper and educ. For example, for a worker who is starting with educ 􏱪 12 and exper 􏱪 5, the next year of experience in- creases wage by about .19 􏱦 .008(5) 􏱕 .007(12) 􏱪 .234, or 23.4 cents per hour. The exact change can be calculated by computing (A.35) at exper 􏱪 5, educ 􏱪 12 and at exper 􏱪 6, educ 􏱪 12, and then taking the difference. This turns out to be .23, which is very close to the approximation. Differential calculus plays an important role in minimizing and maximizing functions of one or more variables. If f(x1, x2, ..., xk) is a differentiable function of k variables, then a necessary condition for x*1 , x*2 , ..., xk* to either minimize or maximize f over all possible values of xj is 􏲉f ___ (x*1, x*2 , ..., xk*) 􏱪 0, j 􏱪 1, 2,...,k. [A.36] 􏲉xj Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 719 In other words, all of the partial derivatives of f must be zero when they are evaluated at the xh*. These are called the first order conditions for minimizing or maximizing a func- tion. Practically, we hope to solve equation (A.36) for the xh*. Then, we can use other criteria to determine whether we have minimized or maximized the function. We will not need those here. [See Sydsaeter and Hammond (1995) for a discussion of multivariable calculus and its use in optimizing functions.] Summary The math tools reviewed here are crucial for understanding regression analysis and the probability and statistics that are covered in Appendices B and C. The material on nonlin- ear functions—especially quadratic, logarithmic, and exponential functions—is critical for understanding modern applied economic research. The level of comprehension required of these functions does not include a deep knowledge of calculus, although calculus is needed for certain derivations. Key Terms Average Ceteris Paribus Constant Elasticity Model Derivative Descriptive Statistic Diminishing Marginal Effect Elasticity Exponential Function Intercept Linear Function Log Function Marginal Effect Median Natural Logarithm Nonlinear Function Partial Derivative Partial Effect Percentage Change Percentage Point Change Proportionate Change Relative Change Semi-Elasticity Slope Summation Operator Problems 1 The following table contains monthly housing expenditures for 10 families. Monthly Housing Family Expenditures (Dollars) 1 300 2 440 3 350 4 1,100 5 640 6 480 7 450 8 700 9 670 10 530 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 720 APPENDICES (i) Find the average monthly housing expenditure. (ii) Find the median monthly housing expenditure. (iii) If monthly housing expenditures were measured in hundreds of dollars, rather than in dollars, what would be the average and median expenditures? (iv) Suppose that family number 8 increases its monthly housing expenditure to $900, but the expenditures of all other families remain the same. Compute the average and median housing expenditures. 2 Suppose the following equation describes the relationship between the average number of classes missed during a semester (missed) and the distance from school (distance, measured in miles): missed 􏱪 3 􏱕 0.2 distance. (i) Sketch this line, being sure to label the axes. How do you interpret the intercept in this equation? (ii) What is the average number of classes missed for someone who lives five miles away? (iii) What is the difference in the average number of classes missed for someone who lives 10 miles away and someone who lives 20 miles away? 3 In Example A.2, quantity of compact discs was related to price and income by quantity 􏱪 120 􏱦 9.8 price 􏱕 .03 income. What is the demand for CDs if price 􏱪 15 and in- come 􏱪 200? What does this suggest about using linear functions to describe demand curves? 4 Suppose the unemployment rate in the United States goes from 6.4% in one year to 5.6% in the next. (i) What is the percentage point decrease in the unemployment rate? (ii) By what percentage has the unemployment rate fallen? 5 Suppose that the return from holding a particular firm’s stock goes from 15% in one year to 18% in the following year. The majority shareholder claims that “the stock re- turn only increased by 3%,” while the chief executive officer claims that “the return on the firm’s stock increased by 20%.” Reconcile their disagreement. 6 Suppose that Person A earns $35,000 per year and Person B earns $42,000. (i) Find the exact percentage by which Person B’s salary exceeds Person A’s. (ii) Now, use the difference in natural logs to find the approximate percentage difference. 7 Suppose the following model describes the relationship between annual salary (salary) and the number of previous years of labor market experience (exper): log(salary) 􏱪 10.6 􏱕 .027 exper. (i) What is salary when exper 􏱪 0? When exper 􏱪 5? (Hint: You will need to exponentiate.) (ii) Use equation (A.28) to approximate the percentage increase in salary when exper increases by five years. (iii) Use the results of part (i) to compute the exact percentage difference in salary when exper 􏱪 5 and exper 􏱪 0. Comment on how this compares with the approximation in part (ii). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX A Basic Mathematical Tools 721 8 Let grthemp denote the proportionate growth in employment, at the county level, from 1990 to 1995, and let salestax denote the county sales tax rate, stated as a proportion. Interpret the intercept and slope in the equation grthemp 􏱪 .043 􏱦 .78 salestax. 9 Suppose the yield of a certain crop (in bushels per acre) is related to fertilizer amount (in pounds per acre) as ________ yield 􏱪 120 􏱕 .19 􏱯 fertilizer. (i) Graph this relationship by plugging in several values for fertilizer. (ii) Describe how the shape of this relationship compares with a linear relationship between yield and fertilizer. 10 Suppose that in a particular state a standardized test is given to all graduating se- niors. Let score denote a student’s score on the test. Someone discovers that perfor- mance on the test is related to the size of the student’s graduating high school class. The relationship is quadratic: score 􏱪 45.6 􏱕 .082 class 􏱦 .000147 class2, where class is the number of students in the graduating class. (i) How do you literally interpret the value 45.6 in the equation? By itself, is it of much interest? Explain. (ii) From the equation, what is the optimal size of the graduating class (the size that maximizes the test score)? (Round your answer to the nearest integer.) What is the highest achievable test score? (iii) Sketch a graph that illustrates your solution in part (ii). (iv) Does it seem likely that score and class would have a deterministic relationship? That is, is it realistic to think that once you know the size of a student’s graduating class you know, with certainty, his or her test score? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability This appendix covers key concepts from basic probability. Appendices B and C are primarily for review; they are not intended to replace a course in probability and statistics. However, all of the probability and statistics concepts that we use in the text are covered in these appendices. Probability is of interest in its own right for students in business, economics, and other social sciences. For example, consider the problem of an airline trying to decide how many reservations to accept for a flight that has 100 available seats. If fewer than 100 people want reservations, then these should all be accepted. But what if more than 100 people request reservations? A safe solution is to accept at most 100 reservations. However, because some people book reservations and then do not show up for the flight, there is some chance that the plane will not be full even if 100 reservations are booked. This results in lost revenue to the airline. A different strategy is to book more than 100 res- ervations and to hope that some people do not show up, so the final number of passengers is as close to 100 as possible. This policy runs the risk of the airline having to compensate people who are necessarily bumped from an overbooked flight. A natural question in this context is: Can we decide on the optimal (or best) number of reservations the airline should make? This is a nontrivial problem. Nevertheless, given certain information (on airline costs and how frequently people show up for reservations), we can use basic probability to arrive at a solution. B.1 Random Variables and Their Probability Distributions Suppose that we flip a coin 10 times and count the number of times the coin turns up heads. This is an example of an experiment. Generally, an experiment is any procedure that can, at least in theory, be infinitely repeated and has a well-defined set of outcomes. We could, in principle, carry out the coin-flipping procedure again and again. Before we flip the coin, we know that the number of heads appearing is an integer from 0 to 10, so the outcomes of the experiment are well defined. 722 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. A random variable is one that takes on numerical values and has an outcome that is determined by an experiment. In the coin-flipping example, the number of heads appearing in 10 flips of a coin is an example of a random variable. Before we flip the coin 10 times, we do not know how many times the coin will come up heads. Once we flip the coin 10 times and count the number of heads, we obtain the outcome of the random variable for this particular trial of the experiment. Another trial can produce a different outcome. In the airline reservation example mentioned earlier, the number of people showing up for their flight is a random variable: before any particular flight, we do not know how many people will show up. To analyze data collected in business and the social sciences, it is important to have a basic understanding of random variables and their properties. Following the usual conven- tions in probability and statistics throughout Appendices B and C, we denote random vari- ables by uppercase letters, usually W, X, Y, and Z; particular outcomes of random variables are denoted by the corresponding lowercase letters, w, x, y, and z. For example, in the coin-flipping experiment, let X denote the number of heads appearing in 10 flips of a coin. Then, X is not associated with any particular value, but we know X will take on a value in the set {0, 1, 2, ..., 10}. A particular outcome is, say, x 􏱪 6. We indicate large collections of random variables by using subscripts. For example, if we record last year’s income of 20 randomly chosen households in the United States, we might denote these random variables by X1, X2, ..., X20; the particular outcomes would be denoted x1, x2, ..., x20. As stated in the definition, random variables are always defined to take on numerical values, even when they describe qualitative events. For example, consider tossing a single coin, where the two outcomes are heads and tails. We can define a random variable as follows: X 􏱪 1 if the coin turns up heads, and X 􏱪 0 if the coin turns up tails. A random variable that can only take on the values zero and one is called a Bernoulli (or binary) random variable. In basic probability, it is traditional to call the event X 􏱪 1 a “success” and the event X 􏱪 0 a “failure.” For a particular application, the success- failure nomenclature might not correspond to our notion of a success or failure, but it is a useful terminology that we will adopt. Discrete Random Variables A discrete random variable is one that takes on only a finite or countably infinite number of values. The notion of “countably infinite” means that even though an infinite number of values can be taken on by a random variable, those values can be put in a one-to-one correspondence with the positive integers. Because the distinction between “countably infinite” and “uncountably infinite” is somewhat subtle, we will concentrate on discrete random variables that take on only a finite number of values. Larsen and Marx (1986, Chapter 3) provide a detailed treatment. A Bernoulli random variable is the simplest example of a discrete random variable. The only thing we need to completely describe the behavior of a Bernoulli random vari- able is the probability that it takes on the value one. In the coin-flipping example, if the coin is “fair,” then P(X 􏱪 1) 􏱪 1/2 (read as “the probability that X equals one is one- half”). Because probabilities must sum to one, P(X 􏱪 0) 􏱪 1/2, also. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 723 724 APPENDICES Social scientists are interested in more than flipping coins, so we must allow for more general situations. Again, consider the example where the airline must decide how many people to book for a flight with 100 available seats. This problem can be analyzed in the context of several Bernoulli random variables as follows: for a randomly selected customer, define a Bernoulli random variable as X 􏱪 1 if the person shows up for the reservation, and X 􏱪 0 if not. There is no reason to think that the probability of any particular customer showing up is 1/2; in principle, the probability can be any number between zero and one. Call this number 􏰩, so that P(X 􏱪 1) 􏱪 􏰩 [B.1] P(X 􏱪 0) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏰩. [B.2] For example, if 􏰩 􏱪 .75, then there is a 75% chance that a customer shows up after making a reservation and a 25% chance that the customer does not show up. Intuitively, the value of 􏰩 is crucial in determining the airline’s strategy for booking reservations. Methods for estimating 􏰩, given historical data on airline reservations, are a subject of mathematical statistics, something we turn to in Appendix C. More generally, any discrete random variable is completely described by listing its possible values and the associated probability that it takes on each value. If X takes on the k possible values {x1, ..., xk}, then the probabilities p1, p2, ..., pk are defined by pj 􏱪 P(X 􏱪 xj), j 􏱪 1, 2, ..., k, [B.3] where each pj is between 0 and 1 and p1 􏱕p2 􏱕...􏱕pk 􏱪1. [B.4] Equation (B.3) is read as: “The probability that X takes on the value xj is equal to pj.” Equations (B.1) and (B.2) show that the probabilities of success and failure for a Bernoulli random variable are determined entirely by the value of 􏰩. Because Bernoulli random variables are so prevalent, we have a special notation for them: X ~ Bernoulli(􏰩) is read as “X has a Bernoulli distribution with probability of success equal to 􏰩.” The probability density function (pdf) of X summarizes the information concerning the possible outcomes of X and the corresponding probabilities: f(xj) 􏱪 pj, j 􏱪 1, 2, ..., k, [B.5] with f(x) 􏱪 0 for any x not equal to xj for some j. In other words, for any real number x, f (x) is the probability that the random variable X takes on the particular value x. When dealing with more than one random variable, it is sometimes useful to subscript the pdf in question: fX is the pdf of X, fY is the pdf of Y, and so on. Given the pdf of any discrete random variable, it is simple to compute the probability of any event involving that random variable. For example, suppose that X is the number of free throws made by a basketball player out of two attempts, so that X can take on the three values {0,1,2}. Assume that the pdf of X is given by f(0) 􏱪 .20, f(1) 􏱪 .44, and f(2) 􏱪 .36. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 725 FIGURE B.1 The pdf of the number of free throws made out of two attempts. f (x) .44 .36 .20 012x The three probabilities sum to one, as they must. Using this pdf, we can calculate the probability that the player makes at least one free throw: P(X 􏱸 1) 􏱪 P(X 􏱪 1) 􏱕 P(X 􏱪 2) 􏱪 .44 􏱕 .36 􏱪 .80. The pdf of X is shown in Figure B.1. Continuous Random Variables A variable X is a continuous random variable if it takes on any real value with zero probability. This definition is somewhat counterintuitive because in any application we eventually observe some outcome for a random variable. The idea is that a continuous random variable X can take on so many possible values that we cannot count them or match them up with the positive integers, so logical consistency dictates that X can take on each value with probability zero. While measurements are always discrete in prac- tice, random variables that take on numerous values are best treated as continuous. For example, the most refined measure of the price of a good is in terms of cents. We can imagine listing all possible values of price in order (even though the list may continue in- definitely), which technically makes price a discrete random variable. However, there are so many possible values of price that using the mechanics of discrete random variables is not feasible. We can define a probability density function for continuous random variables, and, as with discrete random variables, the pdf provides information on the likely outcomes of the random variable. However, because it makes no sense to discuss the probability that a continuous random variable takes on a particular value, we use the pdf of a continuous random variable only to compute events involving a range of values. For example, if a and b are constants where a 􏱷 b, the probability that X lies between the numbers a and b, P(a 􏰯 X 􏰯 b), is the area under the pdf between points a and b, as shown in Figure B.2. If you are familiar with calculus, you recognize this as the integral of the function f between the points a and b. The entire area under the pdf must always equal one. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 726 APPENDICES FIGURE B.2 The probability that X lies between the points a and b. f(x) abx When computing probabilities for continuous random variables, it is easiest to work with the cumulative distribution function (cdf ). If X is any random variable, then its cdf is defined for any real number x by F(x) 􏱲 P(X 􏰯 x). [B.6] For discrete random variables, (B.6) is obtained by summing the pdf over all values xj such that xj 􏰯 x. For a continuous random variable, F(x) is the area under the pdf, f, to the left of the point x. Because F(x) is simply a probability, it is always between 0 and 1. Fur- ther, if x1 􏱷 x2, then P(X 􏰯 x1) 􏰯 P(X 􏰯 x2), that is, F(x1) 􏰯 F(x2). This means that a cdf is an increasing (or at least a nondecreasing) function of x. Two important properties of cdfs that are useful for computing probabilities are the following: For any number c, P(X 􏱰 c) 􏱪 1 􏱦 F(c). [B.7] For any numbers a 􏱷 b, P(a 􏱷 X 􏰯 b) 􏱪 F(b) 􏱦 F(a). [B.8] In our study of econometrics, we will use cdfs to compute probabilities only for continu- ous random variables, in which case it does not matter whether inequalities in probability statements are strict or not. That is, for a continuous random variable X, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 and APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability P(X 􏱸 c) 􏱪 P(X 􏱰 c), P(a 􏱷 X 􏱷 b) 􏱪 P(a 􏰯 X 􏰯 b) 􏱪 P(a 􏰯 X 􏱷 b) 􏱪 P(a 􏱷 X 􏰯 b). 727 [B.9] [B.10] Combined with (B.7) and (B.8), equations (B.9) and (B.10) greatly expand the probability calculations that can be done using continuous cdfs. Cumulative distribution functions have been tabulated for all of the important con- tinuous distributions in probability and statistics. The most well known of these is the normal distribution, which we cover along with some related distributions in Section B.5. B.2 Joint Distributions, Conditional Distributions, and Independence In economics, we are usually interested in the occurrence of events involving more than one random variable. For example, in the airline reservation example referred to earlier, the airline might be interested in the probability that a person who makes a reservation shows up and is a business traveler; this is an example of a joint probability. Or, the airline might be interested in the following conditional probability: conditional on the person being a business traveler, what is the probability of his or her showing up? In the next two subsections, we formalize the notions of joint and conditional distributions and the impor- tant notion of independence of random variables. Joint Distributions and Independence Let X and Y be discrete random variables. Then, (X,Y) have a joint distribution, which is fully described by the joint probability density function of (X,Y): fX,Y(x,y) 􏱪 P(X 􏱪 x,Y 􏱪 y), [B.11] where the right-hand side is the probability that X 􏱪 x and Y 􏱪 y. When X and Y are con- tinuous, a joint pdf can also be defined, but we will not cover such details because joint pdfs for continuous random variables are not used explicitly in this text. In one case, it is easy to obtain the joint pdf if we are given the pdfs of X and Y. In particular, random variables X and Y are said to be independent if, and only if, fX,Y(x,y) 􏱪 fX(x)fY(y) [B.12] forallxandy,wherefX isthepdfofXandfY isthepdfofY.Inthecontextofmorethan one random variable, the pdfs fX and fY are often called marginal probability density func- tions to distinguish them from the joint pdf fX,Y. This definition of independence is valid for discrete and continuous random variables. To understand the meaning of (B.12), it is easiest to deal with the discrete case. If X and Y are discrete, then (B.12) is the same as P(X 􏱪 x,Y 􏱪 y) 􏱪 P(X 􏱪 x)P(Y 􏱪 y); [B.13] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 728 APPENDICES in other words, the probability that X 􏱪 x and Y 􏱪 y is the product of the two probabilities P(X 􏱪 x) and P(Y 􏱪 y). One implication of (B.13) is that joint probabilities are fairly easy to compute, since they only require knowledge of P(X 􏱪 x) and P(Y 􏱪 y). If random variables are not independent, then they are said to be dependent. EXAMPLE B.1 FREE THROW SHOOTING Consider a basketball player shooting two free throws. Let X be the Bernoulli random variable equal to one if she or he makes the first free throw, and zero otherwise. Let Y be a Bernoulli random variable equal to one if he or she makes the second free throw. Suppose that she or he is an 80% free throw shooter, so that P(X 􏱪 1) 􏱪 P(Y 􏱪 1) 􏱪 .8. What is the probability of the player making both free throws? If X and Y are independent, we can easily answer this question: P(X 􏱪 1,Y 􏱪 1) 􏱪 P(X 􏱪 1)P(Y 􏱪 1) 􏱪 (.8)(.8) 􏱪 .64. Thus, there is a 64% chance of making both free throws. If the chance of making the second free throw depends on whether the first was made—that is, X and Y are not independent—then this simple calculation is not valid. Independence of random variables is a very important concept. In the next subsec- tion, we will show that if X and Y are independent, then knowing the outcome of X does not change the probabilities of the possible outcomes of Y, and vice versa. One useful fact about independence is that if X and Y are independent and we define new random vari- ables g(X) and h(Y) for any functions g and h, then these new random variables are also independent. There is no need to stop at two random variables. If X1, X2, ..., Xn are discrete random variables, then their joint pdf is f(x1, x2, ..., xn) 􏱪 P(X1 􏱪 x1, X2 􏱪 x2, ..., Xn 􏱪 xn). The random variables X1, X2, ..., Xn are independent random variables if, and only if, their joint pdf is the product of the individual pdfs for any (x1, x2, ..., xn). This definition of independence also holds for continuous random variables. The notion of independence plays an important role in obtaining some of the classic distributions in probability and statistics. Earlier, we defined a Bernoulli random variable as a zero-one random variable indicating whether or not some event occurs. Often, we are interested in the number of successes in a sequence of independent Bernoulli trials. A standard example of independent Bernoulli trials is flipping a coin again and again. Because the outcome on any particular flip has nothing to do with the outcomes on other flips, independence is an appropriate assumption. Independence is often a reasonable approximation in more complicated situations. In the airline reservation example, suppose that the airline accepts n reservations for a partic- ular flight. For each i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, let Yi denote the Bernoulli random variable indicating whether customer i shows up: Yi 􏱪 1 if customer i appears, and Yi 􏱪 0 otherwise. Letting 􏰩 again denote the probability of success (using reservation), each Yi has a Bernoulli(􏰩) distribution. As an approximation, we might assume that the Yi are independent of one another, although this is not exactly true in reality: some people travel in groups, which means that whether or not a person shows up is not truly independent of whether all others show up. Modeling this kind of dependence is complex, however, so we might be willing to use independence as an approximation. The variable of primary interest is the total number of customers showing up out of the n reservations; call this variable X. Since each Yi is unity when a person shows up, we Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 729 can write X 􏱪 Y1 􏱕 Y2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 Yn. Now, assuming that each Yi has probability of success 􏰩 and that the Yi are independent, X can be shown to have a binomial distribution. That is, the probability density function of X is f(x) 􏱪 􏱵nx􏱷􏰩x(1 􏱦 􏰩)n􏱦x, x 􏱪 0, 1, 2, ..., n, [B.14] where 􏱵 nx 􏱷 􏱪 ____n_!____ , and for any integer n, n! (read “n factorial”) is defined as n! 􏱪 x!(n 􏱦 x)! n.(n 􏱦 1) . (n 􏱦 2) ...1. By convention, 0! 􏱪 1. When a random variable X has the pdf given in (B.14), we write X ~ Binomial(n,􏰩). Equation (B.14) can be used to compute P(X 􏱪 x) for any value of x from 0 to n. If the flight has 100 available seats, the airline is interested in P(X 􏱰 100). Suppose, initially, that n 􏱪 120, so that the airline accepts 120 reservations, and the probability that each person shows up is 􏰩 􏱪 .85. Then, P(X 􏱰 100) 􏱪 P(X 􏱪 101) 􏱕 P(X 􏱪 102) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 P(X 􏱪 120), and each of the probabilities in the sum can be found from equation (B.14) with n 􏱪 120, 􏰩 􏱪 .85, and the appropriate value of x (101 to 120). This is a difficult hand calculation, but many statistical packages have commands for computing this kind of probability. In this case, the probability that more than 100 people will show up is about .659, which is probably more risk of overbooking than the airline wants to tolerate. If, instead, the number of reservations is 110, the probability of more than 100 passengers showing up is only about .024. Conditional Distributions In econometrics, we are usually interested in how one random variable, call it Y, is related to one or more other variables. For now, suppose that there is only one variable whose effects we are interested in, call it X. The most we can know about how X affects Y is con- tained in the conditional distribution of Y given X. This information is summarized by the conditional probability density function, defined by fY|X(y|x) 􏱪 fX,Y(x,y)/fX(x) [B.15] for all values of x such that fX (x) 􏱰 0. The interpretation of (B.15) is most easily seen when X and Y are discrete. Then, fY|X(y|x) 􏱪 P(Y 􏱪 y|X 􏱪 x), [B.16] where the right-hand side is read as “the probability that Y 􏱪 y given that X 􏱪 x.” When Y is continuous, fY|X(y|x) is not interpretable directly as a probability, for the reasons discussed earlier, but conditional probabilities are found by computing areas under the conditional pdf. An important feature of conditional distributions is that, if X and Y are indepen- dent random variables, knowledge of the value taken on by X tells us nothing about the probability that Y takes on various values (and vice versa). That is, fY|X(y|x) 􏱪 fY(y), and fX |Y (x|y) 􏱪 fX (x). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 730 APPENDICES EXAMPLE B.2 FREE THROW SHOOTING Consider again the basketball-shooting example, where two free throws are to be attempted. Assume that the conditional density is fY|X(1|1) 􏱪 .85, fY|X(0|1) 􏱪 .15 fY|X(1|0) 􏱪 .70, fY|X(0|0) 􏱪 .30. This means that the probability of the player making the second free throw depends on whether the first free throw was made: if the first free throw is made, the chance of making the second is .85; if the first free throw is missed, the chance of making the second is .70. This implies that X and Y are not independent; they are dependent. We can still compute P( X 􏱪 1,Y 􏱪 1) provided we know P( X 􏱪 1). Assume that the probability of making the first free throw is .8, that is, P(X 􏱪 1) 􏱪 .8. Then, from (B.15), we have P(X 􏱪 1,Y 􏱪 1) 􏱪 P(Y 􏱪 1|X 􏱪 1).P(X 􏱪 1) 􏱪 (.85)(.8) 􏱪 .68. B.3 Features of Probability Distributions For many purposes, we will be interested in only a few aspects of the distributions of random variables. The features of interest can be put into three categories: measures of central tendency, measures of variability or spread, and measures of association between two random variables. We cover the last of these in Section B.4. A Measure of Central Tendency: The Expected Value The expected value is one of the most important probabilistic concepts that we will encounter in our study of econometrics. If X is a random variable, the expected value (or expectation) of X, denoted E(X) and sometimes 􏱙X or simply 􏱙, is a weighted average of all possible values of X. The weights are determined by the probability density function. Sometimes, the expected value is called the population mean, especially when we want to emphasize that X represents some variable in a population. The precise definition of expected value is simplest in the case that X is a discrete random variable taking on a finite number of values, say, {x1, ..., xk}. Let f(x) denote the probability density function of X. The expected value of X is the weighted average ∑k E(X) 􏱪 x1f(x1) 􏱕 x2 f(x2) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 xk f(xk) 􏱲 x f(x). [B.17] This is easily computed given the values of the pdf at each possible outcome of X. EXAMPLE B.3 COMPUTING AN EXPECTED VALUE Suppose that X takes on the values 􏱦1, 0, and 2 with probabilities 1/8, 1/2, and 3/8, respectively. Then, E(X) 􏱪 (􏱦1).(1/8) 􏱕 0.(1/2) 􏱕 2.(3/8) 􏱪 5/8. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. jj j􏱪1 ∑k E[g(X)]􏱪 􏱦􏱵 EXAMPLE B.4 EXPECTED VALUE OF X 2 For the random variable in Example B.3, let g(X) 􏱪 X2. Then, E(X2) 􏱪 (􏱶1)2(1/8) 􏱕 (0)2(1/2) 􏱕 (2)2(3/8) 􏱪 13/8. [B.19] [B.20] or, for a continuous random variable, E[g(X)] 􏱪 ∫ g(x)f (x)dx. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 731 This example illustrates something curious about expected values: the expected value of X can be a number that is not even a possible outcome of X. We know that X takes on the values 􏱦1, 0, or 2, yet its expected value is 5/8. This makes the expected value deficient for summarizing the central tendency of certain discrete random variables, but calcula- tions such as those just mentioned can be useful, as we will see later. If X is a continuous random variable, then E(X) is defined as an integral: 􏱵 E(X) 􏱪 ∫ xf(x)dx, [B.18] 􏱦􏱵 which we assume is well defined. This can still be interpreted as a weighted average. For the most common continuous distributions, E(X) is a number that is a possible outcome of X. In this text, we will not need to compute expected values using integration, although we will draw on some well-known results from probability for expected values of special random variables. Given a random variable X and a function g(.), we can create a new random variable g(X). For example, if X is a random variable, then so is X2 and log(X) (if X 􏱰 0). The ex- pected value of g(X) is, again, simply a weighted average: j􏱪1 􏱵 g(x)f (x) jXj X In Example B.3, we computed E(X) 􏱪 5/8, so that [E(X)]2 􏱪 25/64. This shows that E(X2) is not the same as [E(X)]2. In fact, for a nonlinear function g(X), E[g(X)] 􏱻 g[E(X)] (except in very special cases). If X and Y are random variables, then g(X,Y) is a random variable for any function g, and so we can define its expectation. When X and Y are both discrete, taking on values {x1, x2, ..., xk} and {y1, y2, ..., ym}, respectively, the expected value is km E[g(X,Y)]􏱪∑∑g(x ,y)f (x ,y), h􏱪1 j􏱪1 where fX,Y is the joint pdf of (X,Y). The definition is more complicated for continuous ran- dom variables since it involves integration; we do not need it here. The extension to more than two random variables is straightforward. Properties of Expected Values In econometrics, we are not so concerned with computing expected values from various distributions; the major calculations have been done many times, and we will largely take Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. h j X,Y h j 732 APPENDICES these on faith. We will need to manipulate some expected values using a few simple rules. These are so important that we give them labels: Property E.1: For any constant c, E(c) 􏱪 c. Property E.2: For any constants a and b, E(aX 􏱕 b) 􏱪 aE(X) 􏱕 b. One useful implication of E.2 is that, if 􏱙 􏱪 E(X), and we define a new random variable as Y 􏱪 X 􏱦 􏱙, then E(Y) 􏱪 0; in E.2, take a 􏱪 1 and b 􏱪 􏱦􏱙. As an example of Property E.2, let X be the temperature measured in Celsius at noon on a particular day at a given location; suppose the expected temperature is E(X) 􏱪 25. If Y is the temperature measured in Fahrenheit, then Y 􏱪 32 􏱕 (9/5)X. From Property E.2, the expected temperature in Fahrenheit is E(Y ) 􏱪 32 􏱕 (9/5).E(X ) 􏱪 32 􏱕 (9/5).25 􏱪 77. Generally, it is easy to compute the expected value of a linear function of many random variables. Property E.3: If {a1, a2, ..., an} are constants and {X1, X2, ..., Xn} are random variables, then E(a1X1 􏱕 a2X2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 anXn) 􏱪 a1E(X1) 􏱕 a2E(X2) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 anE(Xn). Or, using summation notation, As a special case of this, we have (with each ai 􏱪 1) ∑n ∑n i􏱪1 a E(X ). ii [B.21] [B.22] E 􏱵 i􏱪1 ii a X 􏱷 􏱪 ∑n ∑n i􏱪1 E(X ). i E 􏱵 i􏱪1 X 􏱷 􏱪 i so that the expected value of the sum is the sum of expected values. This property is used often for derivations in mathematical statistics. EXAMPLE B.5 FINDING EXPECTED REVENUE Let X1, X2, and X3 be the numbers of small, medium, and large pizzas, respectively, sold dur- ing the day at a pizza parlor. These are random variables with expected values E( X1) 􏱪 25, E(X2) 􏱪 57, and E(X3) 􏱪 40. The prices of small, medium, and large pizzas are $5.50, $7.60, and $9.15. Therefore, the expected revenue from pizza sales on a given day is E(5.50 X1 􏱕 7.60 X2 􏱕 9.15 X3) 􏱪 5.50 E(X1) 􏱕 7.60 E(X2) 􏱕 9.15 E(X3) 􏱪 5.50(25) 􏱕 7.60(57) 􏱕 9.15(40) 􏱪 936.70, that is, $936.70. The actual revenue on any particular day will generally differ from this value, but this is the expected revenue. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 733 We can also use Property E.3 to show that if X ~ Binomial(n,􏰩), then E(X) 􏱪 n􏰩. That is, the expected number of successes in n Bernoulli trials is simply the number of trials times the probability of success on any particular trial. This is easily seen by writing X as X 􏱪 Y1 􏱕 Y2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 Yn, where each Yi ~ Bernoulli(􏰩). Then, E(X) 􏱪 ∑n i􏱪1 E(Y ) 􏱪 i ∑n i􏱪1 􏰩 􏱪 n􏰩. We can apply this to the airline reservation example, where the airline makes n 􏱪 120 reservations, and the probability of showing up is 􏰩 􏱪 .85. The expected number of people showing up is 120(.85) 􏱪 102. Therefore, if there are 100 seats available, the expected number of people showing up is too large; this has some bearing on whether it is a good idea for the airline to make 120 reservations. Actually, what the airline should do is define a profit function that accounts for the net revenue earned per seat sold and the cost per passenger bumped from the flight. This profit function is random because the actual number of people showing up is random. Let r be the net revenue from each passenger. (You can think of this as the price of the ticket for simplicity.) Let c be the compensation owed to any passenger bumped from the flight. Neither r nor c is random; these are assumed to be known to the airline. Let Y denote prof- its for the flight. Then, with 100 seats available, Y􏱪rX ifX􏰯100 􏱪 100r 􏱦 c(X 􏱦 100) if X 􏱰 100. The first equation gives profit if no more than 100 people show up for the flight; the second equation is profit if more than 100 people show up. (In the latter case, the net rev- enue from ticket sales is 100r, since all 100 seats are sold, and then c(X 􏱦 100) is the cost of making more than 100 reservations.) Using the fact that X has a Binomial(n,.85) distri- bution, where n is the number of reservations made, expected profits, E(Y ), can be found as a function of n (and r and c). Computing E(Y) directly would be quite difficult, but it can be found quickly using a computer. Once values for r and c are given, the value of n that maximizes expected profits can be found by searching over different values of n. Another Measure of Central Tendency: The Median The expected value is only one possibility for defining the central tendency of a random variable. Another measure of central tendency is the median. A general definition of me- dian is too complicated for our purposes. If X is continuous, then the median of X, say, m, is the value such that one-half of the area under the pdf is to the left of m, and one-half of the area is to the right of m. When X is discrete and takes on a finite number of odd values, the median is obtained by ordering the possible values of X and then selecting the value in the middle. For example, if X can take on the values {􏱶4,0,2,8,10,13,17}, then the median value of X is 8. If X takes on an even number of values, there are really two median values; sometimes, these are averaged to get a unique median value. Thus, if X takes on the values {–5,3,9,17}, then the median values are 3 and 9; if we average these, we get a median equal to 6. In general, the median, sometimes denoted Med(X), and the expected value, E(X), are different. Neither is “better” than the other as a measure of central tendency; they are both valid ways to measure the center of the distribution of X. In one special case, the median Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 734 APPENDICES F I G U R E B . 3 A symmetric probability distribution. f(x) 􏰽x and expected value (or mean) are the same. If X has a symmetric distribution about the value 􏱙, then 􏱙 is both the expected value and the median. Mathematically, the condition is f(􏱙 􏱕 x) 􏱪 f(􏱙 􏱦 x) for all x. This case is illustrated in Figure B.3. Measures of Variability: Variance and Standard Deviation Although the central tendency of a random variable is valuable, it does not tell us every- thing we want to know about the distribution of a random variable. Figure B.4 shows the pdfs of two random variables with the same mean. Clearly, the distribution of X is more tightly centered about its mean than is the distribution of Y. We would like to have a simple way of summarizing differences in the spreads of distributions. Variance For a random variable X, let 􏱙 􏱪 E(X). There are various ways to measure how far X is from its expected value, but the simplest one to work with algebraically is the squared difference, (X 􏱦 􏱙)2. (The squaring eliminates the sign from the distance measure; the resulting positive value corresponds to our intuitive notion of distance, and treats values above and below 􏱙 symmetrically.) This distance is itself a random variable since it can change with every outcome of X. Just as we needed a number to summarize the central tendency of X, we need a number that tells us how far X is from 􏱙, on average. One such number is the variance, which tells us the expected distance from X to its mean: Var(X) 􏱲 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙)2]. [B.23] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 735 F I G U R E B . 4 Random variables with the same mean but different distributions. pdf fX fY 􏰽 x,y Variance is sometimes denoted 􏱧X2, or simply 􏱧2, when the context is clear. From (B.23), it follows that the variance is always nonnegative. As a computational device, it is useful to observe that 􏱧2 􏱪E(X2 􏱦2X􏱙􏱕􏱙2)􏱪E(X2)􏱦2􏱙2 􏱕􏱙2 􏱪E(X2)􏱦􏱙2. [B.24] In using either (B.23) or (B.24), we need not distinguish between discrete and continuous random variables: the definition of variance is the same in either case. Most often, we first compute E(X), then E(X2), and then we use the formula in (B.24). For example, if X ~ Bernoulli(􏰩), then E(X) 􏱪 􏰩, and, since X2 􏱪 X, E(X2) 􏱪 􏰩. It follows from equation (B.24) that Var(X) 􏱪 E(X2) 􏱦 􏱙2 􏱪 􏰩 􏱦 􏰩2 􏱪 􏰩(1 􏱦 􏰩). Two important properties of the variance follow. Property VAR.1: Var(X) 􏱪 0 if, and only if, there is a constant c such that P(X 􏱪 c) 􏱪 1, in which case E(X) 􏱪 c. This first property says that the variance of any constant is zero and if a random vari- able has zero variance, then it is essentially constant. Property VAR.2: For any constants a and b, Var(aX 􏱕 b) 􏱪 a2Var(X). This means that adding a constant to a random variable does not change the variance, but multiplying a random variable by a constant increases the variance by a factor equal to the square of that constant. For example, if X denotes temperature in Celsius and Y 􏱪 32 􏱕 (9/5)X is temperature in Fahrenheit, then Var(Y) 􏱪 (9/5)2Var(X) 􏱪 (81/25)Var(X). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 736 APPENDICES Standard Deviation The standard deviation of a random variable, denoted sd(X), is simply the positive square ______ root of the variance: sd(X) 􏱲 􏱕􏱻Var(X). The standard deviation is sometimes denoted 􏱧X, or simply 􏱧, when the random variable is understood. Two standard deviation properties immediately follow from Properties VAR.1 and VAR.2. Property SD.1: For any constant c, sd(c) 􏱪 0. Property SD.2: For any constants a and b, sd(aX 􏱕 b) 􏱪 􏰫a􏰫sd(X). In particular, if a 􏱰 0, then sd(aX) 􏱪 a􏱳sd(X). This last property makes the standard deviation more natural to work with than the variance. For example, suppose that X is a random variable measured in thousands of dollars, say, income. If we define Y 􏱪 1,000X, then Y is income measured in dol- lars. Suppose that E(X) 􏱪 20, and sd(X) 􏱪 6. Then, E(Y) 􏱪 1,000E(X) 􏱪 20,000, and sd(Y) 􏱪 1,000􏱳sd(X) 􏱪 6,000, so that the expected value and standard deviation both increase by the same factor, 1,000. If we worked with variance, we would have Var(Y) 􏱪 (1,000)2Var(X), so that the variance of Y is one million times larger than the variance of X. Standardizing a Random Variable As an application of the properties of variance and standard deviation—and a topic of prac- tical interest in its own right—suppose that given a random variable X, we define a new random variable by subtracting off its mean m and dividing by its standard deviation 􏱧: X􏱦􏱙 Z 􏱲 ______, [B.25] 􏱧 which we can write as Z 􏱪 aX 􏱕 b, where a 􏱲 (1/􏱧), and b 􏱲 􏱦(􏱙/􏱧). Then, from Prop- erty E.2, From Property VAR.2, E(Z) 􏱪 aE(X) 􏱕 b 􏱪 (􏱙/􏱧) 􏱦 (􏱙/􏱧) 􏱪 0. Var(Z) 􏱪 a2Var(X) 􏱪 (􏱧2/􏱧2) 􏱪 1. Thus, the random variable Z has a mean of zero and a variance (and therefore a standard deviation) equal to one. This procedure is sometimes known as standardizing the random variable X, and Z is called a standardized random variable. (In introductory statistics courses, it is sometimes called the z-transform of X.) It is important to remember that the standard deviation, not the variance, appears in the denominator of (B.25). As we will see, this transformation is frequently used in statistical inference. As a specific example, suppose that E(X) 􏱪 2, and Var(X) 􏱪 9. Then, Z 􏱪 (X 􏱦 2)/3 has expected value zero and variance one. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Skewness and Kurtosis We can use the standardized version of a random variable to define other features of the distribution of a random variable. These features are described by using what are called higher order moments. For example, the third moment of the random variable Z in (B.25) is used to determine whether a distribution is symmetric about its mean. We can write E(Z3) 􏱪 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙)3]/􏱧3 If X has a symmetric distribution about 􏱙, then Z has a symmetric distribution about zero. (The division by 􏱧3 does not change whether the distribution is symmetric.) That means the density of Z at any two points z and −z is the same, which means that, in computing E(Z3), positive values z3 when z 􏱰 0 are exactly offset with the nega- tive value (􏱦z)3 􏱪 􏱦z3. It follows that, if X is symmetric about zero, then E(Z) 􏱪 0. Generally, E[(X 􏱦 􏱙)3]/􏱧3 is viewed as a measure of skewness in the distribution of X. In a statistical setting, we might use data to estimate E(Z3) to determine whether an underlying population distribution appears to be symmetric. (Computer Exercise C5.4 in Chapter 5 provides an illustration.) It also can be informative to compute the fourth moment of Z, E(Z4) 􏱪 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙)4]/􏱧4. Because Z4 􏱸 0, E(Z4) 􏱸 0 (and, in any interesting case, strictly greater than zero). With- out having a reference value, it is difficult to interpret values of E(Z4), but larger values mean that the tails in the distribution of X are thicker. The fourth moment E(Z4) is called a measure of kurtosis in the distribution of X. In Section B.5 we will obtain E(Z4) for the normal distribution. B.4 Features of Joint and Conditional Distributions Measures of Association: Covariance and Correlation While the joint pdf of two random variables completely describes the relationship between them, it is useful to have summary measures of how, on average, two random variables vary with one another. As with the expected value and variance, this is similar to using a single number to summarize something about an entire distribution, which in this case is a joint distribution of two random variables. Covariance Let 􏱙X 􏱪 E(X) and 􏱙Y 􏱪 E(Y) and consider the random variable (X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y). Now, if X is above its mean and Y is above its mean, then (X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y) 􏱰 0. This is also trueifX􏱷􏱙X andY􏱷􏱙Y.Ontheotherhand,ifX􏱰􏱙X andY􏱷􏱙Y,orviceversa,then (X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y) 􏱷 0. How, then, can this product tell us anything about the relationship between X and Y? The covariance between two random variables X and Y, sometimes called the population covariance to emphasize that it concerns the relationship between two Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 737 738 APPENDICES variables describing a population, is defined as the expected value of the product (X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y): Cov(X,Y) 􏱲 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y)], [B.26] which is sometimes denoted 􏱧XY . If 􏱧XY 􏱆 0, then, on average, when X is above its mean, Y is also above its mean. If 􏱧XY 􏱼 0, then, on average, when X is above its mean, Y is be- low its mean. Several expressions useful for computing Cov(X,Y) are as follows: Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y)] 􏱪 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙X)Y] 􏱪 E[X(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y)] 􏱪 E(XY) 􏱦 􏱙X􏱙Y . [B.27] It follows from (B.27), that if E(X) 􏱪 0 or E(Y) 􏱪 0, then Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 E(XY). Covariance measures the amount of linear dependence between two random variables. A positive covariance indicates that two random variables move in the same direction, while a negative covariance indicates they move in opposite directions. Interpreting the magnitude of a covariance can be a little tricky, as we will see shortly. Because covariance is a measure of how two random variables are related, it is natural to ask how covariance is related to the notion of independence. This is given by the following property. Property COV.1: If X and Y are independent, then Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0. This property follows from equation (B.27) and the fact that E(XY) 􏱪 E(X)E(Y) when X and Y are independent. It is important to remember that the converse of COV.1 is not true: zero covariance between X and Y does not imply that X and Y are independent. In fact, there are random variables X such that, if Y 􏱪 X2, Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0. [Any random variable with E(X) 􏱪 0 and E(X3) 􏱪 0 has this property.] If Y 􏱪 X2, then X and Y are clearly not in- dependent: once we know X, we know Y. It seems rather strange that X and X2 could have zero covariance, and this reveals a weakness of covariance as a general measure of asso- ciation between random variables. The covariance is useful in contexts when relationships are at least approximately linear. The second major property of covariance involves covariances between linear functions. Property COV.2: For any constants a1, b1, a2, and b2, Cov(a1X 􏱕 b1,a2Y 􏱕 b2) 􏱪 a1a2Cov(X,Y). [B.28] An important implication of COV.2 is that the covariance between two random variables can be altered simply by multiplying one or both of the random variables by a constant. This is important in economics because monetary variables, inflation rates, and so on can be defined with different units of measurement without changing their meaning. Finally, it is useful to know that the absolute value of the covariance between any two random variables is bounded by the product of their standard deviations; this is known as the Cauchy-Schwartz inequality. Property COV.3: 􏰫Cov(X,Y)􏰫 􏰯 sd(X)sd(Y). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 739 Correlation Coefficient Suppose we want to know the relationship between amount of education and annual earn- ings in the working population. We could let X denote education and Y denote earnings and then compute their covariance. But the answer we get will depend on how we choose to measure education and earnings. Property COV.2 implies that the covariance between education and earnings depends on whether earnings are measured in dollars or thousands of dollars, or whether education is measured in months or years. It is pretty clear that how we measure these variables has no bearing on how strongly they are related. But the covariance between them does depend on the units of measurement. The fact that the covariance depends on units of measurement is a deficiency that is overcome by the correlation coefficient between X and Y: Cov(X,Y ) 􏱧 Corr(X,Y) 􏱲 __________ 􏱪 ___X_Y_; [B.29] the correlation coefficient between X and Y is sometimes denoted 􏰴XY (and is sometimes called the population correlation). Because 􏱧X and 􏱧Y are positive, Cov(X,Y) and Corr(X,Y) always have the same sign, and Corr(X,Y) 􏱪 0 if, and only if, Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0. Some of the properties of covariance carry over to correlation. If X and Y are independent, then Corr(X,Y ) 􏱪 0, but zero correla- tion does not imply independence. (Like the covariance, the correlation coefficient is also a measure of linear dependence.) However, the magnitude of the correlation coefficient is easier to interpret than the size of the covariance due to the following property. Property CORR.1: 􏱦1 􏰯 Corr(X,Y) 􏰯 1. If Corr(X,Y) 􏱪 0, or equivalently Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0, then there is no linear relationship between X and Y, and X and Y are said to be uncorrelated random variables; other- wise, X and Y are correlated. Corr(X,Y) 􏱪 1 implies a perfect positive linear relationship, which means that we can write Y 􏱪 a 􏱕 bX for some constant a and some constant b 􏱰 0. Corr(X,Y) 􏱪 􏱦1 implies a perfect negative linear relationship, so that Y 􏱪 a 􏱕 bX for some b 􏱷 0. The extreme cases of positive or negative 1 rarely occur. Values of 􏰴XY closer to 1 or 􏱦1 indicate stronger linear relationships. As mentioned earlier, the correlation between X and Y is invariant to the units of measurement of either X or Y. This is stated more generally as follows. Property CORR.2: For constants a1, b1, a2, and b2, with a1a2 􏱰 0, Corr(a1X 􏱕 b1,a2Y 􏱕 b2) 􏱪 Corr(X,Y). If a1a2 􏱷 0, then Corr(a1X 􏱕 b1,a2Y 􏱕 b2) 􏱪 􏱦Corr(X,Y). As an example, suppose that the correlation between earnings and education in the work- ing population is .15. This measure does not depend on whether earnings are measured in dollars, thousands of dollars, or any other unit; it also does not depend on whether education is measured in years, quarters, months, and so on. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. sd(X)􏱳sd(Y) 􏱧X􏱧Y 740 APPENDICES Variance of Sums of Random Variables Now that we have defined covariance and correlation, we can complete our list of major properties of the variance. Property VAR.3: For constants a and b, Var(aX 􏱕 bY) 􏱪 a2Var(X) 􏱕 b2Var(Y) 􏱕 2abCov(X,Y). It follows immediately that, if X and Y are uncorrelated—so that Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0—then Var(X 􏱕 Y) 􏱪 Var(X) 􏱕 Var(Y) [B.30] and Var(X 􏱦 Y) 􏱪 Var(X) 􏱕 Var(Y). [B.31] In the latter case, note how the variance of the difference is the sum of the variances, not the difference in the variances. As an example of (B.30), let X denote profits earned by a restaurant during a Friday night and let Y be profits earned on the following Saturday night. Then, Z 􏱪 X 􏱕 Y is profits for the two nights. Suppose X and Y each have an expected value of $300 and a standard deviation of $15 (so that the variance is 225). Expected profits for the two nights is E(Z) 􏱪 E(X) 􏱕 E(Y) 􏱪 2􏱳(300) 􏱪 600 dollars. If X and Y are independent, and there- fore uncorrelated, then the variance of total profits is the sum of the variances: Var(Z) 􏱪 Var(X) 􏱕 Var(Y) 􏱪 2􏱳(225) 􏱪 450. It follows that the standard deviation of total profits is 􏱻____ 450 or about $21.21. Expressions (B.30) and (B.31) extend to more than two random variables. To state this extension, we need a definition. The random variables {X1, ..., Xn} are pairwise un- correlated random variables if each variable in the set is uncorrelated with every other variable in the set. That is, Cov(Xi,Xj) 􏱪 0, for all i 􏱻 j. Property VAR.4: If {X1, ..., Xn} are pairwise uncorrelated random variables and {ai: i 􏱪 1, ..., n} are constants, then Var(a1X1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 anXn) 􏱪 a21Var(X1) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 a2nVar(Xn). In summation notation, we can write Var􏱵 i􏱪1 ii aX 􏱷􏱪 ∑n ∑n i􏱪1 a2Var(X). ii [B.32] A special case of Property VAR.4 occurs when we take ai 􏱪 1 for all i. Then, for pairwise uncorrelated random variables, the variance of the sum is the sum of the variances: Var 􏱵 i􏱪1 i i ∑n ∑n X 􏱷 􏱪 Var(X ). i􏱪1 [B.33] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 741 Because independent random variables are uncorrelated (see Property COV.1), the variance of a sum of independent random variables is the sum of the va∑riances. If the Xi are not pairwise uncorrelated, then the expression for Var 􏱵 n a X 􏱷 is much ii more complicated; we must add to the right-hand side of (B.32) the terms 2aiajCov(xi,xj) for all i 􏱰 j. We can use (B.33) to derive the variance for a binomial random variable. Let X ~ Binomial(n,􏰩) and write X 􏱪 Y1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 Yn, where the Yi are independent Bernoulli(􏰩) random variables. Then, by (B.33), Var(X) 􏱪 Var(Y1) 􏱕 ... 􏱕 Var(Yn) 􏱪 n􏰩(1 􏱦 􏰩). In the airline reservation example with n 􏱪 120 and 􏰩 􏱪 .85, the variance of the num- ber of passengers arriving for their reservations is 120(.85)(.15) 􏱪 15.3, so the standard deviation is about 3.9. Conditional Expectation Covariance and correlation measure the linear relationship between two random variables and treat them symmetrically. More often in the social sciences, we would like to explain one variable, called Y, in terms of another variable, say, X. Further, if Y is related to X in a nonlinear fashion, we would like to know this. Call Y the explained variable and X the explanatory variable. For example, Y might be hourly wage, and X might be years of formal education. We have already introduced the notion of the conditional probability density func- tion of Y given X. Thus, we might want to see how the distribution of wages changes with education level. However, we usually want to have a simple way of summarizing this dis- tribution. A single number will no longer suffice, since the distribution of Y given X 􏱪 x generally depends on the value of x. Nevertheless, we can summarize the relationship be- tween Y and X by looking at the conditional expectation of Y given X, sometimes called the conditional mean. The idea is this. Suppose we know that X has taken on a particular value, say, x. Then, we can compute the expected value of Y, given that we know this outcome of X. We denote this expected value by E(Y􏰫X 􏱪 x), or sometimes E(Y􏰫x) for shorthand. Generally, as x changes, so does E(Y􏰫x). When Y is a discrete random variable taking on values {y1, ..., ym}, then When Y is continuous, E(Y􏰫x) is defined by integrating yfY􏰫X(y􏰫x) over all possible values of y. As with unconditional expectations, the conditional expectation is a weighted aver- age of possible values of Y, but now the weights reflect the fact that X has taken on a spe- cific value. Thus, E(Y􏰫x) is just some function of x, which tells us how the expected value of Y varies with x. As an example, let (X,Y) represent the population of all working individuals, where X is years of education and Y is hourly wage. Then, E(Y􏰫X 􏱪 12) is the average hourly wage for all people in the population with 12 years of education (roughly a high school educa- tion). E(Y􏰫X 􏱪 16) is the average hourly wage for all people with 16 years of education. Tracing out the expected value for various levels of education provides important infor- mation on how wages and education are related. See Figure B.5 for an illustration. In principle, the expected value of hourly wage can be found at each level of educa- tion, and these expectations can be summarized in a table. Because education can vary Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ∑m E(Y􏰫x)􏱪 yf (y􏰫x). j Y􏰫X j j􏱪1 i􏱪1 742 APPENDICES F I G U R E B . 5 The expected value of hourly wage given various levels of education. E(WAGE | EDUC ) 4 8 12 16 20 EDUC widely—and can even be measured in fractions of a year—this is a cumbersome way to show the relationship between average wage and amount of education. In economet- rics, we typically specify simple functions that capture this relationship. As an example, suppose that the expected value of WAGE given EDUC is the linear function E(WAGE􏰫EDUC) 􏱪 1.05 􏱕 .45 EDUC. If this relationship holds in the population of working people, the average wage for peo- ple with 8 years of education is 1.05 􏱕 .45(8) 􏱪 4.65, or $4.65. The average wage for people with 16 years of education is 8.25, or $8.25. The coefficient on EDUC implies that each year of education increases the expected hourly wage by .45, or 45¢. Conditional expectations can also be nonlinear functions. For example, suppose that E(Y􏰫x) 􏱪 10/x, where X is a random variable that is always greater than zero. This function is graphed in Figure B.6. This could represent a demand function, where Y is quantity de- manded and X is price. If Y and X are related in this way, an analysis of linear association, such as correlation analysis, would be incomplete. Properties of Conditional Expectation Several basic properties of conditional expectations are useful for derivations in econo- metric analysis. Property CE.1: E[c(X)􏰫X] 􏱪 c(X), for any function c(X). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 743 FIGURE B.6 Graph of E(Y|x) 􏱪 10/x. E(Y|x) 10 2 1 E(Y|x) = 10/x 1 5 10 x This first property means that functions of X behave as constants when we compute expec- tations conditional on X. For example, E(X2􏰫X) 􏱪 X2. Intuitively, this simply means that if we know X, then we also know X2. Property CE.2: For functions a(X) and b(X), E[a(X)Y 􏱕 b(X)􏰫X] 􏱪 a(X)E(Y􏰫X) 􏱕 b(X). For example, we can easily compute the conditional expectation of a function such as XY 􏱕 2X2: E(XY 􏱕 2X2􏰫X) 􏱪 XE(Y􏰫X) 􏱕 2X2. The next property ties together the notions of independence and conditional expectations. Property CE.3: If X and Y are independent, then E(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 E(Y). This property means that, if X and Y are independent, then the expected value of Y given X does not depend on X, in which case, E(Y􏰫X) always equals the (unconditional) expected- value of Y. In the wage and education example, if wages were independent of education, then the average wages of high school and college graduates would be the same. Since this is almost certainly false, we cannot assume that wage and education are independent. A special case of Property CE.3 is the following: if U and X are independent and E(U) 􏱪 0, then E(U􏰫X) 􏱪 0. There are also properties of the conditional expectation that have to do with the fact that E(Y􏰫X) is a function of X, say, E(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱙(X). Because X is a random variable, 􏱙(X) is also a random variable. Furthermore, 􏱙(X) has a probability distribution and therefore an expected value. Generally, the expected value of 􏱙(X) could be very difficult to com- pute directly. The law of iterated expectations says that the expected value of 􏱙(X) is simply equal to the expected value of Y. We write this as follows. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 744 APPENDICES Property CE.4: E[E(Y 􏰫X)] 􏱪 E(Y). This property is a little hard to grasp at first. It means that, if we first obtain E(Y􏰫X) as a function of X and take the expected value of this (with respect to the distribution of X, of course), then we end up with E(Y). This is hardly obvious, but it can be derived using the definition of expected values. As an example of how to use Property CE.4, let Y 􏱪 WAGE and X 􏱪 EDUC, where WAGE is measured in hours and EDUC is measured in years. Suppose the expected value of WAGE given EDUC is E(WAGE􏰫EDUC) 􏱪 4 􏱕 .60 EDUC. Further, E(EDUC) 􏱪 11.5. Then, the law of iterated expectations implies that E(WAGE) 􏱪 E(4 􏱕 .60 EDUC) 􏱪 4 􏱕 .60 E(EDUC) 􏱪 4 􏱕 .60(11.5) 􏱪 10.90, or $10.90 an hour. The next property states a more general version of the law of iterated expectations. Property CE.4': E(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 E[E(Y􏰫X,Z)􏰫X]. In other words, we can find E(Y􏰫X) in two steps. First, find E(Y􏰫X,Z) for any other random variable Z. Then, find the expected value of E(Y􏰫X,Z), conditional on X. Property CE.5: If E(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 E(Y), then Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0 [and so Corr(X,Y) 􏱪 0]. In fact, every function of X is uncorrelated with Y. This property means that, if knowledge of X does not change the expected value of Y, then X and Y must be uncorrelated, which implies that if X and Y are correlated, then E(Y􏰫X) must depend on X. The converse of Property CE.5 is not true: if X and Y are uncorrelated, E(Y􏰫X) could still depend on X. For example, suppose Y 􏱪 X2. Then, E(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 X2, which is clearly a function of X. However, as we mentioned in our discussion of covariance and cor- relation, it is possible that X and X2 are uncorrelated. The conditional expectation captures the nonlinear relationship between X and Y that correlation analysis would miss entirely. Properties CE.4 and CE.5 have two important implications: if U and X are random variables such that E(U􏰫X) 􏱪 0, then E(U) 􏱪 0, and U and X are uncorrelated. Property CE.6: If E(Y2) 􏱷 􏱵 and E[g(X)2] 􏱷 􏱵 for some function g, then E{[Y 􏱦 􏱙(X)]2􏰫X} 􏰯 E{[Y 􏱦 g(X)]2􏰫X} and E{[Y 􏱦 􏱙(X)]2} 􏰯 E{[Y 􏱦 g(X)]2}. Property CE.6 is very useful in predicting or forecasting contexts. The first inequality says that, if we measure prediction inaccuracy as the expected squared prediction error, conditional on X, then the conditional mean is better than any other function of X for predicting Y. The conditional mean also minimizes the unconditional expected squared prediction error. Conditional Variance Given random variables X and Y, the variance of Y, conditional on X 􏱪 x, is simply the variance associated with the conditional distribution of Y, given X 􏱪 x: E{[Y 􏱦 E(Y 􏰫x)]2􏰫x}. The formula Var(Y􏰫X 􏱪 x) 􏱪 E(Y2􏰫x) 􏱦 [E(Y􏰫x)]2 is often useful for calculations. Only occasionally will we have to compute a conditional variance. But we will have to make assumptions about and manipulate conditional vari- ances for certain topics in regression analysis. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 745 As an example, let Y 􏱪 SAVING and X 􏱪 INCOME (both of these measured annu- ally for the population of all families). Suppose that Var(SAVING􏰫INCOME) 􏱪 400 􏱕 .25 INCOME. This says that, as income increases, the variance in saving levels also increases. It is important to see that the relationship between the variance of SAVING and INCOME is totally separate from that between the expected value of SAVING and INCOME. We state one useful property about the conditional variance. Property CV.1: If X and Y are independent, then Var(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 Var(Y). This property is pretty clear, since the distribution of Y given X does not depend on X, and Var(Y􏰫X) is just one feature of this distribution. B.5 The Normal and Related Distributions The Normal Distribution The normal distribution and those derived from it are the most widely used distribu- tions in statistics and econometrics. Assuming that random variables defined over popu- lations are normally distributed simplifies probability calculations. In addition, we will rely heavily on the normal and related distributions to conduct inference in statistics and econometrics—even when the underlying population is not necessarily normal. We must postpone the details, but be assured that these distributions will arise many times throughout this text. A normal random variable is a continuous random variable that can take on any value. Its probability density function has the familiar bell shape graphed in Figure B.7. F I G U R E B . 7 The general shape of the normal probability density function. fX for a normal random variable 􏰽x Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 746 APPENDICES Mathematically, the pdf of X can be written as 􏱻___ f (x) 􏱪 __1___ exp[􏱦(x 􏱦 􏱙)2/2􏱧2], 􏱦􏱵 􏱷 x 􏱷 􏱵, [B.34] where 􏱙 􏱪 E(X) and 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(X). We say that X has a normal distribution with expected value 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2, written as X ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱧2). Because the normal distribution is symmetric about 􏱙, 􏱙 is also the median of X. The normal distribution is sometimes called the Gaussian distribution after the famous mathematician C. F. Gauss. Certain random variables appear to roughly follow a normal distribution. Human heights and weights, test scores, and county unemployment rates have pdfs roughly the shape in Figure B.7. Other distributions, such as income distributions, do not appear to follow the normal probability function. In most countries, income is not symmetrically distributed about any value; the distribution is skewed toward the upper tail. In some cases, a variable can be transformed to achieve normality. A popular transformation is the natural log, which makes sense for positive random variables. If X is a positive random variable, such as income, and Y 􏱪 log(X) has a normal distribution, then we say that X has a lognormal distribution. It turns out that the lognormal distribution fits income distribu- tion pretty well in many countries. Other variables, such as prices of goods, appear to be well described as lognormally distributed. The Standard Normal Distribution One special case of the normal distribution occurs when the mean is zero and the variance (and, therefore, the standard deviation) is unity. If a random variable Z has a Normal(0,1) distribution, then we say it has a standard normal distribution. The pdf of a standard nor- mal random variable is denoted 􏰿(z); from (B.34), with 􏱙 􏱪 0 and 􏱧2 􏱪 1, it is given by 􏱻___ 􏰿(z) 􏱪 __1__ exp(􏱦z2/2), 􏱦􏱵 􏱷 z 􏱷 􏱵. [B.35] The standard normal cumulative distribution function is denoted 􏱋(z) and is obtained as the area under 􏰿, to the left of z; see Figure B.8. Recall that 􏱋(z) 􏱪 P(Z 􏰯 z); because Z is continuous, 􏱋(z) 􏱪 P(Z 􏱷 z) as well. No simple formula can be used to obtain the values of 􏱋(z) [because 􏱋(z) is the in- tegral of the function in (B.35), and this intregral has no closed form]. Nevertheless, the values for 􏱋(z) are easily tabulated; they are given for z between 􏱦3.1 and 3.1 in Table G.1 in Appendix G. For z 􏰯 􏱦3.1, 􏱋(z) is less than .001, and for z 􏱸 3.1, 􏱋(z) is greater than .999. Most statistics and econometrics software packages include simple commands for computing values of the standard normal cdf, so we can often avoid printed tables entirely and obtain the probabilities for any value of z. Using basic facts from probability—and, in particular, properties (B.7) and (B.8) con- cerning cdfs—we can use the standard normal cdf for computing the probability of any event involving a standard normal random variable. The most important formulas are P(Z 􏱰 z) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋(z), [B.36] P(Z 􏱷 􏱦z) 􏱪 P(Z 􏱰 z), [B.37] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱧 2􏰵 2􏰵 and APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 747 F I G U R E B . 8 The standard normal cumulative distribution function. 1 0 23 0 3z .5 P(a 􏰯 Z 􏰯 b) 􏱪 􏱋(b) 􏱦 􏱋(a). [B.38] Because Z is a continuous random variable, all three formulas hold whether or not the inequalities are strict. Some examples include P(Z 􏱰 .44) 􏱪 1 􏱦 .67 􏱪 .33, P(Z 􏱷 􏱦.92) 􏱪 P(Z 􏱰 .92) 􏱪 1 􏱦 .821 􏱪 .179, and P(􏱦1 􏱷 Z 􏰯 .5) 􏱪 .692 􏱦 .159 􏱪 .533. Another useful expression is that, for any c 􏱰 0, P(􏰫Z􏰫 􏱰 c) 􏱪 P(Z 􏱰 c) 􏱕 P(Z 􏱷 􏱦c) [B.39] 􏱪 2􏱳P(Z 􏱰 c) 􏱪 2[1 􏱦 􏱋(c)]. Thus, the probability that the absolute value of Z is bigger than some positive constant c is simply twice the probability P(Z 􏱰 c); this reflects the symmetry of the standard normal distribution. In most applications, we start with a normally distributed random variable, X ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱧2), where 􏱙 is different from zero and 􏱧2 􏱻 1. Any normal random variable can be turned into a standard normal using the following property. Property Normal.1: If X ~ Normal(􏲇,􏱧2), then (X 􏱦 􏲇)/􏱧 ~ Normal(0,1). Property Normal.1 shows how to turn any normal random variable into a standard normal. Thus, suppose X ~ Normal(3,4), and we would like to compute P(X 􏰯 1). The steps always involve the normalization of X to a standard normal: P(X 􏰯 1) 􏱪 P(X 􏱦 3 􏰯 1 􏱦 3) 􏱪 P 􏱵_X__􏱦__3_ 􏰯 􏱦1􏱷 2 􏱪 P(Z 􏰯 􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱋(􏱦1) 􏱪 .159. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 748 APPENDICES EXAMPLE B.6 PROBABILITIES FOR A NORMAL RANDOM VARIABLE First, let us compute P(2 􏱷 X 􏰯 6) when X ~ Normal(4,9) (whether we use 􏱷 or 􏰯 is irrelevant because X is a continuous random variable). Now, P(2 􏱷 X 􏰯 6) 􏱪 P 􏱵_2_􏱦__4_ 􏱷 _X__􏱦__4_ 􏰯 _6_􏱶__4_ 􏱷 􏱪 P(􏱦2/3 􏱷 Z 􏰯 2/3) 333 􏱪 􏱋(.67) 􏱦 􏱋(􏱦.67) 􏱪 .749 􏱦 .251 􏱪 .498. Now, let us compute P(􏰫X􏰫 􏱰 2): P(􏰫X􏰫 􏱰 2) 􏱪 P(X 􏱰 2) 􏱕 P(X 􏱷 􏱦2) 􏱪 P[(X 􏱦 4)/3 􏱰 (2 􏱦 4)/3] 􏱕 P[(X 􏱦 4)/3 􏱷 (􏱦2 􏱦 4)/3] 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋(􏱦2/3) 􏱕 􏱋(􏱦2) 􏱪 1 􏱦 .251 􏱕 .023 􏱪 .772. Additional Properties of the Normal Distribution We end this subsection by collecting several other facts about normal distributions that we will later use. Property Normal.2: If X ~ Normal(􏲇,􏰴2), then aX 􏱕 b ~ Normal(a􏲇 􏱕 b,a2􏰴2). Thus, if X ~ Normal(1,9), then Y 􏱪 2X 􏱕 3 is distributed as normal with mean 2E(X) 􏱕 3 􏱪 5 and variance 22􏱳9 􏱪 36; sd(Y) 􏱪 2sd(X) 􏱪 2􏱳3 􏱪 6. Earlier, we discussed how, in general, zero correlation and independence are not the same. In the case of normally distributed random variables, it turns out that zero correla- tion suffices for independence. Property Normal.3: If X and Y are jointly normally distributed, then they are indepen- dent if, and only if, Cov(X,Y) 􏱪 0. Property Normal.4: Any linear combination of independent, identically distributed nor- mal random variables has a normal distribution. For example, let Xi, for i 􏱪 1, 2, and 3, be independent random variables distributed as Normal(􏱙,􏱧2). Define W 􏱪 X1 􏱕 2X2 􏱦 3X3. Then, W is normally distributed; we must simply find its mean and variance. Now, Also, E(W) 􏱪 E(X1) 􏱕 2E(X2) 􏱦 3E(X3) 􏱪 􏱙 􏱕 2􏱙 􏱦 3􏱙 􏱪 0. Var(W) 􏱪 Var(X1) 􏱕 4Var(X2) 􏱕 9Var(X3) 􏱪 14􏱧2. Property Normal.4 also implies that the average of independent, normally distrib- uted random variables has a normal distribution. If Y1, Y2, ..., Yn are independent random variables and each is distributed as Normal(􏱙, 􏱧2), then Y– ~ Normal(􏱙, 􏱧2/n). [B.40] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. This result is critical for statistical inference about the mean in a normal population. Other features of the normal distribution are worth knowing, although they do not play a central role in the text. Because a normal random variable is symmetric about its mean, it has zero skewness, that is, E[(X 􏱦 􏱙)3] 􏱪 0. Further, it can be shown that E[(X􏱦􏱙)4]/􏱧4 􏱪3, or E(Z4) 􏱪 3, where Z has a standard normal distribution. Because the normal distribution is so prevalent in probability and statistics, the measure of kurtosis for any given random variable 􏱓 (whose fourth moment exists) is often defined to be E[(X 􏱦 􏱙)4]/􏱧 4 􏱦 3, that is, relative to the value for the standard normal distribution. If E[(X 􏱶 􏱙)4]/􏱧 4 􏱰 3, then the distribution of 􏱓 has fatter tails than the normal distribution (a somewhat common occurrence, such as with the t distribution to be introduced shortly); if E[(X 􏱶 􏱙)4]/􏱧 4 􏱷 3, then the distribution has thinner tails than the normal (a rarer situation). The Chi-Square Distribution The chi-square distribution is obtained directly from independent, standard nor- mal random variables. Let Zi, i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, be independent random variables, each distributed as standard normal. Define a new random variable as the sum of the squares of the Zi: ∑n X􏱪 Z2. [B.41] i i􏱪1 Then, X has what is known as a chi-square distribution with n degrees of freedom (or df for short). We write this as X ~ 􏱚n2. The df in a chi-square distribution corresponds to the number of terms in the sum in (B.41). The concept of degrees of freedom will play an important role in our statistical and econometric analyses. The pdf for chi-square distributions with varying degrees of freedom is given in Figure B.9; we will not need the formula for this pdf, and so we do not reproduce it here. From equation (B.41), it is clear that a chi-square random variable is always nonnegative, and that, unlike the normal distribution, the chi-square distribution is not symmetric about any point. It can be shown that if X ~ 􏱚n2, then the expected value of X is n [the number of terms in (B.41)], and the variance of X is 2n. The t Distribution The t distribution is the workhorse in classical statistics and multiple regression analysis. We obtain a t distribution from a standard normal and a chi-square random variable. Let Z have a standard normal distribution and let X have a chi-square distribution with n degrees of freedom. Further, assume that Z and X are independent. Then, the random variable __Z___ T 􏱪 􏱻___ [B.42] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 749 X/n 750 APPENDICES F I G U R E B . 9 The chi-square distribution with various degrees of freedom. f(x) df = 2 df = 4 df = 8 x has a t distribution with n degrees of freedom. We will denote this by T ~ tn. The t distribution gets its degrees of freedom from the chi-square random variable in the denominator of (B.42). The pdf of the t distribution has a shape similar to that of the standard normal distribution, except that it is more spread out and therefore has more area in the tails. The expected value of a t distributed random variable is zero (strictly speaking, the expected value exists only for n 􏱰 1), and the variance is n/(n 􏱦 2) for n 􏱰 2. (The variance does not exist for n 􏰯 2 because the distribution is so spread out.) The pdf of the t distribution is plotted in Figure B.10 for various degrees of freedom. As the degrees of freedom gets large, the t distribution approaches the standard normal distribution. The F Distribution Another important distribution for statistics and econometrics is the F distribution. In par- ticular, the F distribution will be used for testing hypotheses in the context of multiple regression analysis. To define an F random variable, let X1 ~ 􏱚k2 and X2 ~ 􏱚k2 are independent. Then, the random variable 1 (X /k ) F 􏱪 ___1__1_ 2 and assume that X1 and X2 [B.43] (X2/k2) has an F distribution with (k1,k2) degrees of freedom. We denote this as F ~ Fk1,k2. The pdf of the F distribution with different degrees of freedom is given in Figure B.11. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 751 F I G U R E B . 1 0 The t distribution with various degrees of freedom. df = 24 df = 2 df = 1 23 0 3 F I G U R E B . 1 1 The Fk1, k2 distribution for various degrees of freedom, k1 and k2. f(x) df = 2, 8 df = 6, 8 df = 6, 20 0x Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 © Cengage Learning, 2013 752 APPENDICES The order of the degrees of freedom in Fk1,k2 is critical. The integer k1 is called the numerator degrees of freedom because it is associated with the chi-square variable in the numerator. Likewise, the integer k2 is called the denominator degrees of freedom because it is associated with the chi-square variable in the denominator. This can be a little tricky because (B.43) can also be written as (X1k2)/(X2k1), so that k1 appears in the denominator. Just remember that the numerator df is the integer associated with the chi-square variable in the numerator of (B.43), and similarly for the denominator df. Summary In this appendix, we have reviewed the probability concepts that are needed in econometrics. Most of the concepts should be familiar from your introductory course in probability and statistics. Some of the more advanced topics, such as features of conditional expectations, do not need to be mastered now—there is time for that when these concepts arise in the context of regression analysis in Part 1. In an introductory statistics course, the focus is on calculating means, variances, covari- ances, and so on for particular distributions. In Part 1, we will not need such calculations: we mostly rely on the properties of expectations, variances, and so on that have been stated in this appendix. Key Terms Bernoulli (or Binary) Random Variable Binomial Distribution Chi-Square Distribution Conditional Distribution Conditional Expectation Continuous Random Variable Correlation Coefficient Covariance Cumulative Distribution Function (cdf) Degrees of Freedom Discrete Random Variable Problems Expected Value Experiment F Distribution Independent Random Variables Joint Distribution Kurtosis Law of Iterated Expectations Median Normal Distribution Pairwise Uncorrelated Random Variables Probability Density Function (pdf) Random Variable Skewness Standard Deviation Standard Normal Distribution Standardized Random Variable Symmetric Distribution t Distribution Uncorrelated Random Variables Variance 1 Suppose that a high school student is preparing to take the SAT exam. Explain why his or her eventual SAT score is properly viewed as a random variable. 2 Let X be a random variable distributed as Normal(5,4). Find the probabilities of the following events: (i) P(X 􏰯 6). (ii) P(X􏱰4). (iii) P(􏰫X 􏱦 5􏰫 􏱰 1). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 3 Much is made of the fact that certain mutual funds outperform the market year after year (that is, the return from holding shares in the mutual fund is higher than the return from holding a portfolio such as the S&P 500). For concreteness, consider a 10-year period and let the population be the 4,170 mutual funds reported in The Wall Street Journal on January 1, 1995. By saying that performance relative to the market is random, we mean that each fund has a 50–50 chance of outperforming the market in any year and that perfor- mance is independent from year to year. (i) If performance relative to the market is truly random, what is the probability that any particular fund outperforms the market in all 10 years? (ii) Find the probability that at least one fund out of 4,170 funds outperforms the market in all 10 years. What do you make of your answer? (iii) If you have a statistical package that computes binomial probabilities, find the probability that at least five funds outperform the market in all 10 years. 4 For a randomly selected county in the United States, let X represent the proportion of adults over age 65 who are employed, or the elderly employment rate. Then, X is restricted to a value between zero and one. Suppose that the cumulative distribution function for X is given by F(x) 􏱪 3x2 􏱦 2x3 for 0 􏰯 x 􏰯 1. Find the probability that the elderly employment rate is at least .6 (60%). 5 Just prior to jury selection for O. J. Simpson’s murder trial in 1995, a poll found that about 20% of the adult population believed Simpson was innocent (after much of the physical evidence in the case had been revealed to the public). Ignore the fact that this 20% is an estimate based on a subsample from the population; for illustration, take it as the true percentage of people who thought Simpson was innocent prior to jury selection. Assume that the 12 jurors were selected randomly and independently from the population (although this turned out not to be true). (i) Find the probability that the jury had at least one member who believed in Simpson’s innocence prior to jury selection. [Hint: Define the Binomial(12,.20) random vari- able X to be the number of jurors believing in Simpson’s innocence.] (ii) FindtheprobabilitythatthejuryhadatleasttwomemberswhobelievedinSimpson’s innocence.[Hint:P(X􏱸2)􏱪1􏱦P(X􏰯1),andP(X􏰯1)􏱪P(X􏱪0)􏱕P(X􏱪1).] 6 (Requires calculus) Let X denote the prison sentence, in years, for people convicted of auto theft in a particular state in the United States. Suppose that the pdf of X is given by f(x) 􏱪 (1/9)x2, 0 􏱷 x 􏱷 3. Use integration to find the expected prison sentence. 7 If a basketball player is a 74% free throw shooter, then, on average, how many free throws will he or she make in a game with eight free throw attempts? 8 Suppose that a college student is taking three courses: a two-credit course, a three-credit course, and a four-credit course. The expected grade in the two-credit course is 3.5, while the expected grade in the three- and four-credit courses is 3.0. What is the expected overall grade point average for the semester? (Remember that each course grade is weighted by its share of the total number of units.) Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX B Fundamentals of Probability 753 754 APPENDICES 9 Let X denote the annual salary of university professors in the United States, measured in thousands of dollars. Suppose that the average salary is 52.3, with a standard deviation of 14.6. Find the mean and standard deviation when salary is measured in dollars. 10 Suppose that at a large university, college grade point average, GPA, and SAT score, SAT, are related by the conditional expectation E(GPA􏰫SAT) 􏱪 .70 􏱕 .002 SAT. (i) Find the expected GPA when SAT 􏱪 800. Find E(GPA􏰫SAT 􏱪 1,400). Comment on the difference. (ii) If the average SAT in the university is 1,100, what is the average GPA? (Hint: Use Property CE.4.) (iii) If a student’s SAT score is 1,100, does this mean he or she will have the GPA found in part (ii)? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics C.1 Populations, Parameters, and Random Sampling Statistical inference involves learning something about a population given the availability of a sample from that population. By population, we mean any well-defined group of sub- jects, which could be individuals, firms, cities, or many other possibilities. By “learning,” we can mean several things, which are broadly divided into the categories of estimation and hypothesis testing. A couple of examples may help you understand these terms. In the population of all working adults in the United States, labor economists are interested in learn- ing about the return to education, as measured by the average percentage increase in earnings given another year of education. It would be impractical and costly to obtain information on earnings and education for the entire working population in the United States, but we can obtain data on a subset of the population. Using the data collected, a labor economist may report that his or her best estimate of the return to another year of education is 7.5%. This is an example of a point estimate. Or, she or he may report a range, such as “the return to education is between 5.6% and 9.4%.” This is an example of an interval estimate. An urban economist might want to know whether neighborhood crime watch pro- grams are associated with lower crime rates. After comparing crime rates of neighbor- hoods with and without such programs in a sample from the population, he or she can draw one of two conclusions: neighborhood watch programs do affect crime, or they do not. This example falls under the rubric of hypothesis testing. The first step in statistical inference is to identify the population of interest. This may seem obvious, but it is important to be very specific. Once we have identified the population, we can specify a model for the population relationship of interest. Such models involve probability distributions or features of probability distributions, and these depend on unknown parameters. Parameters are simply constants that determine the directions and strengths of relationships among variables. In the labor econom- ics example just presented, the parameter of interest is the return to education in the population. 755 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 756 APPENDICES Sampling For reviewing statistical inference, we focus on the simplest possible setting. Let Y be a random variable representing a population with a probability density function f(y;􏰩), which depends on the single parameter 􏰩. The probability density function (pdf ) of Y is as- sumed to be known except for the value of 􏰩; different values of 􏰩 imply different popula- tion distributions, and therefore we are interested in the value of 􏰩. If we can obtain certain kinds of samples from the population, then we can learn something about 􏰩. The easiest sampling scheme to deal with is random sampling. Random Sampling. If Y1, Y2, ..., Yn are independent random variables with a common probability density function f(y;􏰩), then {Y1, ..., Yn} is said to be a random sample from f(y;􏰩) [or a random sample from the population represented by f(y;􏰩)]. When {Y1, ..., Yn} is a random sample from the density f(y;􏰩), we also say that the Yi are independent, identically distributed (or i.i.d.) random variables from f(y;􏰩). In some cases, we will not need to entirely specify what the common distribution is. The random nature of Y1, Y2, ..., Yn in the definition of random sampling reflects the fact that many different outcomes are possible before the sampling is actually car- ried out. For example, if family income is obtained for a sample of n 􏱪 100 families in the United States, the incomes we observe will usually differ for each different sample of 100 families. Once a sample is obtained, we have a set of numbers, say, {y1, y2, ..., yn}, which constitute the data that we work with. Whether or not it is appropriate to assume the sample came from a random sampling scheme requires knowledge about the actual sampling process. Random samples from a Bernoulli distribution are often used to illustrate statistical concepts, and they also arise in empirical applications. If Y1, Y2, ..., Yn are independent random variables and each is distributed as Bernoulli(􏰩), so that P(Yi 􏱪 1) 􏱪 􏰩 and P(Yi 􏱪 0) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏰩, then {Y1, Y2, ..., Yn} constitutes a random sample from the Bernoulli(􏰩) distribution. As an illustration, consider the airline reservation example carried along in Appendix B. Each Yi denotes whether customer i shows up for his or her reservation; Yi 􏱪 1 if passenger i shows up, and Yi 􏱪 0 otherwise. Here, 􏰩 is the probability that a randomly drawn person from the population of all people who make airline reservations shows up for his or her reservation. For many other applications, random samples can be assumed to be drawn from a normal distribution. If {Y1, ..., Yn} is a random sample from the Normal(􏱙,􏱧2) popula- tion, then the population is characterized by two parameters, the mean 􏱙 and the variance 􏱧2. Primary interest usually lies in 􏱙, but 􏱧2 is of interest in its own right because making inferences about 􏱙 often requires learning about 􏱧2. C.2 Finite Sample Properties of Estimators In this section, we study what are called finite sample properties of estimators. The term “finite sample” comes from the fact that the properties hold for a sample of any size, no matter how large or small. Sometimes, these are called small sample properties. In Section C.3, we cover “asymptotic properties,” which have to do with the behavior of estimators as the sample size grows without bound. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 757 Estimators and Estimates To study properties of estimators, we must define what we mean by an estimator. Given a random sample {Y1, Y2, ..., Yn} drawn from a population distribution that depends on an unknown parameter 􏰩, an estimator of 􏰩 is a rule that assigns each possible outcome of the sample a value of 􏰩. The rule is specified before any sampling is carried out; in par- ticular, the rule is the same regardless of the data actually obtained. As an example of an estimator, let {Y1, ..., Yn} be a random sample from a population with mean 􏱙. A natural estimator of 􏱙 is the average of the random sample: ̄ 􏱦 1 ∑n Y􏱪n Yi. [C.1] i􏱪1 Y ̄ is called the sample average but, unlike in Appendix A where we defined the sample average of a set of numbers as a descriptive statistic, Y ̄ is now viewed as an estimator. Given any outcome of the random variables Y1, ..., Yn, we use the same rule to estimate 􏱙: we simply average them. For actual data outcomes {y1, ..., yn}, the estimate is just the average in the sample: y- 􏱪 (y1 􏱕 y2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 yn)/n. EXAMPLE C.1 CITY UNEMPLOYMENT RATES Suppose we obtain the following sample of unemployment rates for 10 cities in the United States: City Unemployment Rate 1 5.1 2 6.4 3 9.2 4 4.1 5 7.5 6 8.3 7 2.6 8 3.5 9 5.8 10 7.5 Our estimate of the average city unemployment rate in the United States is y- 􏱪 6.0. Each sample generally results in a different estimate. But the rule for obtaining the estimate is the same, regardless of which cities appear in the sample, or how many. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 758 APPENDICES More generally, an estimator W of a parameter 􏰩 can be expressed as an abstract mathematical formula: W 􏱪 h(Y1, Y2, ..., Yn), [C.2] for some known function h of the random variables Y1, Y2, ..., Yn. As with the special case of the sample average, W is a random variable because it depends on the random sample: as we obtain different random samples from the population, the value of W can change. When a particular set of numbers, say, {y1, y2, ..., yn}, is plugged into the function h, we obtain an estimate of 􏰩, denoted w 􏱪 h(y1, ..., yn). Sometimes, W is called a point estima- tor and w a point estimate to distinguish these from interval estimators and estimates, which we will come to in Section C.5. For evaluating estimation procedures, we study various properties of the probability distribution of the random variable W. The distribution of an estimator is often called its sampling distribution, because this distribution describes the likelihood of various out- comes of W across different random samples. Because there are unlimited rules for com- bining data to estimate parameters, we need some sensible criteria for choosing among estimators, or at least for eliminating some estimators from consideration. Therefore, we must leave the realm of descriptive statistics, where we compute things such as the sample average to simply summarize a body of data. In mathematical statistics, we study the sampling distributions of estimators. Unbiasedness In principle, the entire sampling distribution of W can be obtained given the probability distribution of Yi and the function h. It is usually easier to focus on a few features of the distribution of W in evaluating it as an estimator of 􏰩. The first important property of an estimator involves its expected value. Unbiased Estimator. An estimator, W of 􏰩, is an unbiased estimator if E(W) 􏱪 􏰩, [C.3] for all possible values of 􏰩. If an estimator is unbiased, then its probability distribution has an expected value equal to the parameter it is supposed to be estimating. Unbiasedness does not mean that the esti- mate we get with any particular sample is equal to 􏰩, or even very close to 􏰩. Rather, if we could indefinitely draw random samples on Y from the population, compute an estimate each time, and then average these estimates over all random samples, we would obtain 􏰩. This thought experiment is abstract because, in most applications, we just have one ran- dom sample to work with. For an estimator that is not unbiased, we define its bias as follows. Bias of an Estimator. If W is a biased estimator of 􏰩, its bias is defined as Bias(W) 􏱲 E(W) 􏱦 􏰩. [C.4] Figure C.1 shows two estimators; the first one is unbiased, and the second one has a positive bias. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 759 F I G U R E C . 1 An unbiased estimator, W1, and an estimator with positive bias, W2. f(w) pdf of W1 pdf of W2 􏰷 = E(W1) E(W2) w The unbiasedness of an estimator and the size of any possible bias depend on the distribution of Y and on the function h. The distribution of Y is usually beyond our control (although we often choose a model for this distribution): it may be determined by nature or social forces. But the choice of the rule h is ours, and if we want an unbiased estimator, then we must choose h accordingly. Some estimators can be shown to be unbiased quite generally. We now show that the sample average Y ̄ is an unbiased estimator of the population mean 􏱙, regardless of the underlying population distribution. We use the properties of expected values (E.1 and E.2) that we covered in Section B.3: ̄ ∑n ∑n ∑n E(Y)􏱪E􏱵(1/n) Yi􏱷􏱪(1/n)E􏱵 Yi􏱷􏱪(1/n)􏱵 E(Yi)􏱷 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 ∑n 􏱪 (1/n) 􏱵 􏱙 􏱷􏱪 (1/n)(n􏱙) 􏱪 􏱙. i􏱪1 For hypothesis testing, we will need to estimate the variance 􏱧2 from a population with mean 􏱙. Letting {Y1,...,Yn} denote the random sample from the population with E(Y) 􏱪 􏱙 and Var(Y) 􏱪 􏱧2, define the estimator as 2 1∑n ̄2 S 􏱪􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊 (Y􏱦Y), [C.5] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. n 􏱦1 i􏱪1 i © Cengage Learning, 2013 760 APPENDICES which is usually called the sample variance. It can be shown that S2 is unbiased for 􏱧2: E(S2) 􏱪 􏱧2. The division by n 􏱦 1, rather than n, accounts for the fact that the mean 􏱙 is es∑timated rather than known. If 􏱙 were known, an unbiased estimator of 􏱧2 would be n􏱦1 n (Y 􏱦 􏱙)2, but 􏱙 is rarely known in practice. 􏱪i i1 Although unbiasedness has a certain appeal as a property for an estimator—indeed, its antonym, “biased,” has decidedly negative connotations—it is not without its prob- lems. One weakness of unbiasedness is that some reasonable, and even some very good, estimators are not unbiased. We will see an example shortly. Another important weakness of unbiasedness is that unbiased estimators exist that are actually quite poor estimators. Consider estimating the mean 􏱙 from a population. Rather than using the sample average Y ̄ to estimate 􏱙, suppose that, after collecting a sample of size n, we discard all of the observations except the first. That is, our estimator of 􏱙 is simply W 􏱲 Y1. This estimator is unbiased because E(Y1) 􏱪 􏱙. Hopefully, you sense that ignoring all but the first observation is not a prudent approach to estimation: it throws out most of the information in the sample. For example, with n 􏱪 100, we obtain 100 out- comes of the random variable Y, but then we use only the first of these to estimate E(Y). The Sampling Variance of Estimators The example at the end of the previous subsection shows that we need additional criteria to evaluate estimators. Unbiasedness only ensures that the sampling distribution of an esti- mator has a mean value equal to the parameter it is supposed to be estimating. This is fine, but we also need to know how spread out the distribution of an estimator is. An estima- tor can be equal to 􏰩, on average, but it can also be very far away with large probability. In Figure C.2, W1 and W2 are both unbiased estimators of 􏰩. But the distribution of W1 is more tightly centered about 􏰩: the probability that W1 is greater than any given distance from 􏰩 is less than the probability that W2 is greater than that same distance from 􏰩. Using W1 as our estimator means that it is less likely that we will obtain a random sample that yields an estimate very far from 􏰩. To summarize the situation shown in Figure C.2, we rely on the variance (or standard deviation) of an estimator. Recall that this gives a single measure of the dispersion in the distribution. The variance of an estimator is often called its sampling variance because it is the variance associated with a sampling distribution. Remember, the sampling variance is not a random variable; it is a constant, but it might be unknown. We now obtain the variance of the sample average for estimating the mean 􏱙 from a population: ∑n i􏱪1 [C.6] ∑n ∑n ∑n Var(Y ̄)􏱪 Var􏱵(1/n) Y 􏱷􏱪 (1/n2)Var􏱵 Y 􏱷􏱪 (1/n2)􏱵 Var(Y)􏱷 i i 􏱪 (1/n2) 􏱵 􏱧2 􏱷 􏱪 (1/n2)(n􏱧2) 􏱪 􏱧2/n. i􏱪1 i􏱪1 i􏱪1 Notice how we used the properties of variance from Sections B.3 and B.4 (VAR.2 and VAR.4), as well as the independence of the Yi. To summarize: If {Yi: i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is a random sample from a population with mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2, then Y ̄ has the same mean as the population, but its sampling variance equals the population variance, 􏱧2, divided by the sample size. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 761 F I G U R E C . 2 The sampling distributions of two unbiased estimators of 􏰩. f(w) pdf of W1 pdf of W2 u w An important implication of Var(Y ̄) 􏱪 􏱧2/n is that it can be made very close to zero by increasing the sample size n. This is a key feature of a reasonable estimator, and we return to it in Section C.3. As suggested by Figure C.2, among unbiased estimators, we prefer the estimator with the smallest variance. This allows us to eliminate certain estimators from consider- ation. For a random sample from a population with mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2, we know that Y ̄ is unbiased, and Var(Y ̄) 􏱪 􏱧2/n. What about the estimator Y1, which is just the first ob- servation drawn? Because Y1 is a random draw from the population, Var(Y1) 􏱪 􏱧2. Thus, the difference between Var(Y1) and Var(Y ̄) can be large even for small sample sizes. If n 􏱪 10, then Var(Y1) is 10 times as large as Var(Y ̄) 􏱪 􏱧2/10. This gives us a formal way of excluding Y1 as an estimator of 􏱙. To emphasize this point, Table C.1 contains the outcome of a small simulation study. Using the statistical package Stata®, 20 random samples of size 10 were gener- ated from a normal distribution, with 􏱙 􏱪 2 and 􏱧2 􏱪 1; we are interested in estimating 􏱙 here. For each of the 20 random samples, we compute two estimates, y1 and -y; these values are listed in Table C.1. As can be seen from the table, the values for y1 are much more spread out than those for -y: y1 ranges from 􏱦0.64 to 4.27, while -y ranges only from 1.16 to 2.58. Further, in 16 out of 20 cases, -y is closer than y1 to 􏱙 􏱪 2. The aver- age of y1 across the simulations is about 1.89, while that for -y is 1.96. The fact that these averages are close to 2 illustrates the unbiasedness of both estimators (and we could get these averages closer to 2 by doing more than 20 replications). But comparing just the average outcomes across random draws masks the fact that the sample average Y ̄ is far superior to Y1 as an estimator of 􏱙. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 762 APPENDICES T A B L E C . 1 Simulation of Estimators for a Normal(􏱙,1) Distribution with 􏱙 = 2 Replication y1 y- 1 􏱦0.64 1.98 2 1.06 1.43 3 4.27 1.65 4 1.03 1.88 5 3.16 2.34 6 2.77 2.58 7 1.68 1.58 8 2.98 2.23 9 2.25 1.96 10 2.04 2.11 11 0.95 2.15 12 1.36 1.93 13 2.62 2.02 14 2.97 2.10 15 1.93 2.18 16 1.14 2.10 17 2.08 1.94 18 1.52 2.21 19 1.33 1.16 20 1.21 1.75 Efficiency Comparing the variances of Y ̄ and Y1 in the previous subsection is an example of a general approach to comparing different unbiased estimators. Relative Efficiency. If W1 and W2 are two unbiased estimators of 􏰩, W1 is efficient relative to W2 when Var(W1) 􏰯 Var(W2) for all 􏰩, with strict inequality for at least one value of 􏰩. Earlier, we showed that, for estimating the population mean 􏱙, Var(Y ̄) 􏱷 Var(Y1) for any value of 􏱧2 whenever n 􏱰 1. Thus, Y ̄ is efficient relative to Y1 for estimating 􏱙. We can- not always choose between unbiased estimators based on the smallest variance criterion: given two unbiased estimators of 􏰩, one can have smaller variance from some values of 􏰩, while the other can have smaller variance for other values of 􏰩. If we restrict our attention to a certain class of estimators, we can show that the sample average has the smallest variance. Problem C.2 asks you to show that Y ̄ has the smallest variance among all unbiased estimators that are also linear functions of Y1, Y2, ..., Yn. The assumptions are that the Yi have common mean and variance, and that they are pair- wise uncorrelated. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 763 If we do not restrict our attention to unbiased estimators, then com- paring variances is meaningless. For example, when estimating the population mean 􏱙, we can use a trivial estimator that is equal to zero, regardless of the sample that we draw. Naturally, the variance of this estimator is zero (since it is the same value for every random sample). But the bias of this estimator is 􏱦􏱙, so it is a very poor estimator when 􏰫􏱙􏰫 is large. One way to compare estimators that are not necessarily unbiased is to compute the mean squared error (MSE) of the estimators. If W is an estimator of 􏰩, then the MSE of W is defined as MSE(W) 􏱪 E[(W 􏱦 􏰩)2]. The MSE measures how far, on average, the estimator is away from 􏰩. It can be shown that MSE(W) 􏱪 Var(W) 􏱕 [Bias(W)]2, so that MSE(W) depends on the variance and bias (if any is present). This allows us to compare two estimators when one or both are biased. C.3 Asymptotic or Large Sample Properties of Estimators In Section C.2, we encountered the estimator Y1 for the population mean 􏱙, and we saw that, even though it is unbiased, it is a poor estimator be- cause its variance can be much larger than that of the sample mean. One notable feature of Y1 is that it has the same variance for any sample size. It seems reasonable to require any estimation procedure to improve as the sample size increases. For estimating a population mean 􏱙, Y ̄ im- proves in the sense that its variance gets smaller as n gets larger; Y1 does not improve in this sense. We can rule out certain silly estimators by studying the asymptotic or large sample properties of estimators. In addition, we can say something positive about estimators that are not unbiased and whose variances are not easily found. Asymptotic analysis involves approximating the features of the sampling distribution of an estimator. These approximations depend on the size of the sample. Unfortunately, we are necessarily limited in what we can say about how “large” a sample size is needed for asymptotic anal- ysis to be appropriate; this depends on the underlying population distribu- tion. But large sample approximations have been known to work well for sample sizes as small as n 􏱪 20. Consistency The first asymptotic property of estimators concerns how far the estimator is likely to be from the parameter it is supposed to be estimating as we let the sample size increase indefinitely. Consistency. Let Wn be an estimator of 􏰩 based on a sample Y1, Y2, ..., Yn of size n. Then, Wn is a consistent estimator of 􏰩 if for every 􏲉 > 0,
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

764 APPENDICES
P(􏰫Wn 􏱦 􏰩􏰫 􏱰 􏲉) 􏱽 0 as n 􏱽 􏱵. [C.7]
If Wn is not consistent for 􏰩, then we say it is inconsistent.
When Wn is consistent, we also say that 􏰩 is the probability limit of Wn, written as
plim(Wn) 􏱪 􏰩.
Unlike unbiasedness—which is a feature of an estimator for a given sample
size—consistency involves the behavior of the sampling distribution of the estimator as the sample size n gets large. To emphasize this, we have indexed the estimator by the sample size in stating this definition, and we will continue with this convention throughout this section.
Equation (C.7) looks technical, and it can be rather difficult to establish based on fundamental probability principles. By contrast, interpreting (C.7) is straightforward. It means that the distribution of Wn becomes more and more concentrated about 􏰩, which roughly means that for larger sample sizes, Wn is less and less likely to be very far from 􏰩. This tendency is illustrated in Figure C.3.
If an estimator is not consistent, then it does not help us to learn about 􏰩, even with an unlimited amount of data. For this reason, consistency is a minimal requirement of an es- timator used in statistics or econometrics. We will encounter estimators that are consistent under certain assumptions and inconsistent when those assumptions fail. When estimators are inconsistent, we can usually find their probability limits, and it will be important to know how far these probability limits are from 􏰩.
As we noted earlier, unbiased estimators are not necessarily consistent, but those whose variances shrink to zero as the sample size grows are consistent. This can be stated
F I G U R E C . 3 The sampling distributions of a consistent estimator for three sample sizes.
fWn(w)
n = 40
n = 16
n=4
􏰷
w
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 765
formally: If Wn is an unbiased estimator of 􏰩 and Var(Wn) 􏱽 0 as n 􏱽 􏱵, then plim(Wn) 􏱪 􏰩. Unbiased estimators that use the entire data sample will usually have a variance that shrinks to zero as the sample size grows, thereby being consistent.
A good example of a consistent estimator is the average of a random sample drawn from a population with mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2. We have already shown that the sample average is unbiased for 􏱙. In equation (C.6), we derived Var(Y ̄n)􏱪􏱧2/n for any sample size n. Therefore, Var(Y ̄n) 􏱽 0 as n 􏱽 􏱵, so Y ̄n is a consistent estimator of 􏱙 (in addition to being unbiased). ̄ ̄
The conclusion that Yn is consistent for 􏱙 holds even if Var(Yn) does not exist. This classic result is known as the law of large numbers (LLN).
Law of Large Numbers. Let Y1, Y2, …, Yn be independent, identically distributed random variables with mean 􏱙. Then,
plim(Y ̄n) 􏱪 􏱙. [C.8]
The law of large numbers means that, if we are interested in estimating the population average 􏱙, we can get arbitrarily close to 􏱙 by choosing a sufficiently large sample. This fundamental result can be combined with basic properties of plims to show that fairly complicated estimators are consistent.
PropertyPLIM.1: Let􏰩beaparameteranddefineanewparameter,􏰸􏱪g(􏰩),forsomecon- tinuous function g(􏰩). Suppose that plim(Wn) 􏱪 􏰩. Define an estimator of 􏰸 by Gn 􏱪 g(Wn). Then,
This is often stated as
for a continuous function g(􏰩).
plim(Gn) 􏱪 􏰸. [C.9]
plim g(Wn) 􏱪 g(plim Wn) [C.10]
The assumption that g(􏰩) is continuous is a technical requirement that has often been
described nontechnically as “a function that can be graphed without lifting your pencil
from the paper.” Because all the functions we encounter in this text are continuous,
we do not provide a formal definition of a continuous function. Examples of continu-
ous functions are g(􏰩) 􏱪 a 􏱕 b􏰩 for constants a and b, g(􏰩) 􏱪 􏰩2, g(􏰩) 􏱪 1/􏰩, g(􏰩) 􏱪 __
􏱯 􏰩 , g(􏰩) 􏱪 exp(􏰩), and many variants on these. We will not need to mention the con- tinuity assumption again.
As an important example of a consistent but biased estimator, consider estimating
the standard deviation, 􏱧, from a population wi􏰭th mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2. We already
claimed that the sample variance Sn2 􏱪 (n 􏱶 1)􏱶1 n (Y 􏱦 Y ̄ )2 is unbiased for 􏱧2. Using i􏱪1 i n
the law of large numbers and some algebra, S2 can also be shown to be consistent for 􏱧2. ___ __ n
The natural estimator of 􏱧 􏱪 􏱯􏱧2 is Sn 􏱪 􏱯Sn2 (where the square root is always the positive square root). Sn, which is called the sample standard deviation, is not an unbiased esti- mator because the expected value of the square root is not the square root of the expected
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

766 APPENDICES
_______ ___
value (see Section B.3). Nevertheless, by PLIM.1, plim Sn 􏱪 􏱯plim Sn2 􏱪 􏱯􏱧2 􏱪 􏱧, so Sn is
a consistent estimator of 􏱧.
Here are some other useful properties of the probability limit:
Property PLIM.2: If plim(Tn) 􏱪 􏱮 and plim(Un) 􏱪 􏱬, then
(i) plim(Tn 􏱕Un)􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱬;
(ii) plim(TnUn) 􏱪 􏱮􏱬;
(iii) plim(Tn /Un) 􏱪 􏱮/􏱬, provided 􏱬 􏱻 0.
These three facts about probability limits allow us to combine consistent estimators in a variety of ways to get other consistent estimators. For example, let {Y1, …, Yn} be a random sample of size n on annual earnings from the population of workers with a high school education and denote the population mean by 􏱙Y . Let {Z1, …, Zn} be a random sample on annual earnings from the population of workers with a college education and denote the population mean by 􏱙Z . We wish to estimate the percentage difference in an- nual earnings between the two groups, which is 􏰸 􏱪 100􏱳(􏱙Z 􏱦 􏱙Y)/􏱙Y . (This is the per- centage by which average earnings for college graduates differs from average earnings for high school graduates.) Because Y ̄n is consistent for 􏱙Y and Z ̄n is consistent for 􏱙Z, it follows from PLIM.1 and part (iii) of PLIM.2 that
Gn􏱲100􏱳(Z ̄n 􏱶Y ̄n)/Y ̄n
is a consistent estimator of 􏰸. Gn is just the percentage difference between Z ̄n and Y ̄n in the sample, so it is a natural estimator. Gn is not an unbiased estimator of 􏰸, but it is still a good estimator except possibly when n is small.
Asymptotic Normality
Consistency is a property of point estimators. Although it does tell us that the distribu- tion of the estimator is collapsing around the parameter as the sample size gets large, it tells us essentially nothing about the shape of that distribution for a given sample size. For constructing interval estimators and testing hypotheses, we need a way to approxi- mate the distribution of our estimators. Most econometric estimators have distributions that are well approximated by a normal distribution for large samples, which motivates the following definition.
Asymptotic Normality. Let {Zn: n 􏱪 1, 2, …} be a sequence of random variables, such that for all numbers z,
P(Zn 􏰯 z) 􏱽 􏱋(z) as n 􏱽 􏱵, [C.11]
where 􏱋(z) is the standard normal cumulative distribution function. Then, Zn is said to have an asymptotic standard normal distribution. In this case, we often write Zn ~a Normal(0,1). (The “a” above the tilde stands for “asymptotically” or “approximately.”)
Property (C.11) means that the cumulative distribution function for Zn gets closer and closer to the cdf of the standard normal distribution as the sample size n gets large. When asymptotic normality holds, for large n we have the approximation
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 767
P(Zn 􏰯 z) 􏱴 􏱋(z). Thus, probabilities concerning Zn can be approximated by standard normal probabilities.
The central limit theorem (CLT) is one of the most powerful results in probability and statistics. It states that the average from a random sample for any population (with finite variance), when standardized, has an asymptotic standard normal distribution.
Central Limit Theorem. Let {Y1, Y2, …, Yn} be a random sample with mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2. Then,
􏱧/􏱯 n has an asymptotic standard normal distribution.
Y ̄ n 􏱶 􏱙
Zn 􏱪 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊_􏲊_􏲊 [C.12]
The variable Zn in (C.12) is the standardized version of Y ̄n: we have subtracted off ̄ ̄__
E(Yn) 􏱪 􏱙 and divided by sd(Yn) 􏱪 􏱧/􏱯 n. Thus, regardless of the population distribution of Y, Zn has mean zero and variance one, which coincides with the mean and variance of the standard normal distribution. Remarkably, the entire distribution of Zn gets arbitrarily close to the standard normal distribution as n gets large.
__ ̄
We can write the standardized variable in equation (C.12) as 􏱯 n(Yn 􏱦 􏱙)/􏱧, which
shows that we must multiply the difference between the sample mean and the population
mean by the square root of the sample size in order to obtain a useful limiting distribu-
̄
in probability to zero. In other words, the distribution of (Y ̄n 􏱦 􏱙)/􏱧 simply collapses to a
__
tion. Without the multiplication by 􏱯 n, we would just have (Yn 􏱦 􏱙)/􏱧, which converges
single point as n 􏱽 􏱵, which we know cannot be a good approximation to the distribution
̄
__
of (Yn 􏱦 􏱙)/􏱧 for reasonable sample sizes. Multiplying by 􏱯 n ensures that the variance of
Zn remains constant. Practically, we often treat Y ̄n as being approximately normally dis- tributed with mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2/n, and this gives us the correct statistical procedures because it leads to the standardized variable in equation (C.12).
Most estimators encountered in statistics and econometrics can be written as functions of sample averages, in which case we can apply the law of large numbers and the central limit theorem. When two consistent estimators have asymptotic normal distributions, we choose the estimator with the smallest asymptotic variance.
In addition to the standardized sample average in (C.12), many other statistics that depend on sample averages turn out to be asymptotically normal. An important one is ob- tained by replacing 􏱧 with its consistent estimator Sn in equation (C.12):
Y ̄ n 􏱶 􏱙
􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊__􏲊 [C.13]
also has an approximate standard normal distribution for large n. The exact (finite sample) distributions of (C.12) and (C.13) are definitely not the same, but the difference is often small enough to be ignored for large n.
Throughout this section, each estimator has been subscripted by n to emphasize the nature of asymptotic or large sample analysis. Continuing this convention clutters the no- tation without providing additional insight, once the fundamentals of asymptotic analysis are understood. Henceforth, we drop the n subscript and rely on you to remember that estimators depend on the sample size, and properties such as consistency and asymptotic normality refer to the growth of the sample size without bound.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
Sn/􏱯n

768 APPENDICES
C.4 General Approaches to Parameter Estimation
Until this point, we have used the sample average to illustrate the finite and large sam- ple properties of estimators. It is natural to ask: Are there general approaches to estima- tion that produce estimators with good properties, such as unbiasedness, consistency, and efficiency?
The answer is yes. A detailed treatment of various approaches to estimation is beyond the scope of this text; here, we provide only an informal discussion. A thorough discussion is given in Larsen and Marx (1986, Chapter 5).
Method of Moments
Given a parameter 􏰩 appearing in a population distribution, there are usually many ways to obtain unbiased and consistent estimators of 􏰩. Trying all different possibilities and comparing them on the basis of the criteria in Sections C.2 and C.3 is not practical. Fortu- nately, some methods have been shown to have good general properties, and, for the most part, the logic behind them is intuitively appealing.
In the previous sections, we have studied the sample average as an unbiased estimator of the population average and the sample variance as an unbiased estimator of the popula- tion variance. These estimators are examples of method of moments estimators. Gener- ally, method of moments estimation proceeds as follows. The parameter 􏰩 is shown to be related to some expected value in the distribution of Y, usually E(Y) or E(Y2) (although more exotic choices are sometimes used). Suppose, for example, that the parameter of interest, 􏰩, is related to the population mean as 􏰩 􏱪 g(􏱙) for some function g. Because the sample average Y ̄ is an unbiased and consistent estimator of 􏱙, it is natural to replace 􏱙 with Y ̄, which gives us the estimator g(Y ̄ ) of 􏰩. The estimator g(Y ̄ ) is consistent for 􏰩, and if g(􏱙) is a linear function of 􏱙, then g(Y ̄ ) is unbiased as well. What we have done is replace the population moment, 􏱙, with its sample counterpart, Y ̄ . This is where the name “method of moments” comes from.
We cover two additional method of moments estimators that will be useful for our
discussion of regression analysis. Recall that the covariance between two random vari-
ables X and Y is define∑d as 􏱧XY 􏱪 E[(X 􏱦 􏱙X)(Y 􏱦 􏱙Y)]. The method of moments suggests
estimating 􏱧XY by n􏱦1 n (X 􏱦 X ̄)(Y 􏱦 Y ̄). This is a consistent estimator of 􏱧 , but it
R 􏱪 XY
_____
∑ i􏱪1 ∑
􏱪 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊 ,
[C.15]
ii XY
i􏱪1
turns out to be biased for essentially the same reason that the sample variance is biased if
n, rather than n 􏱦 1, is used as the divisor. The sample covariance is defined as 1∑n ̄ ̄
SXY 􏱪 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊 (Xi 􏱦 X)(Yi 􏱦 Y). [C.14] n 􏱶 1 i􏱪1
It can be shown that this is an unbiased estimator of 􏱧XY. (Replacing n with n 􏱦 1 makes no difference as the sample size grows indefinitely, so this estimator is still consistent.)
As we discussed in Section B.4, the covariance between two variables is often dif- ficult to interpret. Usually, we are more interested in correlation. Because the population correlation is 􏰴XY 􏱪 􏱧XY /(􏱧X 􏱧Y), the method of moments suggests estimating 􏰴XY as
SXY
∑n ̄ ̄ (Xi 􏱦X)(Yi 􏱦Y)
i
SXSY
n ̄ 2 1/2 n
􏱵 (X􏱦X)􏱷􏱵 (Y􏱦Y)􏱷
i
i􏱪1 i􏱪1
̄ 2 1/2
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 769
which is called the sample correlation coefficient (or sample correlation for short). Notice that we have canceled the division by n 􏱦 1 in the sample covariance and the sample standard deviations. In fact, we could divide each of these by n, and we would ar- rive at the same final formula.
It can be shown that the sample correlation coefficient is always in the interval [􏱦1,1], as it should be. Because SXY, SX, and SY are consistent for the corresponding population pa- rameter, RXY is a consistent estimator of the population correlation, 􏰴XY. However, RXY is a biased estimator for two reasons. First, SX and SY are biased estimators of 􏱧X and 􏱧Y, respec- tively. Second, RXY is a ratio of estimators, so it would not be unbiased, even if SX and SY were. For our purposes, this is not important, although the fact that no unbiased estimator of 􏰴XY exists is a classical result in mathematical statistics.
Maximum Likelihood
Another general approach to estimation is the method of maximum likelihood, a topic covered in many introductory statistics courses. A brief summary in the simplest case will suffice here. Let {Y1, Y2, …, Yn} be a random sample from the population distribution f(y;􏰩). Because of the random sampling assumption, the joint distribution of {Y1, Y2, …, Yn} is simply the product of the densities: f(y1;􏰩)f(y2;􏰩) 􏱳􏱳􏱳 f(yn;􏰩). In the discrete case, this is P(Y1 􏱪 y1, Y2 􏱪 y2, …, Yn 􏱪 yn). Now, define the likelihood function as
L(􏰩;Y1, …, Yn) 􏱪 f(Y1;􏰩)f(Y2;􏰩) 􏱳􏱳􏱳 f(Yn;􏰩),
which is a random variable because it depends on the outcome of the random sample {Y1, Y2, …, Yn}. The maximum likelihood estimator of 􏰩, call it W, is the value of 􏰩 that maximizes the likelihood function. (This is why we write L as a function of 􏰩, followed by the random sample.) Clearly, this value depends on the random sample. The maximum likelihood principle says that, out of all the possible values for 􏰩, the value that makes the likelihood of the observed data largest should be chosen. Intuitively, this is a reasonable approach to estimating 􏰩.
Usually, it is more convenient to work with the log-likelihood function, which is obtained by taking the natural log of the likelihood function:
log [L(􏰩; Y1, …, Yn)] 􏱪
log [ f (Y ; 􏰩)], [C.16]
i􏱪1
where we use the fact that the log of the product is the sum of the logs. Because (C.16)
is the sum of independent, identically distributed random variables, analyzing estimators that come from (C.16) is relatively easy.
Maximum likelihood estimation (MLE) is usually consistent and sometimes unbiased. But so are many other estimators. The widespread appeal of MLE is that it is generally the most asymptotically efficient estimator when the population model f(y;􏰩) is correctly specified. In addition, the MLE is sometimes the minimum variance unbiased estimator; that is, it has the smallest variance among all unbiased estimators of 􏰩. [See Larsen and Marx (1986, Chapter 5) for verification of these claims.]
In Chapter 17, we will need maximum likelihood to estimate the parameters of more advanced econometric models. In econometrics, we are almost always interested in the distribution of Y conditional on a set of explanatory variables, say, X1, X2, …, Xk. Then, we replace the density in (C.16) with f(Yi􏰫Xi1, …, Xik; 􏰩1, …, 􏰩p), where this density is
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
∑n
i

770 APPENDICES
allowed to depend on p parameters, 􏰩1, …, 􏰩p. Fortunately, for successful application of maximum likelihood methods, we do not need to delve much into the computational issues or the large-sample statistical theory. Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 13) covers the theory of maximum likelihood estimation.
Least Squares
A third kind of estimator, and one that plays a major role throughout the text, is called a least squares estimator. We have already seen an example of least squares: the sample mean, Y ̄, is a least squares estimator of the population mean, 􏱙. We already know Y ̄ is a method of moments estimator. What makes it a least squares estimator? It can be shown that the value of m that makes the sum of squared deviations
∑n
i i􏱪1
as small as possible is m 􏱪 Y ̄. Showing this is not difficult, but we omit the algebra.
For some important distributions, including the normal and the Bernoulli, the sample average Y ̄ is also the maximum likelihood estimator of the population mean 􏱙. Thus, the principles of least squares, method of moments, and maximum likelihood often result in
the same estimator. In other cases, the estimators are similar but not identical. C.5 Interval Estimation and Confidence Intervals
The Nature of Interval Estimation
A point estimate obtained from a particular sample does not, by itself, provide enough information for testing economic theories or for informing policy discussions. A point estimate may be the researcher’s best guess at the population value, but, by its nature, it provides no information about how close the estimate is “likely” to be to the population parameter. As an example, suppose a researcher reports, on the basis of a random sample of workers, that job training grants increase hourly wage by 6.4%. How are we to know whether or not this is close to the effect in the population of workers who could have been trained? Because we do not know the population value, we cannot know how close an estimate is for a particular sample. However, we can make statements involving probabili- ties, and this is where interval estimation comes in.
We already know one way of assessing the uncertainty in an estimator: find its sam- pling standard deviation. Reporting the standard deviation of the estimator, along with the point estimate, provides some information on the accuracy of our estimate. However, even if the problem of the standard deviation’s dependence on unknown population pa- rameters is ignored, reporting the standard deviation along with the point estimate makes no direct statement about where the population value is likely to lie in relation to the esti- mate. This limitation is overcome by constructing a confidence interval.
We illustrate the concept of a confidence interval with an example. Suppose the popu- lation has a Normal(􏱙,1) distribution and let {Y1, …, Yn} be a random sample from this population. (We assume that the variance of the population is known and equal to unity for the sake of illustration; we then show what to do in the more realistic case that the
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
(Y 􏱦 m)2

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 771
variance is unknown.) The sample average, Y ̄, has a normal distribution with mean 􏱙 and variance 1/n: Y ̄ ~ Normal(􏱙,1/n). From this, we can standardize Y ̄, and, because the stan- dardized version of Y ̄ has a standard normal distribution, we have
Y ̄ – 􏱙
P 􏱵􏱦1.96 􏱷 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊__􏲊 􏱷 1.96 􏱷 􏱪 .95.
1/􏱯 n
The event in parentheses is identical to the event Y 􏱦 1.96/􏱯 n 􏱷 􏱙 􏱷 Y 􏱕 1.96/􏱯 n, so
̄ __ ̄ __ ̄ __ ̄ __
P(Y 􏱦 1.96/􏱯 n 􏱷 􏱙 􏱷 Y 􏱕 1.96/􏱯 n ) 􏱪 .95. [C.17]
Equation (C.17) is interesting because it tells us that the probability that the random inter- ̄ __ ̄ __
val [Y 􏱦 1.96/􏱯 n,Y 􏱕 1.96/􏱯 n ] contains the population mean 􏱙 is .95, or 95%. This infor- mation allows us to construct an interval estimate of 􏱙, which is obtained by plugging in the sample outcome of the average, y-. Thus,
– __- __
[y 􏱦 1.96/􏱯 n,y 􏱕 1.96/􏱯 n] [C.18]

is an example of an interval estimate of 􏱙. It is also called a 95% confidence interval. A
__ shorthand notation for this interval is y 􏲁 1.96/􏱯 n.
The confidence interval in equation (C.18) is easy to compute, once the sample data
{y1,y2, …, yn} are observed; y- is the only factor that depends on the data. For example, sup-
pose that n 􏱪 16 and the average of the 16 data points is 7.3. Then, the 95% confidence ___
interval for 􏱙 is 7.3 􏲁 1.96/􏱯 16 􏱪 7.3 􏲁 .49, which we can write in interval form as [6.81,7.79]. By construction, y- 􏱪 7.3 is in the center of this interval.
Unlike its computation, the meaning of a confidence interval is more difficult to un- derstand. When we say that equation (C.18) is a 95% confidence interval for 􏱙, we mean that the random interval
̄ __ ̄ __
[Y 􏱦 1.96/􏱯 n,Y 􏱕 1.96/􏱯 n] [C.19]
contains 􏱙 with probability .95. In other words, before the random sample is drawn, there is a 95% chance that (C.19) contains 􏱙. Equation (C.19) is an example of an interval estimator. It is a random interval, since the endpoints change with different samples.
A confidence interval is often interpreted as follows: “The probability that 􏱙 is in the interval (C.18) is .95.” This is incorrect. Once the sample has been observed and y- has been computed, the limits of the confidence interval are simply numbers (6.81 and 7.79 in the example just given). The population parameter, 􏱙, though unknown, is also just some number. Therefore, 􏱙 either is or is not in the interval (C.18) (and we will never know with certainty which is the case). Probability plays no role once the confi- dence interval is computed for the particular data at hand. The probabilistic interpreta- tion comes from the fact that for 95% of all random samples, the constructed confidence interval will contain 􏱙.
To emphasize the meaning of a confidence interval, Table C.2 contains calculations
for 20 random samples (or replications) from the Normal(2,1) distribution with sample
size n 􏱪 10. For each of the 20 samples, y- is obtained, and (C.18) is computed as y- 􏲁 1.96/ ___ –
􏱯10 􏱪 y 􏲁 .62 (each rounded to two decimals). As you can see, the interval changes with each random sample. Nineteen of the 20 intervals contain the population value of 􏱙. Only for replication number 19 is 􏱙 not in the confidence interval. In other words, 95% of the samples result in a confidence interval that contains 􏱙. This did not have to be the case with only 20 replications, but it worked out that way for this particular simulation.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

772 APPENDICES
T A B L E C . 2 Simulated Confidence Intervals from a Normal(􏱙,1) Distribution with 􏱙􏱪2
Replication y- 95% Interval Contains 􏱙?
1
1.98
(1.36,2.60)
Yes
2
1.43
(0.81,2.05)
Yes
3
1.65
(1.03,2.27)
Yes
4
1.88
(1.26,2.50)
Yes
5
2.34
(1.72,2.96)
Yes
6
2.58
(1.96,3.20)
Yes
7
1.58
(.96,2.20)
Yes
8
2.23
(1.61,2.85)
Yes
9
1.96
(1.34,2.58)
Yes
10
2.11
(1.49,2.73)
Yes
11
2.15
(1.53,2.77)
Yes
12
1.93
(1.31,2.55)
Yes
13
2.02
(1.40,2.64)
Yes
14
2.10
(1.48,2.72)
Yes
15
2.18
(1.56,2.80)
Yes
16
2.10
(1.48,2.72)
Yes
17
1.94
(1.32,2.56)
Yes
18
2.21
(1.59,2.83)
Yes
19
1.16
(.54,1.78)
No
20
1.75
(1.13,2.37)
Yes
Confidence Intervals for the Mean from a Normally
Distributed Population
The confidence interval derived in equation (C.18) helps illustrate how to construct and interpret confidence intervals. In practice, equation (C.18) is not very useful for the mean of a normal population because it assumes that the variance is known to be unity. It is easy to extend (C.18) to the case where the standard deviation 􏱧 is known to be any value: the 95% confidence interval is
– __- __
[y 􏱦 1.96􏱧/􏱯 n,y 􏱕 1.96􏱧/􏱯 n]. [C.20]
Therefore, provided 􏱧 is known, a confidence interval for 􏱙 is readily constructed. To allow for unknown 􏱧, we must use an estimate. Let
-21/2
(y 􏱦y) [C.21]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
1 ∑n s􏱪 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊
􏱷
􏱵n – 1 i􏱪1
i
© Cengage Learning, 2013

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 773
denote the sample standard deviation. Then, we obtain a confidence interval that depends
entirely on the observed data by replacing 􏱧 in equation (C.20) with its estimate, s. Un-
̄
fortunately, this does not preserve the 95% level of confidence because s depends on
__
the particular sample. In other words, the random interval [Y 􏲁 1.96(S/􏱯 n)] no longer
contains 􏱙 with probability .95 because the constant 􏱧 has been replaced with the random variable S.
How should we proceed? Rather than using the standard normal distribution, we must rely on the t distribution. The t distribution arises from the fact that
Y ̄ 􏱦 􏱙
􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊_􏲊_􏲊 ~ tn􏱦1, [C.22]
S/􏱯 n
where Y ̄ is the sample average and S is the sample standard deviation of the random sam- ple {Y1,…,Yn}. We will not prove (C.22); a careful proof can be found in a variety of places [for example, Larsen and Marx (1986, Chapter 7)].
To construct a 95% confidence interval, let c denote the 97.5th percentile in the
tn􏱦1 distribution. In other words, c is the value such that 95% of the area in the tn􏱦1 is
between 􏱦c and c: P(􏱦c 􏱷 tn􏱦1 􏱷 c) 􏱪 .95. (The value of c depends on the degrees
of freedom n 􏱦 1, but we do not make this explicit.) The choice of c is illustrated in
̄ __ ̄ Figure C.4. Once c has been properly chosen, the random interval [Y 􏱦 c􏱳S/􏱯 n,Y 􏱕
__
c􏱳S/􏱯 n] contains 􏱙 with probability .95. For a particular sample, the 95% confidence
interval is calculated as
– __- __
[y 􏱦 c􏱳s/􏱯 n,y 􏱕 c􏱳s/􏱯 n]. [C.23]
FIGURE C.4 The 97.5th percentile, c, in a t distribution.
area = .95
area = .025 area = .025
2c 0 c
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

774 APPENDICES
The values of c for various degrees of freedom can be obtained from Table G.2 in
Appendix G. For example, if n 􏱪 20, so that the df is n 􏱦 1 􏱪 19, then c 􏱪 2.093. Thus, – ___ –
the 95% confidence interval is [y 􏲁 2.093(s/􏱯20)], where y and s are the values obtained from the sample. Even if s 􏱪 􏱧 (which is very unlikely), the confidence interval in (C.23) is wider than that in (C.20) because c 􏱰 1.96. For small degrees of freedom, (C.23) is much wider.
More generally, let c􏲋 denote the 100(1 􏱦 􏱮) percentile in the tn􏱦1 distribution. Then, a 100(1 􏱦 􏱮)% confidence interval is obtained as
– __- __
[y 􏱦 c􏲋/2s/􏱯 n,y 􏱕 c􏲋/2s/􏱯 n]. [C.24]
Obtaining c􏲋/2 requires choosing 􏱮 and knowing the degrees of freedom n 􏱦 1; then, Table G.2 can be used. For the most part, we will concentrate on 95% confidence intervals.
There is a simple way to remember how to construct a confidence interval for the
̄
̄ __ ̄
__ __
mean of a normal distribution. Recall that sd(Y) 􏱪 􏱧/􏱯 n. Thus, s/􏱯 n is the point estimate of
sd(Y). The associated random variable, S/􏱯 n, is sometimes called the standard error of Y. __
Because what shows up in formulas is the point estimate s/􏱯 n, we define the standard error

__
of y as se(y) 􏱪 s/􏱯 n. Then, (C.24) can be written in shorthand as
[y- 􏲁 c􏲋/2􏱳se(y-)]. [C.25] This equation shows why the notion of the standard error of an estimate plays an impor-
tant role in econometrics.
EXAMPLE C.2 EFFECT OF JOB TRAINING GRANTS ON WORKER PRODUCTIVITY
Holzer, Block, Cheatham, and Knott (1993) studied the effects of job training grants on worker productivity by collecting information on “scrap rates” for a sample of Michigan manufacturing firms receiving job training grants in 1988. Table C.3 lists the scrap rates— measured as number of items per 100 produced that are not usable and therefore need to be scrapped—for 20 firms. Each of these firms received a job training grant in 1988; there were no grants awarded in 1987. We are interested in constructing a confidence interval for the change in the scrap rate from 1987 to 1988 for the population of all manufacturing firms that could have received grants.
We assume that the change in scrap rates has a normal distribution. Since n 􏱪 20, a 95% confidence interval for the mean change in scrap rates 􏱙 is [ y- 􏲁 2.093􏱳se( y- )], where
– __ th
se( y) 􏱪 s/􏱯 n . The value 2.093 is the 97.5 percentile in a t19 distribution. For the particular
sample values, -y 􏱪 􏱦1.15 and se(-y) 􏱪 .54 (each rounded to two decimals), so the 95% confidence interval is [􏱦2.28,􏱦.02]. The value zero is excluded from this interval, so we conclude that, with 95% confidence, the average change in scrap rates in the population is not zero.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 775
T A B L E C . 3 Scrap Rates for 20 Michigan Manufacturing Firms
Firm 1987 1988 Change
1
10
3
–7
2
1
1
0
3
6
5
–1
4
.45
.5
.05
5
1.25
1.54
.29
6
1.3
1.5
.2
7
1.06
.8
–.26
8
3
2
–1
9
8.18
.67
–7.51
10
1.67
1.17
–.5
11
.98
.51
–.47
12
1
.5
–.5
13
.45
.61
.16
14
5.03
6.7
1.67
15
8
4
–4
16
9
7
–2
17
18
19
1
18
.28
.2
–.08
19
7
5
–2
20
3.97
3.83
–.14
Average
4.38
3.23
–1.15
At this point, Example C.2 is mostly illustrative because it has some potentially serious flaws as an econometric analysis. Most importantly, it assumes that any systematic reduc- tion in scrap rates is due to the job training grants. But many things can happen over the course of the year to change worker productivity. From this analysis, we have no way of knowing whether the fall in average scrap rates is attributable to the job training grants or if, at least partly, some external force is responsible.
A Simple Rule of Thumb for a 95% Confidence Interval
The confidence interval in (C.25) can be computed for any sample size and any confi- dence level. As we saw in Section B.5, the t distribution approaches the standard normal distribution as the degrees of freedom gets large. In particular, for 􏱮 􏱪 .05, c􏲋/2 􏱽 1.96 as n 􏱽 􏱵, although c􏲋/2 is always greater than 1.96 for each n. A rule of thumb for an ap- proximate 95% confidence interval is
[y- 􏲁 2􏱳se(y-)]. [C.26]
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

776 APPENDICES
In other words, we obtain y- and its standard error and then compute y- plus and minus twice its standard error to obtain the confidence interval. This is slightly too wide for very large n, and it is too narrow for small n. As we can see from Example C.2, even for n as small as 20, (C.26) is in the ballpark for a 95% confidence interval for the mean from a normal distribution. This means we can get pretty close to a 95% confidence interval with- out having to refer to t tables.
Asymptotic Confidence Intervals for Nonnormal
Populations
In some applications, the population is clearly nonnormal. A leading case is the Bernoulli distribution, where the random variable takes on only the values zero and one. In other cases, the nonnormal population has no standard distribution. This does not matter, pro- vided the sample size is sufficiently large for the central limit theorem to give a good ap- proximation for the distribution of the sample average Y ̄. For large n, an approximate 95% confidence interval is
[y- 􏲁 1.96􏱳se(y-)], [C.27]
where the value 1.96 is the 97.5th percentile in the standard normal distribution. Mechani- cally, computing an approximate confidence interval does not differ from the normal case. A slight difference is that the number multiplying the standard error comes from the stan- dard normal distribution, rather than the t distribution, because we are using asymptotics. Because the t distribution approaches the standard normal as the df increases, equation (C.25) is also perfectly legitimate as an approximate 95% interval; some prefer this to (C.27) because the former is exact for normal populations.
EXAMPLE C.3 RACE DISCRIMINATION IN HIRING
The Urban Institute conducted a study in 1988 in Washington, D.C., to examine the ex- tent of race discrimination in hiring. Five pairs of people interviewed for several jobs. In each pair, one person was black and the other person was white. They were given résumés indicating that they were virtually the same in terms of experience, education, and other factors that determine job qualification. The idea was to make individuals as similar as possible with the exception of race. Each person in a pair interviewed for the same job, and the researchers recorded which applicant received a job offer. This is an example of a matched pairs analysis, where each trial consists of data on two people (or two firms, two cities, and so on) that are thought to be similar in many respects but different in one important characteristic.
Let 􏰩B denote the probability that the black person is offered a job and let 􏰩W be the probability that the white person is offered a job. We are primarily interested in the differ- ence, 􏰩B 􏱦 􏰩W. Let Bj denote a Bernoulli variable equal to one if the black person gets a job offer from employer i, and zero otherwise. Similarly, Wi 􏱪 1 if the white person gets a job offer from employer i, and zero otherwise. Pooling across the five pairs of people, there were a total of n 􏱪 241 trials (pairs of interviews with employers). Unbiased estimators of 􏰩B and 􏰩W are B- and W- , the fractions of interviews for which blacks and whites were of- fered jobs, respectively.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 777
To put this into the framework of computing a confidence interval for a population mean, define a new variable Yi 􏱪 Bi 􏱦 Wi. Now, Yi can take on three values: 􏱦1 if the black person did not get the job but the white person did, 0 if both people either did or did not get the job, and 1 if the black person got the job and the white person did not. Then, 􏱙􏱲E(Yi)􏱪E(Bi)􏱦E(Wi)􏱪􏰩B 􏱦􏰩W.
The distribution of Yi is certainly not normal—it is discrete and takes on only three values. Nevertheless, an approximate confidence interval for 􏰩B 􏱦 􏰩W can be obtained by using large sample methods.
The data from the Urban Institute audit study are in the file AUDIT.RAW. Using the
241 observed data points, -b 􏱪 .224 and -w 􏱪 .357, so -y 􏱪 .224 􏱦.357 􏱪 􏱦.133. Thus,
22.4% of black applicants were offered jobs, while 35.7% of white applicants were of-
fered jobs. This is prima facie evidence of discrimination against blacks, but we can learn
much more by computing a confidence interval for 􏱙. To compute an approximate 95%
confidence interval, we need the sample standard deviation. This turns out to be s 􏱪 .482
[using equation (C.21)]. Using (C.27), we obtain a 95% CI for 􏱙 􏱪 􏰩 􏱦 􏰩 as 􏱦.133 􏲁 ____ BW
1.96(.482/􏱯241) 􏱪 􏱦.133 􏲁 .031 􏱪 [􏱦.164,􏱦.102]. The approximate 99% CI is 􏱦.133 ____
􏲁 2.58(.482/􏱯 241 ) 􏱪 [􏱦.213,􏱦.053]. Naturally, this contains a wider range of values than the 95% CI. But even the 99% CI does not contain the value zero. Thus, we are very confident that the population difference 􏰩B 􏱦 􏰩W is not zero.
Before we turn to hypothesis testing, it is useful to review the various population and sample quantities that measure the spreads in the population distributions and the sampling distributions of the estimators. These quantities appear often in statistical analysis, and exten- sions of them are important for the regression analysis in the main text. The quantity 􏱧 is the
̄
estimator of 􏱙 gets more and more precise as the sample size grows.
The estimate of 􏱧 for a particular sample, s, is called the sample standard deviation
(unknown) population standard deviation; it is a measure of the spread in the distribution of Y.
__
When we divide 􏱧 by 􏱯 n, we obtain the sampling standard deviation of Y (the sample aver-
__
age). While 􏱧 is a fixed feature of the population, sd(Y ) 􏱪 􏱧/􏱯 n shrinks to zero as n 􏱽 􏱵: our
because it is obtained from the sample. (We also call the underlying random variable, S,
which changes across different samples, the sample standard deviation.) Like y- as an es- __
timate of 􏱙, s is our “best guess” at 􏱧 given the sample at hand. The quantity s/􏱯 n is what

__
we call the standard error of y, and it is our best estimate of 􏱧/􏱯 n. Confidence intervals for
__
the population parameter 􏱙 depend directly on se( y) 􏱪 s/􏱯 n . Because this standard error
shrinks to zero as the sample size grows, a larger sample size generally means a smaller confidence interval. Thus, we see clearly that one benefit of more data is that they result in narrower confidence intervals. The notion of the standard error of an estimate, which in
__
the vast majority of cases shrinks to zero at the rate 1/􏱯 n, plays a fundamental role in hy-
pothesis testing (as we will see in the next section) and for confidence intervals and testing in the context of multiple regression (as discussed in Chapter 4).
C.6 Hypothesis Testing
So far, we have reviewed how to evaluate point estimators, and we have seen—in the case of a population mean—how to construct and interpret confidence intervals. But sometimes the question we are interested in has a definite yes or no answer. Here are
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
̄

778 APPENDICES
some examples: (1) Does a job training program effectively increase average worker productivity? (see Example C.2); (2) Are blacks discriminated against in hiring? (see Example C.3); (3) Do stiffer state drunk driving laws reduce the number of drunk driving arrests? Devising methods for answering such questions, using a sample of data, is known as hypothesis testing.
Fundamentals of Hypothesis Testing
To illustrate the issues involved with hypothesis testing, consider an election example. Suppose there are two candidates in an election, Candidates A and B. Candidate A is re- ported to have received 42% of the popular vote, while Candidate B received 58%. These are supposed to represent the true percentages in the voting population, and we treat them as such.
Candidate A is convinced that more people must have voted for him, so he would like to investigate whether the election was rigged. Knowing something about statistics, Candidate A hires a consulting agency to randomly sample 100 voters to record whether or not each person voted for him. Suppose that, for the sample collected, 53 people voted for Candidate A. This sample estimate of 53% clearly exceeds the reported population value of 42%. Should Candidate A conclude that the election was indeed a fraud?
While it appears that the votes for Candidate A were undercounted, we cannot be certain. Even if only 42% of the population voted for Candidate A, it is possible that, in a sample of 100, we observe 53 people who did vote for Candidate A. The question is: How strong is the sample evidence against the officially reported percentage of 42%?
One way to proceed is to set up a hypothesis test. Let 􏰩 denote the true proportion of the population voting for Candidate A. The hypothesis that the reported results are ac- curate can be stated as
H0: 􏰩 􏱪 .42. [C.28]
This is an example of a null hypothesis. We always denote the null hypothesis by H0. In hypothesis testing, the null hypothesis plays a role similar to that of a defendant on trial in many judicial systems: just as a defendant is presumed to be innocent until proven guilty, the null hypothesis is presumed to be true until the data strongly suggest otherwise. In the current example, Candidate A must present fairly strong evidence against (C.28) in order to win a recount.
The alternative hypothesis in the election example is that the true proportion voting for Candidate A in the election is greater than .42:
H1: 􏰩 􏱰 .42. [C.29]
In order to conclude that H0 is false and that H1 is true, we must have evidence “beyond reasonable doubt” against H0. How many votes out of 100 would be needed before we feel the evidence is strongly against H0? Most would agree that observing 43 votes out of a sample of 100 is not enough to overturn the original election results; such an out- come is well within the expected sampling variation. On the other hand, we do not need to observe 100 votes for Candidate A to cast doubt on H0. Whether 53 out of 100 is enough
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 779
to reject H0 is much less clear. The answer depends on how we quantify “beyond reason- able doubt.”
Before we turn to the issue of quantifying uncertainty in hypothesis testing, we should head off some possible confusion. You may have noticed that the hypotheses in equations (C.28) and (C.29) do not exhaust all possibilities: it could be that 􏰩 is less than .42. For the application at hand, we are not particularly interested in that possibility; it has nothing to do with overturning the results of the election. Therefore, we can just state at the outset that we are ignoring alternatives 􏰩 with 􏰩 􏱷 .42. Nevertheless, some authors prefer to state null and alternative hypotheses so that they are exhaustive, in which case our null hypothesis should be H0: 􏰩 􏰯 .42. Stated in this way, the null hypothesis is a composite null hypothesis because it allows for more than one value under H0. [By contrast, equation (C.28) is an ex- ample of a simple null hypothesis.] For these kinds of examples, it does not matter whether we state the null as in (C.28) or as a composite null: the most difficult value to reject if 􏰩 􏰯 .42 is 􏰩 􏱪 .42. (That is, if we reject the value 􏰩 􏱪 .42, against 􏰩 􏱰 .42, then logically we must reject any value less than .42.) Therefore, our testing procedure based on (C.28) leads to the same test as if H0: 􏰩 􏰯 .42. In this text, we always state a null hypothesis as a simple null hypothesis.
In hypothesis testing, we can make two kinds of mistakes. First, we can reject the null hypothesis when it is in fact true. This is called a Type I error. In the election example, a Type I error occurs if we reject H0 when the true proportion of people voting for Candidate A is in fact .42. The second kind of error is failing to reject H0 when it is actually false. This is called a Type II error. In the election example, a Type II error occurs if 􏰩 􏱰 .42 but we fail to reject H0.
After we have made the decision of whether or not to reject the null hypothesis, we have either decided correctly or we have committed an error. We will never know with certainty whether an error was committed. However, we can compute the probability of making either a Type I or a Type II error. Hypothesis testing rules are constructed to make the probability of committing a Type I error fairly small. Generally, we define the significance level (or simply the level) of a test as the probability of a Type I error; it is typically denoted by 􏱮. Symbolically, we have
􏱮 􏱪 P(Reject H0􏰫H0). [C.30]
The right-hand side is read as: “The probability of rejecting H0 given that H0 is true.” Classical hypothesis testing requires that we initially specify a significance level for a test. When we specify a value for 􏱮, we are essentially quantifying our tolerance for a Type I error. Common values for 􏱮 are .10, .05, and .01. If 􏱮 􏱪 .05, then the researcher is willing to falsely reject H0 5% of the time, in order to detect deviations
from H0.
Once we have chosen the significance level, we would then like to minimize the prob-
ability of a Type II error. Alternatively, we would like to maximize the power of a test against all relevant alternatives. The power of a test is just one minus the probability of a Type II error. Mathematically,
􏰵(􏰩) 􏱪 P(Reject H0􏰫􏰩) 􏱪 1 􏱦 P(Type II􏰫􏰩),
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

780 APPENDICES
where 􏰩 denotes the actual value of the parameter. Naturally, we would like the power to equal unity whenever the null hypothesis is false. But this is impossible to achieve while keeping the significance level small. Instead, we choose our tests to maximize the power for a given significance level.
Testing Hypotheses about the Mean in a Normal
Population
In order to test a null hypothesis against an alternative, we need to choose a test statistic (or statistic, for short) and a critical value. The choices for the statistic and critical value are based on convenience and on the desire to maximize power given a significance level for the test. In this subsection, we review how to test hypotheses for the mean of a normal population.
A test statistic, denoted T, is some function of the random sample. When we compute the statistic for a particular outcome, we obtain an outcome of the test statistic, which we will denote t.
Given a test statistic, we can define a rejection rule that determines when H0 is rejected in favor of H1. In this text, all rejection rules are based on comparing the value of a test statistic, t, to a critical value, c. The values of t that result in rejection of the null hypothesis are collectively known as the rejection region. To determine the critical value, we must first decide on a significance level of the test. Then, given 􏱮, the critical value associated with 􏱮 is determined by the distribution of T, assuming that H0 is true. We will write this critical value as c, suppressing the fact that it depends on 􏱮.
Testing hypotheses about the mean 􏱙 from a Normal(􏱙,􏱧2) population is straightfor- ward. The null hypothesis is stated as
H0: 􏱙 􏱪 􏱙0, [C.31]
where 􏱙0 is a value that we specify. In the majority of applications, 􏱙0 􏱪 0, but the general case is no more difficult.
The rejection rule we choose depends on the nature of the alternative hypothesis. The three alternatives of interest are
and
H1: 􏱙 􏱰 􏱙0, H1: 􏱙 􏱷 􏱙0,
H1: 􏱙 􏱻 􏱙0.
[C.32] [C.33]
[C.34]
Equation (C.32) gives a one-sided alternative, as does (C.33). When the alternative hy- pothesis is (C.32), the null is effectively H0: 􏱙 􏰯 􏱙0, since we reject H0 only when 􏱙 􏱰 􏱙0. This is appropriate when we are interested in the value of 􏱙 only when 􏱙 is at least as large as 􏱙0. Equation (C.34) is a two-sided alternative. This is appropriate when we are interested in any departure from the null hypothesis.
Consider first the alternative in (C.32). Intuitively, we should reject H0 in favor of H1 when the value of the-sample average, y-, is “sufficiently” greater than 􏱙0. But how should we determine when y is large enough for H0 to be rejected at the chosen significance
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 781
level? This requires knowing the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis when it is true. Rather than working directly with y-, we use its standardized version, where 􏱧 is re- placed with the sample standard deviation, s:
__- – –
t 􏱪 􏱯n(y 􏱦 􏱙0)/s 􏱪 (y 􏱦 􏱙0)/se(y), [C.35]
-__ –
where se( y) 􏱪 s/􏱯 n is the standard error of y. Given the sample of data, it is easy to obtain t.
We work with t because, under the null hypothesis, the random variable __ ̄
T 􏱪 􏱯 n (Y 􏱦 􏱙0)/S
has a tn􏱦1 distribution. Now, suppose we have settled on a 5% significance level. Then, the critical value c is chosen so that P(T 􏱰 c􏰫H0) 􏱪 .05; that is, the probability of a Type I er- ror is 5%. Once we have found c, the rejection rule is
t 􏱰 c, [C.36]
where c is the 100(1 􏱦 􏱮) percentile in a tn􏱦1 distribution; as a percent, the significance level is 100􏱳􏱮%. This is an example of a one-tailed test because the rejection region is in one tail of the t distribution. For a 5% significance level, c is the 95th percentile in the tn􏱦1 distribution; this is illustrated in Figure C.5. A different significance level leads to a dif- ferent critical value.
The statistic in equation (C.35) is often called the t statistic for testing H0: 􏱙 􏱪 􏱙0. The t statistic measures the distance from y- to 􏱙0 relative to the standard error of y-, se(y-).
FIGURE C.5 Rejection region for a 5% significance level test against the one-sided alternative 􏱙 > 􏱙0.
area = .95
0
area = .05
rejection
c
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

782 APPENDICES
EXAMPLE C.4 EFFECT OF ENTERPRISE ZONES ON BUSINESS
INVESTMENTS
In the population of cities granted enterprise zones in a particular state [see Papke (1994) for Indiana], let Y denote the percentage change in investment from the year before to the year after a city became an enterprise zone. Assume that Y has a Normal(􏱙,􏱧2) distribution. The null hypothesis that enterprise zones have no effect on business investment is H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0; the alternative that they have a positive effect is H1: 􏱙 􏱰 0. (We assume that they do not have a negative effect.) Suppose that we wish to test H0 at the 5% level. The test statistic in this case is
y-
t 􏱪 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊 􏱪 􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊􏲊. [C.37]
__
s􏱆􏱯 n se(y)
Suppose that we have a sample of 36 cities that are granted enterprise zones. Then, the critical value is c 􏱪 1.69 (see Table G.2), and we reject H0 in favor of H1 if t 􏱰 1.69. Suppose that the sample yields y- 􏱪 8.2 and s 􏱪 23.9. Then, t 􏱴 2.06, and H0 is therefore rejected at the 5% level. Thus, we conclude that, at the 5% significance level, enterprise zones have an effect on average investment. The 1% critical value is 2.44, so H0 is not rejected at the 1% level. The same caveat holds here as in Example C.2: we have not controlled for other factors that might affect investment in cities over time, so we cannot claim that the effect is causal.
The rejection rule is similar for the one-sided alternative (C.33). A test with a signifi- cance level of 100􏱳􏱮% rejects H0 against (C.33) whenever
t 􏱷 􏱦c; [C.38]
in other words, we are looking for negative values of the t statistic—which implies -y 􏱷 􏱙0—that are sufficiently far from zero to reject H0.
For two-sided alternatives, we must be careful to choose the critical value so that the significance level of the test is still 􏱮. If H1 is given by H1: 􏱙 􏱻 􏱙0, then we reject H0 if y- is far from 􏱙0 in absolute value: a y- much larger or much smaller than 􏱙0 provides evidence against H0 in favor of H1. A 100􏱳􏱮% level test is obtained from the rejection rule
􏰫t􏰫 􏱰 c, [C.39]
where 􏰫t􏰫 is the absolute value of the t statistic in (C.35). This gives a two-tailed test. We must now be careful in choosing the critical value: c is the 100(1 􏱦 􏱮/2) percentile in the tn􏱦1 distribution. For example, if 􏱮 􏱪 .05, then the critical value is the 97.5th percentile in the tn􏱦1 distribution. This ensures that H0 is rejected only 5% of the time when it is true (see Figure C.6). For example, if n 􏱪 22, then the critical value is c 􏱪 2.08, the 97.5th percentile in a t21 distribution (see Table G.2). The absolute value of the t statistic must exceed 2.08 in order to reject H0 against H1 at the 5% level.
It is important to know the proper language of hypothesis testing. Sometimes, the appropriate phrase “we fail to reject H0 in favor of H1 at the 5% significance level” is re- placed with “we accept H0 at the 5% significance level.” The latter wording is incorrect. With the same set of data, there are usually many hypotheses that cannot be rejected. In the earlier election example, it would be logically inconsistent to say that H0: 􏰩 􏱪 .42 and H0: 􏰩 􏱪 .43 are both “accepted,” since only one of these can be true. But it is entirely pos- sible that neither of these hypotheses is rejected. For this reason, we always say “fail to reject H0” rather than “accept H0.”
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
y- –

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 783
FIGURE C.6 Rejection region for a 5% significance level test against the two-sided alternative H1: 􏱙 􏱻 􏱙0.
area = .95
area = .025
rejection region –c
0
area = .025
rejection region
c
Asymptotic Tests for Nonnormal Populations
If the sample size is large enough to invoke the central limit theorem (see Section C.3), the mechanics of hypothesis testing for population means are the same whether or not the population distribution is normal. The theoretical justification comes from the fact that, under the null hypothesis,
__ ̄
T 􏱪 􏱯 n(Y 􏱦 􏱙0)/S ~a Normal(0,1).
Therefore, with large n, we can compare the t statistic in (C.35) with the critical values from a standard normal distribution. Because the tn􏱦1 distribution converges to the stan- dard normal distribution as n gets large, the t and standard normal critical values will be very close for extremely large n. Because asymptotic theory is based on n increasing without bound, it cannot tell us whether the standard normal or t critical values are better. For moderate values of n, say, between 30 and 60, it is traditional to use the t distribution because we know this is correct for normal populations. For n 􏱰 120, the choice between the t and standard normal distributions is largely irrelevant because the critical values are practically the same.
Because the critical values chosen using either the standard normal or t distribution are only approximately valid for nonnormal populations, our chosen significance levels are also only approximate; thus, for nonnormal populations, our significance levels are really asymptotic significance levels. Thus, if we choose a 5% significance level, but our population is nonnormal, then the actual significance level will be larger or smaller than
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

784 APPENDICES
5% (and we cannot know which is the case). When the sample size is large, the actual significance level will be very close to 5%. Practically speaking, the distinction is not im- portant, so we will now drop the qualifier “asymptotic.”
EXAMPLE C.5 RACE DISCRIMINATION IN HIRING
In the Urban Institute study of discrimination in hiring (see Example C.3), we are primar-
ily interested in testing H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱙 􏱷 0, where 􏱙 􏱪 􏰩B 􏱦 􏰩W is the difference
in probabilities that blacks and whites receive job offers. Recall that 􏱙 is the popula-
tion mean of in the variable Y 􏱪 B 􏱦 W, where B and W are binary indicators. Using the
n 􏱪 241 paired comparisons in the data file AUDIT.RAW, we obtained -y 􏱪 􏱦.133 and – ____
se(y) 􏱪 .482/􏱯 241 􏱴 .031. The t statistic for testing H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0 is t 􏱪 􏱦.133/.031 􏱴 􏱦4.29. You will remember from Appendix B that the standard normal distribution is, for practical purposes, indistinguishable from the t distribution with 240 degrees of freedom. The value 􏱦4.29 is so far out in the left tail of the distribution that we reject H0 at any reasonable significance level. In fact, the .005 (one-half of a percent) critical value (for the one-sided test) is about 􏱦2.58. A t value of 􏱦4.29 is very strong evidence against H0 in favor of H1. Hence, we conclude that there is discrimination in hiring.
Computing and Using p-Values
The traditional requirement of choosing a significance level ahead of time means that dif- ferent researchers, using the same data and same procedure to test the same hypothesis, could wind up with different conclusions. Reporting the significance level at which we are carrying out the test solves this problem to some degree, but it does not completely remove the problem.
To provide more information, we can ask the following question: What is the larg- est significance level at which we could carry out the test and still fail to reject the null hypothesis? This value is known as the p-value of a test (sometimes called the prob- value). Compared with choosing a significance level ahead of time and obtaining a critical value, computing a p-value is somewhat more difficult. But with the advent of quick and inexpensive computing, p-values are now fairly easy to obtain.
As an illustration, consider the problem of testing H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0 in a Normal(􏱙,􏱧2) popu- __ ̄
lation. Our test statistic in this case is T 􏱪 􏱯 n􏱳Y/S, and we assume that n is large enough to treat T as having a standard normal distribution under H0. Suppose that the observed value of T for our sample is t 􏱪 1.52. (Note how we have skipped the step of choosing a signifi- cance level.) Now that we have seen the value t, we can find the largest significance level at which we would fail to reject H0. This is the significance level associated with using t as our critical value. Because our test statistic T has a standard normal distribution under H0, we have
p-value 􏱪 P(T 􏱰 1.52􏰫H0) 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋(1.52) 􏱪 .065, [C.40]
where 􏱋(􏱳) denotes the standard normal cdf. In other words, the p-value in this example is simply the area to the right of 1.52, the observed value of the test statistic, in a standard normal distribution. See Figure C.7 for illustration.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.

APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 785
FIGURE C.7 The p-value when t 􏱪 1.52 for the one-sided alternative 􏱙 . 􏱙0.
area = .065
= p-value
0
1.52
Because the p-value 􏱪 .065, the largest significance level at which we can carry out this test and fail to reject is 6.5%. If we carry out the test at a level below 6.5% (such as at 5%), we fail to reject H0. If we carry out the test at a level larger than 6.5% (such as 10%), we reject H0. With the p-value at hand, we can carry out the test at any level.
The p-value in this example has another useful interpretation: it is the probability that we observe a value of T as large as 1.52 when the null hypothesis is true. If the null hypothesis is actually true, we would observe a value of T as large as 1.52 due to chance only 6.5% of the time. Whether this is small enough to reject H0 depends on our tolerance for a Type I error. The p-value has a similar interpretation in all other cases, as we will see.
Generally, small p-values are evidence against H0, since they indicate that the out- come of the data occurs with small probability if H0 is true. In the previous example, if t had been a larger value, say, t 􏱪 2.85, then the p-value would be 1 􏱦 􏱋(2.85) 􏱴 .002. This means that, if the null hypothesis were true, we would observe a value of T as large as 2.85 with probability .002. How do we interpret this? Either we obtained a very unusual sample or the null hypothesis is false. Unless we have a very small tolerance for Type I error, we would reject the null hypothesis. On the other hand, a large p-value is weak evidence against H0. If we had gotten t 􏱪 .47 in the previous example, then the p-value 􏱪 1 􏱦 􏱋(.47) 􏱪 .32. Observing a value of T larger than .47 happens with probability .32, even when H0 is true; this is large enough so that there is insufficient doubt about H0, un- less we have a very high tolerance for Type I error.
For hypothesis testing about a population mean using the t distribution, we need de- tailed tables in order to compute p-values. Table G.2 only allows us to put bounds on p-values. Fortunately, many statistics and econometrics packages now compute p-values routinely, and they also provide calculation of cdfs for the t and other distributions used for computing p-values.
Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.
© Cengage Learning, 2013

786 APPENDICES
EXAMPLE C.6 EFFECT OF JOB TRAINING GRANTS ON WORKER
PRODUCTIVITY
Consider again the Holzer et al. (1993) data in Example C.2. From a policy perspective, there are two questions of interest. First, what is our best estimate of the mean change in scrap rates, 􏱙? We have already obtained this for the sample of 20 firms listed in Table C.3: the sample average of the change in scrap rates is 􏱦1.15. Relative to the initial average scrap rate in 1987, this represents a fall in the scrap rate of about 26.3% (􏱦1.15/4.38 􏱴 􏱦.263), which is a nontrivial effect.
We would also like to know whether the sample provides strong evidence for an ef- fect in the population of manufacturing firms that could have received grants. The null hypothesis is H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0, and we test this against H1: 􏱙 􏱷 0, where 􏱙 is the average change in scrap rates. Under the null, the job training grants have no effect on average scrap rates. The alternative states that there is an effect. We do not care about the alternative 􏱙 􏱰 0, so the null hypothesis is effectively H0: 􏱙 􏱸 0.
Since y- 􏱪 􏱦1.15 and se(y-) 􏱪 .54, t 􏱪 􏱦1.15/.54 􏱪 􏱦2.13. This is below the 5% criti- cal value of 􏱦1.73 (from a t19 distribution) but above the 1% critical value, 􏱦2.54. The p-value in this case is computed as
p-value 􏱪 P(T19 􏱷 􏱦2.13), [C.41]
where T19 represents a t distributed random variable with 19 degrees of freedom. The inequality is reversed from (C.40) because the alternative has the form in (C.33). The probability in (C.41) is the area to the left of 􏱦2.13 in a t19 distribution (see Figure C.8).
FIGURE C.8 The p-value when t 􏱪 􏱦2.13 with 19 degrees of freedom for the one-sided alternative 􏱙 < 0. area = p-value = .023 –2.13 0 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 787 Using Table G.2, the most we can say is that the p-value is between .025 and .01, but it is closer to .025 (since the 97.5th percentile is about 2.09). Using a statistical pack- age, such as Stata, we can compute the exact p-value. It turns out to be about .023, which is reasonable evidence against H0. This is certainly enough evidence to reject the null hypothesis that the training grants had no effect at the 2.5% significance level (and there- fore at the 5% level). Computing a p-value for a two-sided test is similar, but we must account for the two- sided nature of the rejection rule. For t testing about population means, the p-value is com- puted as P(􏰫Tn􏱦1􏰫 􏱰 􏰫t􏰫) 􏱪 2P(Tn􏱦1 􏱰 􏰫t􏰫), [C.42] where t is the value of the test statistic and Tn􏱦1 is a t random variable. (For large n, replace Tn􏱦1 with a standard normal random variable.) Thus, compute the absolute value of the t statis- tic, find the area to the right of this value in a tn􏱦1 distribution, and multiply the area by two. For nonnormal populations, the exact p-value can be difficult to obtain. Neverthe- less, we can find asymptotic p-values by using the same calculations. These p-values are valid for large sample sizes. For n larger than, say, 120, we might as well use the standard normal distribution. Table G.1 is detailed enough to get accurate p-values, but we can also use a statistics or econometrics program. EXAMPLE C.7 RACE DISCRIMINATION IN HIRING Using the matched pair data from the Urban Institute (n 􏱪 241), we obtained t 􏱪 􏱦4.29. If Z is a standard normal random variable, P(Z 􏱷 􏱦4.29) is, for practical purposes, zero. In other words, the (asymptotic) p-value for this example is essentially zero. This is very strong evidence against H0. Summary of How to Use p-Values: (i) Choose a test statistic T and decide on the nature of the alternative. This determines whether the rejection rule is t 􏱰 c, t 􏱷 􏱦c, or 􏰫t􏰫 􏱰 c. (ii) Use the observed value of the t statistic as the critical value and compute the cor- responding significance level of the test. This is the p-value. If the rejection rule is of the form t 􏱰 c, then p-value 􏱪 P(T 􏱰 t). If the rejection rule is t 􏱷 􏱦c, then p-value 􏱪 P(T 􏱷 t); if the rejection rule is 􏰫t􏰫 􏱰 c, then p-value 􏱪 P(􏰫T􏰫 􏱰 􏰫t􏰫). (iii) If a significance level 􏱮 has been chosen, then we reject H0 at the 100􏱳􏱮% level if p-value 􏱷 􏱮. If p-value 􏱸 􏱮, then we fail to reject H0 at the 100􏱳􏱮% level. Therefore, it is a small p-value that leads to rejection. The Relationship between Confidence Intervals and Hypothesis Testing Because contructing confidence intervals and hypothesis tests both involve probability state- ments, it is natural to think that they are somehow linked. It turns out that they are. After a confidence interval has been constructed, we can carry out a variety of hypothesis tests. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 788 APPENDICES The confidence intervals we have discussed are all two-sided by nature. (In this text, we will have no need to construct one-sided confidence intervals.) Thus, confidence inter- vals can be used to test against two-sided alternatives. In the case of a population mean, the null is given by (C.31), and the alternative is (C.34). Suppose we have constructed a 95% confidence interval for 􏱙. Then, if the hypothesized value of 􏱙 under H0, 􏱙0, is not in the confidence interval, then H0: 􏱙 􏱪 􏱙0 is rejected against H1: 􏱙 􏱻 􏱙0 at the 5% level. If 􏱙0 lies in this interval, then we fail to reject H0 at the 5% level. Notice how any value for 􏱙0 can be tested once a confidence interval is constructed, and since a confidence interval contains more than one value, there are many null hypotheses that will not be rejected. EXAMPLE C.8 TRAINING GRANTS AND WORKER PRODUCTIVITY In the Holzer et al. example, we constructed a 95% confidence interval for the mean change in scrap rate 􏱙 as [􏱦2.28,􏱦.02]. Since zero is excluded from this interval, we reject H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0 against H1: 􏱙 􏱻 0 at the 5% level. This 95% confidence interval also means that we fail to reject H0: 􏱙 􏱪 􏱦2 at the 5% level. In fact, there is a continuum of null hypotheses that are not rejected given this confidence interval. Practical versus Statistical Significance In the examples covered so far, we have produced three kinds of evidence concerning pop- ulation parameters: point estimates, confidence intervals, and hypothesis tests. These tools for learning about population parameters are equally important. There is an understand- able tendency for students to focus on confidence intervals and hypothesis tests because these are things to which we can attach confidence or significance levels. But in any study, we must also interpret the magnitudes of point estimates. The sign and magnitude of -y determine its practical significance and allow us to discuss the direction of an intervention or policy effect, and whether the estimated effect is “large” or “small.” On the other hand, statistical significance of y- depends on the mag- nitude of its t statistic. For testing H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0, the t statistic is simply t 􏱪 y-/se(y-). In other words, statistical significance depends on the ratio of y- to its standard error. Consequently, a t statistic can be large because -y is large or se(-y) is small. In applications, it is impor- tant to discuss both practical and statistical significance, being aware that an estimate can be statistically significant without being especially large in a practical sense. Whether an estimate is practically important depends on the context as well as on one’s judgment, so there are no set rules for determining practical significance. EXAMPLE C.9 EFFECT OF FREEWAY WIDTH ON COMMUTE TIME Let Y denote the change in commute time, measured in minutes, for commuters in a metro- politan area from before a freeway was widened to after the freeway was widened. Assume that Y ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱧2). The null hypothesis that the widening did not reduce average com- mute time is H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0; the alternative that it reduced average commute time is H1: 􏱙 􏱷 0. Suppose a random sample of commuters of size n 􏱪 900 is obtained to determine the effectiveness of the freeway project. The average change in commute time is computed to - - ____ be y 􏱪 􏱦3.6, and the sample standard deviation is s 􏱪 32.7; thus, se(y) 􏱪 32.7/􏱯 900 􏱪 1.09. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 789 The t statistic is t 􏱪 􏱦3.6/1.09 􏱴 􏱦3.30, which is very statistically significant; the p-value is about .0005. Thus, we conclude that the freeway widening had a statistically significant effect on average commute time. If the outcome of the hypothesis test is all that were reported from the study, it would be misleading. Reporting only statistical significance masks the fact that the estimated re- duction in average commute time, 3.6 minutes, is pretty meager. To be up front, we should report the point estimate of 􏱦3.6, along with the significance test. Finding point estimates that are statistically significant without being practically sig- nificant can occur when we are working with large samples. To discuss why this happens, it is useful to have the following definition. Test Consistency. A consistent test rejects H0 with probability approaching one as the sample size grows whenever H1 is true. Another way to say that a test is consistent is that, as the sample size tends to infinity, the power of the test gets closer and closer to unity whenever H1 is true. All of the tests we cover in this text have this property. In the case of testing hypotheses about a population mean, test consistency follows because the variance of Y ̄ converges to zero as the sample ̄__ ̄ size gets large. The t statistic for testing H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0 is T 􏱪 Y/(S/􏱯 n ). Since plim(Y) 􏱪 􏱙 and plim(S) 􏱪 􏱧, it follows that if, say, 􏱙 􏱰 0, then T gets larger and larger (with high prob- ability) as n 􏱽 􏱵. In other words, no matter how close 􏱙 is to zero, we can be almost cer- tain to reject H0: 􏱙 􏱪 0 given a large enough sample size. This says nothing about whether 􏱙 is large in a practical sense. C.7 Remarks on Notation In our review of probability and statistics here and in Appendix B, we have been careful to use standard conventions to denote random variables, estimators, and test statistics. For example, we have used W to indicate an estimator (random variable) and w to denote a particular estimate (outcome of the random variable W ). Distinguishing between an esti- mator and an estimate is important for understanding various concepts in estimation and hypothesis testing. However, making this distinction quickly becomes a burden in econo- metric analysis because the models are more complicated: many random variables and parameters will be involved, and being true to the usual conventions from probability and statistics requires many extra symbols. In the main text, we use a simpler convention that is widely used in econometrics. If 􏰩 is a population parameter, the notation 􏰩ˆ (“theta hat”) will be used to denote both an estimator and an estimate of 􏰩. This notation is useful in that it provides a simple way of attaching an estima- tor to the population parameter it is supposed to be estimating. Thus, if the population param- eter is 􏱬, then 􏱬ˆ denotes an estimator or estimate of 􏱬; if the parameter is 􏱧2, 􏱧ˆ2 is an estimator or estimate of 􏱧2; and so on. Sometimes, we will discuss two estimators of the same parameter, in which case we will need a different notation, such as 􏰩 ̃ (“theta tilde”). Although dropping the conventions from probability and statistics to indicate estima- tors, random variables, and test statistics puts additional responsibility on you, it is not a big deal once the difference between an estimator and an estimate is understood. If we are discussing statistical properties of 􏰩ˆ—such as deriving whether or not it is unbiased or Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 790 APPENDICES consistent—then we are necessarily viewing 􏰩ˆ as an estimator. On the other hand, if we write something like 􏰩ˆ 􏱪 1.73, then we are clearly denoting a point estimate from a given sample of data. The confusion that can arise by using 􏰩ˆ to denote both should be minimal once you have a good understanding of probability and statistics. Summary We have discussed topics from mathematical statistics that are heavily relied upon in econometric analysis. The notion of an estimator, which is simply a rule for combining data to estimate a population parameter, is fundamental. We have covered various proper- ties of estimators. The most important small sample properties are unbiasedness and effi- ciency, the latter of which depends on comparing variances when estimators are unbiased. Large sample properties concern the sequence of estimators obtained as the sample size grows, and they are also depended upon in econometrics. Any useful estimator is consis- tent. The central limit theorem implies that, in large samples, the sampling distribution of most estimators is approximately normal. The sampling distribution of an estimator can be used to construct confidence intervals. We saw this for estimating the mean from a normal distribution and for computing approximate confi- dence intervals in nonnormal cases. Classical hypothesis testing, which requires specifying a null hypothesis, an alternative hypothesis, and a significance level, is carried out by comparing a test statistic to a critical value. Alternatively, a p-value can be computed that allows us to carry out a test at any significance level. Key Terms Alternative Hypothesis Asymptotic Normality Bias Biased Estimator Central Limit Theorem (CLT) Confidence Interval Consistent Estimator Consistent Test Critical Value Estimate Estimator Hypothesis Test Inconsistent Interval Estimator Law of Large Numbers (LLN) Least Squares Estimator Maximum Likelihood Estimator Mean Squared Error (MSE) Method of Moments Minimum Variance Unbiased Estimator Null Hypothesis One-Sided Alternative One-Tailed Test Population Power of a Test Practical Significance Probability Limit p-Value Random Sample Rejection Region Sample Average Sample Correlation Coefficient Sample Covariance Sample Standard Deviation Sample Variance Sampling Distribution Sampling Standard Deviation Sampling Variance Significance Level Standard Error Statistical Significance t Statistic Test Statistic Two-Sided Alternative Two-Tailed Test Type I Error Type II Error Unbiased Estimator Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Problems APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 791 1 Let Y1, Y2, Y3, and Y4 be independent, identically distributed random variables from a popu- lationwithmean􏱙andvariance􏱧2.LetY ̄􏱪1(Y 􏱕Y 􏱕Y 􏱕Y)denotetheaverageof 􏲊􏲊 1 2 3 4 these four random variables. 4 (i) What are the expected value and variance of Y ̄ in terms of 􏱙 and 􏱧2? (ii) Now, consider a different estimator of 􏱙: 1111 W􏱪􏲊􏲊Y1 􏱕􏲊􏲊Y2 􏱕􏲊􏲊Y3 􏱕􏲊􏲊Y4. 8842 This is an example of a weighted average of the Yi. Show that W is also an unbiased estimator of 􏱙. Find the variance of W. (iii) Based on your answers to parts (i) and (ii), which estimator of 􏱙 do you prefer, Y ̄ or W? 2 This is a more general version of Problem C.1. Let Y1, Y2, ..., Yn be n pairwise uncorrelated random variables with common mean 􏱙 and common variance 􏱧2. Let Y ̄ denote the sample average. (i) Define the class of linear estimators of 􏱙 by Wa 􏱪a1Y1 􏱕a2Y2 􏱕...􏱕anYn, where the ai are constants. What restriction on the ai is needed for Wa to be an unbiased estimator of 􏱙? (ii) Find Var(Wa). (iii) For any numbers a1, a2, ..., an, the following inequality holds: (a1 􏱕 a2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 an)2/n 􏰯 a21 􏱕 a2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 an2. Use this, along with parts (i) and (ii), to show that Var(Wa) 􏱸Var(Y ̄) whenever Wa is unbiased, so that Y ̄ is the best linear unbiased esti- mator. [Hint: What does the inequality become when the ai satisfy the restriction from part (i)?] 3 Let Y ̄ denote the sample average from a random sample with mean 􏱙 and variance 􏱧2. Consider two alternative estimators of 􏱙: W1 􏱪 [(n 􏱦 1)/n]Y ̄ and W2 􏱪Y ̄/2. (i) Show that W1 and W2 are both biased estimators of 􏱙 and find the biases. What hap- pens to the biases as n 􏱽 􏱵? Comment on any important differences in bias for the two estimators as the sample size gets large. (ii) Find the probability limits of W1 and W2. {Hint: Use Properties PLIM.1 and PLIM.2; for W1, note that plim [(n 􏱦 1)/n] 􏱪 1.} Which estimator is consistent? (iii) Find Var(W1) and Var(W2). ̄ (iv) Argue that W1 is a better estimator than Y if 􏱙 is “close” to zero. (Consider both bias and variance.) 4 For positive random variables X and Y, suppose the expected value of Y given X is E(Y􏰫X) 􏱪 􏰩X. The unknown parameter 􏰩 shows how the expected value of Y changes with X. (i) Define the random variable Z 􏱪 Y/X. Show that E(Z) 􏱪 􏰩. [Hint: Use Property CE.2 along with the law of iterated expectations, Property CE.4. In particular, first show that E(Z􏰫X) 􏱪 􏰩 and then use CE.4.] 􏰭 (ii) Use part (i) to prove that the estimator W1 􏱪 n􏱦1 n (Y /X ) is unbiased for 􏰩, where {(Xi,Yi): i 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n} is a random sample. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i􏱪1 i i 792 APPENDICES (iii) Explain why the estimator W2 􏱪 Y ̄/X ̄ , where the overbars denote sample averages, is not the same as W1. Nevertheless, show that W2 is also unbiased for 􏰩. (iv) The following table contains data on corn yields for several counties in Iowa. The USDA predicts the number of hectares of corn in each county based on satellite photos. Researchers count the number of “pixels” of corn in the satellite picture (as opposed to, for example, the number of pixels of soybeans or of uncultivated land) and use these to predict the actual number of hectares. To develop a prediction equation to be used for counties in general, the USDA surveyed farmers in selected counties to obtain corn yields in hectares. Let Yi 􏱪 corn yield in county i and let Xi 􏱪 number of corn pixels in the satellite picture for county i. There are n 􏱪 17 observations for eight counties. Use this sample to compute the estimates of 􏰩 devised in parts (ii) and (iii). Are the estimates similar? Plot Corn Yield Corn Pixels 1 165.76 374 2 96.32 209 3 76.08 253 4 185.35 432 5 116.43 367 6 162.08 361 7 152.04 288 8 161.75 369 9 92.88 206 10 149.94 316 11 64.75 145 12 127.07 355 13 133.55 295 14 77.70 223 15 206.39 459 16 108.33 290 17 118.17 307 5 Let Y denote a Bernoulli(􏰩) random variable with 0 􏱷 􏰩 􏱷 1. Suppose we are interested in estimating the odds ratio, 􏰸 􏱪 􏰩/(1 􏱦 􏰩), which is the probability of success over the probability of failure. Given a random sample {Y1, ..., Yn}, we know that an unbiased and consistent estimator of 􏰩 is Y ̄, the proportion of successes in n trials. A natural estimator of 􏰸 is G 􏱪 Y ̄/(1 􏱦 Y ̄), the proportion of successes over the proportion of failures in the sample. (i) Why is G not an unbiased estimator of 􏰸? (ii) Use PLIM.2(iii) to show that G is a consistent estimator of 􏰸. 6 Youarehiredbythegovernortostudywhetherataxonliquorhasdecreasedaverageliquor consumption in your state. You are able to obtain, for a sample of individuals selected at random, the difference in liquor consumption (in ounces) for the years before and after the Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 793 tax. For person i who is sampled randomly from the population, Yi denotes the change in liquor consumption. Treat these as a random sample from a Normal(􏱙,􏱧2) distribution. (i) The null hypothesis is that there was no change in average liquor consumption. State this formally in terms of 􏱙. (ii) The alternative is that there was a decline in liquor consumption; state the alternative in terms of 􏱙. - (iii) Now, suppose your sample size is n 􏱪 900 and you obtain the estimates y 􏱪 􏱦32.8 and s 􏱪 466.4. Calculate the t statistic for testing H0 against H1; obtain the p-value for the test. (Because of the large sample size, just use the standard normal distribution tabulated in Table G.1.) Do you reject H0 at the 5% level? At the 1% level? (iv) Would you say that the estimated fall in consumption is large in magnitude? Com- ment on the practical versus statistical significance of this estimate. (v) What has been implicitly assumed in your analysis about other determinants of liquor consumption over the two-year period in order to infer causality from the tax change to liquor consumption? 7 The new management at a bakery claims that workers are now more productive than they were under old management, which is why wages have “generally increased.” Let Wib be Worker i’s wage under the old management and let Wia be Worker i’s wage after the change. The difference is Di 􏱲 Wia 􏱦 Wib. Assume that the Di are a random sample from a Normal(􏱙,􏱧2) distribution. (i) Using the following data on 15 workers, construct an exact 95% confidence interval for 􏱙. (ii) Formally state the null hypothesis that there has been no change in average wages. In particular, what is E(Di) under H0? If you are hired to examine the validity of the new management’s claim, what is the relevant alternative hypothesis in terms of 􏱙 􏱪 E(Di)? (iii) Test the null hypothesis from part (ii) against the stated alternative at the 5% and 1% levels. (iv) Obtain the p-value for the test in part (iii). Worker Wage Before Wage After 1 8.30 9.25 2 9.40 9.00 3 9.00 9.25 4 10.50 10.00 5 11.40 12.00 6 8.75 9.50 7 10.00 10.25 8 9.50 9.50 9 10.80 11.50 10 12.55 13.10 11 12.00 11.50 12 8.65 9.00 13 7.75 7.75 14 11.25 11.50 15 12.65 13.00 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 794 APPENDICES 8 The New York Times (2/5/90) reported three-point shooting performance for the top 10 three-point shooters in the NBA. The following table summarizes these data: Player FGA-FGM Mark Price 429-188 Trent Tucker 833-345 Dale Ellis 1,149-472 Craig Hodges 1,016-396 Danny Ainge 1,051-406 Byron Scott 676-260 Reggie Miller 416-159 Larry Bird 1,206-455 Jon Sundvold 440-166 Brian Taylor 417-157 Note: FGA 􏱪 field goals attempted and FGM 􏱪 field goals made. For a given player, the outcome of a particular shot can be modeled as a Bernoulli (zero- one)variable:ifYi istheoutcomeofshoti,thenYi 􏱪1iftheshotismade,andYi 􏱪0if the shot is missed. Let 􏰩 denote the probability of making any particular three-point shot attempt. The natural estimator of 􏰩 is Y ̄ 􏱪 FGM/FGA. (i) Estimate 􏰩 for Mark Price. ̄ (ii) Find the standard deviation of the estimator Y in terms of 􏰩 and the number of shot attempts, n. ̄ ̄ ̄ (iii) The asymptotic distribution of (Y 􏱦 􏰩)/se(Y) is standard normal, where se(Y) 􏱪 _________ 􏱯Y ̄(1 􏱦 Y ̄)/n. Use this fact to test H0: 􏰩 􏱪 .5 against H1: 􏰩 􏱷 .5 for Mark Price. Use a 1% significance level. 9 Suppose that a military dictator in an unnamed country holds a plebiscite (a yes/no vote of confidence) and claims that he was supported by 65% of the voters. A human rights group suspects foul play and hires you to test the validity of the dictator’s claim. You have a bud- get that allows you to randomly sample 200 voters from the country. (i) Let X be the number of yes votes obtained from a random sample of 200 out of the entire voting population. What is the expected value of X if, in fact, 65% of all voters supported the dictator? (ii) What is the standard deviation of X, again assuming that the true fraction voting yes in the plebiscite is .65? (iii) Now, you collect your sample of 200, and you find that 115 people actually voted yes. Use the CLT to approximate the probability that you would find 115 or fewer yes votes from a random sample of 200 if, in fact, 65% of the entire popu- lation voted yes. (iv) How would you explain the relevance of the number in part (iii) to someone who does not have training in statistics? Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX C Fundamentals of Mathematical Statistics 795 10 Before a strike prematurely ended the 1994 major league baseball season, Tony Gwynn of the San Diego Padres had 165 hits in 419 at bats, for a .394 batting average. There was discussion about whether Gwynn was a potential .400 hitter that year. This issue can be couched in terms of Gwynn’s probability of getting a hit on a particular at bat, call it 􏰩. Let Yi be the Bernoulli(􏰩) indicator equal to unity if Gwynn gets a hit during his ith at bat, and zero otherwise. Then, Y1, Y2, ..., Yn is a random sample from a Bernoulli(􏰩) distribution, where 􏰩 is the probability of success, and n 􏱪 419. Our best point estimate of 􏰩 is Gwynn’s batting average, which is just the proportion - - _________ of successes: y 􏱪 .394. Using the fact that se(y) 􏱪 􏱯y ̄(1 􏱦 y ̄)/n, construct an approximate 95% confidence interval for 􏰩, using the standard normal distribution. Would you say there is strong evidence against Gwynn’s being a potential .400 hitter? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. a11 a12 a13 ... a1n aaa...a 􏱶21 22 23 2n 􏲄 A􏱪[aij]􏱪 . , where aij represents the element in the ith row and the jth column. For example, a25 stands for the number in the second row and the fifth column of A. A specific example of a 2 􏱶 3 matrix is A􏱪􏱶2 􏱦1 7􏲄, [D.1] 􏱦4 5 0 where a13 􏱪 7. The shorthand A 􏱪 [aij] is often used to define matrix operations. Definition D.2 (Square Matrix). A square matrix has the same number of rows and columns. The dimension of a square matrix is its number of rows and columns. APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra This appendix summarizes the matrix algebra concepts, including the algebra of probability, needed for the study of multiple linear regression models using matri- ces in Appendix E. None of this material is used in the main text. D.1 Basic Definitions Definition D.1 (Matrix). A matrix is a rectangular array of numbers. More precisely, an m 􏱶 n matrix has m rows and n columns. The positive integer m is called the row dimen- sion, and n is called the column dimension. We use uppercase boldface letters to denote matrices. We can write an m 􏱶 n matrix generically as am1 am2 am3 ... amn 796 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra 797 Definition D.3 (Vectors) (i) A 1 􏱶 m matrix is called a row vector (of dimension m) and can be written as x 􏱲 (x1, x2, ..., xm). (ii) An n 􏱶 1 matrix is called a column vector and can be written as y1 yn Definition D.4 (Diagonal Matrix). A square matrix A is a diagonal matrix when all of its off-diagonal elements are zero, that is, aij 􏱪 0 for all i 􏱻 j. We can always write a diagonal matrix as 􏱶a11 0 0 ... 0􏲄 0 a22 0 ... 0 A􏱪 . . 0 0 0 ... ann Definition D.5 (Identity and Zero Matrices) (i) The n 􏱶 n identity matrix, denoted I, or sometimes In to emphasize its dimension, is the diagonal matrix with unity (one) in each diagonal position, and zero elsewhere: y 􏱲 􏱶.2􏲄. . y 100...0 010...0 I􏱲In􏱲 . . 􏱶􏲄 000...1 (ii) The m 􏱶 n zero matrix, denoted 0, is the m 􏱶 n matrix with zero for all entries. This need not be a square matrix. D.2 Matrix Operations Matrix Addition Two matrices A and B, each having dimension m 􏱶 n, can be added element by element: A 􏱕 B 􏱪 [aij 􏱕 bij]. More precisely, 􏱶􏲄 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. a11 􏱕 b11 a12 􏱕 b12 . . . a1n 􏱕 b1n a21 􏱕 b21 a22 􏱕 b22 . . . a2n 􏱕 b2n A􏱕B􏱪 . . . am1 􏱕 bm1 am2 􏱕 bm2 . . . amn 􏱕 bmn 798 APPENDICES For example, ith row 􏱽 aikbkj 􏱶 2 􏱦1 7􏲄􏱕 􏱶1 0 􏱦4􏲄􏱪 􏱶3 􏱦1 3􏲄. 􏱦4 5 0 4 2 3 0 7 3 Matrices of different dimensions cannot be added. Scalar Multiplication Given any real number 􏰿 (often called a scalar), scalar multiplication is defined as 􏰿A 􏱲 [􏰿aij], or . . . ... 􏰿A 􏱪 . 􏰿am1 􏰿am2 ... 􏰿amn For example, if 􏰿 􏱪 2 and A is the matrix in equation (D.1), then 􏰿A􏱪􏱶4 􏱦2 14􏲄. 􏱦8 10 0 Matrix Multiplication To multiply matrix A by matrix B to form the product AB, the column dimension of A must equal the row dimension of B. Therefore, let A be an m 􏱶 n matrix and let B be an n 􏱶 p matrix. Then, matrix multiplication is defined as 􏰿a11 􏰿a12 􏱶􏰿a21 􏰿a22 􏰿a1n 􏰿a2n 􏲄 􏱶∑ 􏲄 k􏱪1 AB􏱪 ab. ik kj In other words, the (i,j)th element of the new matrix AB is obtained by multiplying each element in the ith row of A by the corresponding element in the jth column of B and adding these n products together. A schematic may help make this process more transparent: . bnj jth column (i,j)th element Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. n A B AB bn . k􏱪1 􏱶􏲄􏱶b1j 􏲄􏱶∑􏲄 2j ai1 ai2 ai3 . . . ain b3j 􏱪 , . APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra 799 where, by the definition of the summation operator in Appendix A, n ∑ab 􏱪ab 􏱕ab 􏱕...􏱕ab. ik kj i1 1j i2 2j in nj k􏱪1 For example, 􏱶2 􏱦1 0􏲄􏱶0 1 6 0􏲄􏱶1 0 12 􏱦1􏲄 􏱦4 1 0 􏱦1 2 0 1􏱪􏱦1􏱦2􏱦24 1. 3000 We can also multiply a matrix and a vector. If A is an n 􏱶 m matrix and y is an m 􏱶 1 vector, then Ay is an n 􏱶 1 vector. If x is a 1 􏱶 n vector, then xA is a 1 􏱶 m vector. Matrix addition, scalar multiplication, and matrix multiplication can be combined in various ways, and these operations satisfy several rules that are familiar from basic operations on numbers. In the following list of properties, A, B, and C are matrices with appropriate dimensions for applying each operation, and 􏱮 and 􏱬 are real numbers. Most of these properties are easy to illustrate from the definitions. Properties of Matrix Multiplication. (1) (􏱮 􏱕 􏱬)A 􏱪 􏱮A 􏱕 􏱬A; (2) 􏱮(A 􏱕 B) 􏱪 􏱮A 􏱕 􏱮B;(3)(􏱮􏱬)A􏱪􏱮(􏱬A);(4)􏱮(AB)􏱪(􏱮A)B;(5)A􏱕B􏱪B􏱕A;(6)(A􏱕B)􏱕C􏱪 A􏱕(B􏱕C);(7)(AB)C􏱪A(BC);(8)A(B􏱕C)􏱪AB􏱕AC;(9)(A􏱕B)C􏱪AC􏱕BC; (10) IA 􏱪 AI 􏱪 A; (11) A 􏱕 0 􏱪 0 􏱕 A 􏱪 A; (12) A 􏱦 A 􏱪 0; (13) A0 􏱪 0A 􏱪 0; and (14) AB 􏱻 BA, even when both products are defined. The last property deserves further comment. If A is n 􏱶 m and B is m 􏱶 p, then AB is defined, but BA is defined only if n 􏱪 p (the row dimension of A equals the column di- mension of B). If A is m 􏱶 n and B is n 􏱶 m, then AB and BA are both defined, but they are not usually the same; in fact, they have different dimensions, unless A and B are both square matrices. Even when A and B are both square, AB 􏱻 BA, except under special circumstances. Transpose Definition D.6 (Transpose). Let A 􏱪 [aij] be an m 􏱶 n matrix. The transpose of A, denoted A􏲃 (called A prime), is the n 􏱶 m matrix obtained by interchanging the rows and columns of A. We can write this as A􏲃 􏱲 [aji]. For example, 􏱶2 􏱦1 7􏲄 􏱶2 􏱦4􏲄 A􏱪 􏱦4 5 0 , A􏲃􏱪 􏱦1 5 . 70 Properties of Transpose. (1) (A􏲃)􏲃 􏱪 A; (2) (􏱮A)􏲃 􏱪 􏱮A􏲃 for any scalar 􏱮∑; (3) (A 􏱕 B)􏲃 􏱪 A􏲃􏱕 B􏲃; (4) (AB)􏲃 􏱪 B􏲃A􏲃, where A is m 􏱶 n and B is n 􏱶 k; (5) x􏲃x 􏱪 n x2, where i x is an n 􏱶 1 vector; and (6) If A is an n 􏱶 k matrix with rows given by the 1 􏱶 k vectors a1, a2, ..., an, so that we can write Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. i􏱪1 800 APPENDICES i􏱪1 matrices, each of which is k 􏱶 m. As a special case, we have a1 A􏱪 . , an A􏲃B 􏱪 bn a􏲃b , . 􏱶a2 􏲄 then A􏲃 􏱪 (a􏲃1 a􏲃2 . . . a􏲃n). Definition D.7 (Symmetric Matrix). A square matrix A is a symmetric matrix if, and only if, A􏲃 􏱪 A. If X is any n 􏱶 k matrix, then X􏲃X is always defined and is a symmetric matrix, as can be seen by applying the first and fourth transpose properties (see Problem 3). Partitioned Matrix Multiplication Let A be an n 􏱶 k matrix with rows given by the 1 􏱶 k vectors a1, a2, ..., an, and let B be an n 􏱶 m matrix with rows given by 1 􏱶 m vectors b1, b2, ..., bn: Then, where for each i, a􏲃i bi is a k 􏱶 m matrix. Therefore, A􏲃B can be written as the sum of n an a1 b1 􏱶􏲄 􏱶􏲄 a2 b2 A􏱪 . ,B􏱪 . . .. ∑n ii ∑n ii A􏲃A 􏱪 where a􏲃i ai is a k 􏱶 k matrix for all i. Trace The trace of a matrix is a very simple operation defined only for square matrices. Definition D.8 (Trace). For any n 􏱶 n matrix A, the trace of a matrix A, denoted tr(A), is the sum of its diagonal elements. Mathematically, ∑n ii i􏱪1 Properties of Trace. (1) tr(In) 􏱪 n; (2) tr(A􏲃) 􏱪 tr(A); (3) tr(A 􏱕 B) 􏱪 tr(A) 􏱕 tr(B); (4) tr(􏱮A) 􏱪 􏱮tr(A), for any scalar 􏱮; and (5) tr(AB) 􏱪 tr(BA), where A is m 􏱶 n and B is n 􏱶 m. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. tr(A) 􏱪 a . i􏱪1 a􏲃a , APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra 801 Inverse The notion of a matrix inverse is very important for square matrices. Definition D.9 (Inverse). An n 􏱶 n matrix A has an inverse, denoted A􏱦1, provided that A􏱦1A 􏱪 In and AA􏱦1 􏱪 In. In this case, A is said to be invertible or nonsingular. Other- wise, it is said to be noninvertible or singular. Properties of Inverse. (1) If an inverse exists, it is unique; (2) (􏱮A)􏱦1 􏱪 (1/􏱮)A􏱦1, if 􏱮 􏱻 0 and A is invertible; (3) (AB)􏱦1 􏱪 B􏱦1A􏱦1, if A and B are both n 􏱶 n and invertible; and (4) (A􏲃)􏱦1 􏱪 (A􏱦1)􏲃. We will not be concerned with the mechanics of calculating the inverse of a matrix. Any matrix algebra text contains detailed examples of such calculations. D.3 Linear Independence and Rank of a Matrix For a set of vectors having the same dimension, it is important to know whether one vector can be expressed as a linear combination of the remaining vectors. Definition D.10 (Linear Independence). Let {x1, x2, ..., xr} be a set of n 􏱶 1 vectors. These are linearly independent vectors if, and only if, 􏱮1x1 􏱕􏱮2x2 􏱕...􏱕􏱮rxr 􏱪0 [D.2] impliesthat􏱮1 􏱪􏱮2 􏱪...􏱪􏱮r 􏱪0.If(D.2)holdsforasetofscalarsthatarenotallzero, then {x1, x2, ..., xr} is linearly dependent. The statement that {x1, x2, ..., xr} is linearly dependent is equivalent to saying that at least one vector in this set can be written as a linear combination of the others. Definition D.11 (Rank) (i) Let A be an n 􏱶 m matrix. The rank of a matrix A, denoted rank(A), is the maxi- mum number of linearly independent columns of A. (ii) If A is n 􏱶 m and rank(A) 􏱪 m, then A has full column rank. If A is n 􏱶 m, its rank can be at most m. A matrix has full column rank if its columns form a linearly independent set. For example, the 3 􏱶 2 matrix 26 can have at most rank two. In fact, its rank is only one because the second column is three times the first column. Properties of Rank. (1) rank(A􏲃) 􏱪 rank(A); (2) If A is n 􏱶 k, then rank(A) 􏰯 min(n,k); and (3) If A is k 􏱶 k and rank(A) 􏱪 k, then A is invertible. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱶1 3􏲄 00 802 APPENDICES D.4 Quadratic Forms and Positive Definite Matrices Definition D.12 (Quadratic Form). Let A be an n 􏱶 n symmetric matrix. The quadratic form associated with the matrix A is the real-valued function defined for all n 􏱶 1 vectors x: ∑n n ∑∑ i􏱪1 i􏱪1 j􏱰1 f(x) 􏱪 x􏲃Ax 􏱪 Definition D.13 (Positive Definite and Positive Semi-Definite) (i) A symmetric matrix A is said to be positive definite (p.d.) if x􏲃Ax 􏱰 0 for all n 􏱶 1 vectors x except x 􏱪 0. (ii) A symmetric matrix A is positive semi-definite (p.s.d.) if x􏲃Ax 􏱸 0 for all n 􏱶 1 vectors. If a matrix is positive definite or positive semi-definite, it is automatically assumed to be symmetric. Properties of Positive Definite and Positive Semi-Definite Matrices. (1) A positive definite matrix has diagonal elements that are strictly positive, while a p.s.d. matrix has nonnegative diagonal elements; (2) If A is p.d., then A􏱦1 exists and is p.d.; (3) If X is n 􏱶 k, then X􏲃X and XX􏲃 are p.s.d.; and (4) If X is n 􏱶 k and rank(X) 􏱪 k, then X􏲃X is p.d. (and therefore nonsingular). D.5 Idempotent Matrices Definition D.14 (Idempotent Matrix). Let A be an n 􏱶 n symmetric matrix. Then A is said to be an idempotent matrix if, and only if, AA 􏱪 A. For example, 􏱶1 0 0􏲄 000 001 is an idempotent matrix, as direct multiplication verifies. PropertiesofIdempotentMatrices. LetAbeann􏱶nidempotentmatrix.(1)rank(A)􏱪 tr(A), and (2) A is positive semi-definite. We can construct idempotent matrices very generally. Let X be an n 􏱶 k matrix with rank(X) 􏱪 k. Define P 􏱲 X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃 M􏱲In 􏱦X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃􏱪In 􏱦P. Then P and M are symmetric, idempotent matrices with rank(P) 􏱪 k and rank(M) 􏱪 n 􏱦 k. The ranks are most easily obtained by using Property 1: tr(P) 􏱪 tr[(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃X] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. a x2 􏱕 2 ii i a x x . ij i j APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra 803 (from Property 5 for trace) 􏱪 tr(Ik) 􏱪 k (by Property 1 for trace). It easily follows that tr(M) 􏱪 tr(In) 􏱦 tr(P) 􏱪 n 􏱦 k. D.6 Differentiation of Linear and Quadratic Forms For a given n 􏱶 1 vector a, consider the linear function defined by f(x) 􏱪 a􏲃x, for all n 􏱶 1 vectors x. The derivative of f with respect to x is the 1 􏱶 n vector of partial Then, which is a 1 􏱶 n vector. D.7 Moments and Distributions of Random Vectors In order to derive the expected value and variance of the OLS estimators using matrices, we need to define the expected value and variance of a random vector. As its name sug- gests, a random vector is simply a vector of random variables. We also need to define the multivariate normal distribution. These concepts are simply extensions of those covered in Appendix B. Expected Value Definition D.15 (Expected Value) (i) If y is an n 􏱶 1 random vector, the expected value of y, denoted E( y), is the vector of expected values: E( y) 􏱪 [E(y1), E(y2), ..., E(yn)]􏲃. (ii) If Z is an n 􏱶 m random matrix, E(Z) is the n 􏱶 m matrix of expected values: E(Z) 􏱪 [E(zij)]. Properties of Expected Value. (1) If A is an m 􏱶 n matrix and b is an n 􏱶 1 vector, where both are nonrandom, then E(Ay 􏱕 b) 􏱪 AE( y) 􏱕 b; and (2) If A is p 􏱶 n and B is m 􏱶 k, where both are nonrandom, then E(AZB) 􏱪 AE(Z)B. Variance-Covariance Matrix Definition D.16 (Variance-Covariance Matrix). If y is an n 􏱶 1 random vector, its variance-covariance matrix, denoted Var( y), is defined as Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. derivatives, which is simply For an n 􏱶 n symmetric matrix A, define the quadratic form 􏲌f(x)/􏲌x 􏱪 a􏲃. g(x) 􏱪 x􏲃Ax. 􏲌g(x)/􏲌x 􏱪 2x􏲃A, 804 APPENDICES Var( y) 􏱪 􏱶􏱧21 . . 􏱧 n 1 􏱧2 􏱧 n 2 . . . . . . 􏱧2n 􏲄 , 􏱧 2n 􏱧21 􏱧12 ... 􏱧1n where 􏱧j2 􏱪 Var(yj) and 􏱧ij 􏱪 Cov(yi,yj). In other words, the variance-covariance ma- trix has the variances of each element of y down its diagonal, with covariance terms in the off diagonals. Because Cov(yi,yj) 􏱪 Cov(yj,yi), it immediately follows that a variance- covariance matrix is symmetric. Properties of Variance. (1) If a is an n 􏱶 1 nonrandom vector, then Var(a􏲃y) 􏱪 a􏲃[Var(y)]a 􏱸 0; (2) If Var(a􏲃y) 􏱰 0 for all a 􏱻 0, Var( y) is positive definite; (3) Var( y) 􏱪 E[( y 􏱦 􏱙)( y 􏱦 􏱙)􏲃], where 􏱙 􏱪 E( y); (4) If the elements of y are uncorrelated, Var( y) is a diagonal matrix. If, in addition, Var(yj) 􏱪 􏱧2 for j 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, then Var(y) 􏱪 􏱧2In; and (5) If A is an m 􏱶 n nonrandom matrix and b is an n 􏱶 1 nonrandom vector, then Var(Ay 􏱕 b) 􏱪 A[Var(y)]A􏲃. Multivariate Normal Distribution The normal distribution for a random variable was discussed at some length in Appendix B. We need to extend the normal distribution to random vectors. We will not provide an expression for the probability distribution function, as we do not need it. It is important to know that a multivariate normal random vector is completely characterized by its mean and its variance-covariance matrix. Therefore, if y is an n 􏱶 1 multivariate normal random vector with mean 􏱙 and variance-covariance matrix 􏱥, we write y ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱥). We now state several useful properties of the multivariate normal distribution. Properties of the Multivariate Normal Distribution. (1) If y ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱥), then each element of y is normally distributed; (2) If y ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱥), then yi and yj, any two elements of y, are independent if, and only if, they are uncorrelated, that is, 􏱧ij 􏱪 0; (3) If y ~ Normal(􏱙,􏱥), then Ay 􏱕 b ~ Normal(A􏱙 􏱕 b,A􏱥A􏲃), where A and b are non- random; (4) If y ~ Normal(0,􏱥), then, for nonrandom matrices A and B, Ay and By are independent if, and only if, A􏱥B􏲃 􏱪 0. In particular, if 􏱥 􏱪 􏱧2In, then AB􏲃 􏱪 0 is neces- sary and sufficient for independence of Ay and By; (5) If y ~ Normal(0,􏱧2In), A is a k 􏱶 n nonrandom matrix, and B is an n 􏱶 n symmetric, idempotent matrix, then Ay and y􏲃By are independent if, and only if, AB 􏱪 0; and (6) If y ~ Normal(0,􏱧2In) and A and B are nonrandom symmetric, idempotent matrices, then y􏲃Ay and y􏲃By are independent if, and only if, AB 􏱪 0. Chi-Square Distribution In Appendix B, we defined a chi-square random variable as the sum of squared inde- pendent standard normal random variables. In vector notation, if u ~ Normal(0,In), then u􏲃u ~ 􏱚n2. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX D Summary of Matrix Algebra 805 Properties of the Chi-Square Distribution. (1) If u ~ Normal(0,In) and A is an n 􏱶 n symmetric, idempotent matrix with rank(A) 􏱪 q, then u􏲃Au ~ 􏱚q2; (2) If u ~ Normal(0,In) and A and B are n 􏱶 n symmetric, idempotent matrices such that AB 􏱪 0, then u􏲃Au and u􏲃Bu are independent, chi-square random variables; and (3) If z ~ Normal(0,C) where C is an m 􏱶 m nonsingular matrix, then z􏲃C􏱦1z ~ 􏱚m2 . t Distribution We also defined the t distribution in Appendix B. Now we add an important property. Property of the t Distribution. If u ~ Normal(0,In), c is an n 􏱶 1 nonrandom vector, A is a nonrandom n 􏱶 n symmetric, idempotent matrix with rank q, and Ac 􏱪 0, then {c􏲃u/ (c􏲃c)1/2}/(u􏲃Au/q)1/2 ~ tq. F Distribution Recall that an F random variable is obtained by taking two independent chi-square random variables and finding the ratio of each, standardized by degrees of freedom. Property of the F Distribution. If u ~ Normal(0,In) and A and B are n 􏱶 n nonran- dom symmetric, idempotent matrices with rank(A) 􏱪 k1, rank(B) 􏱪 k2, and AB 􏱪 0, then (u􏲃Au/k1)/(u􏲃Bu/k2) ~ Fk1,k2. Summary This appendix contains a condensed form of the background information needed to study the classical linear model using matrices. Although the material here is self-contained, it is pri- marily intended as a review for readers who are familiar with matrix algebra and multivariate statistics, and it will be used extensively in Appendix E. Key Terms Chi-Square Random Variable Column Vector Diagonal Matrix Expected Value F Random Variable Idempotent Matrix Identity Matrix Inverse Linearly Independent Vectors Matrix Matrix Multiplication Multivariate Normal Distribution Positive Definite (p.d.) Positive Semi-Definite (p.s.d.) Quadratic Form Random Vector Rank of a Matrix Row Vector Scalar Multiplication Square Matrix Symmetric Matrix t Distribution Trace of a Matrix Transpose Variance-Covariance Matrix Zero Matrix Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 806 APPENDICES Problems 1 i(i) Find the product AB using 􏱶2 􏱦1 7􏲄 􏱶0 1 6􏲄 A􏱪􏱦4 5 0,B􏱪1 8 0. 300 (ii) DoesBAexist? 2 If A and B are n 􏱶 n diagonal matrices, show that AB 􏱪 BA. 3 Let X be any n 􏱶 k matrix. Show that X􏲃X is a symmetric matrix. Use the properties of trace to argue that tr(A􏲃A) 􏱪 tr(AA􏲃) for any n 􏱶 m matrix A. 030 4 (i)i (ii) For A 􏱪 􏱶2 0 􏱦1􏲄, verify that tr(A􏲃A) 􏱪 tr(AA􏲃). Use the definition of inverse to prove the following: if A and B are n 􏱶 n nonsingular matrices, then (AB)􏱦1 􏱪 B􏱦1A􏱦1. 5 (i)i (ii) If A, B, and C are all n 􏱶 n nonsingular matrices, find (ABC)􏱦1 in terms of A􏱦1, B􏱦1, and C􏱦1. Show that if A is an n 􏱶 n symmetric, positive definite matrix, then A must have strictly positive diagonal elements. 6 (i)i (ii) Write down a 2 􏱶 2 symmetric matrix with strictly positive diagonal elements that is not positive definite. A be an n 􏱶 n symmetric, positive definite matrix. Show that if P is any n 􏱶 n nonsin- 7 Let gular matrix, then P􏲃AP is positive definite. 8 Prove Property 5 of variances for vectors, using Property 3. 9 Letabeann􏱶1nonrandomvectorandletubeann􏱶1randomvectorwith E(uu􏲃) 􏱪 In. Show that E[tr(auu􏲃a􏲃)] 􏱪 􏰭ni􏱪1 a2i · 10 Takeasgiventhepropertiesofthechi-squaredistributionlistedinthetext.Showhowthose properties, along with the definition of an F random variable, imply the stated property of the F distribution (concerning ratios of quadratic forms). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form This appendix derives various results for ordinary least squares estimation of the multiple linear regression model using matrix notation and matrix algebra (see Appendix D for a summary). The material presented here is much more advanced than that in the text. E.1 The Model and Ordinary Least Squares Estimation Throughout this appendix, we use the t subscript to index observations and an n to denote the sample size. It is useful to write the multiple linear regression model with k parameters as follows: yt 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1xt1 􏱕 􏱬2xt2 􏱕 ... 􏱕 􏱬k xtk 􏱕 ut, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, [E.1] where yt is the dependent variable for observation t, and xtj, j 􏱪 1, 2, ..., k, are the indepen- dent variables. As usual, 􏱬0 is the intercept and 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k denote the slope parameters. Foreacht,definea1􏱶(k􏱕1)vector,xt 􏱪(1,xt1,...,xtk),andlet􏱬􏱪(􏱬0,􏱬1,..., 􏱬k)􏲃 be the (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector of all parameters. Then, we can write (E.1) as yt 􏱪 xt 􏱬 􏱕 ut, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. [E.2] [Some authors prefer to define xt as a column vector, in which case xt is replaced with xt􏲃 in (E.2). Mathematically, it makes more sense to define it as a row vector.] We can write (E.2) in full matrix notation by appropriately defining data vectors and matrices. Let y denote the n 􏱶 1 vector of observations on y: the tth element of y is yt. Let X be the n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) vector of observations on the explanatory variables. In other words, the tth row of X consists of the vector xt. Written out in detail, 807 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. x1 1 x11 x12 ... x1k x1xx...x 􏱶2􏲄􏱶 21 22 2k􏲄 X 􏱲.􏱪. . n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) . xn 1 xn1 xn2 ... xnk . 808 APPENDICES Finally, let u be the n 􏱶 1 vector of unobservable errors or disturbances. Then, we can write (E.2) for all n observations in matrix notation: y 􏱪 X􏱬 􏱕 u. [E.3] Remember, because X is n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) and 􏱬 is (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1, X􏱬 is n 􏱶 1. Estimation of 􏱬 proceeds by minimizing the sum of squared residuals, as in Section 3.2. Define the sum of squared residuals function for any possible (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 parameter vector b as ∂SSR(􏱬ˆ)/∂b 􏱲 0. [E.4] Using the fact that the derivative of ( yt 􏱦 xtb)2 with respect to b is the 1 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) vector 􏱦2( yt 􏱦 xtb)xt, (E.4) is equivalent to ∑n ˆ x􏲃t(yt 􏱦xt􏱬)􏱲0. [E.5] t􏱪1 (We have divided by 􏱦2 and taken the transpose.) We can write this first order condition as ∑n ˆˆ ˆ (yt 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xt1 􏱦...􏱦􏱬kxtk)􏱪0 SSR(b)􏱲 (y 􏱦xb)2. 􏱬ˆ to minimize the sum of squared residuals, it must solve the first order condition t􏱪1 ∑n ˆˆ ˆ ∑n tt t􏱪1 The (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector of ordinary least squares estimates, 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 (􏱬ˆ0, 􏱬ˆ1, ..., 􏱬ˆk)􏲃, minimizes SSR(b) over all possible (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vectors b. This is a problem in multivariable calculus. For xt1(yt 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xt1 􏱦...􏱦􏱬kxtk)􏱪0 t􏱪1 . . . ∑n ˆˆ ˆ xtk(yt 􏱦􏱬0 􏱦􏱬1xt1 􏱦...􏱦􏱬kxtk)􏱪0, t􏱪1 which is identical to the first order conditions in equation (3.13). We want to write these in matrix form to make them easier to manipulate. Using the formula for partitioned multiplication in Appendix D, we see that (E.5) is equivalent to or X􏲃(y 􏱦 X􏱬ˆ) 􏱪 0 [E.6] (X􏲃X)􏱬ˆ 􏱪 X􏲃y. [E.7] It can be shown that (E.7) always has at least one solution. Multiple solutions do not help us, as we are looking for a unique set of OLS estimates given our data set. Assuming that the (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) symmetric matrix X􏲃X is nonsingular, we can premultiply both sides of (E.7) by (X􏲃X)􏱦1 to solve for the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ: 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃y. [E.8] Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 809 This is the critical formula for matrix analysis of the multiple linear regression model. The assumption that X􏲃X is invertible is equivalent to the assumption that rank(X) 􏱪 (k 􏱕 1), which means that the columns of X must be linearly independent. This is the ma- trix version of MLR.3 in Chapter 3. Before we continue, (E.8) warrants a word of warning. It is tempting to simplify the formula for 􏱬ˆ as follows: 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃y 􏱪 X􏱦1(X􏲃)􏱦1X􏲃y 􏱪 X􏱦1y. The flaw in this reasoning is that X is usually not a square matrix, so it cannot be inverted. In other words, we cannot write (X􏲃X)􏱦1 􏱪 X􏱦1(X􏲃)􏱦1 unless n 􏱪 (k 􏱕 1), a case that vir- tually never arises in practice. The n 􏱶 1 vectors of OLS fitted values and residuals are given by ˆy 􏱪 X􏱬ˆ, uˆ 􏱪 y 􏱦 ˆy 􏱪 y 􏱦 X􏱬ˆ, respectively. From (E.6) and the definition of ˆu, we can see that the first order condition for 􏱬ˆ is the same as X􏲃ˆu 􏱪 0. [E.9] Because the first column of X consists entirely of ones, (E.9) implies that the OLS re- siduals always sum to zero when an intercept is included in the equation and that the sample covariance between each independent variable and the OLS residuals is zero. (We discussed both of these properties in Chapter 3.) The sum of squared residuals can be written as ∑n ˆˆ SSR 􏱪 uˆt2 􏱪 ˆu􏲃ˆu 􏱪 (y 􏱦 X􏱬)􏲃(y 􏱦 X􏱬). [E.10] t􏱪1 All of the algebraic properties from Chapter 3 can be derived using matrix algebra. For ex- ample, we can show that the total sum of squares is equal to the explained sum of squares plus the sum of squared residuals [see (3.27)]. The use of matrices does not provide a sim- pler proof than summation notation, so we do not provide another derivation. The matrix approach to multiple regression can be used as the basis for a geometrical interpretation of regression. This involves mathematical concepts that are even more ad- vanced than those we covered in Appendix D. [See Goldberger (1991) or Greene (1997).] E.2 Finite Sample Properties of OLS Deriving the expected value and variance of the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ is facilitated by matrix algebra, but we must show some care in stating the assumptions. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Assumption E.1 Linear in Parameters The model can be written as in (E.3), where y is an observed n 􏱶 1 vector, X is an n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) observed matrix, and u is an n 􏱶 1 vector of unobserved errors or disturbances. 810 APPENDICES Assumption E.2 No Perfect Collinearity The matrix X has rank (k 􏱕 1). This is a careful statement of the assumption that rules out linear dependencies among the explanatory variables. Under Assumption E.2, X􏲃X is nonsingular, so 􏱬ˆ is unique and can be written as in (E.8). In vector form, Assumption E.3 can be written as E(u􏰫X) 􏱪 0. [E.11] This assumption is implied by MLR.4 under the random sampling assumption, MLR.2. In time series applications, Assumption E.3 imposes strict exogeneity on the explana- tory variables, something discussed at length in Chapter 10. This rules out explanatory variables whose future values are correlated with ut; in particular, it eliminates lagged dependent variables. Under Assumption E.3, we can condition on the xtj when we compute the expected value of 􏱬ˆ. Assumption E.3 Zero Conditional Mean Conditional on the entire matrix X, each error ut has zero mean: E(ut􏰫X) 􏱪 0, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. THEOREM E.1 UNBIASEDNESS OF OLS Under Assumptions E.1, E.2, and E.3, the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ is unbiased for 􏱬. PROOF: Use Assumptions E.1 and E.2 and simple algebra to write 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃y 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃(X􏱬 􏱕 u) 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1(X􏲃X)􏱬 􏱕 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃u 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃u, [E.12] where we use the fact that (X􏲃X)􏱦1(X􏲃X) 􏱪 Ik 􏱕 1. Taking the expectation conditional on X gives E(􏱬ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃E(u􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃0 􏱪 􏱬, because E(u􏰫X) 􏱪 0 under Assumption E.3. This argument clearly does not depend on the value of 􏱬, so we have shown that 􏱬ˆ is unbiased. To obtain the simplest form of the variance-covariance matrix of 􏱬ˆ, we impose the assumptions of homoskedasticity and no serial correlation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 811 Assumption E.4 Homoskedasticity and No Serial Correlation (i) Var(ut􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. (ii) Cov(ut,us􏰫X) 􏱪 0, for all t 􏱻 s. In matrix form, we can write these two assumptions as where In is the n 􏱶 n identity matrix. Var(u􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2In, [E.13] Part (i) of Assumption E.4 is the homoskedasticity assumption: the variance of ut cannot depend on any element of X, and the variance must be constant across observations, t. Part (ii) is the no serial correlation assumption: the errors cannot be correlated across observa- tions. Under random sampling, and in any other cross-sectional sampling schemes with independent observations, part (ii) of Assumption E.4 automatically holds. For time series applications, part (ii) rules out correlation in the errors over time (both conditional on X and unconditionally). Because of (E.13), we often say that u has a scalar variance-covariance matrix when Assumption E.4 holds. We can now derive the variance-covariance matrix of the OLS estimator. THEOREM E.2 VARIANCE-COVARIANCE MATRIX OF THE OLS ESTIMATOR Under Assumptions E.1 through E.4, Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2(X􏲃X)􏱦1. PROOF: From the last formula in equation (E.12), we have Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 Var[(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃u􏰫X] 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃[Var(u􏰫X)]X(X􏲃X)􏱦1. Now, we use Assumption E.4 to get Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃(􏱧2In)X(X􏲃X)􏱦1 􏱪 􏱧2(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃X(X􏲃X)􏱦1 􏱪 􏱧2(X􏲃X)􏱦1. [E.14] Formula (E.14) means that the variance of 􏱬ˆj (conditional on X) is obtained by multiply- ing 􏱧2 by the jth diagonal element of (X􏲃X)􏱦1. For the slope coefficients, we gave an interpretable formula in equation (3.51). Equation (E.14) also tells us how to obtain the covariance between any two OLS estimates: multiply 􏱧2 by the appropriate off-diagonal element of (X􏲃X)􏱦1. In Chapter 4, we showed how to avoid explicitly finding covari- ances for obtaining confidence intervals and hypothesis tests by appropriately rewriting the model. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 812 APPENDICES The Gauss-Markov Theorem, in its full generality, can be proven. THEOREM E.3 GAUSS-MARKOV THEOREM Under Assumptions E.1 through E.4, 􏱬ˆ is the best linear unbiased estimator. PROOF: Any other linear estimator of 􏱬 can be written as 􏱬 ̃ 􏱪 A􏲃y, [E.15] where A is an n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix. In order for 􏱬 ̃ to be unbiased conditional on X, A can consist of nonrandom numbers and functions of X. (For example, A cannot be a function of y.) To see what further restrictions on A are needed, write Then, 􏱬 ̃ 􏱪 A 􏲃 ( X 􏱬 􏱕 u ) 􏱪 ( A 􏲃 X ) 􏱬 􏱕 A 􏲃 u . [E.16] E(􏱬 ̃ 􏰫X) 􏱪 A􏲃X􏱬 􏱕 E(A􏲃u􏰫X) 􏱪 A􏲃X􏱬 􏱕 A􏲃E(u􏰫X) because A is a function of X 􏱪 A􏲃X􏱬 because E(u􏰫X) 􏱪 0. For 􏱬 ̃ to be an unbiased estimator of 􏱬, it must be true that E(􏱬 ̃􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱬 for all (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vectors 􏱬, that is, A􏲃X􏱬 􏱪 􏱬 for all (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vectors 􏱬. [E.17] Because A􏲃X is a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix, (E.17) holds if, and only if, A􏲃X 􏱪 Ik 􏱕 1. Equations (E.15) and (E.17) characterize the class of linear, unbiased estimators for 􏱬. Next, from (E.16), we have Var( 􏱬 ̃ 􏰫X) 􏱪 A􏲃[Var(u􏰫X)]A 􏱪 􏱧2A􏲃A, by Assumption E.4. Therefore, Var(􏱬 ̃ 􏰫X) 􏱦 Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2[A􏲃A 􏱦 (X􏲃X)􏱦1] 􏱪 􏱧2[A􏲃A 􏱦 A􏲃X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃A] because A􏲃X 􏱪 Ik 􏱕 1 􏱪 􏱧2A􏲃[In 􏱦 X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃]A 􏱲 􏱧2A􏲃MA, where M 􏱲 In 􏱦 X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃. Because M is symmetric and idempotent, A􏲃MA is positive semi-definite for any n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix A. This establishes that the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ is BLUE. Why is this important? Let c be any (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector and consider the linear combination c􏲃􏱬 􏱪 c0 􏱬0 􏱕 c1􏱬1 􏱕 ... 􏱕 ck 􏱬k, which is a scalar. The unbiased estimators of c􏲃􏱬 are c􏲃􏱬ˆ and c􏲃􏱬 ̃. But Var(c􏲃􏱬 ̃􏰫X) 􏱦 Var(c􏲃􏱬ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 c􏲃[Var(􏱬 ̃􏰫X) 􏱦 Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X)]c 􏱸 0, because [Var(􏱬 ̃􏰫X) 􏱦 Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X)] is p.s.d. Therefore, when it is used for estimating any linear combination of 􏱬, OLS yields the smallest variance. In particular, Var(􏱬ˆj􏰫X) 􏰯 Var(􏱬 ̃j􏰫X) for any other linear, unbiased estimator of 􏱬j. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 813 The unbiased estimator of the error variance 􏱧2 can be written as 􏱧ˆ2 􏱪uˆ􏲃uˆ/(n􏱦k􏱦1), which is the same as equation (3.56). THEOREM E.4 UNBIASEDNESS OF 􏰴2 Under Assumptions E.1 through E.4, 􏱧ˆ2 is unbiased for 􏱧2: E(􏱧ˆ2􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱧2 for all 􏱧2 􏱰 0. PROOF: Write uˆ 􏱪 y 􏱦 X􏱬ˆ 􏱪 y 􏱦 X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃y 􏱪 My 􏱪 Mu, where M 􏱪 In 􏱦 X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃, and the last equality follows because MX 􏱪 0. Because M is symmetric and idempotent, uˆ􏲃uˆ 􏱪 u􏲃M􏲃Mu 􏱪 u􏲃Mu. Because u􏲃Mu is a scalar, it equals its trace. Therefore, E(u􏲃Mu􏰫X) 􏱪 E[tr(u􏲃Mu)􏰫X] 􏱪 E[tr(Muu􏲃)􏰫X] 􏱪 tr[E(Muu􏲃|X)] 􏱪 tr[ME(uu􏲃|X)] 􏱪 tr(M􏱧2In) 􏱪 􏱧2tr(M) 􏱪 􏱧2(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1). The last equality follows from tr(M) 􏱪 tr(In) 􏱦 tr[X(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃] 􏱪 n 􏱦 tr[(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃X] 􏱪 n 􏱦 tr (Ik 􏱕 1) 􏱪 n 􏱦 (k 􏱕 1)􏱪 n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1. Therefore, E(􏱧ˆ2􏰫X) 􏱪 E(u􏲃Mu􏰫X)/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) 􏱪 􏱧2. E.3 Statistical Inference When we add the final classical linear model assumption, 􏱬ˆ has a multivariate normal distribution, which leads to the t and F distributions for the standard test statistics covered in Chapter 4. Assumption E.5 Normality of Errors Conditional on X, the ut are independent and identically distributed as Normal(0, 􏱧2). Equivalently, u given X is distributed as multivariate normal with mean zero and variance- covariance matrix 􏱧2In: u ~ Normal(0,􏱧2In). Under Assumption E.5, each ut is independent of the explanatory variables for all t. In a time series setting, this is essentially the strict exogeneity assumption. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 814 APPENDICES THEOREM E.5 NORMALITY OF 􏱬 Under the classical linear model Assumptions E.1 through E.5, 􏱬ˆ conditional on X is distributed as multivariate normal with mean 􏱬 and variance-covariance matrix 􏱧2(X􏲃X)􏱦1. Theorem E.5 is the basis for statistical inference involving 􏱬. In fact, along with the prop- erties of the chi-square, t, and F distributions that we summarized in Appendix D, we can use Theorem E.5 to establish that t statistics have a t distribution under Assumptions E.1 through E.5 (under the null hypothesis) and likewise for F statistics. We illustrate with a proof for the t statistics. THEOREM E.6 DISTRIBUTION OF t STATISTIC Under Assumptions E.1 through E.5, (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) ~ tn 􏱦 k 􏱦 1, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k. PROOF: The proof requires several steps; the following statements are initially conditional on ˆˆ ˆ__th X. First, by Theorem E.5, (􏱬j 􏱦 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬j) ~ Normal(0,1), where sd(􏱬j) 􏱪 􏱧􏱯cjj, and cjj is the j diagonal element of (X􏲃X)􏱦1. Next, under Assumptions E.1 through E.5, conditional on X, (n􏱦k􏱦1)􏱧ˆ2/􏱧2 ~􏱚2n􏱦k􏱦1. [E.18] This follows because (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)􏱧ˆ2/􏱧2 􏱪 (u/􏱧)􏲃M(u/􏱧), where M is the n 􏱶 n symmetric, idempotent matrix defined in Theorem E.4. But u/􏱧 ~ Normal(0,In) by Assumption E.5. It follows from Property 1 for the chi-square distribution in Appendix D that (u/􏱧)􏲃M(u/􏱧) ~ 􏱚n2􏱦k􏱦1 (because M has rank n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1). We also need to show that 􏱬ˆ and 􏱧ˆ 2 are independent. But 􏱬ˆ 􏱪 􏱬 􏱕 (X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃u, and 􏱧ˆ2 􏱪 u􏲃Mu/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1). Now, [(X􏲃X)􏱦1X􏲃]M 􏱪 0 because X􏲃M 􏱪 0. It follows, from Prop- erty 5 of the multivariate normal distribution in Appendix D, that 􏱬ˆ and Mu are indepen- dent. Because 􏱧ˆ 2 is a function of Mu, 􏱬ˆ and 􏱧ˆ 2 are also independent. (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) 􏱪 [(􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/sd(􏱬ˆj)]/(􏱧ˆ2/􏱧2)1/2, which is the ratio of a standard normal random variable and the square root of a 􏱚n2 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 / (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1) random variable. We just showed that these are independent, so, by definition of a t random variable, ( 􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se( 􏱬ˆj) has the tn 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 distribution. Because this distri- bution does not depend on X, it is the unconditional distribution of (􏱬ˆj 􏱦 􏱬j)/se(􏱬ˆj) as well. From this theorem, we can plug in any hypothesized value for 􏱬j and use the t statistic for testing hypotheses, as usual. Under Assumptions E.1 through E.5, we can compute what is known as the Cramer- Rao lower bound for the variance-covariance matrix of unbiased estimators of 􏱬 (again conditional on X) [see Greene (1997, Chapter 4)]. This can be shown to be 􏱧2(X􏲃X)􏱦1, Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. as maximizing its natural logarithm: ∑n APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 815 which is exactly the variance-covariance matrix of the OLS estimator. This implies that 􏱬ˆ is the minimum variance unbiased estimator of 􏱬 (conditional on X): Var(􏱬 ̃􏰫X) 􏱦 Var(􏱬ˆ􏰫X) is positive semi-definite for any other unbiased estimator 􏱬 ̃; we no longer have to restrict our attention to estimators linear in y. It is easy to show that the OLS estimator is in fact the maximum likelihood estimator of 􏱬 under Assumption E.5. For each t, the distribution of yt given X is Normal(xt 􏱬,􏱧2). Because the yt are independent conditional on X, the likelihood function for the sample is obtained from the product of the densities: n 􏱀(2􏰵􏱧2)􏱦1/2exp[􏱦(yt 􏱦 xt 􏱬)2/(2􏱧2)], t􏱪1 where 􏱀 denotes product. Maximizing this function with respect to 􏱬 and 􏱧2 is the same For obtaining 􏱬ˆ, this is the same as minimizing n (y 􏱦 x 􏱬)2—the division by 2􏱧2 tt [􏱦(1/2)log(2􏰵􏱧2) 􏱦 (y 􏱦 x 􏱬)2/(2􏱧2)]. tt t􏱪1 ∑ t􏱪1 does not affect the optimization—which is just the problem that OLS solves. The estimator of 􏱧2 that we have used, SSR/(n 􏱦 k), turns out not to be the MLE of 􏱧2; the MLE is SSR/n, which is a biased estimator. Because the unbiased estimator of 􏱧2 results in t and F statistics with exact t and F distributions under the null, it is always used instead of the MLE. That the OLS estimator is the MLE under Assumption E.5 implies an interesting robustness property of the MLE based on the normal distribution. The reasoning is simple. We know that the OLS estimator is unbiased under Assumptions E.1 to E.3; normality of the errors is used nowhere in the proof, and neither is Assumption E.4. As the next section shows, the OLS estimator is also consistent without normality, provided the law of large numbers holds (as is widely true). These statistical properties of the OLS estimator imply that the MLE based on the normal log-likelihood function is robust to distributional speci- fication: the distribution can be (almost) anything and yet we still obtain a consistent (and, under E.1 to E.3, unbiased) estimator. As discussed in Section 17.3, a maximum likeli- hood estimator obtained without assuming the distribution is correct is often called a quasi- maximum likelihood estimator (QMLE). Generally, consistency of the MLE relies on having a correct distribution in order to conclude that it is consistent for the parameters. We have just seen that the normal distribu- tion is a notable exception. There are some other distributions that share this property, includ- ing the Poisson distribution—as discussed in Section 17.3. Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 18) discusses some other useful examples. E.4 Some Asymptotic Analysis The matrix approach to the multiple regression model can also make derivations of asymptotic properties more concise. In fact, we can give general proofs of the claims in Chapter 11. We begin by proving the consistency result of Theorem 11.1. Recall that these assumptions contain, as a special case, the assumptions for cross-sectional analysis under random sampling. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 816 APPENDICES Proof of Theorem 11.1. As in Problem E.1 and using Assumption TS.1􏲃, we write the OLS estimator as ˆ ∑n 􏱦1 ∑n ∑n x􏲃txt􏱷 􏱵 x􏲃tyt􏱷􏱪 􏱵 t􏱪1 ∑n 􏱦1∑n 􏱦1 ∑n x􏲃t(xt􏱬 􏱕 ut)􏱷 􏱬 􏱪 􏱵 t􏱪1 x􏲃txt􏱷 􏱵 x􏲃tut􏱷. t􏱪1 􏱪􏱬􏱕􏱵n Now, by the law of large numbers, t􏱪1 􏱪􏱬􏱕􏱵 x􏲃txt􏱷 􏱵 x􏲃tut􏱷 [E.19] [E.20] t􏱪1 t􏱪1 ∑n n􏱦1 t􏱪1 􏱦1 􏱦1∑n t􏱪1 􏱦1∑n x􏲃txt􏱷 􏱵n x􏲃x p 􏲍andn􏱦1 tt􏱽 we have used the fact that E(x􏲃t ut) 􏱪 0 under Assumption TS.3􏲃. Now, we must use a ma- trix version of Property PLIM.1 in Appendix C. Namely, because A is nonsingular, ∑n 􏱦1p􏱦1 t􏱪1 t􏱪1 t􏱪1 where A 􏱪 E(x􏲃t xt) is a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) nonsingular matrix under Assumption TS.2􏲃 and x􏲃txt􏱷 􏱽A . [E.21] [Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 3) contains a discussion of these kinds of convergence re- 􏱵n􏱦1 sults.] It now follows from (E.19), (E.20), and (E.21) that plim(􏱬ˆ)􏱪􏱬􏱕A􏱦1 􏱳0􏱪􏱬. This completes the proof. Next, we sketch a proof of the asymptotic normality result in Theorem 11.2. Proof of Theorem 11.2. From equation (E.19), we can write __ ˆ 􏱯 n (􏱬 􏱦 􏱬) 􏱪 􏱵􏱷∑ ∑n x􏲃u p 0, tt􏱽 ∑n n􏱦1 x􏲃x 􏱦1 n􏱦1/2 n x􏲃u t􏱪1 􏱦1 􏱦1/2∑n t􏱪1 where the term “op(1)∑” is a remainder term that c∑onverges in probability to zero. This term is equal to 􏱶􏱵n􏱦1 n x􏲃x 􏱷􏱦1 􏱦 A􏱦1􏲄 􏱵n􏱦1/2 n x􏲃u 􏱷. The term in brackets con- 􏱪A 􏱵n [E.22] tt t􏱪1 t􏱪1 tt verges in pr∑obability to zero (by the same argument used in the proof of Theorem 11.1), while 􏱵n􏱦1/2 n x􏲃u 􏱷 is bounded in probability because it converges to a multivariate tt t􏱪1 normaldistributionbythecentrallimittheorem.Aw∑ell-knownresultinasymptoticˆtheory is that the product of such terms converges in prob __ ability to zero. Further, 􏱯 n (􏱬 􏱦 􏱬) inherits its asymptotic distribution from A􏱦1 􏱵n􏱦1/2 n x􏲃u 􏱷. See Wooldridge (2010, t􏱪1 Chapter 3) for more details on the convergence results used in this proof. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 􏱵t􏱪1 􏱷 x􏲃tut􏱷􏱕op(1), tt tt tt APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 817 By the central limit theorem, n􏱦1/2 ∑ n x􏲃t ut has an asymptotic normal distribution t􏱪1 __ ˆ with mean zero and, say, (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) variance-covariance matrix B. Then, 􏱯 n(􏱬 􏱦 􏱬) has an asymptotic multivariate normal distribution with mean zero and variance- covariance matrix A􏱦1BA􏱦1. We now show that, under Assumptions TS.4􏲃 and TS.5􏲃, B 􏱪 􏱧2A. (The general expression is useful because it underlies heteroskedasticity- robust and serial-correlation robust standard errors for OLS, of the kind discussed in Chapter 12.) First, under Assumption TS.5􏲃, x􏲃t ut and xs􏲃us are uncorrelated for t 􏱳 s. Why? Suppose s 􏱷 t for concreteness. Then, by the law of iterated expectations, E(x􏲃t utusxs) 􏱪 E[E(utusx􏲃t xs)􏱜x􏲃t xs] 􏱪 E[E(utus􏱜x􏲃t xs)x􏲃t xs] 􏱪 E[0 􏱳 x􏲃t xs] 􏱪 0. The zero covariances imply that the variance of the sum is the sum of the variances. But Var(x􏲃t ut) 􏱪 E(x􏲃t ututxt) 􏱪 E(u2t x􏲃t xt). By the law of iterated expectations, E(u2t x􏲃t xt) 􏱪 E[E(u2t x􏲃t xt􏱜xt)] 􏱪 E[E(u2t 􏱜xt)x􏲃t xt] 􏱪 E(􏱧2x􏲃t xt) 􏱪 􏱧2E(x􏲃t xt) 􏱪 􏱧2A, where we use E(u2t 􏱜xt) 􏱪 􏱧2 under Assumptions TS.3􏲃 and TS.4􏲃. This shows that B 􏱪 􏱧2A, and so, under Assumptions TS.1􏲃 to TS.5􏲃, we have __ˆ a 2􏱦1 􏱯 n (􏱬 􏱦 􏱬)~ Normal (0,􏱧 A ). [E.23] This completes the proof. ˆ From equation (E.23), we treat 􏱬 as if it is approximately normally distributed with mean 􏱬 and variance-covariance matrix 􏱧2A􏱦1/n. The division by the sample size, n, is expected here: the approximation to the variance-covariance matrix of 􏱬ˆ shrinks to zero at the rate 1/n. When we replace 􏱧2 with its co and replace A with its consistent estimator, n􏱦1 n x􏲃x 􏱪X􏲃X/n, we obtain an estimator for the asymptotic variance of 􏱬ˆ: t􏱪1 􏱾ˆ 2 􏱦1 where the division by n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 rather than n is a degrees of freedom adjustment that typi- cally helps the finite sample properties of the estimator. When we use the expression in equation (E.25), we obtain Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 2 ∑nsistentestimator,􏱧ˆ 􏱪SSR/(n􏱦k􏱦1), tt Avar(􏱬)􏱪 􏱧ˆ (X􏲃X) . [E.24] Notice how the two divisions by n cancel, and the right-hand side of (E.24) is just the usual way we estimate the variance matrix of the OLS estimator under the Gauss-Markov assumptions. To summarize, we have shown that, under Assumptions TS.1􏲃 to TS.5􏲃— which contain MLR.1 to MLR.5 as special cases—the usual standard errors and t statistics are asymptotically valid. It is perfectly legitimate to use the usual t distribution to obtain critical values and p-values for testing a single hypothesis. Interestingly, in the general setup of Chapter 11, assuming normality of the errors—say, ut given xt, ut􏱦1, xt􏱦1, ..., u1, x1 is distributed as Normal(0,􏱧2)—does not necessarily help, as the t statistics would not generally have exact t statistics under this kind of normality assumption. When we do not assume strict exogeneity of the explanatory variables, exact distributional results are dif- ficult, if not impossible, to obtain. If we modify the argument above, we can derive a heteroskedasticity-robust, variance- covariance matrix. The key is that we must estimate E(u2t x􏲃t xt) separately because this matrix no longer equals 􏱧2E(x􏲃t xt). But, if the uˆt are the OLS residuals, a consistent estimator is ∑n (n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)􏱦1 uˆ2x􏲃x , [E.25] ttt t􏱪1 818 APPENDICES ∑n 􏱾Avar(􏱬ˆ) 􏱪 [n/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1)](X􏲃X)􏱦1 􏱵 uˆ2x􏲃x 􏱷(X􏲃X)􏱦1. [E.26] The square roots of the diagonal elements of this matrix are the same heteroskedasticity- robust standard errors we obtained in Section 8.2 for the pure cross-sectional case. A matrix extension of the serial correlation- (and heteroskedasticity-) robust standard er- rors we obtained in Section 12.5 is also available, but the matrix that must replace (E.25) is complicated because of the serial correlation. See, for example, Hamilton (1994, Section 10.5). Wald Statistics for Testing Multiple Hypotheses Similar arguments can be used to obtain the asymptotic distribution of the Wald statistic for testing multiple hypotheses. Let R be a q 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix, with q 􏰯 (k 􏱕 1). Assume that the q restrictions on the (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector of parameters, 􏱬, can be expressed as H0􏱲R􏱬 􏱪 r, where r is a q 􏱶 1 vector of known constants. Under Assumptions TS.1􏲃 to TS.5􏲃, it can be shown that, under H0, __ ˆ 2 􏱦1 􏱦1 __ ˆ a 2 [􏱯 n(R􏱬 􏱦 r)]􏲃(􏱧 RA R􏲃) [􏱯 n(R􏱬 􏱦 r)]~ 􏰨q, [E.27] where A 􏱪 E(x􏲃t xt), as in the proofs of Theorems 11.1 and 11.2. The intuition behind __ ˆ 2 􏱦1 equation (E.25) is simple. Because 􏱯 n(􏱬 􏱦 􏱬) is roughly distributed as Normal(0,􏱧 A ), __ˆ __ˆ 2􏱦1 R[􏱯 n (􏱬 􏱦 􏱬)] 􏱪 􏱯 n R( 􏱬 􏱦 􏱬) is approximately Normal(0,􏱧 RA R􏲃) by Property 3 of the multivariate normal distribution in Appendix D. Under H0, R􏱬 􏱪 r, so __ˆ 2􏱦1 􏱯 n(R􏱬 􏱦 r) ~ Normal(0,􏱧 RA R􏲃) under H0. By Property 3 of the chi-square distri- bution, z􏲃(􏱧2RA􏱦1R􏲃)􏱦1z ~ 􏰨2q if z ~ Normal(0,􏱧2RA􏱦1R􏲃). To obtain the final result formally, we need to use an asymptotic version of this property, which can be found in Wooldridge (2010, Chapter 3). Given the result in (E.25), we obtain a computable statistic by replacing A and 􏱧2 with their consistent estimators; doing so does not change the asymptotic distribution. The result is the so-called Wald statistic, which, after cancelling the sample sizes and doing a little algebra, can be written as W 􏱪 (R􏱬ˆ 􏱦 r)􏲃[R(X􏲃X)􏱦1R􏲃]􏱦1(R􏱬ˆ 􏱦 r)􏱚ˆ􏱧2. [E.28] Under H0,W~a 􏰨2q, where we recall that q is the number of restrictions being tested. If ˆ􏱧2 􏱪 SSR/(n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1), it can be shown that W/q is exactly the F statistic we obtained in Chapter 4 for testing multiple linear restrictions. [See, for example, Greene (1997, Chap- ter 7).] Therefore, under the classical linear model assumptions TS.1 to TS.6 in Chapter 10, W/q has an exact Fq,n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 distribution. Under Assumptions TS.1􏲃 to TS.5􏲃, we only have the asymptotic result in (E.26). Nevertheless, it is appropriate, and common, to treat the usual F statistic as having an approximate Fq,n 􏱦 k 􏱦 1 distribution. A Wald statistic that is robust to heteroskedasticity of unknown form is obtained by using the matrix in (E.26) in place of ˆ􏱧2(X􏲃X)􏱦1, and similarly for a test statistic robust to both heteroskedasticity and serial correlation. The robust versions of the test statistics cannot be computed via sums of squared residuals or R-squareds from the restricted and unrestricted regressions. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. ttt t􏱪1 APPENDIX E The Linear Regression Model in Matrix Form 819 Summary This appendix has provided a brief treatment of the linear regression model using matrix no- tation. This material is included for more advanced classes that use matrix algebra, but it is not needed to read the text. In effect, this appendix proves some of the results that we ei- ther stated without proof, proved only in special cases, or proved through a more cumbersome method of proof. Other topics—such as asymptotic properties, instrumental variables estima- tion, and panel data models—can be given concise treatments using matrices. Advanced texts in econometrics, including Davidson and MacKinnon (1993), Greene (1997), Hayashi (2000), and Wooldridge (2010), can be consulted for details. Key Terms First Order Condition Matrix Notation Minimum Variance Unbiased Estimator Scalar Variance-Covariance Matrix Variance-Covariance Matrix of the OLS Estimator Wald Statistic Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimator (QMLE) Problems 1 Let xt be the 1 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) vector of explanatory variables for observation t. Show that the OLS estimator 􏱬ˆ can be written as ˆ∑n 􏱦1∑n 􏱬􏱪􏱵 x􏲃txt􏱷 􏱵 x􏲃tyt􏱷. t􏱪1 t􏱪1 Dividing each summation by n shows that 􏱬ˆ is a function of sample averages. 2 Let 􏱬ˆ be the (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector of OLS estimates. (i) Show that for any (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector b, we can write the sum of squared residuals as SSR(b) 􏱪 uˆ􏲃uˆ 􏱕 (􏱬ˆ 􏱦 b)􏲃X􏲃X(􏱬ˆ 􏱦 b). {Hint: Write (y 􏱦 Xb)􏲃(y 􏱦 Xb) 􏱪 [uˆ 􏱕 X(􏱬ˆ 􏱦 b)]􏲃[uˆ 􏱕 X(􏱬ˆ 􏱦 b)] and use the fact that X􏲃uˆ 􏱪 0.} ˆ (ii) Explain how the expression for SSR(b) in part (i) proves that 􏱬 uniquely minimizes SSR(b) over all possible values of b, assuming X has rank k 􏱕 1. 3 L e t ˆ􏱬 b e t h e O L S e s t i m a t e f r o m t h e r e g r e s s i o n o f y o n X . L e t A b e a ( k 􏱕 1 ) 􏱶 (k􏱕1)nonsingularmatrixanddefinezt􏱲xtA,t􏱪1,...,n.Therefore,zt is1􏱶(k􏱕1) and is a nonsingular linear combination of xt. Let Z be the n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix with rows zt. Let 􏱬 ̃ denote the OLS estimate from a regression of y on Z. (i) Show that 􏱬 ̃ 􏱪 A􏱦1􏱬ˆ. (ii) Let yˆt be the fitted values from the original regression and let y ̃t be the fitted values from regressing y on Z. Show that y ̃t 􏱪 yˆt, for all t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n. How do the residuals from the two regressions compare? (iii) Show that the estimated variance matrix for 􏱬 ̃ is 􏱧ˆ2A􏱦1(X􏲃X)􏱦1A􏱦1􏲃, where 􏱧ˆ2 is the usual variance estimate from regressing y on X. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 820 APPENDICES (iv) Let the 􏱬ˆj be the OLS estimates from regressing yt on 1, xt1, ..., xtk, and let the 􏱬 ̃j be the OLS estimates from the regression of yt on 1, a1xt1, ..., ak xtk, where aj 􏱻 0, j 􏱪 1, ..., k. Use the results from part (i) to find the relationship between the 􏱬 ̃j and the 􏱬ˆj. ̃ ˆ (v) Assuming the setup of part (iv), use part (iii) to show that se(􏱬j) 􏱪 se(􏱬j)/􏰫aj􏰫. ̃ (vi) Assuming the setup of part (iv), show that the absolute values of the t statistics for 􏱬j and 􏱬ˆj are identical. 4 Assume that the model y 􏱪 X􏱬 􏱕 u satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions, let G be a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) nonsingular, nonrandom matrix, and define 􏱛 􏱪 G􏱬, so that 􏱛 is also a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector. Let 􏱬ˆ be the (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector of OLS estimators and define 􏱛ˆ 􏱪 G􏱬ˆ as the OLS estimator of 􏱛. (i) Show that E(􏱛ˆ􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱛. (ii) Find Var(􏱛ˆ􏰫X) in terms of 􏱧2, X, and G. (iii) Use Problem E.3 to verify that 􏱛ˆ and the appropriate estimate of Var(􏱛ˆ􏰫X) are obtained from the regression of y on XG􏱦1. (iv) Now, let c be a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 1 vector with at least one nonzero entry. For concreteness, assume that ck 􏱻 0. Define 􏰩 􏱪 c􏲃􏱬, so that 􏰩 is a scalar. Define 􏱛j 􏱪 􏱬j, j 􏱪 0, 1, ..., k 􏱦 1 and 􏱛k 􏱪 􏰩. Show how to define a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) nonsingular matrix G so that 􏱛 􏱪 G􏱬. (Hint: Each of the first k rows of G should contain k zeros and a one. What is the last row?) (v) Show that for the choice of G in part (iv), 100...0 􏱶010...0􏲄 . . . 00...10 􏱦c0 /ck 􏱦c1/ck . . . 􏱦ck􏱦1/ck 1/ck Use this expression for G􏱦1 and part (iii) to conclude that 􏰩ˆ and its standard error are ob- tained as the coefficient on xtk /ck in the regression of yt on [1 􏱦 (c0/ck)xtk], [xt1 􏱦 (c1/ck)xtk], ..., [xt,k􏱦1 􏱦 (ck􏱦1/ck)xtk], xtk/ck, t 􏱪 1, ..., n. This regression is exactly the one obtained by writing 􏱬k in terms of 􏰩 and 􏱬0, 􏱬1, ..., 􏱬k􏱦1, plugging the result into the original model, and rearranging. Therefore, we can formally justify the trick we use throughout the text for obtaining the standard error of a linear com- bination of parameters. 5 Assume that the model y 􏱪 X􏱬 􏱕 u satisfies the Gauss-Markov assumptions and let 􏱬ˆ be the OLS estimator of 􏱬. Let Z 􏱪 G(X) be an n 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix function of X and assume that Z􏲃X [a (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix] is nonsingular. Define a new estimator of 􏱬 by 􏱬 ̃ 􏱪 (Z􏲃X)􏱦1Z􏲃y. (i) Show that E(􏱬 ̃􏰫X) 􏱪 􏱬, so that 􏱬 ̃ is also unbiased conditional on X. (ii) Find Var(􏱬 ̃􏰫X). Make sure this is a symmetric, (k 􏱕 1) 􏱶 (k 􏱕 1) matrix that depends on Z, X, and 􏱧2. ˆ ̃ (iii) Which estimator do you prefer, 􏱬 or 􏱬? Explain. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. G􏱦1 􏱪 Chapter 2 Question2.1: Whenstudentability,motivation,age,andotherfactorsinuarenotrelated to attendance, (2.6) would hold. This seems unlikely to be the case. Question 2.2: About $11.05. To see this, from the average wages measured in 1976 and 2003 dollars, we can get the CPI deflator as 19.06/5.90 􏱴 3.23. When we multiply 3.42 by 3.23, we obtain about 11.05. Question 2.3: 54.65, as can be seen by plugging shareA 􏱪 60 into equation (2.28). This is not unreasonable: if Candidate A spends 60% of the total money spent, he or she is predicted to receive almost 55% of the vote. Question 2.4: The equation will be 􏱾salaryhun 􏱪 9,631.91 􏱕 185.01 roe, as is easily seen by multiplying equation (2.39) by 10. Q∑uestion 2.5: Equation (2.58) can be written as Var(ˆ􏱬0)􏱪(􏱧2n􏱦1) 􏱵∑n xi2􏱷􏱚 n - 2 2 􏱦1 i􏱪1 􏱵 i􏱪1 (xi 􏱦 x) 􏱷, where the term multiplying 􏱧 n is greater than or equal to one, but it is equal to one if, and only if, x- 􏱪 0. In this case, the variance is as small as it can possibly be: Var(􏱬ˆ0) 􏱪 􏱧2/n. Chapter 3 Question 3.1: Just a few factors include age and gender distribution, size of the police force (or, more generally, resources devoted to crime fighting), population, and general historical factors. These factors certainly might be correlated with prbconv and avgsen, which means (3.5) would not hold. For example, size of the police force is possibly cor- related with both prbcon and avgsen, as some cities put more effort into crime prevention and law enforcement. We should try to bring as many of these factors into the equation as possible. Question 3.2: We use the third property of OLS concerning predicted values and residuals: when we plug the average values of all independent variables into the OLS 821 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX F Answers to Chapter Questions 822 APPENDICES regression line, we obtain the average value of the dependent variable. So colGPA 􏱪 1.29 􏱕 .453 hsGPA 􏱕 .0094 ACT 􏱪 1.29 􏱕 .453(3.4) 􏱕 .0094(24.2) 􏱴 3.06. You can check the average of colGPA in GPA1.RAW to verify this to the second decimal place. Question 3.3: No. The variable shareA is not an exact linear function of expendA and expendB, even though it is an exact nonlinear function: shareA 􏱪 100􏱳[expendA/ (expendA 􏱕 expendB)]. Therefore, it is legitimate to have expendA, expendB, and shareA as explanatory variables. Question 3.4: As we discussed in Section 3.4, if we are interested in the effect of x1 on y, correlation among the other explanatory variables (x2, x3, and so on) does not affect Var(􏱬ˆ1). These variables are included as controls, and we do not have to worry about collinearity among the control variables. Of course, we are controlling for them primarily because we think they are correlated with attendance, but this is necessary to perform a ceteris paribus analysis. Chapter 4 Question 4.1: Under these assumptions, the Gauss-Markov assumptions are satisfied: u is independent of the explanatory variables, so E(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 E(u), and Var(u􏰫x1, ..., xk) 􏱪 Var(u). Further, it is easily seen that E(u) 􏱪 0. Therefore, MLR.4 and MLR.5 hold. The classical linear model assumptions are not satisfied because u is not normally distributed (which is a violation of MLR.6). Question 4.2: H0: 􏱬1 􏱪 0, H1: 􏱬1 􏱷 0. Question 4.3: Because 􏱬ˆ1 􏱪 .56 􏱰 0 and we are testing against H1: 􏱬1 􏱰 0, the one-sided p-value is one-half of the two-sided p-value, or .043. Question4.4: H0:􏱬5 􏱪􏱬6 􏱪􏱬7 􏱪􏱬8 􏱪0.k􏱪8andq􏱪4.Therestrictedversionof the model is score 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1classize 􏱕 􏱬2expend 􏱕 􏱬3tchcomp 􏱕 􏱬4enroll 􏱕 u. Question 4.5: The F statistic for testing exclusion of ACT is [(.291 􏱦 .183)/ (1 􏱦 .291)](680 􏱦 3) 􏱴 103.13. Therefore, the absolute value of the t statistic is about 10.16. The t statistic on ACT is negative, because 􏱬ˆACT is negative, so tACT 􏱪 􏱦10.16. Question 4.6: Not by much. The F test for joint significance of droprate and gradrate is easily computed from the R-squareds in the table: F 􏱪 [(.361 􏱦 .353)/(1 􏱦 .361)](402/2) 􏱴 2.52. The 10% critical value is obtained from Table G.3a as 2.30, while the 5% critical value from Table G.3b is 3. The p-value is about .082. Thus, droprate and gradrate are jointly significant at the 10% level, but not at the 5% level. In any case, controlling for these variables has a minor effect on the b/s coefficient. Chapter 5 Question 5.1: This requires some assumptions. It seems reasonable to assume that 􏱬2 􏱰 0 (score depends positively on priGPA) and Cov(skipped,priGPA) 􏱷 0 (skipped and priGPA Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. are negatively correlated). This means that 􏱬2􏱛1 􏱷 0, which means that plim 􏱬 ̃1 􏱷 􏱬1. Because 􏱬1 is thought to be negative (or at least nonpositive), a simple regression is likely to overestimate the importance of skipping classes. Question 5.2: 􏱬ˆj 􏲁 1.96se(􏱬ˆj) is the asymptotic 95% confidence interval. Or, we can replace 1.96 with 2. Chapter 6 Question 6.1: Because fincdol 􏱪 1,000􏱳faminc, the coefficient on fincdol will be the coefficient on faminc divided by 1,000, or .0927/1,000 􏱪 .0000927. The standard error also drops by a factor of 1,000, so the t statistic does not change, nor do any of the other OLS statistics. For readability, it is better to measure family income in thousands of dollars. Question 6.2: We can do this generally. The equation is log(y) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(x1) 􏱕 􏱬2x2 􏱕 ..., where x2 is a proportion rather than a percentage. Then, ceteris paribus, 􏰧log(y) 􏱪 􏱬2􏰧 x2, 100􏱳􏰧log(y) 􏱪 􏱬2(100􏱳􏰧 x2), or %􏰧 y 􏱴 􏱬2(100􏱳􏰧 x2). Now, because 􏰧 x2 is the change in the proportion, 100􏱳􏰧 x2 is a percentage point change. In particular, if 􏰧 x2 􏱪 .01, then 100􏱳􏰧 x2 􏱪 1, which corresponds to a one percentage point change. But then 􏱬2 is the percentage change in y when 100􏱳􏰧 x2 􏱪 1. Question6.3: Thenewmodelwouldbestndfnl􏱪􏱬0􏱕􏱬1atndrte􏱕􏱬2priGPA􏱕􏱬3ACT􏱕 􏱬4 priGPA2 􏱕 􏱬5 ACT 2 􏱕 􏱬6 priGPA􏱳atndrte 􏱕 􏱬7 ACT􏱳atndrte 􏱕 u. Therefore, the partial effect of atndrte on stndfnl is 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬6 priGPA 􏱕 􏱬7 ACT. This is what we multiply by 􏰧atndrte to obtain the ceteris paribus change in stndfnl. Question6.4: Fromequation(6.21),R-2 􏱪1􏱦􏱧ˆ2/[SST/(n􏱦1)].Foragivensampleand a given dependent variable, SST/(n 􏱦 1) is fixed. When we use different sets of explana- tory variables, only 􏱧ˆ2 changes. As 􏱧ˆ2 decreases, R-2 increases. If we make 􏱧ˆ, and therefore 􏱧ˆ 2, as small as possible, we are making R- 2 as large as possible. Question 6.5: One possibility is to collect data on annual earnings for a sample of actors, along with profitability of the movies in which they each appeared. In a simple regres- sion analysis, we could relate earnings to profitability. But we should probably control for other factors that may affect salary, such as age, gender, and the kinds of movies in which the actors performed. Methods for including qualitative factors in regression models are considered in Chapter 7. Chapter 7 Question 7.1: No, because it would not be clear when party is one and when it is zero. A better name would be something like Dem, which is one for Democratic candidates and zero for Republicans. Or, Rep, which is one for Republicans and zero for Democrats. Question 7.2: With outfield as the base group, we would include the dummy variables frstbase, scndbase, thrdbase, shrtstop, and catcher. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX F Answers to Chapter Questions 823 824 APPENDICES Question7.3: ThenullinthiscaseisH0:􏱛1 􏱪􏱛2 􏱪􏱛3 􏱪􏱛4 􏱪0,sothattherearefour restrictions. As usual, we would use an F test (where q 􏱪 4 and k depends on the number of other explanatory variables). Question 7.4: Because tenure appears as a quadratic, we should allow separate quadrat- ics for men and women. That is, we would add the explanatory variables female􏱳tenure and female􏱳tenure2. Question 7.5: We plug pcnv 􏱪 0, avgsen 􏱪 0, tottime 􏱪 0, ptime86 􏱪 0, qemp86 􏱪 4, black 􏱪 1, and hispan 􏱪 0 into (7.31): 􏱾arr86 􏱪 .380 􏱦 .038(4) 􏱕 .170 􏱪 .398, or almost .4. It is hard to know whether this is “reasonable.” For someone with no prior convictions who was employed throughout the year, this estimate might seem high, but remember that the population consists of men who were already arrested at least once prior to 1986. Chapter 8 Question8.1: Thisstatementisclearlyfalse.Forexample,inequation(8.7),theusualstan- dard error for black is .147, while the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error is .118. Question 8.2: The F test would be obtained by regressing uˆ2 on marrmale, marrfem, and singfem (singmale is the base group). With n 􏱪 526 and three independent variables in this regression, the df are 3 and 522. Question 8.3: Certainly the outcome of the statistical test suggests some cause for con- cern. A t statistic of 2.96 is very significant, and it implies that there is heteroskedasticity in the wealth equation. As a practical matter, we know that the WLS standard error, .063, is substantially below the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error for OLS, .104, and so the heteroskedasticity seems to be practically important. (Plus, the nonrobust OLS stan- dard error is .061, which is too optimistic. Therefore, even if we simply adjust the OLS standard error for heteroskedasticity of unknown form, there are nontrivial implications.) Question 8.4: The 1% critical value in the F distribution with (2, 􏱵) df is 4.61. An F statistic of 11.15 is well above the 1% critical value, and so we strongly reject the null hy- __ pothesis that the transformed errors, ui/􏱯hi, are homoskedastic. (In fact, the p-value is less than .00002, which is obtained from the F2,804 distribution.) This means that our model for Var(u􏰫x) is inadequate for fully eliminating the heteroskedasticity in u. Chapter 9 Question9.1: Thesearebinaryvariables,andsquaringthemhasnoeffect:black2􏱪black, and hispan2 􏱪 hispan. Question 9.2: When educ􏱳IQ is in the equation, the coefficient on educ, say, 􏱬1, mea- sures the effect of educ on log(wage) when IQ 􏱪 0. (The partial effect of education is 􏱬1 􏱕 􏱬9IQ.) There is no one in the population of interest with an IQ close to zero. At the average population IQ, which is 100, the estimated return to education from column (3) is .018 􏱕 .00034(100) 􏱪 .052, which is almost what we obtain as the coefficient on educ in column (2). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Question 9.3: No. If educ* is an integer—which means someone has no education past the previous grade completed—the measurement error is zero. If educ* is not an integer, educ 􏱷 educ*, so the measurement error is negative. At a minimum, e1 cannot have zero mean, and e1 and educ* are probably correlated. Question 9.4: An incumbent’s decision not to run may be systematically related to how he or she expects to do in the election. Therefore, we may only have a sample of incumbents who are stronger, on average, than all possible incumbents who could run. This results in a sample selection problem if the population of interest includes all in- cumbents. If we are only interested in the effects of campaign expenditures on election outcomes for incumbents who seek reelection, there is no sample selection problem. Chapter 10 Question10.1: Theimpactpropensityis.48,whilethelong-runpropensityis.48􏱦.15􏱕 .32 􏱪 .65. Question 10.2: The explanatory variables are xt1 􏱪 zt and xt2 􏱪 zt􏱦1. The absence of per- fect collinearity means that these cannot be constant, and there cannot be an exact linear relationship between them in the sample. This rules out the possibility that all the z1, ..., zn take on the same value or that the z0, z1, ..., zn􏱦1 take on the same value. But it eliminates other patterns as well. For example, if zt 􏱪 a 􏱕 bt for constants a and b, then zt􏱦1 􏱪 a 􏱕 b(t 􏱦 1) 􏱪 (a 􏱕 bt) 􏱦 b 􏱪 zt􏱦 b, which is a perfect linear function of zt. Question 10.3: If {zt} is slowly moving over time—as is the case for the levels or logs of many economic time series—then zt and zt􏱦1 can be highly correlated. For example, the correlation between unemt and unemt􏱦1 in PHILLIPS.RAW is .75. Question 10.4: No, because a linear time trend with 􏱮1 􏱷 0 becomes more and more negative as t gets large. Since gfr cannot be negative, a linear time trend with a negative trend coefficient cannot represent gfr in all future time periods. Question 10.5: The intercept for March is 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱛2. Seasonal dummy variables are strictly exogenous because they follow a deterministic pattern. For example, the months do not change based upon whether either the explanatory variables or the dependent variable change. Chapter 11 Question 11.1: (i) No, because E(yt) 􏱪 􏱛0 􏱕 􏱛1t depends on t. (ii) Yes, because yt 􏱦 E(yt) 􏱪 et is an i.i.d. sequence. Question11.2: Wepluginfte􏱪(1/2)inft􏱦1􏱕(1/2)inft􏱦2intoinft􏱦infte􏱪􏱬1(unemt􏱦􏱙0)􏱕 et and rearrange: inft 􏱦 (1/2)(inft􏱦1 􏱕 inft􏱦2) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1unemt 􏱕 et, where 􏱬0 􏱪 􏱦􏱬1􏱙0, as before. Therefore, we would regress yt on unemt, where yt 􏱪 inft 􏱦 (1/2)(inft􏱦1 􏱕 inft􏱦2). Note that we lose the first two observations in constructing yt. Question11.3: No,becauseutandut􏱦1arecorrelated.Inparticular,Cov(ut,ut􏱦1)􏱪E[(et􏱕 􏱮1et􏱦1)(et􏱦1 􏱕 􏱮1et􏱦2)] 􏱪 􏱮1E(et2􏱦1) 􏱪 􏱮1􏱧e2 􏱻 0 if 􏱮1 􏱻 0. If the errors are serially cor- related, the model cannot be dynamically complete. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX F Answers to Chapter Questions 825 826 APPENDICES Chapter 12 Question 12.1: We use equation (12.4). Now, only adjacent terms are correlated. In par- ticular, the covariance between xtut and xt􏱕1ut􏱕1 is xt xt􏱕1Cov(ut,ut􏱕1) 􏱪 xt xt􏱕1􏱮􏱧e2. There- fore, the formula is ˆ ∑n Var(􏱬1) 􏱪 SST􏱦x 2 􏱵 xt2Var(ut) 􏱕 2 n􏱦1 ∑n􏱦1 t􏱪1 ∑ t􏱪1 xtxt􏱕1E(utut􏱕1)􏱷 􏱪 􏱧2/SSTx 􏱕 (2/SSTx2) 􏱮􏱧2x x t􏱪1 ∑ 􏱪 􏱧2/SSTx 􏱕 􏱮􏱧e2(2/SSTx2) x x , t t􏱕1 t􏱪1 where 􏱧2 􏱪 Var(ut) 􏱪 􏱧e2 􏱕 􏱮12 􏱧e2 􏱪 􏱧e2(1 􏱕 􏱮12). Unless xt and xt􏱕1 are uncorrelated in the sample, the second term is nonzero whenever 􏱮 􏱻 0. Notice that if xt and xt􏱕1 are positively correlated and 􏱮 􏱷 0, the true variance is actually smaller than the usual variance. When the equation is in levels (as opposed to being differenced), the typical case is 􏱮 􏱰 0, with positive correlation between xt and xt􏱕1. Question 12.2: 􏰴ˆ 􏲁 1.96se(􏰴ˆ), where se(􏰴ˆ) is the standard error reported in the regres- sion. Or, we could use the heteroskedasticity-robust standard error. Showing that this is asymptotically valid is complicated because the OLS residuals depend on 􏱬ˆj, but it can be done. Question 12.3: The model we have in mind is ut 􏱪 􏰴1ut􏱦1 􏱕 􏰴4ut􏱦4 􏱕 et, and we want to test H0: 􏰴1 􏱪 0, 􏰴4 􏱪 0 against the alternative that H0 is false. We would run the regression of uˆt on uˆt􏱦1 and uˆt􏱦4 to obtain the usual F statistic for joint significance of the two lags. (We are testing two restrictions.) Question12.4: Wewouldprobablyestimatetheequationusingfirstdifferences,as􏰴ˆ􏱪.92 is close enough to 1 to raise questions about the levels regression. See Chapter 18 for more discussion. Question 12.5: Because there is only one explanatory variable, the White test is easy to compute. Simply regress uˆt2 on returnt􏱦1 and return2t􏱦1 (with an intercept, as always) and compute the F test for joint significance of returnt􏱦1 and return2t􏱦1. If these are jointly sig- nificant at a small enough significance level, we reject the null of homoskedasticity. Chapter 13 Question 13.1: Yes, assuming that we have controlled for all relevant factors. The coef- ficient on black is 1.076, and, with a standard error of .174, it is not statistically different from 1. The 95% confidence interval is from about .735 to 1.417. Question 13.2: The coefficient on highearn shows that, in the absence of any change in the earnings cap, high earners spend much more time—on the order of 29.2% on average [because exp(.256) 􏱦 1 􏱴 .292]—on workers’ compensation. Question 13.3: First, E(vi1) 􏱪 E(ai 􏱕 ui1) 􏱪 E(ai) 􏱕 E(vi1) 􏱪 0. Similarly, E(vi2) 􏱪 0. Therefore, the covariance between vi1 and vi2 is simply E(vi1vi2) 􏱪 E[(ai 􏱕 ui1)(ai 􏱕 ui2)] 􏱪 E(a2i ) 􏱕 E(aiui1) 􏱕 E(aiui2) 􏱕 E(ui1ui2) 􏱪 E(ai2), because all of the covariance terms are Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. e t t􏱕1 n􏱦1 APPENDIX F Answers to Chapter Questions 827 zero by assumption. But E(ai2) 􏱪 Var(ai), because E(ai) 􏱪 0. This causes positive serial correlation across time in the errors within each i, which biases the usual OLS standard errors in a pooled OLS regression. Question 13.4: Because 􏰧admn 􏱪 admn90 􏱦 admn85 is the difference in binary indica- tors, it can be 􏱦1 if, and only if, admn90 􏱪 0 and admn85 􏱪 1. In other words, Washington state had an administrative per se law in 1985 but it was repealed by 1990. Question 13.5: No, just as it does not cause bias and inconsistency in a time series regression with strictly exogenous explanatory variables. There are two reasons it is a con- cern. First, serial correlation in the errors in any equation generally biases the usual OLS standard errors and test statistics. Second, it means that pooled OLS is not as efficient as estimators that account for the serial correlation (as in Chapter 12). Chapter 14 Question 14.1: Whether we use first differencing or the within transformation, we will have trouble estimating the coefficient on kidsit. For example, using the within transfor- ̈􏰲 mation, if kidsit does not vary for family i, then kidsit 􏱪 kidsit 􏱦 kidsi 􏱪 0 for t 􏱪 1,2,3. As long as some families have variation in kidsit, then we can compute the fixed effects estimator, but the kids coefficient could be very imprecisely estimated. This is a form of multicollinearity in fixed effects estimation (or first-differencing estimation). Question 14.2: If a firm did not receive a grant in the first year, it may or may not receive a grant in the second year. But if a firm did receive a grant in the first year, it could not get a grant in the second year. That is, if grant􏱦1 􏱪 1, then grant 􏱪 0. This induces a negative correlation between grant and grant􏱦1. We can verify this by computing a regression of grant on grant􏱦1, using the data in JTRAIN.RAW for 1989. Using all firms in the sample, we get g􏱾rant 􏱪 .248 􏱦 .248 grant􏱦1 (.035) (.072) n 􏱪 157, R2 􏱪 .070. The coefficient on grant􏱦1 must be the negative of the intercept because 􏱾grant 􏱪 0 when grant􏱦1 􏱪 1. Question 14.3: It suggests that the unobserved effect ai is positively correlated with unionit. Remember, pooled OLS leaves ai in the error term, while fixed effects removes ai. By definition, ai has a positive effect on log(wage). By the standard omitted variables analysis (see Chapter 3), OLS has an upward bias when the explanatory variable (union) is positively correlated with the omitted variable (ai). Thus, belonging to a union appears to be positively related to time-constant, unobserved factors that affect wage. Question 14.4: Not if all sisters within a family have the same mother and father. Then, because the parents’ race variables would not change by sister, they would be differenced away in (14.13). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 828 APPENDICES Chapter 15 Question 15.1: Probably not. In the simple equation (15.18), years of education is part of the error term. If some men who were assigned low draft lottery numbers obtained additional schooling, then lottery number and education are negatively correlated, which violates the first requirement for an instrumental variable in equation (15.4). Question 15.2: (i) For (15.27), we require that high school peer group effects carry over to college. Namely, for a given SAT score, a student who went to a high school where smoking marijuana was more popular would smoke more marijuana in college. Even if the identification condition (15.27) holds, the link might be weak. (ii) We have to assume that percentage of students using marijuana at a student’s high school is not correlated with unobserved factors that affect college grade point average. Although we are somewhat controlling for high school quality by including SAT in the equation, this might not be enough. Perhaps high schools that did a better job of preparing students for college also had fewer students smoking marijuana. Or marijuana usage could be correlated with average income levels. These are, of course, empirical questions that we may or may not be able to answer. Question 15.3: Although prevalence of the NRA and subscribers to gun magazines are probably correlated with the presence of gun control legislation, it is not obvious that they are uncorrelated with unobserved factors that affect the violent crime rate. In fact, we might argue that a population interested in guns is a reflection of high crime rates, and controlling for economic and demographic variables is not sufficient to capture this. It would be hard to argue persuasively that these are truly exogenous in the violent crime equation. Question 15.4: As usual, there are two requirements. First, it should be the case that growth in government spending is systematically related to the party of the president, after netting out the investment rate and growth in the labor force. In other words, the instru- ment must be partially correlated with the endogenous explanatory variable. While we might think that government spending grows more slowly under Republican presidents, this certainly has not always been true in the United States and would have to be tested us- ing the t statistic on REPt􏱦1 in the reduced form gGOVt 􏱪 􏰵0 􏱕 􏰵1REPt􏱦1 􏱕 􏰵2INVRATt 􏱕 􏰵3gLABt 􏱕 vt. We must assume that the party of the president has no separate effect on gGDP. This would be violated if, for example, monetary policy differs systematically by presidential party and has a separate effect on GDP growth. Chapter 16 Question 16.1: Probably not. It is because firms choose price and advertising expendi- tures jointly that we are not interested in the experiment where, say, advertising changes exogenously and we want to know the effect on price. Instead, we would model price and advertising each as a function of demand and cost variables. This is what falls out of the economic theory. Question 16.2: We must assume two things. First, money supply growth should appear in equation (16.22), so that it is partially correlated with inf. Second, we must assume that money supply growth does not appear in equation (16.23). If we think we must include Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX F Answers to Chapter Questions 829 money supply growth in equation (16.23), then we are still short an instrument for inf. Of course, the assumption that money supply growth is exogenous can also be questioned. Question 16.3: Use the Hausman test from Chapter 15. In particular, let vˆ2 be the OLS residuals from the reduced form regression of open on log(pcinc) and log(land). Then, use an OLS regression of inf on open, log(pcinc), and vˆ2 and compute the t statistic for signifi- cance of vˆ2. If vˆ2 is significant, the 2SLS and OLS estimates are statistically different. Question 16.4: The demand equation looks like log(fisht) 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 􏱬1log(prcfisht) 􏱕 􏱬2log(inct) 􏱕 􏱬3log(prcchickt) 􏱕 􏱬4log(prcbeeft) 􏱕 ut1, where logarithms are used so that all elasticities are constant. By assumption, the demand function contains no seasonality, so the equation does not contain monthly dummy vari- ables (say, febt, mart, ..., dect, with January as the base month). Also, by assumption, the supply of fish is seasonal, which means that the supply function does depend on at least some of the monthly dummy variables. Even without solving the reduced form for log(prcfish), we conclude that it depends on the monthly dummy variables. Since these are exogenous, they can be used as instruments for log(prcfish) in the demand equation. Therefore, we can estimate the demand-for-fish equation using monthly dummies as the IVs for log(prcfish). Identification requires that at least one monthly dummy variable appears with a nonzero coefficient in the reduced form for log(prcfish). Chapter 17 Question 17.1: H0: 􏱬4 􏱪 􏱬5 􏱪 􏱬6 􏱪 0, so that there are three restrictions and therefore three df in the LR or Wald test. Question 17.2: We need the partial derivative of 􏱋(ˆ􏱬0 􏱕 ˆ􏱬1nwifeinc 􏱕 ˆ􏱬2educ 􏱕 􏱬ˆ3exper 􏱕 􏱬ˆ4exper2 􏱕 ...) with respect to exper, which is 􏰿(􏱳)(􏱬ˆ3 􏱕 2􏱬ˆ4exper), where 􏰿(􏱳) is evaluated at the given values and the initial level of experience. Therefore, we need to evaluate the standard normal probability density at .270 􏱦 .012(20.13) 􏱕 .131(12.3) 􏱕 .123(10) 􏱦 .0019(102) 􏱦 .053(42.5) 􏱦 .868(0) 􏱕 .036(1) 􏱴 .463, where we plug in the initial level of experience (10). But 􏰿(.463) 􏱪 (2􏰵)􏱦1/2 exp[􏱦(.4632)/2] 􏱴 .358. Next, we multiply this by 􏱬ˆ3 􏱕 2􏱬ˆ4exper, which is evaluated at exper 􏱪 10. The partial effect us- ing the calculus approximation is .358[.123 􏱦 2(.0019)(10)] 􏱴 .030. In other words, at the given values of the explanatory variables and starting at exper 􏱪 10, the next year of experience increases the probability of labor force participation by about .03. Question 17.3: No. The number of extramarital affairs is a nonnegative integer, which presumably takes on zero or small numbers for a substantial fraction of the population. It is not realistic to use a Tobit model, which, while allowing a pileup at zero, treats y as be- ing continuously distributed over positive values. Formally, assuming that y 􏱪 max(0,y*), where y* is normally distributed, is at odds with the discreteness of the number of extra- marital affairs when y 􏱰 0. Question 17.4: The adjusted standard errors are the usual Poisson MLE standard errors __ multiplied by 􏱧ˆ 􏱪 􏱯 2 􏱴 1.41, so the adjusted standard errors will be about 41% higher. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 830 APPENDICES The quasi-LR statistic is the usual LR statistic divided by 􏱧ˆ 2, so it will be one-half of the usual LR statistic. Question 17.5: By assumption, mvpi 􏱪 􏱬0 􏱕 xi􏱬 􏱕 ui, where, as usual, xi􏱬 denotes a linear function of the exogenous variables. Now, observed wage is the largest of the mini- mum wage and the marginal value product, so wagei 􏱪 max(minwagei,mvpi), which is very similar to equation (17.34), except that the max operator has replaced the min operator. Chapter 18 Question 18.1: We can plug these values directly into equation (18.1) and take expecta- tions.First,becausezs 􏱪0,foralls􏱷0,y􏱦1 􏱪􏱮􏱕u􏱦1.Then,z0􏱪1,soy0 􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛0 􏱕 u0. For h 􏱸 1, yh 􏱪 􏱮 􏱕 􏱛h􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛h 􏱕 uh. Because the errors have zero expected values, E(y􏱦1)􏱪􏱮,E(y0)􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛0,andE(yh)􏱪􏱮􏱕􏱛h􏱦1 􏱕􏱛,forallh􏱸1.Ash􏱽􏱵,􏱛h 􏱽0. It follows that E(yh) 􏱽 􏱮 as h 􏱽 􏱵, that is, the expected value of yh returns to the expected value before the increase in z, at time zero. This makes sense: although the increase in z lasted for two periods, it is still a temporary increase. Question 18.2: Under the described setup, 􏰧yt and 􏰧xt are i.i.d. sequences that are inde- pendent of one another. In particular, 􏰧yt and 􏰧xt are uncorrelated. If 􏰸ˆ1 is the slope coef- ficient from regressing 􏰧yt on 􏰧xt, t 􏱪 1, 2, ..., n, then plim 􏰸ˆ1 􏱪 0. This is as it should be, as we are regressing one I(0) process on another I(0) process, and they are uncorrelated. We write the equation 􏰧yt 􏱪 􏰸0 􏱕 􏰸1􏰧xt 􏱕 et, where 􏰸0 􏱪 􏰸1 􏱪 0. Because {et} is inde- pendent of {􏰧xt}, the strict exogeneity assumption holds. Moreover, {et} is serially uncor- related and homoskedastic. By Theorem 11.2 in Chapter 11, the t statistic for 􏰸ˆ1 has an approximate standard normal distribution. If et is normally distributed, the classical linear model assumptions hold, and the t statistic has an exact t distribution. Question 18.3: Write xt 􏱪 xt􏱦1 􏱕 at, where {at} is I(0). By assumption, there is a linear combination,say,st 􏱪yt 􏱦􏱬xt,whichisI(0).Now,yt 􏱦􏱬xt􏱦1 􏱪yt 􏱦􏱬(xt 􏱦at)􏱪st 􏱕 􏱬at. Because st and at are I(0) by assumption, so is st 􏱕 􏱬at. Question 18.4: Just use the sum of squared residuals form of the F test and assume homoskedasticity. The restricted SSR is obtained by regressing 􏰧hy6t 􏱦 􏰧hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 (hy6t􏱦1 􏱦 hy3t􏱦2) on a constant. Notice that 􏱮0 is the only parameter to estimate in 􏰧hy6t 􏱪 􏱮0 􏱕 􏰸0􏰧hy3t􏱦1 􏱕 􏱛(hy6t􏱦1 􏱦 hy3t􏱦2) when the restrictions are imposed. The unrestricted sum of squared residuals is obtained from equation (18.39). Question 18.5: We are fitting two equations: yˆt 􏱪 􏱮ˆ 􏱕 􏱬ˆt and yˆt 􏱪 􏰸ˆ 􏱕 􏱛ˆyeart. We can obtain the relationship between the parameters by noting that yeart 􏱪 t 􏱕 49. Plug- ging this into the second equation gives yˆt 􏱪 􏰸ˆ 􏱕 􏱛ˆ(t 􏱕 49) 􏱪 (􏰸ˆ 􏱕 49􏱛ˆ) 􏱕 􏱛ˆt. Matching the slope and intercept with the first equation gives 􏱛ˆ 􏱪 􏱬ˆ—so that the slopes on t and yeart are identical—and 􏱮ˆ 􏱪 􏰸ˆ 􏱕 49􏱛ˆ. Generally, when we use year rather than t, the in- tercept will change, but the slope will not. (You can verify this by using one of the time series data sets, such as HSEINV.RAW or INVEN.RAW.) Whether we use t or some measure of year does not change fitted values, and, naturally, it does not change forecasts of future values. The intercept simply adjusts appropriately to different ways of including a trend in the regression. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. APPENDIX G Statistical Tables T A B L E G . 1 Cumulative Areas under the Standard Normal Distribution z0123456789 􏱦3.0 0.0013 0.0013 0.0013 0.0012 0.0012 0.0011 0.0011 0.0011 0.0010 0.0010 􏱦2.9 0.0019 0.0018 0.0018 0.0017 0.0016 0.0016 0.0015 0.0015 0.0014 0.0014 􏱦2.8 0.0026 0.0025 0.0024 0.0023 0.0023 0.0022 0.0021 0.0021 0.0020 0.0019 􏱦2.7 0.0035 0.0034 0.0033 0.0032 0.0031 0.0030 0.0029 0.0028 0.0027 0.0026 􏱦2.6 0.0047 0.0045 0.0044 0.0043 0.0041 0.0040 0.0039 0.0038 0.0037 0.0036 􏱦2.5 0.0062 0.0060 0.0059 0.0057 0.0055 0.0054 0.0052 0.0051 0.0049 0.0048 􏱦2.4 0.0082 0.0080 0.0078 0.0075 0.0073 0.0071 0.0069 0.0068 0.0066 0.0064 􏱦2.3 0.0107 0.0104 0.0102 0.0099 0.0096 0.0094 0.0091 0.0089 0.0087 0.0084 􏱦2.2 0.0139 0.0136 0.0132 0.0129 0.0125 0.0122 0.0119 0.0116 0.0113 0.0110 􏱦2.1 0.0179 0.0174 0.0170 0.0166 0.0162 0.0158 0.0154 0.0150 0.0146 0.0143 􏱦2.0 0.0228 0.0222 0.0217 0.0212 0.0207 0.0202 0.0197 0.0192 0.0188 0.0183 􏱦1.9 0.0287 0.0281 0.0274 0.0268 0.0262 0.0256 0.0250 0.0244 0.0239 0.0233 􏱦1.8 0.0359 0.0351 0.0344 0.0336 0.0329 0.0322 0.0314 0.0307 0.0301 0.0294 􏱦1.7 0.0446 0.0436 0.0427 0.0418 0.0409 0.0401 0.0392 0.0384 0.0375 0.0367 􏱦1.6 0.0548 0.0537 0.0526 0.0516 0.0505 0.0495 0.0485 0.0475 0.0465 0.0455 􏱦1.5 0.0668 0.0655 0.0643 0.0630 0.0618 0.0606 0.0594 0.0582 0.0571 0.0559 􏱦1.4 0.0808 0.0793 0.0778 0.0764 0.0749 0.0735 0.0721 0.0708 0.0694 0.0681 􏱦1.3 0.0968 0.0951 0.0934 0.0918 0.0901 0.0885 0.0869 0.0853 0.0838 0.0823 􏱦1.2 0.1151 0.1131 0.1112 0.1093 0.1075 0.1056 0.1038 0.1020 0.1003 0.0985 􏱦1.1 0.1357 0.1335 0.1314 0.1292 0.1271 0.1251 0.1230 0.1210 0.1190 0.1170 􏱦1.0 0.1587 0.1562 0.1539 0.1515 0.1492 0.1469 0.1446 0.1423 0.1401 0.1379 􏱦0.9 0.1841 0.1814 0.1788 0.1762 0.1736 0.1711 0.1685 0.1660 0.1635 0.1611 􏱦0.8 0.2119 0.2090 0.2061 0.2033 0.2005 0.1977 0.1949 0.1922 0.1894 0.1867 􏱦0.7 0.2420 0.2389 0.2358 0.2327 0.2296 0.2266 0.2236 0.2206 0.2177 0.2148 􏱦0.6 0.2743 0.2709 0.2676 0.2643 0.2611 0.2578 0.2546 0.2514 0.2483 0.2451 􏱦0.5 0.3085 0.3050 0.3015 0.2981 0.2946 0.2912 0.2877 0.2843 0.2810 0.2776 (continued ) 831 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 832 APPENDICES TABLE G.1 (Continued) z0123456789 0.3446 0.3409 0.3372 0.3336 0.3300 0.3264 0.3228 0.3192 0.3156 􏱦0.4 􏱦0.3 0.3821 0.3783 0.3745 0.3707 0.3669 0.3632 0.3594 0.3557 0.3520 􏱦0.2 􏱦0.1 0.4602 0.4562 0.4522 0.4483 0.4443 0.4404 0.4364 0.4325 0.4286 􏱦0.0 0.0 0.5000 0.5040 0.5080 0.5120 0.5160 0.5199 0.5239 0.5279 0.5319 0.1 0.2 0.5793 0.5832 0.5871 0.5910 0.5948 0.5987 0.6026 0.6064 0.6103 0.3 0.4 0.6554 0.6591 0.6628 0.6664 0.6700 0.6736 0.6772 0.6808 0.6844 0.5 0.6 0.7257 0.7291 0.7324 0.7357 0.7389 0.7422 0.7454 0.7486 0.7517 0.7 0.8 0.7881 0.7910 0.7939 0.7967 0.7995 0.8023 0.8051 0.8078 0.8106 0.9 1.0 0.8413 0.8438 0.8461 0.8485 0.8508 0.8531 0.8554 0.8577 0.8599 1.1 1.2 0.8849 0.8869 0.8888 0.8907 0.8925 0.8944 0.8962 0.8980 0.8997 1.3 1.4 0.9192 0.9207 0.9222 0.9236 0.9251 0.9265 0.9279 0.9292 0.9306 1.5 1.6 0.9452 0.9463 0.9474 0.9484 0.9495 0.9505 0.9515 0.9525 0.9535 1.7 1.8 0.9641 0.9649 0.9656 0.9664 0.9671 0.9678 0.9686 0.9693 0.9699 1.9 2.0 0.9772 0.9778 0.9783 0.9788 0.9793 0.9798 0.9803 0.9808 0.9812 2.1 2.2 0.9861 0.9864 0.9868 0.9871 0.9875 0.9878 0.9881 0.9884 0.9887 2.3 2.4 0.9918 0.9920 0.9922 0.9925 0.9927 0.9929 0.9931 0.9932 0.9934 2.5 2.6 0.9953 0.9955 0.9956 0.9957 0.9959 0.9960 0.9961 0.9962 0.9963 2.7 2.8 0.9974 0.9975 0.9976 0.9977 0.9977 0.9978 0.9979 0.9979 0.9980 2.9 3.0 0.9987 0.9987 0.9987 0.9988 0.9988 0.9989 0.9989 0.9989 0.9990 Examples: If Z ~ Normal(0,1), then P(Z 􏰯 􏱦1.32) 􏱪 .0934 and P(Z 􏰯 1.84) 􏱪 .9671. Source: This table was generated using the Stata® function normprob. 0.3121 0.3483 0.3859 0.4247 0.4641 0.5359 0.5753 0.6141 0.6517 0.6879 0.7224 0.7549 0.7852 0.8133 0.8389 0.8621 0.8830 0.9015 0.9177 0.9319 0.9441 0.9545 0.9633 0.9706 0.9767 0.9817 0.9857 0.9890 0.9916 0.9936 0.9952 0.9964 0.9974 0.9981 0.9986 0.9990 0.4207 0.4168 0.4129 0.4090 0.4052 0.4013 0.3974 0.3936 0.3897 0.5000 0.4960 0.4920 0.4880 0.4840 0.4801 0.4761 0.4721 0.4681 0.5398 0.5438 0.5478 0.5517 0.5557 0.5596 0.5636 0.5675 0.5714 0.6179 0.6217 0.6255 0.6293 0.6331 0.6368 0.6406 0.6443 0.6480 0.6915 0.6950 0.6985 0.7019 0.7054 0.7088 0.7123 0.7157 0.7190 0.7580 0.7611 0.7642 0.7673 0.7704 0.7734 0.7764 0.7794 0.7823 0.8159 0.8186 0.8212 0.8238 0.8264 0.8289 0.8315 0.8340 0.8365 0.8643 0.8665 0.8686 0.8708 0.8729 0.8749 0.8770 0.8790 0.8810 0.9032 0.9049 0.9066 0.9082 0.9099 0.9115 0.9131 0.9147 0.9162 0.9332 0.9345 0.9357 0.9370 0.9382 0.9394 0.9406 0.9418 0.9429 0.9554 0.9564 0.9573 0.9582 0.9591 0.9599 0.9608 0.9616 0.9625 0.9713 0.9719 0.9726 0.9732 0.9738 0.9744 0.9750 0.9756 0.9761 0.9821 0.9826 0.9830 0.9834 0.9838 0.9842 0.9846 0.9850 0.9854 0.9893 0.9896 0.9898 0.9901 0.9904 0.9906 0.9909 0.9911 0.9913 0.9938 0.9940 0.9941 0.9943 0.9945 0.9946 0.9948 0.9949 0.9951 0.9965 0.9966 0.9967 0.9968 0.9969 0.9970 0.9971 0.9972 0.9973 0.9981 0.9982 0.9982 0.9983 0.9984 0.9984 0.9985 0.9985 0.9986 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX G Statistical Tables 833 T A B L E G . 2 Critical Values of the t Distribution 1-Tailed: .10 2-Tailed: .20 Significance Level .05 .025 .10 .05 2.920 4.303 2.132 2.776 1.943 2.447 1.860 2.306 1.812 2.228 1.782 2.179 1.761 2.145 1.746 2.120 1.734 2.101 1.725 2.086 1.717 2.074 1.711 2.064 1.706 2.056 1.701 2.048 1.697 2.042 1.671 2.000 1.658 1.980 .01 .02 6.965 3.747 3.143 2.896 2.764 2.681 2.624 2.583 2.552 2.528 2.508 2.492 2.479 2.467 2.457 2.390 2.358 .005 .01 63.657 9.925 5.841 4.604 4.032 3.707 3.499 3.355 3.250 3.169 3.106 3.055 3.012 2.977 2.947 2.921 2.898 2.878 2.861 2.845 2.831 2.819 2.807 2.797 2.787 2.779 2.771 2.763 2.756 2.750 2.704 2.660 2.632 2.617 2.576 1 3.078 6.314 12.706 31.821 3 1.638 2.353 3.182 4.541 5 1.476 2.015 2.571 3.365 7 1.415 1.895 2.365 2.998 9 1.383 1.833 2.262 2.821 D e g r e e s o f F r e e d o m 2 1.886 4 1.533 6 1.440 8 1.397 10 1.372 12 1.356 14 1.345 16 1.337 18 1.330 20 1.325 22 1.321 24 1.318 26 1.315 28 1.313 30 1.310 60 1.296 120 1.289 11 1.363 1.796 2.201 2.718 13 1.350 1.771 2.160 2.650 15 1.341 1.753 2.131 2.602 17 1.333 1.740 2.110 2.567 19 1.328 1.729 2.093 2.539 21 1.323 1.721 2.080 2.518 23 1.319 1.714 2.069 2.500 25 1.316 1.708 2.060 2.485 27 1.314 1.703 2.052 2.473 29 1.311 1.699 2.045 2.462 40 1.303 1.684 2.021 2.423 90 1.291 1.662 1.987 2.368 􏱵 1.282 1.645 1.960 2.326 Examples: The 1% critical value for a one-tailed test with 25 df is 2.485. The 5% critical value for a two-tailed test with large (􏱰 120) df is 1.96. Source: This table was generated using the Stata® function invttail. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 834 APPENDICES TABLE G.3a 10% Critical Values of the F Distribution D e n 12 3.18 2.81 2.61 2.48 2.39 2.33 2.28 2.24 2.21 2.19 o m i 14 3.10 2.73 2.52 2.39 2.31 2.24 2.19 2.15 2.12 2.10 n a t 16 3.05 2.67 2.46 2.33 2.24 2.18 2.13 2.09 2.06 2.03 13 3.14 2.96 2.76 2.57 2.56 2.40 2.36 Numerator Degrees of Freedom 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 10 3.29 2.92 2.73 2.61 2.52 2.46 2.41 2.38 2.35 2.32 11 3.23 2.86 2.66 2.54 2.43 2.27 2.23 r 22 2.95 2.56 2.35 2.22 2.13 2.06 2.01 1.97 1.93 1.90 e e s 24 2.93 2.54 2.33 2.19 2.10 2.04 1.98 1.94 1.91 1.88 2.45 2.35 2.18 2.14 2.39 2.28 2.21 2.11 2.08 2.34 2.23 2.16 2.06 2.02 2.30 2.20 2.12 2.02 1.98 2.27 2.09 2.25 2.16 2.14 15 3.07 2.70 2.49 2.36 2.27 2.06 17 3.03 2.64 2.44 1.98 2.00 o r 18 3.01 2.62 2.42 2.29 2.20 2.13 2.08 2.04 2.00 1.98 2.31 2.22 2.15 2.10 2.06 2.03 19 2.99 2.61 1.96 De 20 2.97 2.59 2.38 2.25 2.16 2.09 2.04 2.00 1.96 1.94 g 21 1.95 1.92 23 2.94 2.55 2.34 2.21 2.11 2.05 1.99 1.95 1.92 1.89 o f 26 2.91 2.52 2.31 2.17 2.08 2.01 1.96 1.92 1.88 1.86 25 2.92 2.53 2.32 2.18 2.09 2.02 1.97 1.93 1.87 27 2.90 2.51 2.30 2.17 2.07 2.00 1.89 F r 28 2.89 2.50 2.29 2.16 2.06 2.00 1.94 1.90 1.87 1.84 1.85 e e d 30 2.88 2.49 2.28 2.14 2.05 1.98 1.93 1.88 1.85 1.82 1.95 1.91 1.87 29 2.89 2.50 2.28 2.15 2.06 1.83 􏱵 2.71 2.30 2.08 1.94 1.85 1.99 1.77 1.93 1.78 1.72 1.89 o m 60 2.79 2.39 2.18 2.04 1.95 1.87 1.82 1.77 1.74 1.71 40 2.84 2.44 2.23 1.74 1.67 1.86 1.70 1.76 90 2.76 2.36 2.15 2.09 2.01 2.00 1.91 1.93 1.84 1.87 1.83 1.79 1.67 120 2.75 2.35 2.13 1.99 1.90 1.82 1.77 1.72 1.68 1.65 1.63 1.60 Example: The 10% critical value for numerator df 􏱪 2 and denominator df 􏱪 40 is 2.44. Source: This table was generated using the Stata® function invFtail. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX G Statistical Tables 835 TABLE G.3b 5% Critical Values of the F Distribution D e n 12 4.75 3.89 3.49 3.26 3.11 3.00 2.91 2.85 2.80 2.75 3.52 3.13 Numerator Degrees of Freedom 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 10 4.96 4.10 3.71 3.48 3.33 3.22 3.14 3.07 3.02 2.98 11 4.84 3.98 3.59 3.36 2.96 or 18 4.41 3.55 3.16 2.93 2.77 2.66 2.58 2.51 2.46 2.41 2.90 3.20 2.81 2.74 3.09 3.01 2.71 2.61 2.54 2.95 2.64 2.55 2.48 2.90 2.59 2.85 o m i 14 4.60 3.74 3.34 3.11 2.96 2.85 2.76 2.70 2.65 2.60 13 15 4.67 4.54 3.81 3.68 3.41 3.29 3.18 3.06 3.03 2.90 2.92 2.79 2.83 2.77 2.71 2.67 2.54 n a t 16 4.49 3.63 3.24 3.01 2.85 2.74 2.66 2.59 2.54 2.49 17 4.45 3.59 3.20 2.70 2.49 2.42 2.45 19 4.38 2.63 2.38 D 20 4.35 3.49 3.10 2.87 2.71 2.60 2.51 2.45 2.39 2.35 e g r 22 4.30 3.44 3.05 2.82 2.66 2.55 2.46 2.40 2.34 2.30 e e s 24 4.26 3.40 3.01 2.78 2.62 2.51 2.42 2.36 2.30 2.25 21 4.32 3.47 3.07 2.84 2.68 2.57 2.49 2.42 2.37 2.32 23 4.28 3.42 3.03 2.80 2.64 2.53 2.44 2.37 2.32 2.27 o f 26 4.23 3.37 2.98 2.74 2.59 2.47 2.39 2.32 2.27 2.22 25 4.24 3.39 2.99 2.76 2.60 2.49 2.40 2.34 2.24 27 4.21 3.35 2.96 2.73 2.57 2.46 2.28 F r 28 4.20 3.34 2.95 2.71 2.56 2.45 2.36 2.29 2.24 2.19 2.20 29 4.18 3.33 2.93 2.70 2.43 2.37 2.31 2.25 e e d 30 4.17 3.32 2.92 2.69 2.53 2.42 2.33 2.27 2.21 2.16 2.18 o m 60 4.00 3.15 2.76 2.53 2.37 2.25 2.17 2.10 2.04 1.99 40 􏱵 4.08 3.84 3.23 3.00 2.60 2.37 2.55 2.21 2.34 2.10 2.35 2.11 2.01 2.28 2.04 1.94 2.22 1.99 2.08 90 3.95 3.10 2.84 2.71 2.61 2.47 2.45 2.32 2.20 2.25 2.18 2.12 1.94 120 3.92 3.07 2.68 2.45 2.29 2.17 2.09 2.02 1.96 1.91 1.88 1.83 Example: The 5% critical value for numerator df 􏱪 4 and large denominator df (􏱵) is 2.37. Source: This table was generated using the Stata® function invFtail. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 836 APPENDICES TABLE G.3c 1% Critical Values of the F Distribution D e n 12 9.33 6.93 5.95 5.41 5.06 4.82 4.64 4.50 4.39 4.30 11 13 15 9.07 6.70 5.74 Numerator Degrees of Freedom 1 2 3 4 5 6 7 8 9 10 10 10.04 7.56 6.55 5.99 5.64 5.39 5.20 5.06 4.94 4.85 9.65 7.21 6.22 5.67 5.21 mo 14 8.86 6.51 5.56 5.04 4.69 4.46 4.28 4.14 4.03 3.94 i na 16 8.53 6.23 5.29 4.77 4.44 4.20 4.03 3.89 3.78 3.69 t 17 19 5.93 5.18 5.01 4.67 4.50 5.32 4.86 4.56 4.34 4.17 5.07 4.62 4.89 4.44 4.14 3.93 3.77 4.74 4.30 4.00 3.79 3.63 4.63 3.89 4.54 4.19 4.10 8.68 6.36 5.42 4.89 4.32 3.80 8.40 6.11 4.10 3.68 3.52 3.59 or 18 8.29 6.01 5.09 4.58 4.25 4.01 3.84 3.71 3.60 3.51 8.18 3.94 3.43 D 20 8.10 5.85 4.94 4.43 4.10 3.87 3.70 3.56 3.46 3.37 e gr 22 7.95 5.72 4.82 4.31 3.99 3.76 3.59 3.45 3.35 3.26 e e s 24 7.82 5.61 4.72 4.22 3.90 3.67 3.50 3.36 3.26 3.17 21 8.02 5.78 4.87 4.37 4.04 3.81 3.64 3.51 3.40 3.31 23 25 7.88 5.66 4.76 4.26 3.94 3.71 3.54 3.41 3.30 3.21 o f 26 7.72 5.53 4.64 4.14 3.82 3.59 3.42 3.29 3.18 3.09 7.77 5.57 4.68 4.18 3.85 3.63 3.46 3.32 3.22 3.13 F r 28 7.64 5.45 4.57 4.07 3.75 3.53 3.36 3.23 3.12 3.03 27 7.68 7.60 5.49 5.42 4.60 4.54 4.11 4.04 3.78 3.73 3.56 3.50 3.39 3.26 3.15 3.06 e e d 30 7.56 5.39 4.51 4.02 3.70 3.47 3.30 3.17 3.07 2.98 3.00 o m 60 7.08 4.98 4.13 3.65 3.34 3.12 2.95 2.82 2.72 2.63 29 40 90 􏱵 7.31 6.93 6.63 5.18 4.85 4.61 4.31 4.01 3.78 3.83 3.54 3.32 3.51 3.23 3.02 3.29 3.01 2.80 3.33 3.12 2.84 2.64 3.20 2.99 2.72 2.51 3.09 2.89 2.61 2.80 2.52 120 6.85 4.79 3.95 3.48 3.17 2.96 2.79 2.66 2.56 2.47 2.41 2.32 Example: The 1% critical value for numerator df 􏱪 3 and denominator df 􏱪 60 is 4.13. Source: This table was generated using the Stata® function invFtail. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 APPENDIX G Statistical Tables 837 T A B L E G . 4 Critical Values of the Chi-Square Distribution F r e 18 25.99 28.87 34.81 13 17 21 19.81 24.77 29.62 32.01 Significance Level .10 .05 .01 1 2.71 3.84 22.36 6.63 2 4.61 5.99 9.21 3 6.25 7.81 11.34 4 7.78 9.49 13.28 D e 10 15.99 18.31 23.21 g r e 12 18.55 21.03 26.22 5 9 9.24 14.68 11.07 16.92 15.09 6 10.64 12.59 16.81 7 12.02 14.07 18.48 8 13.36 15.51 20.09 21.67 e 11 17.28 19.68 24.72 27.69 14 21.06 23.68 29.14 o 15 22.31 25.00 27.59 32.67 30.58 16 23.54 26.30 32.00 33.41 e d o m 20 28.41 31.41 37.57 19 27.20 30.14 36.19 38.93 22 30.81 33.92 40.29 23 35.17 41.64 24 33.20 36.42 42.98 25 34.38 37.65 44.31 26 35.56 38.89 45.64 27 36.74 40.11 46.96 28 37.92 41.34 48.28 29 39.09 42.56 49.59 30 40.26 43.77 50.89 s f Example: The 5% critical value with df 􏱪 8 is 15.51. Source: This table was generated using the Stata® function invchi2tail. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. © Cengage Learning, 2013 REFERENCES Angrist, J. D. (1990), “Lifetime Earnings and the Vietnam Era Draft Lottery: Evidence from Social Security Administrative Records,” American Economic Re- view 80, 313–336. Angrist, J. D., and A. B. Krueger (1991), “Does Com- pulsory School Attendance Affect Schooling and Earnings?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 106, 979–1014. Ashenfelter, O., and A. B. Krueger (1994), “Estimates of the Economic Return to Schooling from a New Sample of Twins,” American Economic Review 84, 1157–1173. Averett, S., and S. Korenman (1996), “The Economic Reality of the Beauty Myth,” Journal of Human Resources 31, 304–330. Ayres, I., and S. D. Levitt (1998), “Measuring Positive Externalities from Unobservable Victim Precaution: An Empirical Analysis of Lojack,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 43–77. Banerjee, A., J. Dolado, J. W. Galbraith, and D. F. Hendry (1993), Co-Integration, Error-Correction, and the Econometric Analysis of Non-Stationary Data. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Bartik, T. J. (1991), “The Effects of Property Taxes and Other Local Public Policies on the Intrametro- politan Pattern of Business Location,” in Industry Location and Public Policy, ed. H. W. Herzog and A. M. Schlottmann, 57–80. Knoxville: University of Tennessee Press. Becker, G. S. (1968), “Crime and Punishment: An Economic Approach,” Journal of Political Economy 76, 169–217. Belsley, D., E. Kuh, and R. Welsch (1980), Regres- sion Diagnostics: Identifying Influential Data and Sources of Collinearity. New York: Wiley. Berk, R. A. (1990), “A Primer on Robust Regression,” in Modern Methods of Data Analysis, ed. J. Fox and J. S. Long, 292–324. Newbury Park, CA: Sage Publications. Betts, J. R. (1995), “Does School Quality Matter? Evidence from the National Longitudinal Survey 838 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. of Youth,” Review of Economics and Statistics 77, 231–250. Biddle, J. E., and D. S. Hamermesh (1990), “Sleep and the Allocation of Time,” Journal of Political Economy 98, 922–943. Biddle, J. E., and D. S. Hamermesh (1998), “Beauty, Productivity, and Discrimination: Lawyers’ Looks and Lucre,” Journal of Labor Economics 16, 172–201. Blackburn, M., and D. Neumark (1992), “Unobserved Ability, Efficiency Wages, and Interindustry Wage Differentials,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 1421–1436. Blomström, M., R. E. Lipsey, and M. Zejan (1996), “Is Fixed Investment the Key to Economic Growth?” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 269–276. Blundell, R., A. Duncan, and K. Pendakur (1998), “Semi- parametric Estimation and Consumer Demand,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 13, 435–461. Bollerslev, T., R. Y. Chou, and K. F. Kroner (1992), “ARCH Modeling in Finance: A Review of the Theory and Empirical Evidence,” Journal of Econo- metrics 52, 5–59. Bollerslev, T., R. F. Engle, and D. B. Nelson (1994), “ARCH Models,” in Handbook of Econometrics, volume 4, chapter 49, ed. R. F. Engle and D. L. McFadden, 2959–3038. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Bound, J., D. A. Jaeger, and R. M. Baker (1995), “Prob- lems with Instrumental Variables Estimation when the Correlation between the Instruments and Endog- enous Explanatory Variables Is Weak,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 90, 443–450. Breusch, T. S., and A. R. Pagan (1979), “A Simple Test for Heteroskedasticity and Random Coefficient Variation,” Econometrica 47, 987–1007. Cameron, A. C., and P. K. Trivedi (1998), Regression Analysis of Count Data. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Campbell, J. Y., and N. G. Mankiw (1990), “Permanent Income, Current Income, and Consumption,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 8, 265–279. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Card, D. (1995), “Using Geographic Variation in College Proximity to Estimate the Return to Schooling,” in Aspects of Labour Market Behavior: Essays in Honour of John Vanderkamp, ed. L. N. Christophides, E. K. Grant, and R. Swidinsky, 201–222. Toronto: University of Toronto Press. Card, D., and A. Krueger (1992), “Does School Quality Matter? Returns to Education and the Characteristics of Public Schools in the United States,” Journal of Political Economy 100, 1–40. Castillo-Freeman, A. J., and R. B. Freeman (1992), “When the Minimum Wage Really Bites: The Effect of the U.S.-Level Minimum on Puerto Rico,” in Immigration and the Work Force, ed. G. J. Borjas and R. B. Freeman, 177–211. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Clark, K. B. (1984), “Unionization and Firm Perfor- mance: The Impact on Profits, Growth, and Produc- tivity,” American Economic Review 74, 893–919. Cloninger, D. O. (1991), “Lethal Police Response as a Crime Deterrent: 57-City Study Suggests a Decrease in Certain Crimes,” American Journal of Economics and Sociology 50, 59–69. Cloninger, D. O., and L. C. Sartorius (1979), “Crime Rates, Clearance Rates and Enforcement Effort: The Case of Houston, Texas,” American Journal of Eco- nomics and Sociology 38, 389–402. Cochrane, J. H. (1997), “Where Is the Market Going? Uncertain Facts and Novel Theories,” Economic Perspectives 21, Federal Reserve Bank of Chicago, 3–37. Cornwell, C., and W. N. Trumbull (1994), “Estimating the Economic Model of Crime Using Panel Data,” Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 360–366. Craig, B. R., W. E. Jackson III, and J. B. Thomson (2007), “Small Firm Finance, Credit Rationing, and the Impact of SBA-Guaranteed Lending on Local Economic Growth,” Journal of Small Business Man- agement 45, 116–132. Currie, J. (1995), Welfare and the Well-Being of Children. Chur, Switzerland: Harwood Academic Publishers. Currie, J., and N. Cole (1993), “Welfare and Child Health: The Link between AFDC Participation and Birth Weight,” American Economic Review 83, 971–983. Currie, J., and D. Thomas (1995), “Does Head Start Make a Difference?” American Economic Review 85, 341–364. Davidson, R., and J. G. MacKinnon (1981), “Several Tests of Model Specification in the Presence of Alter- native Hypotheses,” Econometrica 49, 781–793. Davidson, R., and J. G. MacKinnon (1993), Estimation and Inference in Econometrics. New York: Oxford University Press. De Long, J. B., and L. H. Summers (1991), “Equipment Investment and Economic Growth,” Quarterly Jour- nal of Economics 106, 445–502. Dickey, D. A., and W. A. Fuller (1979), “Distributions of the Estimators for Autoregressive Time Series with a Unit Root,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 74, 427–431. Diebold, F. X. (2001), Elements of Forecasting. 2nd ed. Cincinnati: South-Western. Downes, T. A., and S. M. Greenstein (1996), “Under- standing the Supply Decisions of Nonprofits: Model- ing the Location of Private Schools,” Rand Journal of Economics 27, 365–390. Draper, N., and H. Smith (1981), Applied Regression Analysis. 2nd ed. New York: Wiley. Duan, N. (1983), “Smearing Estimate: A Nonparametric Retransformation Method,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 78, 605–610. Durbin, J. (1970), “Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares Regressions when Some of the Regressors Are Lagged Dependent Variables,” Econometrica 38, 410–421. Durbin, J., and G. S. Watson (1950), “Testing for Serial Correlation in Least Squares Regressions I,” Biometrika 37, 409–428. Eicker, F. (1967), “Limit Theorems for Regressions with Unequal and Dependent Errors,” Proceedings of the Fifth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability 1, 59–82. Berkeley: University of California Press. Eide, E. (1994), Economics of Crime: Deterrence and the Rational Offender. Amsterdam: North-Holland. Engle, R. F. (1982), “Autoregressive Conditional Het- eroskedasticity with Estimates of the Variance of United Kingdom Inflation,” Econometrica 50, 987–1007. Engle, R. F., and C. W. J. Granger (1987), “Cointegration and Error Correction: Representation, Estimation, and Testing,” Econometrica 55, 251–276. Evans, W. N., and R. M. Schwab (1995), “Finishing High School and Starting College: Do Catholic Schools Make a Difference?” Quarterly Journal of Econom- ics 110, 941–974. Fair, R. C. (1996), “Econometrics and Presidential Elec- tions,” Journal of Economic Perspectives 10, 89–102. Franses, P. H., and R. Paap (2001), Quantitative Mod- els in Marketing Research. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. References 839 840 References Freeman, D. G. (2007), “Drunk Driving Legislation and Traffic Fatalities: New Evidence on BAC 08 Laws,” Contemporary Economic Policy 25, 293–308. Friedman, B. M., and K. N. Kuttner (1992), “Money, Income, Prices, and Interest Rates,” American Eco- nomic Review 82, 472–492. Geronimus, A. T., and S. Korenman (1992), “The Socioeconomic Consequences of Teen Childbearing Reconsidered,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 107, 1187–1214. Goldberger, A. S. (1991), A Course in Econometrics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Graddy, K. (1995), “Testing for Imperfect Competition at the Fulton Fish Market,” Rand Journal of Econom- ics 26, 75–92. Graddy, K. (1997), “Do Fast-Food Chains Price Dis- criminate on the Race and Income Characteristics of an Area?” Journal of Business and Economic Statis- tics 15, 391–401. Granger, C. W. J., and P. Newbold (1974), “Spurious Regressions in Econometrics,” Journal of Economet- rics 2, 111–120. Greene, W. (1997), Econometric Analysis. 3rd ed. New York: MacMillan. Griliches, Z. (1957), “Specification Bias in Estimates of Production Functions,” Journal of Farm Economics 39, 8–20. Grogger, J. (1990), “The Deterrent Effect of Capital Pun- ishment: An Analysis of Daily Homicide Counts,” Journal of the American Statistical Association 410, 295–303. Grogger, J. (1991), “Certainty vs. Severity of Punish- ment,” Economic Inquiry 29, 297–309. Hall, R. E. (1988), “The Relation between Price and Marginal Cost in U.S. Industry,” Journal of Political Economy 96, 921–948. Hamermesh, D. S., and J. E. Biddle (1994), “Beauty and the Labor Market,” American Economic Review 84, 1174–1194. Hamermesh, D. H., and A. Parker (2005), “Beauty in the Classroom: Instructors’ Pulchritude and Putative Pedagogical Productivity,” Economics of Education Review 24, 369–376. Hamilton, J. D. (1994), Time Series Analysis. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Hanushek, E. (1986), “The Economics of Schooling: Production and Efficiency in Public Schools,” Jour- nal of Economic Literature 24, 1141–1177. Harvey, A. (1990), The Econometric Analysis of Economic Time Series. 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Hausman, J. A. (1978), “Specification Tests in Econo- metrics,” Econometrica 46, 1251–1271. Hausman, J. A., and D. A. Wise (1977), “Social Experimentation, Truncated Distributions, and Effi- cient Estimation,” Econometrica 45, 319–339. Hayasyi, F. (2000), Econometrics. Princeton, NJ: Princeton University Press. Heckman, J. J. (1976), “The Common Structure of Statistical Models of Truncation, Sample Selec- tion, and Limited Dependent Variables and a Simple Estimator for Such Models,” Annals of Economic and Social Measurement 5, 475–492. Herrnstein, R. J., and C. Murray (1994), The Bell Curve: Intelligence and Class Structure in American Life. New York: Free Press. Hersch, J., and L. S. Stratton (1997), “Housework, Fixed Effects, and Wages of Married Workers,” Journal of Human Resources 32, 285–307. Hines, J. R. (1996), “Altered States: Taxes and the Location of Foreign Direct Investment in America,” American Economic Review 86, 1076–1094. Holzer, H. (1991), “The Spatial Mismatch Hypothesis: What Has the Evidence Shown?” Urban Studies 28, 105–122. Holzer, H., R. Block, M. Cheatham, and J. Knott (1993), “Are Training Subsidies Effective? The Michigan Experience,” Industrial and Labor Relations Review 46, 625–636. Horowitz, J. (2001), “The Bootstrap,” in Handbook of Econometrics, volume 5, chapter 52, ed. E. Leamer and J. L. Heckman, 3159–3228. Amsterdam: North Holland. Hoxby, C. M. (1994), “Do Private Schools Provide Com- petition for Public Schools?” National Bureau of Economic Research Working Paper Number 4978. Huber, P. J. (1967), “The Behavior of Maximum Like- lihood Estimates under Nonstandard Conditions,” Proceedings of the Fifth Berkeley Symposium on Mathematical Statistics and Probability 1, 221–233. Berkeley: University of California Press. Hunter, W. C., and M. B. Walker (1996), “The Cultural Affinity Hypothesis and Mortgage Lending Decisions,” Journal of Real Estate Finance and Economics 13, 57–70. Hylleberg, S. (1992), Modelling Seasonality. Oxford: Oxford University Press. Imbens, G. W., and J. M. Wooldridge (2007), “What’s New in Econometrics?” Lecture Notes, National Bureau of Economic Research Summer Institute, 2007. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Kane, T. J., and C. E. Rouse (1995), “Labor-Market Returns to Two- and Four-Year Colleges,” American Economic Review 85, 600–614. Kiefer, N. M., and T. J. Vogelsang (2005), “A New Asymptotic Theory for Heteroskedasticity- Autocorrelation Robust Tests,” Econometric Theory 21, 1130–1164. Kiel, K. A., and K. T. McClain (1995), “House Prices during Siting Decision Stages: The Case of an Incinerator from Rumor through Operation,” Journal of Environmental Economics and Management 28, 241–255. Kleck, G., and E. B. Patterson (1993), “The Impact of Gun Control and Gun Ownership Levels on Vio- lence Rates,” Journal of Quantitative Criminology 9, 249–287. Koenker, R. (1981), “A Note on Studentizing a Test for Het- eroskedasticity,” Journal of Econometrics 17, 107–112. Koenker, R. (2005), Quantile Regression. Cambridge: Cambridge University Press. Korenman, S., and D. Neumark (1991), “Does Marriage Really Make Men More Productive?” Journal of Human Resources 26, 282–307. Korenman, S., and D. Neumark (1992), “Marriage, Moth- erhood, and Wages,” Journal of Human Resources 27, 233–255. Krueger, A. B. (1993), “How Computers Have Changed the Wage Structure: Evidence from Microdata, 1984–1989,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 33–60. Krupp, C. M., and P. S. Pollard (1996), “Market Responses to Antidumping Laws: Some Evidence from the U.S. Chemical Industry,” Canadian Journal of Economics 29, 199–227. Kwiatkowski, D., P. C. B. Phillips, P. Schmidt, and Y. Shin (1992), “Testing the Null Hypothesis of Stationarity against the Alternative of a Unit Root: How Sure Are We That Economic Time Series Have a Unit Root?” Journal of Econometrics 54, 159–178. Lalonde, R. J. (1986), “Evaluating the Econometric Evaluations of Training Programs with Experimental Data,” American Economic Review 76, 604–620. Larsen, R. J., and M. L. Marx (1986), An Introduction to Mathematical Statistics and Its Applications. 2nd ed. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice-Hall. Leamer, E. E. (1983), “Let’s Take the Con Out of Econo- metrics,” American Economic Review 73, 31–43. Levine, P. B., A. B. Trainor, and D. J. Zimmerman (1996), “The Effect of Medicaid Abortion Funding References 841 Restrictions on Abortions, Pregnancies, and Births,” Journal of Health Economics 15, 555–578. Levine, P. B., and D. J. Zimmerman (1995), “The Benefit of Additional High-School Math and Science Classes for Young Men and Women,” Journal of Business and Economics Statistics 13, 137–149. Levitt, S. D. (1994), “Using Repeat Challengers to Estimate the Effect of Campaign Spending on Elec- tion Outcomes in the U.S. House,” Journal of Politi- cal Economy 102, 777–798. Levitt, S. D. (1996), “The Effect of Prison Popula- tion Size on Crime Rates: Evidence from Prison Overcrowding Legislation,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 111, 319–351. Low, S. A., and L. R. McPheters (1983), “Wage Differentials and the Risk of Death: An Empirical Analysis,” Economic Inquiry 21, 271–280. Lynch, L. M. (1992), “Private Sector Training and the Earnings of Young Workers,” American Economic Review 82, 299–312. MacKinnon, J. G., and H. White (1985), “Some Het- eroskedasticity Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimators with Improved Finite Sample Properties,” Journal of Econometrics 29, 305–325. Maloney, M. T., and R. E. McCormick (1993), “An Examination of the Role that Intercollegiate Athletic Participation Plays in Academic Achievement: Ath- letes’ Feats in the Classroom,” Journal of Human Resources 28, 555–570. Mankiw, N. G. (1994), Macroeconomics. 2nd ed. New York: Worth. Mark, S. T., T. J. McGuire, and L. E. Papke (2000), “The Influence of Taxes on Employment and Popu- lation Growth: Evidence from the Washington, D.C. Metropolitan Area,” National Tax Journal 53, 105–123. McCarthy, P. S. (1994), “Relaxed Speed Limits and Highway Safety: New Evidence from California,” Economics Letters 46, 173–179. McClain, K. T., and J. M. Wooldridge (1995), “A Simple Test for the Consistency of Dynamic Linear Regres- sion in Rational Distributed Lag Models,” Economics Letters 48, 235–240. McCormick, R. E., and M. Tinsley (1987), “Athlet- ics versus Academics: Evidence from SAT Scores,” Journal of Political Economy 95, 1103–1116. McFadden, D. L. (1974), “Conditional Logit Analy- sis of Qualitative Choice Behavior,” in Frontiers in Econometrics, ed. P. Zarembka, 105–142. New York: Academic Press. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 842 References Meyer, B. D. (1995), “Natural and Quasi-Experiments in Economics,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 13, 151–161. Meyer, B. D., W. K. Viscusi, and D. L. Durbin (1995), “Workers’ Compensation and Injury Duration: Evidence from a Natural Experiment,” American Economic Review 85, 322–340. Mizon, G. E., and J. F. Richard (1986), “The Encom- passing Principle and Its Application to Testing Nonnested Hypotheses,” Econometrica 54, 657–678. Mroz, T. A. (1987), “The Sensitivity of an Empirical Model of Married Women’s Hours of Work to Eco- nomic and Statistical Assumptions,” Econometrica 55, 765–799. Mullahy, J., and P. R. Portney (1990), “Air Pollution, Cigarette Smoking, and the Production of Respiratory Health,” Journal of Health Economics 9, 193–205. Mullahy, J., and J. L. Sindelar (1994), “Do Drinkers Know When to Say When? An Empirical Analysis of Drunk Driving,” Economic Inquiry 32, 383–394. Netzer, D. (1992), “Differences in Reliance on User Charges by American State and Local Governments,” Public Finance Quarterly 20, 499–511. Neumark, D. (1996), “Sex Discrimination in Restaurant Hiring: An Audit Study,” Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics 111, 915–941. Neumark, D., and W. Wascher (1995), “Minimum Wage Effects on Employment and School Enrollment,” Jour- nal of Business and Economic Statistics 13, 199–206. Newey, W. K., and K. D. West (1987), “A Simple, Posi- tive Semi-Definite Heteroskedasticity and Autocorre- lation Consistent Covariance Matrix,” Econometrica 55, 703–708. Papke, L. E. (1987), “Subnational Taxation and Capital Mobility: Estimates of Tax-Price Elasticities,” National Tax Journal 40, 191–203. Papke, L. E. (1994), “Tax Policy and Urban Develop- ment: Evidence from the Indiana Enterprise Zone Program,” Journal of Public Economics 54, 37–49. Papke, L. E. (1995), “Participation in and Contributions to 401(k) Pension Plans: Evidence from Plan Data,” Journal of Human Resources 30, 311–325. Papke, L. E. (1999), “Are 401(k) Plans Replacing Other Employer-Provided Pensions? Evidence from Panel Data,” Journal of Human Resources, 34, 346–368. Papke, L. E. (2005), “The Effects of Spending on Test Pass Rates: Evidence from Michigan,” Journal of Public Economics 89, 821–839. Park, R. (1966), “Estimation with Heteroskedastic Error Terms,” Econometrica 34, 888. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Peek, J. (1982), “Interest Rates, Income Taxes, and Anticipated Inflation,” American Economic Review 72, 980–991. Pindyck, R. S., and D. L. Rubinfeld (1992), Microeco- nomics. 2nd ed. New York: Macmillan. Ram, R. (1986), “Government Size and Economic Growth: A New Framework and Some Evidence from Cross-Section and Time-Series Data,” American Eco- nomic Review 76, 191–203. Ramanathan, R. (1995), Introductory Econometrics with Applications. 3rd ed. Fort Worth: Dryden Press. Ramey, V. (1991), “Nonconvex Costs and the Behavior of Inventories,” Journal of Political Economy 99, 306–334. Ramsey, J. B. (1969), “Tests for Specification Errors in Classical Linear Least-Squares Analysis,” Journal of the Royal Statistical Association, Series B, 71, 350–371. Romer, D. (1993), “Openness and Inflation: Theory and Evidence,” Quarterly Journal of Economics 108, 869–903. Rose, N. L. (1985), “The Incidence of Regulatory Rents in the Motor Carrier Industry,” Rand Journal of Eco- nomics 16, 299–318. Rose, N. L., and A. Shepard (1997), “Firm Diversifi- cation and CEO Compensation: Managerial Abil- ity or Executive Entrenchment?” Rand Journal of Economics 28, 489–514. Rouse, C. E. (1998), “Private School Vouchers and Stu- dent Achievement: An Evaluation of the Milwaukee Parental Choice Program,” Quarterly Journal of Eco- nomics 113, 553–602. Sander, W. (1992), “The Effect of Women’s Schooling on Fertility,” Economic Letters 40, 229–233. Savin, N. E., and K. J. White (1977), “The Durbin-Watson Test for Serial Correlation with Extreme Sample Sizes or Many Regressors,” Econometrica 45, 1989–1996. Shea, J. (1993), “The Input-Output Approach to Instru- ment Selection,” Journal of Business and Economic Statistics 11, 145–155. Shughart, W. F., and R. D. Tollison (1984), “The Ran- dom Character of Merger Activity,” Rand Journal of Economics 15, 500–509. Solon, G. (1985), “The Minimum Wage and Teenage Employment: A Re-analysis with Attention to Serial Correlation and Seasonality,” Journal of Human Resources 20, 292–297. Staiger, D., and J. H. Stock (1997), “Instrumental Vari- ables Regression with Weak Instruments,” Econo- metrica 65, 557–586. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Stigler, S. M. (1986), The History of Statistics. Cambridge, MA: Harvard University Press. Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson (1989), “Interpreting the Evidence on Money-Income Causality,” Journal of Econometrics 40, 161–181. Stock, J. H., and M. W. Watson (1993), “A Simple Estimator of Cointegrating Vectors in Higher Order Integrated Systems,” Econometrica 61, 783–820. Sydsaeter, K., and P. J. Hammond (1995), Mathematics for Economic Analysis. Englewood Cliffs, NJ: Prentice Hall. Terza, J. V. (2002), “Alcohol Abuse and Employment: A Second Look,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 17, 393–404. Tucker, I. B. (2004), “A Reexamination of the Effect of Big-time Football and Basketball Success on Gradu- ation Rates and Alumni Giving Rates,” Economics of Education Review 23, 655–661. Vella, F., and M. Verbeek (1998), “Whose Wages Do Unions Raise? A Dynamic Model of Unionism and Wage Rate Determination for Young Men,” Journal of Applied Econometrics 13, 163–183. Wald, A. (1940), “The Fitting of Straight Lines if Both Variables Are Subject to Error,” Annals of Mathemat- ical Statistics 11, 284–300. Wallis, K. F. (1972), “Testing for Fourth-Order Autocor- relation in Quarterly Regression Equations,” Econo- metrica 40, 617–636. White, H. (1980), “A Heteroskedasticity-Consistent Covariance Matrix Estimator and a Direct Test for Heteroskedasticity,” Econometrica 48, 817–838. White, H. (1984), Asymptotic Theory for Econometri- cians. Orlando: Academic Press. White, M. J. (1986), “Property Taxes and Firm Location: Evidence from Proposition 13,” in Studies in State References 843 and Local Public Finance, ed. H. S. Rosen, 83–112. Chicago: University of Chicago Press. Whittington, L. A., J. Alm, and H. E. Peters (1990), “Fertility and the Personal Exemption: Implicit Pronatalist Policy in the United States,” American Economic Review 80, 545–556. Wooldridge, J. M. (1989), “A Computationally Simple Heteroskedasticity and Serial Correlation-Robust Standard Error for the Linear Regression Model,” Economics Letters 31, 239–243. Wooldridge, J. M. (1991a), “A Note on Computing R-Squared and Adjusted R-Squared for Trending and Seasonal Data,” Economics Letters 36, 49–54. Wooldridge, J. M. (1991b), “On the Application of Robust, Regression-Based Diagnostics to Models of Conditional Means and Conditional Variances,” Journal of Econometrics 47, 5–46. Wooldridge, J. M. (1994a), “A Simple Specification Test for the Predictive Ability of Transformation Models,” Review of Economics and Statistics 76, 59–65. Wooldridge, J. M. (1994b), “Estimation and Inference for Dependent Processes,” in Handbook of Econo- metrics, volume 4, chapter 45, ed. R. F. Engle and D. L. McFadden, 2639–2738. Amsterdam: North- Holland. Wooldridge, J. M. (1995), “Score Diagnostics for Linear Models Estimated by Two Stage Least Squares,” in Advances in Econometrics and Quantitative Economics, ed. G. S. Maddala, P. C. B. Phillips, and T. N. Srinivasan, 66–87. Oxford: Blackwell. Wooldridge, J. M. (2010), Econometric Analysis of Cross Section and Panel Data. 2nd ed. Cambridge, MA: MIT Press. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. GLOSSARY A Adjusted R-Squared: A goodness-of-fit measure in multiple regression analysis that penalizes additional explanatory variables by using a degrees of freedom adjustment in estimating the error variance. Alternative Hypothesis: The hypothesis against which the null hypothesis is tested. AR(1) Serial Correlation: The errors in a time series regression model follow an AR(1) model. Asymptotic Bias: See inconsistency. Asymptotic Confidence Interval: A confidence inter- val that is approximately valid in large sample sizes. Asymptotic Normality: The sampling distribution of a properly normalized estimator converges to the standard normal distribution. Asymptotic Properties: Properties of estimators and test statistics that apply when the sample size grows without bound. Asymptotic Standard Error: A standard error that is valid in large samples. Asymptotic t Statistic: A t statistic that has an approxi- mate standard normal distribution in large samples. Asymptotic Variance: The square of the value by which we must divide an estimator in order to obtain an asymptotic standard normal distribution. Asymptotically Efficient: For consistent estimators with asymptotically normal distributions, the estima- tor with the smallest asymptotic variance. Asymptotically Uncorrelated: A time series process in which the correlation between random variables at two points in time tends to zero as the time interval between them increases. (See also weakly dependent.) Attenuation Bias: Bias in an estimator that is always toward zero; thus, the expected value of an estimator with attenuation bias is less in magnitude than the absolute value of the parameter. Augmented Dickey-Fuller Test: A test for a unit root that includes lagged changes of the variable as regressors. 844 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Autocorrelation: See serial correlation. Autoregressive Conditional Heteroskedasticity (ARCH): A model of dynamic heteroskedasticity where the variance of the error term, given past information, depends linearly on the past squared errors. Autoregressive Process of Order One [AR(1)]: A time series model whose current value depends lin- early on its most recent value plus an unpredictable disturbance. Auxiliary Regression: A regression used to compute a test statistic—such as the test statistics for het- eroskedasticity and serial correlation—or any other regression that does not estimate the model of pri- mary interest. Average: The sum of n numbers divided by n. Average Marginal Effect: See average partial effect. AveragePartialEffect: Fornonconstantpartialeffects, the partial effect averaged across the specified population. Average Treatment Effect: A treatment, or policy, effect averaged across the population. B Balanced Panel: A panel data set where all years (or periods) of data are available for all cross-sectional units. Base Group: The group represented by the overall intercept in a multiple regression model that includes dummy explanatory variables. Base Period: For index numbers, such as price or pro- duction indices, the period against which all other time periods are measured. Base Value: The value assigned to the base period for constructing an index number; usually the base value is 1 or 100. Benchmark Group: See base group. Bernoulli (or Binary) Random Variable: A random variable that takes on the values zero or one. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Best Linear Unbiased Estimator (BLUE): Among all linear unbiased estimators, the one with the smallest variance. OLS is BLUE, conditional on the sample values of the explanatory variables, under the Gauss- Markov assumptions. Beta Coefficients: See standardized coefficients. Bias: The difference between the expected value of an estimator and the population value that the estimator is supposed to be estimating. Biased Estimator: An estimator whose expectation, or sampling mean, is different from the population value it is supposed to be estimating. Biased Towards Zero: A description of an estimator whose expectation in absolute value is less than the absolute value of the population parameter. Binary Response Model: A model for a binary (dummy) dependent variable. Binary Variable: See dummy variable. Binomial Distribution: The probability distribution of the number of successes out of n independent Bernoulli trials, where each trial has the same prob- ability of success. Bivariate Regression Model: See simple linear regres- sion model. BLUE: See best linear unbiased estimator. Bootstrap: A resampling method that draws random samples, with replacement, from the original data set. Bootstrap Standard Error: A standard error obtained as the sample standard deviation of an estimate across all bootstrap samples. Breusch-Godfrey Test: An asymptotically justified test for AR(p) serial correlation, with AR(1) being the most popular; the test allows for lagged depen- dent variables as well as other regressors that are not strictly exogenous. Breusch-Pagan Test: A test for heteroskedasticity where the squared OLS residuals are regressed on the explanatory variables in the model. C Causal Effect: A ceteris paribus change in one variable that has an effect on another variable. Censored Normal Regression Model: The special case of the censored regression model where the underlying population model satisfies the classical linear model assumptions. Censored Regression Model: A multiple regression model where the dependent variable has been cen- sored above or below some known threshold. Glossary 845 Central Limit Theorem (CLT): A key result from probability theory which implies that the sum of independent random variables, or even weakly dependent random variables, when standardized by its standard deviation, has a distribution that tends to standard normal as the sample size grows. Ceteris Paribus: All other relevant factors are held fixed. Chi-Square Distribution: A probability distribution obtained by adding the squares of independent standard normal random variables. The number of terms in the sum equals the degrees of freedom in the distribution. Chi-Square Random Variable: A random variable with a chi-square distribution. Chow Statistic: An F statistic for testing the equality of regression parameters across different groups (say, men and women) or time periods (say, before and after a policy change). Classical Errors-in-Variables (CEV): A measure- ment error model where the observed measure equals the actual variable plus an independent, or at least an uncorrelated, measurement error. Classical Linear Model: The multiple linear regres- sion model under the full set of classical linear model assumptions. Classical Linear Model (CLM) Assumptions: The ideal set of assumptions for multiple regression analysis: for cross-sectional analysis, Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.6, and for time series analysis, Assumptions TS.1 through TS.6. The assumptions include linearity in the parameters, no perfect col- linearity, the zero conditional mean assumption, homoskedasticity, no serial correlation, and normal- ity of the errors. Cluster Effect: An unobserved effect that is common to all units, usually people, in the cluster. Cluster Sample: A sample of natural clusters or groups that usually consist of people. Clustering: In the context of panel data, computing standard errors and test statistics that are robust to any form of serial correlation (and heteroskedasticity). Cochrane-Orcutt (CO) Estimation: A method of estimating a multiple linear regression model with AR(1) errors and strictly exogenous explanatory variables; unlike Prais-Winsten, Cochrane-Orcutt does not use the equation for the first time period. Coefficient of Determination: See R-squared. Cointegration: The notion that a linear combination of two series, each of which is integrated of order one, is integrated of order zero. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 846 Glossary Column Vector: A vector of numbers arranged as a column. Composite Error Term: In a panel data model, the sum of the time-constant unobserved effect and the idiosyncratic error. Conditional Distribution: The probability distribution of one random variable, given the values of one or more other random variables. Conditional Expectation: The expected or average value of one random variable, called the dependent or explained variable, that depends on the values of one or more other variables, called the independent or explanatory variables. Conditional Forecast: A forecast that assumes the future values of some explanatory variables are known with certainty. Conditional Median: The median of a response vari- able conditional on some explanatory variables. Conditional Variance: The variance of one random variable, given one or more other random variables. Confidence Interval (CI): A rule used to construct a random interval so that a certain percentage of all data sets, determined by the confidence level, yields an interval that contains the population value. Confidence Level: The percentage of samples in which we want our confidence interval to contain the popu- lation value; 95% is the most common confidence level, but 90% and 99% are also used. Consistency: An estimator converges in probability to the correct population value as the sample size grows. Consistent Estimator: An estimator that converges in probability to the population parameter as the sample size grows without bound. Consistent Test: A test where, under the alternative hypothesis, the probability of rejecting the null hypothesis converges to one as the sample size grows without bound. Constant Elasticity Model: A model where the elas- ticity of the dependent variable, with respect to an explanatory variable, is constant; in multiple regres- sion, both variables appear in logarithmic form. Contemporaneously Homoskedastic: Describes a time series or panel data applications in which the variance of the error term, conditional on the regres- sors in the same time period, is constant. Contemporaneously Exogenous: Describes a time series or panel data application in which a regressor is contemporaneously exogenous if it is uncorrelated with the error term in the same time period, although Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. it may be correlated with the errors in other time periods. Continuous Random Variable: A random variable that takes on any particular value with probability zero. Control Group: In program evaluation, the group that does not participate in the program. Control Variable: See explanatory variable. Corner Solution Response: A nonnegative dependent variable that is roughly continuous over strictly positive values but takes on the value zero with some regularity. Correlated Random Effects: An approach to panel data analysis where the correlation between the unobserved effect and the explanatory variables is modeled, usually as a linear relationship. Correlation Coefficient: A measure of linear depen- dence between two random variables that does not depend on units of measurement and is bounded between –1 and 1. Count Variable: A variable that takes on nonnegative integer values. Covariance: A measure of linear dependence between two random variables. Covariance Stationary: A time series process with constant mean and variance where the covariance between any two random variables in the sequence depends only on the distance between them. Covariate: See explanatory variable. Critical Value: In hypothesis testing, the value against which a test statistic is compared to determine whether or not the null hypothesis is rejected. Cross-Sectional Data Set: A data set collected by sam- pling a population at a given point in time. Cumulative Distribution Function (cdf): A function that gives the probability of a random variable being less than or equal to any specified real number. Cumulative Effect: At any point in time, the change in a response variable after a permanent increase in an explanatory variable—usually in the context of distributed lag models. D Data Censoring: A situation that arises when we do not always observe the outcome on the dependent variable because at an upper (or lower) threshold we only know that the outcome was above (or below) the threshold. (See also censored regression model.) or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Data Frequency: The interval at which time series data are collected. Yearly, quarterly, and monthly are the most common data frequencies. Data Mining: The practice of using the same data set to estimate numerous models in a search to find the “best” model. Davidson-MacKinnon Test: A test that is used for testing a model against a nonnested alternative; it can be implemented as a t test on the fitted values from the competing model. Degrees of Freedom (df): In multiple regression analy- sis, the number of observations minus the number of estimated parameters. Denominator Degrees of Freedom: In an F test, the degrees of freedom in the unrestricted model. Dependent Variable: The variable to be explained in a multiple regression model (and a variety of other models). Derivative: The slope of a smooth function, as defined using calculus. Descriptive Statistic: A statistic used to summarize a set of numbers; the sample average, sample median, and sample standard deviation are the most common. Deseasonalizing: The removing of the seasonal com- ponents from a monthly or quarterly time series. Detrending: The practice of removing the trend from a time series. Diagonal Matrix: A matrix with zeros for all off- diagonal entries. Dickey-Fuller Distribution: The limiting distribution of the t statistic in testing the null hypothesis of a unit root. Dickey-Fuller (DF) Test: A t test of the unit root null hypothesis in an AR(1) model. (See also augmented Dickey-Fuller test.) Difference in Slopes: A description of a model where some slope parameters may differ by group or time period. Difference-in-Differences Estimator: An estimator that arises in policy analysis with data for two time periods. One version of the estimator applies to independently pooled cross sections and another to panel data sets. Difference-Stationary Process: A time series sequence that is I(0) in its first differences. Diminishing Marginal Effect: The marginal effect of an explanatory variable becomes smaller as the value of the explanatory variable increases. Discrete Random Variable: A random variable that takes on at most a finite or countably infinite number of values. Glossary 847 Distributed Lag Model: A time series model that relates the dependent variable to current and past values of an explanatory variable. Disturbance: See error term. Downward Bias: The expected value of an estimator is below the population value of the parameter. Dummy Dependent Variable: See binary response model. Dummy Variable: A variable that takes on the value zero or one. Dummy Variable Regression: In a panel data setting, the regression that includes a dummy variable for each cross-sectional unit, along with the remaining explanatory variables. It produces the fixed effects estimator. Dummy Variable Trap: The mistake of including too many dummy variables among the independent variables; it occurs when an overall intercept is in the model and a dummy variable is included for each group. Duration Analysis: An application of the censored regression model where the dependent variable is time elapsed until a certain event occurs, such as the time before an unemployed person becomes reemployed. Durbin-Watson (DW) Statistic: A statistic used to test for first order serial correlation in the errors of a time series regression model under the classical linear model assumptions. Dynamically Complete Model: A time series model where no further lags of either the dependent variable or the explanatory variables help to explain the mean of the dependent variable. E Econometric Model: An equation relating the depen- dent variable to a set of explanatory variables and unobserved disturbances, where unknown population parameters determine the ceteris paribus effect of each explanatory variable. Economic Model: A relationship derived from eco- nomic theory or less formal economic reasoning. Economic Significance: See practical significance. Elasticity: The percentage change in one variable given a 1% ceteris paribus increase in another variable. Empirical Analysis: A study that uses data in a for- mal econometric analysis to test a theory, estimate a relationship, or determine the effectiveness of a policy. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 848 Glossary Endogeneity: A term used to describe the presence of an endogenous explanatory variable. Endogenous Explanatory Variable: An explanatory variable in a multiple regression model that is corre- lated with the error term, either because of an omitted variable, measurement error, or simultaneity. Endogenous Sample Selection: Nonrandom sample selection where the selection is related to the depen- dent variable, either directly or through the error term in the equation. Endogenous Variables: In simultaneous equations models, variables that are determined by the equa- tions in the system. Engle-Granger Test: A test of the null hypothesis that two time series are not cointegrated; the statistic is obtained as the Dickey-Fuller statistic using OLS residuals. Engle-Granger Two-Step Procedure: A two-step method for estimating error correction models whereby the cointegrating parameter is estimated in the first stage, and the error correction parameters are estimated in the second. Error Correction Model: A time series model in first differences that also contains an error correction term, which works to bring two I(1) series back into long-run equilibrium. Error Term: The variable in a simple or multiple regression equation that contains unobserved factors which affect the dependent variable. The error term may also include measurement errors in the observed dependent or independent variables. Error Variance: The variance of the error term in a multiple regression model. Errors-in-Variables: A situation where either the dependent variable or some independent variables are measured with error. Estimate: The numerical value taken on by an estima- tor for a particular sample of data. Estimator: A rule for combining data to produce a numeri- cal value for a population parameter; the form of the rule does not depend on the particular sample obtained. Event Study: An econometric analysis of the effects of an event, such as a change in government regulation or economic policy, on an outcome variable. Excluding a Relevant Variable: In multiple regres- sion analysis, leaving out a variable that has a non- zero partial effect on the dependent variable. Exclusion Restrictions: Restrictions which state that certain variables are excluded from the model (or have zero population coefficients). Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Exogenous Explanatory Variable: An explanatory variable that is uncorrelated with the error term. Exogenous Sample Selection: A sample selection that either depends on exogenous explanatory variables or is independent of the error term in the equation of interest. Exogenous Variable: Any variable that is uncorrelated with the error term in the model of interest. Expected Value: A measure of central tendency in the distribution of a random variable, including an estimator. Experiment: In probability, a general term used to denote an event whose outcome is uncertain. In econometric analysis, it denotes a situation where data are collected by randomly assigning individuals to control and treatment groups. Experimental Data: Data that have been obtained by running a controlled experiment. Experimental Group: See treatment group. Explained Sum of Squares (SSE): The total sample variation of the fitted values in a multiple regression model. Explained Variable: See dependent variable. Explanatory Variable: In regression analysis, a vari- able that is used to explain variation in the dependent variable. Exponential Function: A mathematical function defined for all values that has an increasing slope but a constant proportionate change. Exponential Smoothing: A simple method of forecast- ing a variable that involves a weighting of all previ- ous outcomes on that variable. Exponential Trend: A trend with a constant growth rate. F Distribution: The probability distribution obtained by forming the ratio of two independent chi-square random variables, where each has been divided by its degrees of freedom. F Random Variable: A random variable with an F distribution. F Statistic: A statistic used to test multiple hypotheses about the parameters in a multiple regression model. Feasible GLS (FGLS) Estimator: A GLS proce- dure where variance or correlation parameters are unknown and therefore must first be estimated. (See also generalized least squares estimator.) or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. F Finite Distributed Lag (FDL) Model: A dynamic model where one or more explanatory variables are allowed to have lagged effects on the dependent variable. First Difference: A transformation on a time series constructed by taking the difference of adjacent time periods, where the earlier time period is subtracted from the later time period. First-Differenced (FD) Equation: In time series or panel data models, an equation where the depen- dent and independent variables have all been first differenced. First-Differenced (FD) Estimator: In a panel data setting, the pooled OLS estimator applied to first dif- ferences of the data across time. First Order Autocorrelation: For a time series pro- cess ordered chronologically, the correlation coef- ficient between pairs of adjacent observations. First Order Conditions: The set of linear equations used to solve for the OLS estimates. Fitted Values: The estimated values of the dependent variable when the values of the independent vari- ables for each observation are plugged into the OLS regression line. Fixed Effect: See unobserved effect. Fixed Effects Estimator: For the unobserved effects panel data model, the estimator obtained by applying pooled OLS to a time-demeaned equation. Fixed Effects Model: An unobserved effects panel data model where the unobserved effects are allowed to be arbitrarily correlated with the explanatory vari- ables in each time period. Fixed Effects Transformation: For panel data, the time-demeaned data. Forecast Error: The difference between the actual outcome and the forecast of the outcome. Forecast Interval: In forecasting, a confidence interval for a yet unrealized future value of a time series vari- able. (See also prediction interval.) Functional Form Misspecification: A problem that occurs when a model has omitted functions of the explanatory variables (such as quadratics) or uses the wrong functions of either the dependent variable or some explanatory variables. G Gauss-Markov Assumptions: The set of assump- tions (Assumptions MLR.1 through MLR.5 or TS.1 through TS.5) under which OLS is BLUE. Glossary 849 Gauss-Markov Theorem: The theorem that states that, under the five Gauss-Markov assumptions (for cross- sectional or time series models), the OLS estimator is BLUE (conditional on the sample values of the explanatory variables). Generalized Least Squares (GLS) Estimator: An estimator that accounts for a known structure of the error variance (heteroskedasticity), serial correlation pattern in the errors, or both, via a transformation of the original model. Geometric (or Koyck) Distributed Lag: An infinite distributed lag model where the lag coefficients decline at a geometric rate. Goodness-of-Fit Measure: A statistic that summarizes how well a set of explanatory variables explains a dependent or response variable. Granger Causality: A limited notion of causality where past values of one series (xt) are useful for predicting future values of another series (yt), after past values of yt have been controlled for. Growth Rate: The proportionate change in a time series from the previous period. It may be approxi- mated as the difference in logs or reported in percent- age form. H Heckit Method: An econometric procedure used to correct for sample selection bias due to incidental truncation or some other form of nonrandomly miss- ing data. Heterogeneity Bias: The bias in OLS due to omitted heterogeneity (or omitted variables). Heteroskedasticity: The variance of the error term, given the explanatory variables, is not constant. Heteroskedasticity of Unknown Form: Heteroskedasti- city that may depend on the explanatory variables in an unknown, arbitrary fashion. Heteroskedasticity-Robust F Statistic: An F-type statistic that is (asymptotically) robust to heteroske- dasticity of unknown form. Heteroskedasticity-Robust LM Statistic: An LM sta- tistic that is robust to heteroskedasticity of unknown form. Heteroskedasticity-Robust Standard Error: A stan- dard error that is (asymptotically) robust to het- eroskedasticity of unknown form. Heteroskedasticity-Robust t Statistic: A t statistic that is (asymptotically) robust to heteroskedasticity of unknown form. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 850 Glossary Highly Persistent: A time series process where out- comes in the distant future are highly correlated with current outcomes. Homoskedasticity: The errors in a regression model have constant variance conditional on the explana- tory variables. Hypothesis Test: A statistical test of the null, or main- tained, hypothesis against an alternative hypothesis. I Idempotent Matrix: A (square) matrix where multipli- cation of the matrix by itself equals itself. Identification: A population parameter, or set of parameters, can be consistently estimated. Identified Equation: An equation whose parameters can be consistently estimated, especially in models with endogenous explanatory variables. Identity Matrix: A square matrix where all diagonal elements are one and all off-diagonal elements are zero. Idiosyncratic Error: In panel data models, the error that changes over time as well as across units (say, individuals, firms, or cities). Impact Elasticity: In a distributed lag model, the imme- diate percentage change in the dependent variable given a 1% increase in the independent variable. Impact Multiplier: See impact propensity. Impact Propensity: In a distributed lag model, the immediate change in the dependent variable given a one-unit increase in the independent variable. Incidental Truncation: A sample selection problem whereby one variable, usually the dependent vari- able, is only observed for certain outcomes of another variable. Inclusion of an Irrelevant Variable: The including of an explanatory variable in a regression model that has a zero population parameter in estimating an equation by OLS. Inconsistency: The difference between the probability limit of an estimator and the parameter value. Inconsistent: Describes an estimator that does not converge (in probability) to the correct population parameter as the sample size grows. Independent Random Variables: Random variables whose joint distribution is the product of the mar- ginal distributions. Independent Variable: See explanatory variable. Independently Pooled Cross Section: A data set obtained by pooling independent random samples from different points in time. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Index Number: A statistic that aggregates information on economic activity, such as production or prices. Infinite Distributed Lag (IDL) Model: A distributed lag model where a change in the explanatory variable can have an impact on the dependent variable into the indefinite future. Influential Observations: See outliers. Information Set: In forecasting, the set of variables that we can observe prior to forming our forecast. In-Sample Criteria: Criteria for choosing forecasting models that are based on goodness-of-fit within the sample used to obtain the parameter estimates. Instrument Exogeneity: In instrumental variables esti- mation, the requirement that an instrumental variable is uncorrelated with the error term. Instrument Relevance: In instrumental variables esti- mation, the requirement that an instrumental variable helps to partially explain variation in the endogenous explanatory variable. Instrumental Variable (IV): In an equation with an endogenous explanatory variable, an IV is a variable that does not appear in the equation, is uncorrelated with the error in the equation, and is (partially) correlated with the endogenous explana- tory variable. Instrumental Variables (IV) Estimator: An estimator in a linear model used when instrumental variables are available for one or more endogenous explana- tory variables. Integrated of Order One [I(1)]: A time series process that needs to be first-differenced in order to produce an I(0) process. Integrated of Order Zero [I(0)]: A stationary, weakly dependent time series process that, when used in regression analysis, satisfies the law of large num- bers and the central limit theorem. Interaction Effect: In multiple regression, the partial effect of one explanatory variable depends on the value of a different explanatory variable. Interaction Term: An independent variable in a regres- sion model that is the product of two explanatory variables. Intercept: In the equation of a line, the value of the y variable when the x variable is zero. Intercept Parameter: The parameter in a multiple linear regression model that gives the expected value of the dependent variable when all the independent variables equal zero. Intercept Shift: The intercept in a regression model differs by group or time period. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Internet: A global computer network that can be used to access information and download databases. Interval Estimator: A rule that uses data to obtain lower and upper bounds for a population parameter. (See also confidence interval.) Inverse: For an n × n matrix, its inverse (if it exists) is the n × n matrix for which pre- and post-multi- plication by the original matrix yields the identity matrix. Inverse Mills Ratio: A term that can be added to a multiple regression model to remove sample selec- tion bias. J Joint Distribution: The probability distribution deter- mining the probabilities of outcomes involving two or more random variables. Joint Hypotheses Test: A test involving more than one restriction on the parameters in a model. Jointly Insignificant: Failure to reject, using an F test at a specified significance level, that all coefficients for a group of explanatory variables are zero. Jointly Statistically Significant: The null hypothesis that two or more explanatory variables have zero population coefficients is rejected at the chosen sig- nificance level. Just Identified Equation: For models with endog- enous explanatory variables, an equation that is identified but would not be identified with one fewer instrumental variable. K Kurtosis: A measure of the thickness of the tails of a distribution based on the fourth moment of the standardized random variable; the measure is usu- ally compared to the value for the standard normal distribution, which is three. L Lag Distribution: In a finite or infinite distributed lag model, the lag coefficients graphed as a function of the lag length. Lagged Dependent Variable: An explanatory variable that is equal to the dependent variable from an earlier time period. Lagged Endogenous Variable: In a simultaneous equations model, a lagged value of one of the endog- enous variables. Glossary 851 Lagrange Multiplier (LM) Statistic: A test statistic with large-sample justification that can be used to test for omitted variables, heteroskedasticity, and serial correlation, among other model specification problems. Large Sample Properties: See asymptotic properties. Latent Variable Model: A model where the observed dependent variable is assumed to be a function of an underlying latent, or unobserved, variable. Law of Iterated Expectations: A result from prob- ability that relates unconditional and conditional expectations. Law of Large Numbers (LLN): A theorem that says that the average from a random sample converges in probability to the population average; the LLN also holds for stationary and weakly dependent time series. Leads and Lags Estimator: An estimator of a cointe- grating parameter in a regression with I(1) variables, where the current, some past, and some future first differences in the explanatory variable are included as regressors. Least Absolute Deviations (LAD): A method for esti- mating the parameters of a multiple regression model based on minimizing the sum of the absolute values of the residuals. Least Squares Estimator: An estimator that mini- mizes a sum of squared residuals. Level-Level Model: A regression model where the dependent variable and the independent variables are in level (or original) form. Level-Log Model: A regression model where the dependent variable is in level form and (at least some of) the independent variables are in logarithmic form. Likelihood Ratio Statistic: A statistic that can be used to test single or multiple hypotheses when the con- strained and unconstrained models have been esti- mated by maximum likelihood. The statistic is twice the difference in the unconstrained and constrained log-likelihoods. Limited Dependent Variable (LDV): A dependent or response variable whose range is restricted in some important way. Linear Function: A function where the change in the dependent variable, given a one-unit change in an independent variable, is constant. Linear Probability Model (LPM): A binary response model where the response probability is linear in its parameters. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 852 Glossary Linear Time Trend: A trend that is a linear function of time. Linear Unbiased Estimator: In multiple regression analysis, an unbiased estimator that is a linear func- tion of the outcomes on the dependent variable. Linearly Independent Vectors: A set of vectors such that no vector can be written as a linear combination of the others in the set. Log Function: A mathematical function, defined only for strictly positive arguments, with a positive but decreasing slope. Logarithmic Function: A mathematical function defined for positive arguments that has a positive, but diminishing, slope. Logit Model: A model for binary response where the response probability is the logit function evaluated at a linear function of the explanatory variables. Log-Level Model: A regression model where the dependent variable is in logarithmic form and the independent variables are in level (or original) form. Log-Likelihood Function: The sum of the log-likelihoods, where the log-likelihood for each observation is the log of the density of the dependent variable given the explanatory variables; the log-likelihood function is viewed as a function of the parameters to be estimated. Log-Log Model: A regression model where the depen- dent variable and (at least some of) the explanatory variables are in logarithmic form. Longitudinal Data: See panel data. Long-Run Elasticity: The long-run propensity in a dis- tributed lag model with the dependent and indepen- dent variables in logarithmic form; thus, the long-run elasticity is the eventual percentage increase in the explained variable, given a permanent 1% increase in the explanatory variable. Long-Run Multiplier: See long-run propensity. Long-Run Propensity (LRP): In a distributed lag model, the eventual change in the dependent variable given a permanent, one-unit increase in the indepen- dent variable. Loss Function: A function that measures the loss when a forecast differs from the actual outcome; the most common examples are absolute value loss and squared loss. M Marginal Effect: The effect on the dependent variable that results from changing an independent variable by a small amount. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Martingale: A time series process whose expected value, given all past outcomes on the series, simply equals the most recent value. Martingale Difference Sequence: The first difference of a martingale. It is unpredictable (or has a zero mean), given past values of the sequence. Matched Pair Sample: A sample where each observation is matched with another, as in a sample consisting of a husband and wife or a set of two siblings. Matrix: An array of numbers. Matrix Multiplication: An algorithm for multiplying together two conformable matrices. Matrix Notation: A convenient mathematical nota- tion, grounded in matrix algebra, for expressing and manipulating the multiple regression model. Maximum Likelihood Estimation (MLE): A broadly applicable estimation method where the parameter estimates are chosen to maximize the log-likelihood function. Maximum Likelihood Estimator: An estimator that maximizes the (log of the) likelihood function. Mean: See expected value. Mean Absolute Error (MAE): A performance mea- sure in forecasting, computed as the average of the absolute values of the forecast errors. Mean Independent: The key requirement in multiple regression analysis, which says the unobserved error has a mean that does not change across subsets of the population defined by different values of the explanatory variables. Mean Squared Error (MSE): The expected squared distance that an estimator is from the population value; it equals the variance plus the square of any bias. Measurement Error: The difference between an observed variable and the variable that belongs in a multiple regression equation. Median: In a probability distribution, it is the value where there is a 50% chance of being below the value and a 50% chance of being above it. In a sample of numbers, it is the middle value after the numbers have been ordered. Method of Moments Estimator: An estimator obtained by using the sample analog of population moments; ordinary least squares and two stage least squares are both method of moments estimators. Micronumerosity: A term introduced by Arthur Gold- berger to describe properties of econometric estima- tors with small sample sizes. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Minimum Variance Unbiased Estimator: An esti- mator with the smallest variance in the class of all unbiased estimators. Missing Data: A data problem that occurs when we do not observe values on some variables for certain observations (individuals, cities, time periods, and so on) in the sample. Misspecification Analysis: The process of determining likely biases that can arise from omitted variables, measurement error, simultaneity, and other kinds of model misspecification. Moving Average Process of Order One [MA(1)]: A time series process generated as a linear function of the current value and one lagged value of a zero- mean, constant variance, uncorrelated stochastic process. Multicollinearity: A term that refers to correlation among the independent variables in a multiple regression model; it is usually invoked when some correlations are “large,” but an actual magnitude is not well defined. Multiple Hypotheses Test: A test of a null hypoth- esis involving more than one restriction on the parameters. Multiple Linear Regression (MLR) Model: A model linear in its parameters, where the dependent vari- able is a function of independent variables plus an error term. Multiple Regression Analysis: A type of analysis that is used to describe estimation of and inference in the multiple linear regression model. MultipleRestrictions: Morethanonerestrictiononthe parameters in an econometric model. Multiple-Step-Ahead Forecast: A time series forecast of more than one period into the future. Multiplicative Measurement Error: Measurement error where the observed variable is the product of the true unobserved variable and a positive measure- ment error. Multivariate Normal Distribution: A distribution for multiple random variables where each linear combi- nation of the random variables has a univariate (one- dimensional) normal distribution. N n-R-Squared Statistic: See Lagrange multiplier statistic. Natural Experiment: A situation where the eco- nomic environment—sometimes summarized by an Glossary 853 explanatory variable—exogenously changes, per- haps inadvertently, due to a policy or institutional change. Natural Logarithm: See logarithmic function. Nominal Variable: A variable measured in nominal or current dollars. Nonexperimental Data: Data that have not been obtained through a controlled experiment. Nonlinear Function: A function whose slope is not constant. Nonnested Models: Two (or more) models where no model can be written as a special case of the other by imposing restrictions on the parameters. Nonrandom Sample: A sample obtained other than by sampling randomly from the population of interest. Nonstationary Process: A time series process whose joint distributions are not constant across different epochs. Normal Distribution: A probability distribution com- monly used in statistics and econometrics for modeling a population. Its probability distribution function has a bell shape. Normality Assumption: The classical linear model assumption which states that the error (or dependent variable) has a normal distribution, conditional on the explanatory variables. Null Hypothesis: In classical hypothesis testing, we take this hypothesis as true and require the data to provide substantial evidence against it. Numerator Degrees of Freedom: In an F test, the number of restrictions being tested. O Observational Data: See nonexperimental data. OLS: See ordinary least squares. OLS Intercept Estimate: The intercept in an OLS regression line. OLS Regression Line: The equation relating the pre- dicted value of the dependent variable to the inde- pendent variables, where the parameter estimates have been obtained by OLS. OLS Slope Estimate: A slope in an OLS regression line. OmittedVariableBias: ThebiasthatarisesintheOLS estimators when a relevant variable is omitted from the regression. Omitted Variables: One or more variables, which we would like to control for, have been omitted in esti- mating a regression model. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 854 Glossary One-Sided Alternative: An alternative hypothesis that states that the parameter is greater than (or less than) the value hypothesized under the null. One-Step-Ahead Forecast: A time series forecast one period into the future. One-Tailed Test: A hypothesis test against a one-sided alternative. Online Databases: Databases that can be accessed via a computer network. Online Search Services: Computer software that allows the Internet or databases on the Internet to be searched by topic, name, title, or keywords. Order Condition: A necessary condition for identi- fying the parameters in a model with one or more endogenous explanatory variables: the total number of exogenous variables must be at least as great as the total number of explanatory variables. Ordinal Variable: A variable where the ordering of the values conveys information but the magnitude of the values does not. Ordinary Least Squares (OLS): A method for esti- mating the parameters of a multiple linear regres- sion model. The ordinary least squares estimates are obtained by minimizing the sum of squared residuals. Outliers: Observations in a data set that are substan- tially different from the bulk of the data, perhaps because of errors or because some data are gener- ated by a different model than most of the other data. Out-of-Sample Criteria: Criteria used for choosing forecasting models which are based on a part of the sample that was not used in obtaining parameter estimates. Over Controlling: In a multiple regression model, including explanatory variables that should not be held fixed when studying the ceteris paribus effect of one or more other explanatory variables; this can occur when variables that are themselves outcomes of an intervention or a policy are included among the regressors. Overall Significance of a Regression: A test of the joint significance of all explanatory variables appear- ing in a multiple regression equation. Overdispersion: In modeling a count variable, the variance is larger than the mean. Overidentified Equation: In models with endogenous explanatory variables, an equation where the number of instrumental variables is strictly greater than the number of endogenous explanatory variables. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Overidentifying Restrictions: The extra moment con- ditions that come from having more instrumental variables than endogenous explanatory variables in a linear model. Overspecifying a Model: See inclusion of an irrelevant variable. P p-Value: The smallest significance level at which the null hypothesis can be rejected. Equivalently, the largest significance level at which the null hypothesis cannot be rejected. Pairwise Uncorrelated Random Variables: A set of two or more random variables where each pair is uncorrelated. Panel Data: A data set constructed from repeated cross sections over time. With a balanced panel, the same units appear in each time period. With an unbalanced panel, some units do not appear in each time period, often due to attrition. Parameter: An unknown value that describes a popula- tion relationship. Parsimonious Model: A model with as few parameters as possible for capturing any desired features. Partial Derivative: For a smooth function of more than one variable, the slope of the function in one direction. Partial Effect: The effect of an explanatory variable on the dependent variable, holding other factors in the regression model fixed. Partial Effect at the Average (PEA): In models with nonconstant partial effects, the partial effect evaluated at the average values of the explanatory variables. Percent Correctly Predicted: In a binary response model, the percentage of times the prediction of zero or one coincides with the actual outcome. Percentage Change: The proportionate change in a variable, multiplied by 100. Percentage Point Change: The change in a variable that is measured as a percentage. Perfect Collinearity: In multiple regression, one inde- pendent variable is an exact linear function of one or more other independent variables. Plug-In Solution to the Omitted Variables Prob- lem: A proxy variable is substituted for an unob- served omitted variable in an OLS regression. Point Forecast: The forecasted value of a future outcome. or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Poisson Distribution: A probability distribution for count variables. Poisson Regression Model: A model for a count dependent variable where the dependent variable, conditional on the explanatory variables, is nomi- nally assumed to have a Poisson distribution. Policy Analysis: An empirical analysis that uses econo- metric methods to evaluate the effects of a certain policy. Pooled Cross Section: A data configuration where independent cross sections, usually collected at differ- ent points in time, are combined to produce a single data set. Pooled OLS Estimation: OLS estimation with inde- pendently pooled cross sections, panel data, or cluster samples, where the observations are pooled across time (or group) as well as across the cross- sectional units. Population: A well-defined group (of people, firms, cities, and so on) that is the focus of a statistical or econometric analysis. Population Model: A model, especially a multiple lin- ear regression model, that describes a population. Population R-Squared: In the population, the frac- tion of the variation in the dependent variable that is explained by the explanatory variables. Population Regression Function: See conditional expectation. Positive Definite: A symmetric matrix such that all quadratic forms, except the trivial one that must be zero, are strictly positive. Positive Semi-Definite: A symmetric matrix such that all quadratic forms are nonnegative. Power of a Test: The probability of rejecting the null hypothesis when it is false; the power depends on the values of the population parameters under the alternative. Practical Significance: The practical or economic importance of an estimate, which is measured by its sign and magnitude, as opposed to its statistical significance. Prais-Winsten (PW) Estimation: A method of esti- mating a multiple linear regression model with AR(1) errors and strictly exogenous explanatory variables; unlike Cochrane-Orcutt, Prais-Winsten uses the equation for the first time period in estimation. Predetermined Variable: In a simultaneous equations model, either a lagged endogenous variable or a lagged exogenous variable. Predicted Variable: See dependent variable. Glossary 855 Prediction: The estimate of an outcome obtained by plugging specific values of the explanatory variables into an estimated model, usually a multiple regres- sion model. Prediction Error: The difference between the actual outcome and a prediction of that outcome. Prediction Interval: A confidence interval for an unknown outcome on a dependent variable in a mul- tiple regression model. Predictor Variable: See explanatory variable. Probability Density Function (pdf): A function that, for discrete random variables, gives the probability that the random variable takes on each value; for continuous random variables, the area under the pdf gives the probability of various events. Probability Limit: The value to which an estimator converges as the sample size grows without bound. Probit Model: A model for binary responses where the response probability is the standard normal cdf evaluated at a linear function of the explanatory variables. Program Evaluation: An analysis of a particular pri- vate or public program using econometric methods to obtain the causal effect of the program. Proportionate Change: The change in a variable rela- tive to its initial value; mathematically, the change divided by the initial value. Proxy Variable: An observed variable that is related but not identical to an unobserved explanatory vari- able in multiple regression analysis. Pseudo R-Squared: Any number of goodness-of-fit measures for limited dependent variable models. Q Quadratic Form: A mathematical function where the vector argument both pre- and post-multiplies a square, symmetric matrix. Quadratic Functions: Functions that contain squares of one or more explanatory variables; they capture diminishing or increasing effects on the dependent variable. Qualitative Variable: A variable describing a non- quantitative feature of an individual, a firm, a city, and so on. Quasi-Demeaned Data: In random effects estima- tion for panel data, it is the original data in each time period minus a fraction of the time average; these calculations are done for each cross-sectional observation. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 856 Glossary Quasi-Differenced Data: In estimating a regression model with AR(1) serial correlation, it is the differ- ence between the current time period and a multiple of the previous time period, where the multiple is the parameter in the AR(1) model. Quasi-Experiment: See natural experiment. Quasi-Likelihood Ratio Statistic: A modification of the likelihood ratio statistic that accounts for pos- sible distributional misspecification, as in a Poisson regression model. Quasi-Maximum Likelihood Estimation (QMLE): Maximum likelihood estimation where the log-likelihood function may not correspond to the actual conditional distribution of the dependent variable. R R-Bar Squared: See adjusted R-squared. R-Squared: In a multiple regression model, the pro- portion of the total sample variation in the depen- dent variable that is explained by the independent variable. R-Squared Form of the F Statistic: The F statistic for testing exclusion restrictions expressed in terms of the R-squareds from the restricted and unrestricted models. Random Coefficient (Slope) Model: A multiple regres- sion model where the slope parameters are allowed to depend on unobserved unit-specific variables. Random Effects Estimator: A feasible GLS esti- mator in the unobserved effects model where the unobserved effect is assumed to be uncorre- lated with the explanatory variables in each time period. Random Effects Model: The unobserved effects panel data model where the unobserved effect is assumed to be uncorrelated with the explanatory variables in each time period. Random Sample: A sample obtained by sampling ran- domly from the specified population. Random Sampling: A sampling scheme whereby each observation is drawn at random from the population. In particular, no unit is more likely to be selected than any other unit, and each draw is independent of all other draws. Random Variable: A variable whose outcome is uncertain. Random Vector: A vector consisting of random variables. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Random Walk: A time series process where next peri- od’s value is obtained as this period’s value, plus an independent (or at least an uncorrelated) error term. Random Walk with Drift: A random walk that has a constant (or drift) added in each period. Rank Condition: A sufficient condition for identi- fication of a model with one or more endogenous explanatory variables. Rank of a Matrix: The number of linearly independent columns in a matrix. Rational Distributed Lag (RDL) Model: A type of infinite distributed lag model where the lag distribu- tion depends on relatively few parameters. Real Variable: A monetary value measured in terms of a base period. Reduced Form Equation: A linear equation where an endogenous variable is a function of exogenous variables and unobserved errors. Reduced Form Error: The error term appearing in a reduced form equation. Reduced Form Parameters: The parameters appear- ing in a reduced form equation. Regressand: See dependent variable. Regression Specification Error Test (RESET): A general test for functional form in a multiple regres- sion model; it is an F test of joint significance of the squares, cubes, and perhaps higher powers of the fit- ted values from the initial OLS estimation. Regression through the Origin: Regression analysis where the intercept is set to zero; the slopes are obtained by minimizing the sum of squared residu- als, as usual. Regressor: See explanatory variable. Rejection Region: The set of values of a test statistic that leads to rejecting the null hypothesis. Rejection Rule: In hypothesis testing, the rule that determines when the null hypothesis is rejected in favor of the alternative hypothesis. Relative Change: See proportionate change. Resampling Method: A technique for approximating standard errors (and distributions of test statistics) whereby a series of samples are obtained from the original data set and estimates are computed for each subsample. Residual: The difference between the actual value and the fitted (or predicted) value; there is a residual for each observation in the sample used to obtain an OLS regression line. Residual Analysis: A type of analysis that stud- ies the sign and size of residuals for particular or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. observations after a multiple regression model has been estimated. Residual Sum of Squares: See sum of squared residuals. Response Probability: In a binary response model, the probability that the dependent variable takes on the value one, conditional on explanatory variables. Response Variable: See dependent variable. Restricted Model: In hypothesis testing, the model obtained after imposing all of the restrictions required under the null. Retrospective Data: Data collected based on past, rather than current, information. Root Mean Squared Error (RMSE): Another name for the standard error of the regression in multiple regression analysis. Row Vector: A vector of numbers arranged as a row. S Sample Average: The sum of n numbers divided by n; a measure of central tendency. Sample Correlation: For outcomes on two random variables, the sample covariance divided by the prod- uct of the sample standard deviations. Sample Correlation Coefficient: An estimate of the (population) correlation coefficient from a sample of data. Sample Covariance: An unbiased estimator of the population covariance between two random variables. Sample Regression Function (SRF): See OLS regres- sion line. Sample Selection Bias: Bias in the OLS estimator which is induced by using data that arise from endog- enous sample selection. Sample Standard Deviation: A consistent estimator of the population standard deviation. Sample Variance: An unbiased, consistent estimator of the population variance. Sampling Distribution: The probability distribution of an estimator over all possible sample outcomes. Sampling Standard Deviation: The standard devia- tion of an estimator, that is, the standard deviation of a sampling distribution. Sampling Variance: The variance in the sampling distribution of an estimator; it measures the spread in the sampling distribution. Scalar Multiplication: The algorithm for multiplying a scalar (number) by a vector or matrix. Glossary 857 Scalar Variance-Covariance Matrix: A variance- covariance matrix where all off-diagonal terms are zero and the diagonal terms are the same positive constant. Score Statistic: See Lagrange multiplier statistic. Seasonal Dummy Variables: A set of dummy vari- ables used to denote the quarters or months of the year. Seasonality: A feature of monthly or quarterly time series where the average value differs systematically by season of the year. Seasonally Adjusted: Monthly or quarterly time series data where some statistical procedure—possibly regression on seasonal dummy variables—has been used to remove the seasonal component. Selected Sample: A sample of data obtained not by random sampling but by selecting on the basis of some observed or unobserved characteristic. Self-Selection: Deciding on an action based on the likely benefits, or costs, of taking that action. Semi-Elasticity: The percentage change in the depen- dent variable given a one-unit increase in an inde- pendent variable. Sensitivity Analysis: The process of checking whether the estimated effects and statistical significance of key explanatory variables are sensitive to inclusion of other explanatory variables, functional form, drop- ping of potentially outlying observations, or different methods of estimation. Sequentially Exogenous: A feature of an explanatory variable in time series (or panel data) models where the error term in the current time period has a zero mean conditional on all current and past explanatory variables; a weaker version is stated in terms of zero correlations. Serial Correlation: In a time series or panel data model, correlation between the errors in different time periods. Serial Correlation-Robust Standard Error: A stan- dard error for an estimator that is (asymptotically) valid whether or not the errors in the model are seri- ally correlated. Serially Uncorrelated: The errors in a time series or panel data model are pairwise uncorrelated across time. Short-Run Elasticity: The impact propensity in a dis- tributed lag model when the dependent and indepen- dent variables are in logarithmic form. Significance Level: The probability of a Type I error in hypothesis testing. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 858 Glossary Simple Linear Regression Model: A model where the dependent variable is a linear function of a single independent variable, plus an error term. Simultaneity: A term that means at least one explana- tory variable in a multiple linear regression model is determined jointly with the dependent variable. Simultaneity Bias: The bias that arises from using OLS to estimate an equation in a simultaneous equa- tions model. Simultaneous Equations Model (SEM): A model that jointly determines two or more endogenous variables, where each endogenous variable can be a function of other endogenous variables as well as of exogenous variables and an error term. Skewness: A measure of how far a distribution is from being symmetric, based on the third moment of the standardized random variable. Slope: In the equation of a line, the change in the y vari- able when the x variable increases by one. Slope Parameter: The coefficient on an independent variable in a multiple regression model. Smearing Estimate: A retransformation method par- ticularly useful for predicting the level of a response variable when a linear model has been estimated for the natural log of the response variable. Spreadsheet: Computer software used for entering and manipulating data. Spurious Correlation: A correlation between two variables that is not due to causality, but perhaps to the dependence of the two variables on another unobserved factor. Spurious Regression Problem: A problem that arises when regression analysis indicates a relationship bet- ween two or more unrelated time series processes simply because each has a trend, is an integrated time series (such as a random walk), or both. Square Matrix: A matrix with the same number of rows as columns. Stable AR(1) Process: An AR(1) process where the parameter on the lag is less than one in absolute value. The correlation between two random variables in the sequence declines to zero at a geometric rate as the distance between the random variables increases, and so a stable AR(1) process is weakly dependent. Standard Deviation: A common measure of spread in the distribution of a random variable. Standard Deviation of 􏱬ˆj: A common measure of spread in the sampling distribution of 􏱹ˆj. Standard Error: Generically, an estimate of the stan- dard deviation of an estimator. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. StandardErrorof􏱬ˆj:Anestimateofthestandard deviation in the sampling distribution of 􏱹ˆj. Standard Error of the Estimate: See standard error of the regression. Standard Error of the Regression (SER): In multiple regression analysis, the estimate of the standard deviation of the population error, obtained as the square root of the sum of squared residuals over the degrees of freedom. Standard Normal Distribution: The normal distribu- tion with mean zero and variance one. Standardized Coefficients: Regression coefficients that measure the standard deviation change in the dependent variable given a one standard deviation increase in an independent variable. Standardized Random Variable: A random variable transformed by subtracting off its expected value and dividing the result by its standard deviation; the new random variable has mean zero and standard deviation one. Static Model: A time series model where only contem- poraneous explanatory variables affect the dependent variable. Stationary Process: A time series process where the marginal and all joint distributions are invariant across time. Statistical Inference: The act of testing hypotheses about population parameters. Statistical Significance: The importance of an estimate as measured by the size of a test statistic, usually a t statistic. Statistically Different from Zero: See statistically significant. Statistically Insignificant: Failure to reject the null hypothesis that a population parameter is equal to zero, at the chosen significance level. Statistically Significant: Rejecting the null hypothesis that a parameter is equal to zero against the specified alternative, at the chosen significance level. Stochastic Process: A sequence of random variables indexed by time. Stratified Sampling: A nonrandom sampling scheme whereby the population is first divided into several nonoverlapping, exhaustive strata, and then random samples are taken from within each stratum. Strict Exogeneity: An assumption that holds in a time series or panel data model when the explanatory variables are strictly exogenous. Strictly Exogenous: A feature of explanatory vari- ables in a time series or panel data model where the or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. error term at any time period has zero expectation, conditional on the explanatory variables in all time periods; a less restrictive version is stated in terms of zero correlations. Strongly Dependent: See highly persistent. Structural Equation: An equation derived from economic theory or from less formal economic reasoning. Structural Error: The error term in a structural equa- tion, which could be one equation in a simultaneous equations model. Structural Parameters: The parameters appearing in a structural equation. Studentized Residuals: The residuals computed by excluding each observation, in turn, from the estima- tion, divided by the estimated standard deviation of the error. Sum of Squared Residuals (SSR): In multiple regres- sion analysis, the sum of the squared OLS residuals across all observations. Summation Operator: A notation, denoted by ∑, used to define the summing of a set of numbers. Symmetric Distribution: A probability distribution characterized by a probability density function that is symmetric around its median value, which must also be the mean value (whenever the mean exists). Symmetric Matrix: A (square) matrix that equals its transpose. T t Distribution: The distribution of the ratio of a stan- dard normal random variable and the square root of an independent chi-square random variable, where the chi-square random variable is first divided by its df. t Ratio: See t statistic. t Statistic: The statistic used to test a single hypothesis about the parameters in an econometric model. Test Statistic: A rule used for testing hypotheses where each sample outcome produces a numerical value. Text Editor: Computer software that can be used to edit text files. Text (ASCII) File: A universal file format that can be transported across numerous computer platforms. Time-Demeaned Data: Panel data where, for each cross-sectional unit, the average over time is sub- tracted from the data in each time period. Time Series Data: Data collected over time on one or more variables. Glossary 859 Time Series Process: See stochastic process. Time Trend: A function of time that is the expected value of a trending time series process. Tobit Model: A model for a dependent variable that takes on the value zero with positive prob- ability but is roughly continuously distributed over strictly positive values. (See also corner solution response.) Top Coding: A form of data censoring where the value of a variable is not reported when it is above a given threshold; we only know that it is at least as large as the threshold. Total Sum of Squares (SST): The total sample vari- ation in a dependent variable about its sample average. Trace of a Matrix: For a square matrix, the sum of its diagonal elements. Transpose: For any matrix, the new matrix obtained by interchanging its rows and columns. Treatment Group: In program evaluation, the group that participates in the program. Trending Process: A time series process whose expected value is an increasing or a decreasing func- tion of time. Trend-Stationary Process: A process that is station- ary once a time trend has been removed; it is usu- ally implicit that the detrended series is weakly dependent. True Model: The actual population model relating the dependent variable to the relevant independent vari- ables, plus a disturbance, where the zero conditional mean assumption holds. Truncated Normal Regression Model: The special case of the truncated regression model where the underlying population model satisfies the classical linear model assumptions. Truncated Regression Model: A linear regression model for cross-sectional data in which the sam- pling scheme entirely excludes, on the basis of outcomes on the dependent variable, part of the population. Two-Sided Alternative: An alternative where the population parameter can be either less than or greater than the value stated under the null hypothesis. Two Stage Least Squares (2SLS) Estimator: An instrumental variables estimator where the IV for an endogenous explanatory variable is obtained as the fitted value from regressing the endogenous explana- tory variable on all exogenous variables. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 860 Glossary Two-Tailed Test: A test against a two-sided alternative. Type I Error: A rejection of the null hypothesis when it is true. Type II Error: The failure to reject the null hypothesis when it is false. U Unbalanced Panel: A panel data set where certain years (or periods) of data are missing for some cross- sectional units. Unbiased Estimator: An estimator whose expected value (or mean of its sampling distribution) equals the population value (regardless of the population value). Uncentered R-squared: The R-squared computed without subtracting the sample average of the depen- dent variable when obtaining the total sum of squares (SST). Unconditional Forecast: A forecast that does not rely on knowing, or assuming values for, future explana- tory variables. Uncorrelated Random Variables: Random variables that are not linearly related. Underspecifying a Model: See excluding a relevant variable. Unidentified Equation: An equation with one or more endogenous explanatory variables where sufficient instrumental variables do not exist to identify the parameters. Unit Root Process: A highly persistent time series process where the current value equals last period’s value, plus a weakly dependent disturbance. Unobserved Effect: In a panel data model, an unobserved variable in the error term that does not change over time. For cluster samples, an unob- served variable that is common to all units in the cluster. Unobserved Effects Model: A model for panel data or cluster samples where the error term contains an unobserved effect. Unobserved Heterogeneity: See unobserved effect. Unrestricted Model: In hypothesis testing, the model that has no restrictions placed on its parameters. Upward Bias: The expected value of an estimator is greater than the population parameter value. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. V Variance: A measure of spread in the distribution of a random variable. Variance-CovarianceMatrix: Forarandomvector,the positive semi-definite matrix defined by putting the variances down the diagonal and the covariances in the appropriate off-diagonal entries. Variance-Covariance Matrix of the OLS Estima- tor: The matrix of sampling variances and covari- ances for the vector of OLS coefficients. Variance Inflation Factor: In multiple regression analysis under the Gauss-Markov assumptions, the term in the sampling variance affected by correlation among the explanatory variables. Variance of the Prediction Error: The variance in the error that arises when predicting a future value of the dependent variable based on an estimated multiple regression equation. Vector Autoregressive (VAR) Model: A model for two or more time series where each variable is modeled as a linear function of past values of all variables, plus disturbances that have zero means given all past values of the observed variables. W Wald Statistic: A general test statistic for testing hypotheses in a variety of econometric settings; typi- cally, the Wald statistic has an asymptotic chi-square distribution. Weak Instruments: Instrumental variables that are only slightly correlated with the relevant endogenous explanatory variable or variables. Weakly Dependent: A term that describes a time series process where some measure of dependence between random variables at two points in time—such as correlation—diminishes as the interval between the two points in time increases. Weighted Least Squares (WLS) Estimator: An estimator used to adjust for a known form of heteroskedasticity, where each squared residual is weighted by the inverse of the (estimated) variance of the error. White Test: A test for heteroskedasticity that involves regressing the squared OLS residuals on the OLS fit- ted values and on the squares of the fitted values; in its most general form, the squared OLS residuals are or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. regressed on the explanatory variables, the squares of the explanatory variables, and all the nonredundant interactions of the explanatory variables. Within Estimator: See fixed effects estimator. Within Transformation: See fixed effects transformation. Y Year Dummy Variables: For data sets with a time series component, dummy (binary) variables equal to one in the relevant year and zero in all other years. Z Zero Conditional Mean Assumption: A key assumption used in multiple regression analysis that states that, given any values of the explana- tory variables, the expected value of the error equals zero. (See Assumptions MLR.4, TS.3, and TS.3' in the text.) Zero Matrix: A matrix where all entries are zero. Zero-One Variable: See dummy variable. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Glossary 861 INDEX Numbers 2SLS. See two stage least squares 401(k) plans asymptotic normality, 174–175 comparison of simple and multiple regression estimates, 79 statistical vs. practical significance, 136 WLS estimation, 285 A ability and wage causality, 14 excluding ability from model, 89, 90–91, 92 IV for ability, 515, 533–534 mean independence, 25 proxy variable for ability, 308–312 achievement test scores. See college GPA adaptive expectations, 390, 392 adjusted R-squareds, 202–205, 414 AFDC participation, 255 age financial wealth and, 283–284, 291 smoking and, 288–289 aggregate consumption function, 568–570 air pollution and housing prices beta coefficients, 190–191 logarithmic forms, 191–192 quadratic functions, 196–198 t test, 132–133 airline and reservations. See probability alcohol drinking, 255 alternative hypotheses defined, 778 one-sided, 123–128, 780–782 two-sided, 128–130, 780–783 antidumping filings and chemical imports AR(3) serial correlation, 422 dummy variables, 361–362 862 forecasting, 663, 664, 665 PW estimation, 426 seasonality, 372 apples, ecolabeled, 201 AR(1) models, consistency example, 387 AR(1) serial correlation correcting for, 423–428 testing for, 416–421 testing for, after 2SLS estimation, 539–540 AR(2) models EMH example, 389 forecasting example, 666 ARCH model, 437–438 AR(q) serial correlation correcting for, 428–429 testing for, 421–422 arrests asymptotic normality, 174 average sentence length and, 275 goodness-of-fit, 82 heteroskedasticity-robust LM statistic, 275 linear probability model, 252–253 normality assumption and, 120 Poisson regression, 607–608 ASCII files, 680 assumptions for 2SLS, 551–553 classical linear model (CLM), 119 establishing unbiasedness of OLS, 45–50, 83–88, 349–352 for first differencing, 481–483 for fixed and random effects estimation, 509–511 homoskedasticity, 51–54, 93, 101, 402 for multiple linear regressions, 83–88, 93, 101, 171 normality, 118–121, 355 for OLS in matrix form, 809–815 for simple linear regressions, 45–50, 51–54 for time series regressions, 349–356, 384–391, 402 zero conditional mean. See zero conditional mean assumption Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. zero mean and zero correlation, 171 asymptotic bias, deriving, 172–173 asymptotic confidence interval, 177 asymptotic efficiency of OLS, 181–182 asymptotic normality of estimators, in general, 766–767 asymptotic normality of OLS for multiple linear regressions, 175–178 for time series regressions, 387–391 asymptotic sample properties of estimators, 763–767 asymptotic standard errors, 177–178, 630–631 asymptotic t statistics, 177 asymptotically uncorrelated sequences, 382–384 asymptotics, OLS. See OLS asymptotics attenuation bias, 322 attrition, 491–492 augmented Dickey-Fuller test, 642 autocorrelation, 353–354. See also serial correlation autoregressive conditional heteroskedacity (ARCH) model, 437–438 autoregressive model of order two [AR(2)]. See AR(2) models autoregressive process of order one, 383 auxiliary regression, 179 average, using summation operator, 704–705 average marginal effect (AME), 316, 592 average partial effect (APE), 316, 592, 600–601 average treatment effect, 457 B balanced panel, 469 barium chloride. See antidumping filings and chemical imports base group, 230 base period and value, 360 baseball players’ salaries nonnested models, 203 testing exclusion restrictions, 143–149 Becker, Gary, 3 beer price and demand, 207 taxes and traffic fatalities, 205 benchmark group, 230 Bernoulli random variables, 723–724 best linear unbiased estimator (BLUE), 102 beta coefficients, 189–191 between estimators, 485 Index 863 bias. See also unbiasedness attenuation, 322 heterogeneity, 460 omitted variable, 88–92, 115–116 simultaneity, in OLS, 558–560 biased estimators, 758–759 biased toward zero, 91 binary response models. See logit and probit models binary variables. See also qualitative information defined, 227 random, 723–724 binomial distribution, 729 birth weight AFDC participation and, 255 asymptotic standard error, 178 data scaling, 186–189 F statistic, 151 IV estimation, 522–523 bivariate linear regression model. See simple regression model BLUE (best linear unbiased estimator), 102 bootstrapping, 225–226 Breusch-Godfrey test, 422 Breusch-Pagan test, 277–278 C calculus, differential, 717–719 campus crimes, t test, 131–132 causality, 12–16 cdf (cumulative distribution functions), 726–727 censored regression models, 609–613 Center for Research in Security Prices, 680 central limit theorem, 767 CEO salaries in multiple regressions motivation for multiple regression, 71–72 nonnested models, 204–205 predicting, 214–215 writing in population form, 84 returns on equity and fitted values and residuals, 35–36 goodness-of-fit, 39 OLS Estimates, 32–33 sales and, constant elasticity model, 43 ceteris paribus, 12–16, 74, 76–77 chemical firms, nonnested models, 204 chemical imports. See antidumping filings and chemical imports Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 864 Index chi-square distribution critical values table, 837 discussions, 749, 804–805 Chow tests differences across groups, 247–248 heteroskedasticity and, 273–274 for panel data, 473 for structural change across time, 453 cigarettes. See smoking city crimes. See also crimes law enforcement and, 14–15 panel data, 10–11 classical errors-in-variables (CEV), 323 classical linear model (CLM) assumptions, 119 clear-up rate, distributed lag estimation, 464–465 clusters, 483, 500–501, 511 Cochrane-Orcutt (CO) estimation, 425, 433 coefficient of determination. See R-squareds cointegration, 646–651 college admission, omitting unobservables, 315 college GPA beta coefficients, 189 comparison of simple and multiple regression estimates, 79 fitted values and intercept, 77 gender and, 245–248 goodness-of-fit, 81 heteroskedasticity-robust F statistic, 273 interaction effect, 199–200 interpreting equations, 75 with measurement error, 322–323 partial effect, 76 population regression function, 26 predicted, 208–209, 210–211 with single dummy variable, 232 t test, 129–130 college proximity, as IV for education, 526–527 colleges, junior vs. four-year, 140–143 collinearity, perfect, 84–86 column vectors, 797 commute time and freeway width, 788–789 compact discs, demand for, 707 composite error, 460 composite error term, 493 Compustat, 680 computer ownership college GPA and, 232 determinants of, 295–296 computer usage and wages with interacting terms, 241 proxy variable in, 312–313 computers, grants to buy reducing error variance, 207 R-squared size, 201 conceptual framework, 687 conditional distributions features of, 730–737 overview, 727, 729–730 conditional expectations, 741–744 conditional forecasts, 654 conditional median, 332–333 conditional variances, 744–745 confidence intervals 95%, rule of thumb for, 775–776 asymptotic, 177 asymptotic, for nonnormal populations, 776–777 hypothesis testing and, 787–788 interval estimation and, 770–777 main discussions, 138–140, 770–772 for mean from normally distributed population, 772–775 for predictions, 207–211 consistency of estimators, in general, 763–766 consistency of OLS in multiple regressions, 169–173 sampling selection and, 615–617 in time series regressions, 384–387, 412–413 consistent tests, 789 constant dollars, 360–361 constant elasticity model, 43, 85, 714 constant terms, 23 consumer price index (CPI), 360 consumption. See under family income contemporaneously exogenous variables, 351 continuous random variables, 725–727 control group, 232 control variables, 23. See also independent variables corner solution responses. See Tobit model corrected R-squareds, 202–205 correlated random effects, 497–499 correlation, 24–25. See also serial correlation correlation coefficients, 739 count variables, 604–609 county crimes, multi-year panel data, 471–472 covariance stationary processes, 381–382 covariances, 737–738 covariates, 23 CPI (consumer price index), 360 crimes. See also arrests on campuses, t test, 131–132 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. in cities, panel data, 10–11 in cities, law enforcement and, 14–15 clear-up rate, 464–465 in counties, multi-year panel data, 471–472 earlier data, use of, 313–314 econometric model of, 4–5 economic model of, 3, 180, 305–306 functional form misspecification, 305–306 housing prices and, beta coefficients, 190–191 LM statistic, 180 prison population and, SEM, 573–574 unemployment and, two-period panel data, 459–462 criminologists, 678 critical values discussions, 124, 780 tables of, 833–837 crop yields and fertilizers causality, 13, 14 simple equation, 23–24 cross-sectional data. See also panel data; pooled cross sections; regression analysis Gauss-Markov assumptions and, 93, 354 main discussion, 5–7 time series data vs., 344–345 cumulative areas under standard normal distribution, 831–832 cumulative distribution functions (cdf), 726–727 cumulative effect, 348 current dollars, 360 cyclical unemployment, 390 D data economic, types of, 5–12 experimental vs. nonexperimental, 2 data collection, 679–683 data frequency, 8 data issues. See also misspecification measurement error, 317–323 missing data, 324 multicollinearity, 94–98, 324 nonrandom samples, 324–326 outliers and influential observations, 326–331 random slopes, 315–317 unobserved explanatory variables, 308–315 data mining, 685–686 data scaling, effects on OLS statistics, 186–191 data sources, 701–702 Davidson-MacKinnon test, 308 deficits. See under interest rates degrees of freedom (df) chi-square distributions with n, 749 for fixed effects estimator, 486 for OLS estimators, 100 demand equations, 2 dependent variables. See also regression analysis; specific event studies defined, 22–23 measurement error in, 318–320 derivation of equation, 114 derivation of first order conditions in equation, 113–114 derivatives, 710 descriptive statistics, 704 detrending, 368–370 diagonal matrices, 797 Dickey-Fuller test, 640–642 difference in slopes, 241–245 difference-in-differences estimator, 455–458, 467 difference-stationary processes, 396 differencing panel data two-period, 461–465 with more than two periods, 468–473 serial correlation and, 429–430 differential calculus, 717–719 diminishing marginal effects, 710 discrete random variables, 723–725 disturbance terms, 5, 23, 71 disturbance variances, 51 downward bias, 91 drug usage, 255 drunk driving laws and fatalities, 467–468 dummy variables. See also qualitative information; year dummy variables defined, 227 regression, 488–489 duration analysis, 611–612 Durbin-Watson test, 418–420, 422 dynamically complete models, 399–401 E Eagle-Granger test, 647–648 earnings of veterans, IV estimation, 521 EconLit, 677, 678 econometric analysis in projects, 683–686 econometric models, 4–5. See also specific topics econometrics, 1–2. See also specific topics economic growth and government policies, 7 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Index 865 866 Index economic models, 2–5 economic vs. statistical significance, 135–138, 788–789 economists, types of, 676–677 education birth weight and, 151 fertility and 2SLS, 541 with discrete dependent variables, 256–257 independent cross sections, 450–451 gender wage gap and, 451–453 IV for, 515, 516, 526–527 return to 2SLS, 530 differencing, 500 fixed effects estimation, 488 independent cross sections, 451–453 IQ and, 311–312 IV estimation, 518–520 testing for endogeneity, 535 testing overidentifying restrictions, 537 smoking and, 288–289 wages and. See under wages women and, 249–251. See also under women in labor force efficiency asymptotic, 181–182 of estimators in general, 762–763 of OLS with serially correlated errors, 413–414 efficient markets hypothesis (EMH) asymptotic analysis example, 388–389 heteroskedasticity and, 436 elasticity, 44, 713–715 elections. See voting outcomes EMH. See efficient markets hypothesis (EMH) empirical analysis data collection, 679–683 data sources, 701–702 econometric analysis, 683–686 journals listing, 700–701 literature review, 678–679 posing question, 676–678 sample projects, 694–700 steps in, 2–5 writing paper, 686–694 employment and unemployment. See also wages arrests and, 252–253 crimes and, 459–462 enterprise zones and, 470–471 estimating average rate, 757 forecasting, 656, 659, 662 inflation and. See under inflation in Puerto Rico logarithmic form, 356–357 time series data, 8–9 women and. See women in labor force endogenous explanatory variables. See also instrumental variables; simultaneous equations models; two stage least squares defined, 87, 303 in logit and probit models, 596 sample selection and, 620–621 tesing for, 534–535 endogenous sample selection, 325 Engle-Granger two-step procedure, 652 enrollment, t test, 131–132 enterprise zones business investments and, 782 unemployment and, 470–471 error correction models, 651–652 error terms, 5, 23, 71 error variances adding regressors to reduce, 206–207 defined, 51, 94 estimating, 54–56 errors-in-variables problem, 512, 532–534. See also instrumental variables estimated GLS. See feasible GLS estimation and estimators. See also first differencing; fixed effects; instrumental variables; logit and probit models; OLS (ordinary least squares); random effects; Tobit model advantages of multiple over simple regression, 68–72 asymptotic sample properties of, 763–767 changing independent variables simultaneously, 77 defined, 757 difference-in-differences, 455–458, 467 finite sample properties of, 756–763 LAD, 331–334 language of, 103–104 method of moments approach, 28 misspecifying models, 88–92 sampling distributions of OLS estimators, 118–121 WLS. See weighted least squares estimation event studies, 359, 361–362. See also specific event studies Excel, 681 excluding relevant variables, 88–92 exclusion restrictions for 2SLS, 528 general linear, 153–154 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistic, 178–181 overall significance of regressions, 152–153 for SEM, 562, 567 testing, 143–149 exogenous explanatory variables, 87. See also instrumental variables; two stage least squares exogenous instrumental variables, 552 exogenous sample selection, 325, 616 expectations augmented Phillips curve, 390–391, 418 expectations hypothesis, 16 expected values, 730–733, 803 experience wage and causality, 14 interpreting equations, 76 motivation for multiple regression, 69, 70 omitted variable bias, 92 partial effect, 718 quadratic functions, 194–196, 711–712 women and, 249–251 experimental data, 2 experimental group, 232 experiments, defined, 722 explained sum of squares (SSE), 37–38, 80–81 explained variables, 22–23. See also dependent variables explanatory variables, 23. See also independent variables exponential function, 716 exponential smoothing, 653 exponential trends, 365–366 exponentiating, 42–43 F F distribution critical values table, 834–836 discussions, 750–752, 805 F statistics. See also F tests defined, 146 heteroskedasticity-robust, 273–274. See also heteroskedasticity F tests. See also Chow tests; F statistics F and t statistics, 149–150 functional form misspecification and, 304–308 general linear restrictions, 153–154 LM tests and, 180–181 overall significance of regressions, 152–153 p-values for, 151–152 reporting regression results, 154–156 R-squared form, 150–151 testing exclusion restrictions, 143–149 family income. See also savings birth weight and asymptotic standard error, 178 data scaling, 186–189 college GPA and, 322–323 consumption and motivation for multiple regression, 70, 71 perfect collinearity and, 85 test scores and. See standardized test scores farmers and pesticide usage, 206 FDL (finite distributed lag) models, 346–348, 386, 464–465 feasible GLS AR(1) model estimation, 425–428 with heteroskedasticity and AR(1) serial correlations, 439 main discussion, 286–290 OLS vs., 427–428 Federal Bureau of Investigation, 680 fertility rate education and, 541 forecasting, 666 over time, 449–451 tax exemption and with binary variables, 357–359 cointegration, 649 FDL model, 346, 348 first differences, 397–398 serial correlation, 401 trends, 368 fertility studies, with discrete dependent variables, 256–257 fertilizers land quality and, 25 soybean yields and causality, 13, 14 simple equation, 23–24 final exam scores interaction effect, 199–200 skipping classes and, 515–516 financial wealth nonrandom sampling, 325 WLS estimation, 283–284, 291 finite distributed lag (FDL) models, 346–348, 386, 464–465 finite sample properties of estimators, 756–763 of OLS in matrix form, 809–813 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Index 867 868 Index firm sales. See sales first differencing assumptions for, 481–483 defined, 461 fixed effects vs., 489–491 I(1) time series and, 396 panel data, pitfalls in, 473–474 first order autocorrelation, 397 first order conditions, 30, 73–74, 719, 808 first-differenced equations, 461 fitted values. See also OLS (ordinary least squares) in multiple regressions, 77–78 in simple regressions, 30, 35–36 fixed effects assumptions for, 509–511 defined, 460 dummy variable regression, 488–489 estimation, 484–492 first differencing vs., 489–491 random effects vs., 495–496 with unbalanced panels, 491–492 forecast intervals, 655–656 forecasting multiple-step-ahead, 660–662 one-step-ahead, 655–659 overview and definitions, 652–654 trending, seasonal, and integrated processes, 662–667 types of models used for, 654–655 free throw shooting, 728, 730 freeway width and commute time, 788–789 frequency, data, 8 frequency distributions, 401(k) plans, 174 functional forms in multiple regressions with interaction terms, 198–200 logarithmic, 191–194 misspecification, 304–308 quadratic, 194–198 in simple regressions, 39–44 in time series regressions, 356–357 G Gauss-Markov assumptions for multiple linear regressions, 83–88, 93 for simple linear regressions, 45–50, 51–54 Gauss-Markov Theorem for multiple linear regressions, 101–102, 116–117 for OLS in matrix form, 812 for time series regressions, 352–354 GDL (geometric distributed lag), 635–637 GDP. See gross domestic product (GDP) gender as binary variable. See qualitative information oversampling, 326 wage gap, 451–453 generalized least squares (GLS) estimators for AR(1) models, 424–428 with heteroskedasticity and AR(1) serial correlations, 439 when heteroskedasticity function must be estimated, 286–290 when heteroskedasticity is known up to a multiplicative constant, 282–283 geometric distributed lag (GDL), 635–637 GLS estimators. See generalized least squares (GLS) estimators Goldberger, Arthur, 96 goodness-of-fit. See also predictions; R-squareds change in unit of measurement and, 41 in multiple regressions, 80–81 overemphasizing, 205–206 percent correctly predicted, 251, 590 in simple regressions, 38–39 in time series regressions, 414 Google Scholar, 677 government policies economic growth and, 7 housing prices and, 9–10 GPA. See college GPA Granger, Clive W. J., 169 Granger causality, 657 gross domestic product (GDP) data frequency for, 8 government policies and, 7 high persistence, 393–394 in real terms, 360 seasonal adjustment of, 372 unit root test, 643 growth rate, 366, 396 gun control laws, 255 H HAC standard errors, 432 Hartford School District, 211–212 Hausman test, 290, 496 Head Start participation, 255 Heckit method, 618–619 heterogeneity bias, 460 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. heteroskedasticity. See also weighted least squares estimation 2SLS with, 538 consequences of, for OLS, 268–269 defined, 51 HAC standard errors, 432 heteroskedasticity-robust procedures, 269–275 linear probability model and, 294–296 testing for, 275–280 in time series regressions, 434–439 in wage equation, 52 high school and college GPAs. See college GPA highly persistent time series deciding whether I(0) or I(1), 396–399 description of, 391–395 transformations on, 395–396 histogram, 401(k) plan participation, 174 homoskedasticity for 2SLS, 552 for IV estimation, 517 for multiple linear regressions, 93–94, 101 for OLS in matrix form, 811 for simple linear regressions, 51–54 for time series regressions, 352–353, 387–388, 402 hourly wages. See wages housing prices and expenditures air pollution and. See air pollution and housing prices general linear restrictions, 153–154 heteroskedasticity BP test, 278 White test, 280 incinerators and inconsistency in OLS, 173 pooled cross sections, 454–457 income and, 706 inflation, 637–639 investment and computing R-squared, 370–371 spurious relationship, 367 over controlling, 206 property taxes and, 9–10 with qualitative information, 234 RESET, 307 residual analysis, 211 rooms and. See rooms and housing prices savings and, 557–558 hypotheses. See also hypothesis testing about single linear combination of parameters, 140–143 about single population parameter. See t tests Index 869 after 2SLS estimation, 532 expectations, 16 language of classical testing, 135 in logit and probit models, 588–589 multiple linear restrictions. See F tests stating, in empirical analysis, 5 hypothesis testing about mean in normal population, 780–783 asymptotic tests for nonnormal populations, 783–784 computing and using p-values, 784–787 confidence intervals and, 787–788 in matrix form, Wald statistics for, 818 overview and fundamentals, 777–780 practical vs. statistical significance, 788–789 I I(0) and I(1) processes, 396–399 idempotent matrices, 802–803 identification defined, 516 in systems with three or more equations, 567–568 in systems with two equations, 560–565 identity matrices, 797 idiosyncratic error, 460 IDL (infinite distributed lag models), 633–639 IIP (index of industrial production), 359–360 impact propensity/multiplier, 347 incidental truncation, 615, 617–621 incinerators and housing prices inconsistency in OLS, 173 pooled cross sections, 454–457 including irrelevant variables, 88 income. See also wages family. See family income housing expenditure and, 706 PIH, 570–571 savings and. See under savings inconsistency in OLS, deriving, 172–173 inconsistent estimators, 764 independence, joint distributions and, 727–729 independent variables. See also regression analysis; specific event studies changing simultaneously, 77 defined, 23 maximum likelihood estimation with, 630 measurement error in, 320–323 in misspecified models, 88–92 random, 728 simple vs. multiple regression, 69–72 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 870 Index independently pooled cross sections. See also pooled cross sections across time, 449–453 defined, 448 index numbers, 359–362 industrial production, index of (IIP), 359–360 infant mortality rates, outliers, 330–331 inference in multiple regressions confidence intervals, 138–140 hypotheses. See hypotheses statistical, with IV estimator, 517–521 differencing, 430 inference under CLM assumptions, 356 T-bill. See T-bill rates interval estimation, 755, 770–772. See also confidence intervals inverse Mills ratio, 598 inverse of matrix, 801 IQ ability and, 309–312, 314–315 nonrandom sampling, 325 irrelevant variables, including, 88 IV. See instrumental variables J JEL (Journal of Economic Literature), 677 job training. See also training grants scrap rates and. See scrap rates and job training as self-selection problem, 255 worker productivity and program evaluation, 254 sample model, 4 joint distributions features of, 730–737 independence and, 727–729 joint hypotheses tests, 144 jointly statistically significant/insignificant, 148 Journal of Economic Literature (JEL), 677 journals listing, 700–701 junior colleges vs. universities, 140–143 just identified equations, 568 K Koyck distributed lag, 635–637 kurtosis, 737 L labor economists, 676, 678 labor force. See employment and unemployment; women in labor force labor supply and demand, 555–556 labor supply function, 715 LAD (least absolute deviations) estimation, 331–334 lag distribution, 347 lagged dependent variables as proxy variables, 313–314 serial correlation and, 415–416 lagged endogenous variables, 659 lagged explanatory variables, 349 in time series regressions, 355–356, 413–414 infinite distributed lag models, 633–639 inflation from 1948 to 2003, 345 interest rates and. See under interest rates openness and, 564–565, 566 random walk model for, 392 unemployment and expectations augmented Phillips curve, 390–391 forecasting, 656 static Phillips curve, 346, 355–356 unit root test, 642 influential observations, 326–331 information set, 653 in-sample criteria, 658–659 instrumental variables. See also two stage least squares computing R-squared after estimation, 523 in multiple regressions, 524–527 overview and definitions, 513, 514, 516 properties, with poor instrumental variable, 521–523 in simple regressions, 513–523 solutions to errors-in-variables problems, 532–534 statistical inference, 517–521 integrated of order zero/one processes, 396–399 integrated processes, forecasting, 662–667 interaction effect, 198–200 interaction terms, 240–241 intercept shifts, 229–230 intercepts. See also OLS estimators; regression analysis change in unit of measurement and, 40–41 defined, 23, 705 in regressions on a constant, 58 in regressions through origin, 57–58 interest rates inflation, deficits, and Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistics heteroskedasticity-robust, 274–275. See also heteroskedasticity main discussion, 178–181 land quality and fertilizers, 25 large sample properties, 763–767. See also asymptotic entries; OLS asymptotics latent variable models, 585 law enforcement city crime levels and (causality), 14–15 murder rates and (SEM), 557 law of iterated expectations, 743–744 law of large numbers, 765 law school rankings as dummy variables, 239–240 residual analysis, 211 LDV. See limited dependent variables leads and lags estimators, 650 least absolute deviations (LAD) estimation, 331–334 least squares estimator, 770 likelihood ratio statistic, 589 limited dependent variables asymptotic standard errors in, 630–631 binary response. See logit and probit models censored and truncated regression models, 609–615 corner solution response. See Tobit model count response, Poisson regression for, 604–609 overview, 583–584 sample selection corrections, 615–621 linear functions, 705–707 linear in parameters assumption for 2SLS, 551–552 for multiple linear regressions, 83 for OLS in matrix form, 809–810 for simple linear regressions, 45, 49 for time series regressions, 349–350 linear independence, 801 linear probability model (LPM). See also limited dependent variables heteroskedasticity and, 294–296 main discussion, 248–253 linear regression model, 44, 72. See also multiple regression analysis; simple regression model linear relationship among independent variables, 95–96 linear time trends, 364–365 linearity and weak dependence assumption, 384–385 literature review, 678–679 LM statistics. See Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistics loan approval rates F and t statistics, 150 multicollinearity, 97 program evaluation, 254–255 logarithms in multiple regressions, 191–194 natural, overview, 712–715 predicting y when log(y) is dependent, 212–215 qualitative information and, 233–235 real dollars and, 361 in simple regressions, 41–43 in time series regressions, 356–357 logit and probit models interpreting estimates, 589–596 maximum likelihood estimation of, 587–588 specifying, 584–587 testing multiple hypotheses, 588–589 log-likelihood functions, 588 longitudinal data. See also panel data long-run elasticity, 357 long-run propensity (LRP), 348 loss functions, 653 LPM. See linear probability model (LPM) LRP (long-run propensity), 348 lunch program and math performance, 50 M macroeconomists, 677 MAE (mean absolute error), 659 marginal effect, 705 marital status. See qualitative information martingale difference sequence, 639 martingale functions, 653 matched pair samples, 500 math performance and lunch program, 50 mathematical statistics. See statistics matrices. See also OLS in matrix form basic definitions, 796–797 differentiation of linear and quadratic forms, 803 idempotent, 802–803 linear independence and rank of, 801 moments and distributions of random vectors, 803–805 operations, 797–801 quadratic forms and positive definite, 802 matrix notation, 808 maximum likelihood estimation, 587–588, 630, 769–770 mean, using summation operator, 704–705 mean absolute error (MAE), 659 mean independence, 25 mean squared error (MSE), 763 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Index 871 872 Index measurement error IV solutions to, 532–534 properties of OLS under, 317–323 measures of association, 737–739 measures of central tendency, 730–734 measures of variability, 734–737 median, 704, 733–734 men, return to education, 518–519 method of moments approach, 28, 768–769 micronumerosity, 96 military personnel survey, oversampling in, 326 minimum variance unbiased estimators, 119, 769, 815 minimum wages employment/unemployment and AR(1) serial correlation, testing for, 420–421 causality, 15 detrending, 369–370 logarithmic form, 356–357 SC-robust standard error, 434 in Puerto Rico, effects of, 8–9 minorities and loans. See loan approval rates missing data, 324 misspecification in empirical projects, 684–685 functional form, 304–308 unbiasedness and, 88–92 variances, 98–99 motherhood, teenage, 499–500 moving average process of order one, 383 MSE (mean squared error), 763 multicollinearity 2SLS and, 530–531 among explanatory variables, 324 main discussion, 94–98 multiple hypotheses tests, 144 multiple regression analysis. See also data issues; estimation and estimators; heteroskedasticity; hypotheses; OLS (ordinary least squares); predictions; R-squareds adding regressors to reduce error variance, 206–207 advantages over simple regression, 68–72 confidence intervals, 138–140 functional forms. See under functional forms over controlling, 205–206 with qualitative information. See under qualitative information multiple restrictions, 144 multiple-step-ahead forecasts, 660–662 multiplicative measurement error, 319 multivariate normal distribution, 804 municipal bond interest rates, 237–238 murder rates SEM, 557 static Phillips curve, 346 N natural experiments, 457, 521 natural logarithms, 712–715. See also logarithms netting out, 78 no perfect collinearity assumption for multiple linear regressions, 84–86, 87 for OLS in matrix form, 810 for time series regressions, 350, 385 no serial correlation assumption. See also serial correlation for 2SLS, 553 for OLS in matrix form, 811 for time series regressions, 353–354, 387–388 nominal dollars, 360 nonexperimental data, 2 nonlinear functions, 710–716 nonlinearities, incorporating in simple regressions, 41–44 nonnested models choosing between, 203–205 functional form misspecification and, 307–308 nonrandom samples, 324–326, 615 nonstationary time series processes, 381–382 normal distribution, 745–749 normal sampling distributions for multiple linear regressions, 120–121 for time series regressions, 355–356 normality assumption for multiple linear regressions, 118–121 for time series regressions, 355 normality of errors assumption, 813 normality of estimators in general, asymptotic, 766–767 normality of OLS, asymptotic in multiple regressions, 173–178, 185 in time series regressions, 387–391 n-R-squared statistic, 178–181 null hypothesis, 122–123, 778. See also hypotheses O observational data, 2 OLS (ordinary least squares). See also heteroskedasticity; panel data; predictions; other OLS entries Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. cointegration and, 649–650 comparison of simple and multiple regression estimates, 78–80 consistency. See consistency of OLS logit and probit vs., 593–595 in multiple regressions algebraic properties, 72–83 computational properties, 72–83 effects of data scaling, 186–191 fitted values and residuals, 77–78 goodness-of-fit, 80–81 interpreting equations, 74–76 measurement error and, 317–323 obtaining estimates, 72–74 partialling out, 78 regression through origin, 81–83 statistical properties, 83–92 Poisson vs., 606, 607–608 in simple regressions algebraic properties, 35–39 defined, 30 deriving estimates, 27–35 statistical properties, 45–56 units of measurement, changing, 40–41 simultaneity bias in, 558–560 in time series regressions correcting for serial correlation, 425–428 FGLS vs., 427–428 finite sample properties, 349–356 SC-robust standard errors, 431–434 with serially correlated errors, properties of, 412–416 Tobit vs., 601–603 OLS asymptotics in matrix form, 815–818 in multiple regressions consistency, 169–173 efficiency, 181–182 Lagrange multiplier (LM) statistic, 178–181 normality, 173–178, 185 overview, 168 in time series regressions consistency, 384–387 normality, 387–391 OLS estimators. See also heteroskedasticity defined, 45 in multiple regressions asymptotics. See OLS asymptotics efficiency of, 101–102 expected value of, 83–92 Index 873 sampling distributions of, 118–121 unbiasedness of, 87–88 variances of, 93–101 in simple regressions unbiasedness of, 45–50 variances of, 50–56 in time series regressions sampling distributions of, 355–356 unbiasedness of, 349–352 variances of, 352–354 OLS in matrix form asymptotic analysis, 815–818 finite sample properties, 809–813 overview, 807–809 statistical inference, 813–815 Wald statistics for testing multiple hypotheses, 818 OLS intercept estimates, defined, 74 OLS regression line. See also OLS (ordinary least squares) defined, 31 in multiple regressions, 74 OLS slope estimates, defined, 74 omitted variable bias. See also instrumental variables general discussions, 88–92, 115–116 using proxy variables, 308–314 one-sided alternatives, 780–782 one-step-ahead forecasts, 655–659 one-tailed tests, 124, 781. See also t tests online databases, 680 online search services, 678–679 order condition, 531, 563 ordinal variables, 237–240 ordinary least squares. See OLS (ordinary least squares) outliers guarding against, 331–334 main discussion, 326–331 out-of-sample criteria, 658–659 over controlling, 205–206 overall significance of regressions, 152–153 overdispersion, 607 overidentified equations, 568 overidentifying restrictions, testing, 535–538 overspecifying the model, 88 P pairwise uncorrelated random variables, 740–741 panel data applying 2SLS to, 540–542 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 874 Index panel data (continued) applying methods to other structures, 499–501 correlated random effects, 497–499 differencing with more than two periods, 468–473 fixed effects, 484–492 independently pooled cross sections vs., 448–449 organizing, 465 overview, 10–11 pitfalls in first differencing, 473–474 random effects, 492–496 simultaneous equations models with, 572–574 two-period, analysis, 459–465 two-period, policy analysis with, 465–468 unbalanced, 491–492 Panel Study of Income Dynamics, 680 parameters defined, 5, 755 estimation, general approach to, 768–770 partial derivatives, 717–718 partial effect, 74, 76–77. See also regression analysis partial effect at the average (PEA), 591–592, 600 partialling out, 78 partitioned matrix multiplication, 800 pdf (probability density functions), 724–725 percent correctly predicted, 251, 590 percentages, 707–709 perfect collinearity, 84–86 permanent income hypothesis, 570–571 per-student spending. See standardized test scores pesticide usage, over controlling, 206 physical attractiveness and wages, 238–239 pizzas, expected revenue, 732 plug-in solution, 309 point estimates, 755 point forecasts, 655 Poisson regression model, 604–609 policy analysis with pooled cross sections, 454–459 with qualitative information, 232, 253–256 with two-period panel data, 465–468 pollution. See air pollution and housing prices pooled cross sections. See also independently pooled cross sections applying 2SLS to, 540–542 overview, 9–10 policy analysis with, 454–459 population, defined, 755. See also confidence intervals; hypothesis testing population model, defined, 83 population regression function (PRF), 25–26 population R-squareds, 202 positive definite and semi-definite matrices, defined, 802 poverty rate in absence of suitable proxies, 315 excluding from model, 91 power of a test, 779–780 practical vs. statistical significance, 135–138, 788–789 Prais-Winsten (PW) estimation, 425–426, 428, 433 predetermined variables, 659 predicted variables, 23. See also dependent variables predictions confidence intervals for, 207–211 with heteroskedasticity, 292–294 residual analysis, 211–212 for y when log(y) is dependent, 212–215 predictor variables, 23. See also independent variables price index, 360–361 prisons population and crime rates, 573–574 recidivism, 611–612 probability. See also conditional distributions; joint distributions features of distributions, 730–737 independence, 727–729 normal and related distributions, 745–752 overview, 722 random variables and their distributions, 722–727 probability density functions (pdf), 724–725 probability limits, 764–766 probit model. See logit and probit models productivity. See worker productivity program evaluation, 232, 253–256 projects. See empirical analysis property taxes and housing prices, 9–10 proportions, 707–709 proxy variables, 308–314 pseudo R-squareds, 590–591 public finance study researchers, 676 Puerto Rico, employment in detrending, 369–370 logarithmic form, 356–357 time series data, 8–9 p-values computing and using, 784–787 for F tests, 151–152 for t tests, 133–135 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Q quadratic form for matrices, 802, 803 quadratic functions, 194–198, 710–712 quadratic time trends, 366 qualitative information. See also linear probability model (LPM) in multiple regressions allowing for different slopes, 241–245 binary dependent variable, 248–253 describing, 227–228 discrete dependent variables, 256–257 interactions among dummy variables, 240–241 with log(y) dependent variable, 233–235 multiple dummy independent variables, 235–240 ordinal variables, 237–240 overview, 227 policy analysis and program evaluation, 253–256 proxy variables, 312–313 single dummy independent variable, 228–235 testing for differences in regression functions across groups, 245–248 in time series regressions main discussion, 357–363 seasonal, 372–373 quantile regression, 334 quasi- (natural) experiments, 457, 521 quasi-demeaned data, 493 quasi-differenced data, 424 quasi-likelihood ratio statistic, 607 quasi-maximum likelihood estimation (QMLE), 606, 815 R Index 875 random coefficient model, 315–317 random effects assumptions for, 509–511 correlated, 497–499 fixed effects vs., 495–496 main discussion, 492–495 random sampling assumption for 2SLS, 552 for multiple linear regressions, 84 for simple linear regressions, 45–46, 47, 49 cross-sectional data and, 6–7 defined, 756 random slope model, 315–317 random variables, 722–727 random vectors, 803 random walks, 391–395 rank condition, 531, 552, 562–563 rank of matrix, 801 RDL (rational distributed lag models), 637–639 real dollars, 360–361 recidivism, duration analysis, 611–612 reduced form equations, 525, 559 regressands, 23. See also dependent variables regression analysis, 57–58. See also multiple regression analysis; simple regression model; time series data regression specification error test (REST), 306–307 regressors, 23, 206–207. See also independent variables rejection region, 780 rejection rule, 124. See also t tests relative change, 708–709 relative efficiency, 762–763 relevant variables, excluding, 88–92 reporting multiple regression results, 154–156 resampling methods, defined, 225 rescaling, 186–189 residual analysis, 211–212 residual sum of squares (SSR). See sum of squared residuals residuals. See also OLS (ordinary least squares) in multiple regressions, 77–78, 328–329 in simple regressions, 30, 35–36, 55 studentized, 328–329 response probability, 249, 584 response variables, 23. See also dependent variables REST (regression specification error test), 306–307 restricted model, 145–146. See also F tests retrospective data, 2 R&D and sales confidence intervals, 139–140 nonnested models, 203–204 outliers, 327–328, 329–330 R2j, 95–96 race arrests and, 253 baseball player salaries and, 244–245 discrimination in hiring asymptotic confidence interval, 776–777 hypothesis testing, 784 p-value, 787 loans and. See loan approval rates rational distributed lag models, 637–639 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 876 Index returns on equity and CEO salaries fitted values and residuals, 35–36 goodness-of-fit, 39 OLS Estimates, 32–33 RMSE (root mean squared error), 56, 100, 659 robust regression, 334 rooms and housing prices beta coefficients, 190–191 interaction effect, 198–199 quadratic functions, 196–198 residual analysis, 211 root mean squared error (RMSE), 56, 100, 659 row vectors, 797 R-squareds. See also predictions of OLS estimators, 118–121 sampling standard deviation, 777 sampling variances of estimators in general, 760–762 of OLS estimators for multiple linear regressions, 94, 116 for simple linear regressions, 53–54 savings housing expenditures and, 557–558 income and heteroskedasticity, 281–282 scatterplot, 27 measurement error in, 318 with nonrandom sample, 325 scalar multiplication, 798 scalar variance-covariance matrices, 811 scatterplots R&D and sales, 328 savings and income, 27 wage and education, 29 school lunch program and math performance, 50 school size and student performance, 127–128 score statistic, 178–181 scrap rates and job training 2SLS, 541–542 confidence interval, 774–775 confidence interval and hypothesis testing, 788 fixed effects estimation, 486–487 measurement error in, 319 program evaluation, 254 p-value, 786–787 statistical vs. practical significance, 137 two-period panel data, 466 unbalanced panel data, 492 seasonality forecasting, 662–667 serial correlation and, 422–423 of time series, 371–373 selected samples, 616 self-selection problems, 255–256 SEM. See simultaneous equations models semi-elasticity, 44, 715 sensitivity analysis, 685 sequential exogeneity, 401 serial correlation correcting for, 423–429 differencing and, 429–430 dynamic completeness and, 399–401 heteroskedasticity and, 438–439 lagged dependent variables and, 415–416 adjusted, 202–205, 414 after IV estimation, 523 change in unit of measurement and, 41 for F statistic, 150–151 in fixed effects estimation, 487, 488–489 in multiple regressions, main discussion, 80–83 for probit and logit models, 590–591 for PW estimation, 426 in regressions through origin, 57–58, 81–83 in simple regressions, 38–39, 57–58 size of, 200–201 in time series regressions, 414 trending dependent variables and, 370–371 uncentered, 237 S salaries. See CEO salaries; income; wages sales CEO salaries and constant elasticity model, 43 nonnested models, 204–205 motivation for multiple regression, 71–72 R&D and. See R&D and sales sales tax increase, 709 sample average, 757 sample correlation coefficient, 769 sample covariance, 768 sample regression function (SRF), 31, 74 sample selection corrections, 615–621 sample standard deviation, 765 sample variation in the explanatory variable assumption, 46, 49 sampling, nonrandom, 324–326 sampling distributions defined, 758 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. no serial correlation assumption, 353–354, 387–388 properties of OLS with, 412–416 testing for, 416–423 serial correlation-robust standard errors, 431–434 short-run elasticity, 357 significance level, 123. See also t tests simple regression model. See also OLS (ordinary least squares) defined, 22–26 incorporating nonlinearities in, 41–44 IV estimation, 513–523 multiple regression vs., 68–71 regression on a constant, 58 regression through origin, 57–58 simultaneous equations models bias in OLS, 558–560 identifying and estimating structural equations, 560–566 overview and nature of, 554–558 with panel data, 572–574 systems with more than two equations, 567–568 with time series, 568–572 skewness, 737 sleeping vs. working, 463–465 slopes. See also OLS estimators; regression analysis change in unit of measurement and, 40–41, 43 defined, 23, 705 qualitative information and, 241–245 random, 315–317 in regressions on a constant, 58 in regressions through origin, 57–58 smearing estimates, 213 smoking birth weight and asymptotic standard error, 178 data scaling, 186–189 IV estimation, 522–523 cigarette taxes and consumption, 459 demand for cigarettes, 288–289 measurement error, 323 Social Sciences Citation Index, 677 soybean yields and fertilizers causality, 13, 14 simple equation, 23–24 spreadsheets, 681 spurious regression, 366–367, 644–646 square matrices, 796–797 SRF (sample regression function), 31, 74 SSE (explained sum of squares), 37–38, 80–81 Index 877 SSR (residual sum of squares). See sum of squared residuals SST (total sum of squares), 37–38, 80–81 SSTj (total sample variation in xj), 94–95 stable AR(1) processes, 383–384 standard deviation of 􏱹ˆj, 101 defined, 51, 736 estimating, 56 properties of, 736 standard error of the regression (SER), 56, 100 standard errors asymptotic, 177–178 of 􏱹ˆ1, 56 of 􏱹ˆj, 101 heteroskedasticity-robust, 271–273 of OLS estimators, 99–101 serial correlation-robust, 431–434 standard normal distribution, 746–748, 831–832 standardized coefficients, 189–191 standardized random variables, 736 standardized test scores beta coefficients, 189 collinearity, 84–85 interaction effect, 199–200 motivation for multiple regression, 69, 70 omitted variable bias, 91 omitting unobservables, 315 residual analysis, 211–212 static models, 346, 386 static Phillips curve, 346, 355–356, 418, 428 stationary time series processes, 381–382 statistical inference with IV estimator, 517–521 for OLS in matrix form, 813–815 statistical significance defined, 129 economic/practical significance vs., 135–138, 788–789 joint, 148 statistical tables, 831–837 statistics. See also hypothesis testing asymptotic properties of estimators, 763–767 finite sample properties of estimators, 756–763 interval estimation and confidence intervals, 770–777 notation, 789–790 overview and definitions, 755–756 parameter estimation, general approaches to, 768–770 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 878 Index stepwise regression, 686 stochastic processes, 345, 381. See also time series data stock prices and trucking regulations, 359 stock returns, 438. See also efficient markets hypothesis (EMH) stratified sampling, 325–326 strict exogeneity assumption, 461, 468, 634 strict stationarity, 382 strictly exogenous variables serial correlation correcting for, 423–429 testing for, 416–423 in time series regressions, 351–352 strongly dependent time series. See highly persistent time series structural equations definitions, 524, 555, 556, 559 identifying and estimating, 560–566 student enrollment, t test, 131–132 student performance. See also college GPA; final exam scores; standardized test scores in math, lunch program and, 50 school expenditures and, 96–97 school size and, 127–128 studentized residuals, 328–329 style hints for empirical papers, 692–694 sum of squared residuals. See also OLS (ordinary least squares) minimizing, 66–67 in multiple regressions, 80–81 in simple regressions, 37–38 summation operator, 703–705 supply shock, 390 Survey of Consumer Finances, 679 symmetric matrices, 800 system estimation methods, 568 systematic part, defined, 26 T t distribution critical values table, 833 discussions, 121–122, 749–750, 751, 805 t statistics. See also t tests asymptotic, 177 defined, 122, 781 F statistic and, 149–150 heteroskedasticity-robust, 271–273. See also heteroskedasticity t tests. See also t statistics for AR(1) serial correlation, 416–418 null hypothesis, 122–123 one-sided alternatives, 123–128 other hypotheses about 􏱹j, 130–133 overview, 121–123 p-values for, 133–135 two-sided alternatives, 128–130 tables, statistical, 831–837 tax exemption. See under fertility rate T-bill rates cointegration, 646–647, 650 error correction model, 652 inflation, deficits, and. See under interest rates random walk characterization of, 393, 394 unit root test, 641 teachers, salary-pension tradeoff, 155–156 teenage motherhood, 499–500 tenure. See also wages interpreting equations, 76 motivation for multiple regression, 71–72 test scores, as indicators of ability, 534. See also college GPA; final exam scores; standardized test scores test statistics, 780 text files and editors, 680–681 theorems for 2SLS, 551–553 asymptotic efficiency of OLS, 182 asymptotic normality of OLS for multiple linear regressions, 175–178 for time series regressions, 387–391 consistency of OLS for multiple linear regressions, 169–171 for time series regressions, 384–387 Gauss-Markov for multiple linear regressions, 101–102, 116–117 for time series regressions, 352–354 normal sampling distributions, 120–121 for OLS in matrix form Gauss-Markov, 812 statistical inference, 814–815 unbiasedness, 813 variance-covariance matrix of OLS estimator, 811 sampling variances of OLS estimators for multiple linear regressions, 94, 116 for simple linear regressions, 53–54 for time series regressions, 352–354 t distribution for standardized estimators, 121–122 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. unbiased estimation of 􏱀2 for multiple linear regressions, 100–101 for simple linear regressions, 56 for time series regressions, 354 unbiasedness of OLS for multiple linear regressions, 87–88, 114–115 for simple linear regressions, 48–49 for time series regressions, 349–352 theoretical framework, 687 three stage least squares, 568 time series data. See also forecasting; panel data; pooled cross sections; serial correlation; trends absence of serial correlation, 399–401 applying 2SLS to, 538–540 cointegration, 646–651 dynamically complete models, 399–401 error correction models, 651–652 examples of models, 345–349 functional forms, 356–357 heteroskedasticity in, 434–439 highly persistent. See highly persistent time series homoskedasticity assumption for, 402 infinite distributed lag models, 633–639 nature of, 344–345 OLS. See under OLS (ordinary least squares); OLS estimators overview, 8–9 in panel data, 10–11 in pooled cross sections, 9–10 with qualitative information. See under qualitative information seasonality, 371–373 simultaneous equations models with, 568–572 spurious regression, 644–646 stationary and nonstationary, 381–382 unit roots, testing for, 639–644 weakly dependent, 382–384 time trends. See trends time-demeaned data, 485 time-varying error, 460 Tobit model interpreting estimates, 598–603 overview, 596–598 specification issues in, 603–604 top coding, 610 total sample variation in xj, 94–95 total sum of squares (SST), 37–38, 80–81 trace of matrix, 800 traffic fatalities beer taxes and, 205 Index 879 drunk driving laws and, 467–468 training grants. See also job training program evaluation, 254 single dummy variable, 233 transpose of matrix, 799–800 treatment group, 232 trends characterizing trending time series, 363–366 detrending, 368–370 forecasting, 662–667 high persistence vs., 394 R-squared and trending dependent variable, 370–371 seasonality and, 373 using trending variables, 366–368 trend-stationary processes, 384 trucking regulations and stock prices, 359 true model, defined, 83 truncated regression models, 609, 613–615 two stage least squares applied to pooled cross sections and panel data, 540–542 applied to time series data, 538–540 assumptions and theorems for, 551–553 with heteroskedasticity, 538 multicollinearity and, 530–531 multiple endogenous explanatory variables, 531 for SEM, 565–566, 568 single endogenous explanatory variable, 528–530 tesing multiple hypotheses after estimation, 532 testing for endogeneity, 534–535 testing overidentifying restrictions, 535–538 two-period panel data analysis, 459–465 policy analysis with, 465–468 two-sided alternatives, 780–783 two-tailed tests, 128, 782. See also t tests two-variable linear regression model. See simple regression model Type I/II error, 779 U u (“unobserved” term). See also regression analysis CEV assumption and, 323 foregoing specifying models with, 314–315 general discussions, 4–5, 23–25 in time series regressions, 351 using proxy variables for, 308–314 unanticipated inflation, 390 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. 880 Index unbalanced panels, 491–492 unbiased estimation of 􏱀2 for multiple linear regressions, 100–101 for simple linear regressions, 56 for time series regressions, 354 unbiasedness in general, 758–760 of OLS in matrix form, 810 in multiple regressions, 87–88, 114–115 in simple regressions, 45–50 in time series regressions, 349–352, 412–413 of 􏱀ˆ 2, 813 uncentered R-squareds, 237 unconditional forecasts, 654 uncorrelated random variables, 739 underspecifying the model, 88–92 unemployment. See employment and unemployment unidentified equations, 568 unit roots forecasting processes with, 665–666 process, 393, 395 testing for, 639–644 units of measurement, effects of changing, 40–41, 186–188 universities vs. junior colleges, 140–143 unobserved effects/heterogeneity, 460, 485. See also fixed effects “unobserved” terms. See u (“unobserved” term) unrestricted model, 145–146. See also F tests unsystematic part, defined, 26 upward bias, 91 utility maximization, 2–3 V VAR model, 657, 666–667 variables. See also dependent variables; independent variables; specific types dummy, 227. See also qualitative information in multiple regressions, 69–72 in simple regressions, 22–23 variance inflation factor (VIF), 98 variance of prediction error, 210 variance-covariance matrices, 803–804, 811 variances conditional, 744–745 of OLS estimators in multiple regressions, 93–101 in simple regressions, 50–56 in time series regressions, 352–354 overview and properties of, 734–735, 740–741 vector autoregressive model, 657, 666–667 vectors, defined, 797 veterans, earnings of, 521 voting outcomes campaign expenditures and deriving OLS estimate, 34 perfect collinearity, 85–86 economic performance and, 362–363 W wages. See also CEO salaries; income; minimum wages; women in labor force ability and. See ability and wage education and. See also subheading multiple regressions 2SLS, 542 causality, 13–14 conditional expectation, 741–742 heteroskedasticity, 52–53 independent cross sections, 451–453 logarithmic equation, 715 nonlinear relationship, 41–43 OLS estimates, 33–34 partial effect, 718 return to education, over time, 451–453 rounded averages, 37 scatterplot, 29 simple equation, 24 experience and. See under experience gender gap independent cross sections, 451–453 panel data, 451–453 with heteroskedasticity-robust standard errors, 272 labor supply and demand, 555–556 labor supply function, 715 multiple regressions. See also subheading with qualitative information beta coefficients, 189 homoskedasticity, 93 hypotheses with more than one parameter, 140–143 interpreting equations, 76 misspecified functional forms, 304 motivation for multiple regression, 69, 70 nonrandom sampling, 325, 326 normality assumption and, 120 null hypothesis, 122 Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. omitted variable bias, 89, 90–91, 92 quadratic functions, 194–196 random slope model, 316 reporting results, 155–156 t test, 125 with unobservables, general approach, 314–315 with unobservables, using proxy, 308–312 nominal vs. real, 360 productivity and, 398 quadratic function, 711–712 with qualitative information of baseball players, race and, 244–245 computer usage and, 241 with different slopes, 241–245 education and, 241–244 gender and, 228–231, 234–236, 241–244 with interacting terms, 241 law school rankings and, 239–240 with log(y) dependent variable, 234–235 marital status and, 235–236 with multiple dummy variables, 235–236 with ordinal variables, 238–240 physical attractiveness and, 238–239 random effects model, 494–495 working individuals in 1976, 6–7 Wald test/statistics, 588–589, 598, 818 weak instruments, 523 weakly dependent time series, 382–384 wealth. See financial wealth weighted least squares estimation Index 881 binary dependent variable, 249–251 heteroskedasticity, 294–296 LPM, logit, and probit estimates, 593–595 OLS and Tobit estimates, 601–603 return to education 2SLS, 530 IV estimation, 518–519 testing for endogeneity, 535 testing overidentifying restrictions, 537 sample selection correction, 619–620 SEM, 563–566 women’s fertility. See fertility rate worker compensation laws and weeks out of work, 458 worker productivity. See also scrap rates and job training job training and program evaluation, 254 sample model, 4 in U.S., trend in, 364 wages and, 398 working vs. sleeping, 463–465 working women. See women in labor force writing empirical papers, 686–694 Y year dummy variables in fixed effects model, 486–488 pooling independent cross sections across time, 449–453 in random effects model, 494–495 Z zero conditional mean assumption homoskedasticity vs., 51 for multiple linear regressions, 70–71, 86–87 for OLS in matrix form, 810 for simple linear regressions, 25–26, 47, 49 for time series regressions, 350–351, 385 zero mean and zero correlation assumption, 171 zero-one variables, 227. See also qualitative information linear probability model, 294–296 overview, 280–281 prediction and prediction intervals, 292–294 for time series regressions, 433, 437 when assumed heteroskedasticity function is wrong, 290–292 when heteroskedasticity function must be estimated, 286–290 when heteroskedasticity is known up to a multiplicative constant, 281–286 White test for heteroskedasticity, 279–280 within estimators, 485. See also fixed effects women in labor force Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it. Copyright 2012 Cengage Learning. All Rights Reserved. May not be copied, scanned, or duplicated, in whole or in part. Due to electronic rights, some third party content may be suppressed from the eBook and/or eChapter(s). Editorial review has deemed that any suppressed content does not materially affect the overall learning experience. Cengage Learning reserves the right to remove additional content at any time if subsequent rights restrictions require it.